China Soes Final

download China Soes Final

of 15

Transcript of China Soes Final

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    1/15

    Page 1 of15

    Chinas state-owned enterprises remain a drag on the economy during the reform era

    even though their efficiency might be improving, (World Bank 1996). Discuss.

    Introduction

    It is no doubt that Chinas state-owned industrial enterprises (SOEs) have fared poorly in

    comparison to non-SOEs during the reform era, with statistics available detailing the

    declining profitability endured by these firms. However, to proclaim they have been a drag on

    the economy without giving much thought into the changing nature of Chinas restructuring

    economy would be unreasonable. SOEs have performed far better than is conventionally

    held (Laurenceson and Chai, 2000; 24), despite having to pay higher taxes, wages, and

    increasing social welfare burdens compared to non-SOEs. Advocates of shock therapy or the

    big bang approach will disagree (Lo, 1999; 693), linking the weaker performance to

    institutions that conform less to market regulation and claim SOEs are not reformable. This

    paper will argue that SOEs have not been a drag on the economy as the World Bank has

    alleged in its 1996 report (World Bank, 1996; 23), but have performed remarkably well given

    their circumstances during Chinas reform era.

    SOEs by nature are enterprises owned and governed by the state. A significant discussion has

    centred around SOEs being inefficient and loss making, one when considering 44% of

    Chinese SOEs were loss-making enterprises in 1996 is difficult to contest (Bramall, 2000;

    394). Given that collectively owned enterprises (COEs) are mainly township and village

    enterprises (TVEs) run and influenced by local governments, the comparison between them

    and SOEs cannot justify private ownership is better (Lo, 1999; 695). These smaller firms are

    usually characterised by labour-intensive modes of production, due to the abundance of rural

    labour and with capital being expensive to deploy in such areas.

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    2/15

    Page 2 of15

    If one looks into the performance of large and medium size enterprises (LMEs), which have

    been at the heart of Chinas transformed Soviet-type economy you will see their performance

    has been comparable, if not better than COEs throughout the entire reform era accounting for

    46 percent of industrial output in 1993 (Lo,1999; 695). LMEs are overwhelmingly state-

    owned enterprises, but a question arises to why LMEs have been considered to be more

    successful than both SOEs and non-SOEs given their operations are less marketised and their

    institutions far less akin to private ownership (Lo, 1999; 694). To assess whether SOEs have

    been a drag on the economy we must venture into three important areas affecting their

    performance: profitability, productive efficiency and the restructuring of firms since 1978.

    Profitability

    Basic economy theory will tell us falling profitability is a serious issue for the competitive

    firm, even if these losses are subsidised by the state. During the reform era, both SOEs and

    non-SOEs have faced declining performance though greater focus has been given to SOEs.

    Financially SOEs outperformed COEs in the boom years of the 1980s, but were outperformed

    by COEs during the recession and subsequent rebound period in the 1990s (Lo, 1999; 696).

    During the downturn SOEs had incentives not to cut production, as a build up of inventory

    stock in the then accounting system would have proportionally cut the share of the wage bill

    and depreciation charges thereby boosting profits (Holz, 2003; 66).

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    3/15

    Page 3 of15

    Source: (Lo, 1999; 699)

    To be fair, the rapid rise of rural firms did not begin to erupt until after 1984 and the growth

    of their numbers bore into the monopoly profits enjoyed by SOEs and subsequently reduced

    profit margins (Bramall, 2000; 393). Naughton proposes it was this rise in competition from

    rural TVEs and COEs which contributed to the declining profitability of state-owned

    enterprises (Naughton, 2007; 275), and given in a perfectly competitive economy exit for

    non- profitable firms is easy, in Chinas context the exit ofSOEs was incredibly difficult

    (Holz, 2003; 164). New rural enterprises could enter product niches in which SOEs did not

    operate in, such as producing miscellaneous household goods including buttons, ribbons and

    plastic ID card holders as displayed by households in the Wenzhou region (Naughton, 2007;

    283).

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    4/15

    Page 4 of15

    Whilst credible, Naughtons argument has been opposed by Fan Gang , Wing-Thye Woo and

    Jeffrey Sachs who propose excessive labour remuneration is to blame (Holz, 2003; 96).

    They show in aggregate that total income rose faster than total net output (ibid), however

    with the emergence of new firms and the introduction of competitive policies, SOE managers

    would have had to keep wages competitive or else suffer a haemorrhage of skilled labour

    (Bramall, 2000; 391). Furthermore, the wages of workers would eventually be tied to

    enterprise performance.

    To simply ignore other costs such as tax and welfare a fair and accurate diagnosis cannot be

    made. COEs have enjoyed lower taxes and tax concessions throughout the reform era, as

    have firms in special economic zones, both paying 35 percent and 15 percent income tax

    prior to 1994 (Laurenceson and Chai, 2000; 33). Although 30 percent of TVE profits were

    channelled to local governments to support agriculture, this money was reinvested in rural

    enterprises as local governments knew they would make a return on their investments. SOEs

    on the other hand faced much higher tax obligations; 55 percent prior to 1994 (ibid). It should

    be noted before the tax reforms were implemented in the early 1990s, SOEs were obligated to

    hand over all profits to the state, and profit incentives did not come into force until the early

    1980s (Naughton, 2007; 304). Contribution to state revenue by SOEs and COEs was 71

    percent and 17 percent respectively in 1995, highlighting the tax inequality between the

    enterprises (Lo, 1999; 706). As a legacy of the planning system SOEs face high welfare

    burdens including providing housing, health insurance, disability insurance and pensions; an

    obligation not necessitated by rural enterprises (Qian and Weingast, 1997; 259). Pension

    payments in particular have been on the rise, increasing from 9bn Yuan in 1985 to a

    staggering 60bn in 1995, equivalent to 12 percent and 90 percent of their after-tax profits

    respectively (Lo, 1999; 706).

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    5/15

    Page 5 of15

    Private firms will generally avoid venturing into industries where profitability is low, such as

    the energy sector in Chinese industry. In sectors such as coal mining, petroleum extraction

    and electricity output prices were kept administratively low by the state, as these outputs

    would act as inputs for other sectors. The lions share (Cheng and Lo, 2002; 421) of losses

    endured by SOEs was concentrated in this sector, accounting for 83 percent of total losses in

    1986, 80 percent in 1990 and 72 percent in 1995. Although productivity may have been high,

    profits could not be increased due to the state-set prices. One cannot simply overlook this fact

    and ascertain that SOEs are inherently unprofitable, because if output prices in this sector

    were set at market prices, then inputs in other sectors would have been much higher,

    producing uncompetitive firms.

    Neoclassical economists will argue fixed prices distort the optimal allocation of resources and

    do not reflect the level of scarcity in an economy (Laurenceson, 2000; 23), though fixed

    prices in China have allowed inflation to remain relatively low. A surge in inflation did occur

    in 1988, at the cause of market-price implementation which would have caused demand to

    fall and real income to decline; this led to a policy of macroeconomic contraction which then

    adversely affected profits and productivity (Bramall, 2000; 390).

    Profitability by itself cannot explain the worsening performance of state-owned enterprises

    during the reform era, nor can it dig into the changing productivity of firms throughout this

    period which we now look into.

    Productive efficiency

    SOEs are said to be less efficient than COEs and TVEs, with their share of industrial output

    falling to 33 percent in 1996 from 77 percent in 1978, whilst the TVE share of output rose

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    6/15

    Page 6 of15

    from 9 percent to 28 percent in the same period (Naughton, 2007; 300). By having the state

    subsidise losses and finance investment, SOEs could afford to be lacklustre in their

    productivity habits, unlike rural enterprises that had to compete to survive in an ever growing

    atmosphere. However, enterprise loss subsidies have been falling throughout the reform era

    accounting for only 0.5 percent of GDP in 1996 (Lo, 1999; 702) indicating performance has

    been improving.

    Source: (Lo, 1999; 702)

    To analyse changes in productivity growth we look into changes in total factor productivity

    (TFP), a residual we can obtain from the Cobb Douglas function:

    a = q - l (1-)k,

    where a represents TFP and and (1-) the elasticity of labour and capital respectively. Lo

    estimates TFP growth for SOEs to have been 1.49 percent between 1980-1886, and 3.6

    percent for COEs in the same period when =0.4 (ibid; 699).

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    7/15

    Page 7 of15

    Source: (Lo, 1999; 700)

    Laurenceson and Chai have graphed the changing patterns of TFP of SOEs over the course of

    reform along with total price performance (TFP), with the results showing a rising trend in

    TFP but a decline in TPP, indicating a worsening of the terms of trade for SOEs due to input

    prices from agriculture being high and many output prices being low (Laurenceson and Chai,

    2000; 31).

    Source: (Laurenceson and Chai, 2000; 32)

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    8/15

    Page 8 of15

    One explanation for the slower rise in TFP can be attributed to the fact that many SOEs

    corporatized following the introduction of Company Law in 1994, thus changing their

    enterprise category and leaving inefficient firms behind in the SOE category. However the

    shareholding sector experienced declining TFP, at an average rate of 7.96% per annum

    between 1993-1996 (Jefferson, et.al, 200; 13), quite surprising due to their nature as profit-

    seeking enterprises. Furthermore, some TFP growth can be credited to accelerated technical

    progress in the 1980s, and through technology transfers through FDI which expanded after

    1992 (Bramall, 2000; 237) causing a rise in capital productivity in SOEs of 7.72 percent

    between 1992-1996 (Jefferson et.al, 2000; 8). As firms were restructuring their enterprises,

    many formed joint-ventures with foreign firms who then invested and transferred new capital

    into China. Foreign firms were encouraged to invest in China with intellectual property rights

    incentives if production and technology were transferred (Naughton, 2007; 360). Although

    rural enterprises enjoy greater property rights over collective land, TVE property rights have

    been viewed as fuzzy (ibid; 121) given the complexity of land-use negotiations.

    Rural enterprises were able to absorb surplus labour, and were free to relieve workers if their

    contributions were not providing much value. In contrast, as many SOEs predate back to the

    planned era in where employment was preferred over profitability; state-industrial workers

    were offered permanent contracts and could not be laid off during downturns or periods of

    falling demand (Laurenceson, 2000; 29). Thus in the economic downturn of 1988-92 labour

    productivity fell, but began to rise across all sectors during the decade as corporatisation

    allowed firms to lay off redundant workers, growing at 8.5 percent for SOEs between 1992-

    1996 and 18.81 percent for COEs (Jefferson et.al, 2000; 9). SOE capital productivity too

    suffered similar declines in the downturn, averaging 3.42 percent per annum in the downturn,

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    9/15

    Page 9 of15

    but rose to 7.72 percent between 1992-96; with their profit-to-capital ratio being close to that

    of COEs (Lo, 1999; 694).

    Source: (Lo, 1999; 698)

    One advantage state-owned enterprises enjoyed over their rural competitors was the fact that

    they were able to benefit from soft budget constraints, with 62 percent of fixed investment

    being funded by the government in 1978 (Naughton, 2007; 305) though this figure dropped to

    a mere 3 percent in 1997. The state soon stopped lending to banks but carried on asking for

    remittances, and the only source of finance for enterprises were now banks which had been

    broken up into central and four large smaller banks (Holz, 2003; 62). Borrowing from banks

    was an incentive to increase efficiency, though in practise many banks lent on the request of

    local politicians and planners rather than commercial viability (ibid). In contrast, TVEs and

    COEs faced a hard budget constraint. They did not have access to state finance, but relied on

    finance from rural credit cooperatives (RCCs), who were funded from household savings

    (Qian and Weingast, 1997; 259). Household savings began to grow along with the rapid rise

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    10/15

    Page 10 of15

    of rural enterprises, and with it loans increased because deposits increased (Naughton, 2007;

    279). Harder budget constraints simply contributed to greater incentives for non-SOEs to

    increase their profitability; else they would of course go out of business.

    Restructuring

    The pre-reform era was characterised by central planning and fixed prices, neither of which

    would deem practical to neoclassical economists. However, the 1980s would see many

    reforms be implemented to provide greater incentives for SOEs to improve their productivity

    and profitability, in order to become more competitive with the rising trend of rural

    enterprises.

    Pilot reforms in the 1980s and the Company Law act in the early 1990s sought to turn

    enterprises into profit-seeking firms, and paved way for the restructuring of

    organisations.(Lin and Zhu, 2001; 310). Under the modern enterprise system SOEs

    transformed into limited liability and limited liability stock companies, employee-

    shareholding co-operative and private enterprises, the latter being the least favourite with

    only 7 percent of restructured SOEs choosing this option according to an industrial survey

    carried out in 1998 (ibid; 321).

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    11/15

    Page 11 of15

    Source: (Lin and Zhu, 2001; 323)

    For the limited companies, assets would be divided into shares and sold internally and

    externally, with limited liability stock companies being allowed to enlist on the stock

    exchanges. The number of industrial SOEs shrank from 120,000 in the mid 1990s to 31,750

    in 2004 (Naughton, 2007; 313), and with it the proportion of loss-making SOEs have fallen

    but non-SOEs have gone up (Cheng and Lo, 2002; 421). Better performance has come about

    through greater pressures slapped onto managers who now report to the board of directors,

    albeit they are still chosen or appointed by members of the state. But then why have profits

    been falling despite this drive for profit-seeking? Many firms were heavily indebted and had

    surplus personnel which they simply could not lay off easily, giving rise to Nicholas Lardys

    argument that it is this high liability-to-asset ratio which is the cause of loss making (Cheng

    and Lo, 2002; 421). Though the debt problem was alleviated somewhat by banks lowering

    interests rates seven times between 1996-1999 reducing SOE obligation in interest payments

    by 250bnYuan (Lin and Zhu, 2001; 337).

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    12/15

    Page 12 of15

    Profit incentives introduced in the early 1980s were accompanied with the dual-track price

    system. Managers could retain a portion of the profits earned by the enterprise should quota

    targets be met (Naughton, 2007, 311) and these profits would be paid out in bonuses to

    managers and employees, causing a concern for the state council who levied a progressive

    bonus tax in 1984 (Holz, 2003; 78). Greater autonomy in price setting was given to

    enterprises and managers were given greater latitude in setting wages for workers, which

    were later linked to profits (Yusuf, 2006; 56); giving rise to criticism that excessive wages

    have caused falling profitability. No longer would workers be offered permanent employment

    but rather 5 year contracts would be the new method (Bramall, 2000; 391). TVEs have also

    privatised during the reform era mainly in 1995-6, with many closing down due to

    inefficiency or increased competition both domestically and abroad (Naughton, 2007; 271).

    Conclusion

    This paper has attempted to counter the argument that SOEs have remained a drag on the

    Chinese economy throughout the reform era, despite improvements in efficiency. The

    performance of SOEs to non-SOEs has been close, despite having to pay higher taxes, wages

    and welfare contributions, whilst having to remit all profits back to the state until later

    reforms were implemented.

    SOEs located in the energy industries were subject to keeping output prices low, so that other

    sectors in the economy could benefit from cheaper inputs; this of course contributed to lower

    profitability but labour productivity in these sectors has remained high. Labour productivity

    has risen in the state sector, albeit through the policy reforms carried out in the 1980s causing

    firms to be more profit-seeking (Cheng and Lo, 2002; 418). A shift towards market prices has

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    13/15

    Page 13 of15

    taken place, and although earlier efforts resulted in a rise in inflation, later efforts have been

    much smoother.

    The comparison of SOEs to non-SOEs is biased against SOEs. The average performance of

    SOEs is poor because the worst performing SOEs are not allowed to exit in large numbers

    whereas some of the best performing SOEs prior to 1998 restructured into companies or joint

    ventures (Holz, 2003; 164). This paper has confined the analysis to three areas: profitability,

    productive efficiency and restructuring, but one must go beyond competition and ownership

    analysis to determine how best to solve the paradox of declining profitability and increasing

    efficiency (Jefferson, et.al 2000; 16) if China is to set a concrete example of successful

    economic development for other developing countries to follow.

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    14/15

    Page 14 of15

    Bibliography

    Bramall, C. (2000), Sources of Chinese Economic Growth 1978-1996, (New York: Oxford

    University Press)

    Cheng, Y.-S. and Lo, D.(2002) Explaining the financial performance of Chinas industrial

    enterprises: beyond the competition-ownership controversy, The China Quarterly,

    no.170: 413-440.

    Holz, C.A. (2003), Chinas Industrial State-Owned Enterprises: Between Profitability and

    Bankruptcy, (Singapore: World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd)

    Jefferson, G.H., T.G. Rawski, L. Wang and Y. Zheng (2000) Ownership, productivity

    change, and financial performance in Chinese industry, Journal of Comparative

    Economics, 28: 786-813.

    Laurenceson, J. and J.C.H. Chai (2000) The economic performance of Chinas state -owned

    industrial enterprises,Journal of Contemporary China, 9 (23): 21-39.

    Lin, Y.-M. and T. Zhu (2001) Ownership restructuring in Chinese state industry: an analysis

    of evidence on initial organizational changes,The China Quarterly, 166: 305-41.

    Lo, D. (1999) Re-appraising the performance of Chinas state-owned industrial enterprises,

    1980-96, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 23 (6): 693-718.

    Naughton, B. (2007) The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth, (Cambridge and

    London: MIT Press).

    Qian, Y. and B.R. Weingast (1997) Institutions, state activism, and economic development:

    a comparison of state-owned and township-village enterprises in China, ch.9, in M. Aoki,

  • 8/3/2019 China Soes Final

    15/15

    Page 15 of15

    H.-K. Kim and M. Okuno-Fujiwara (2006) The Role of Government in East Asian

    Economic Development(Oxford: OUP).

    Smyth, R., J. Wang, and Q.L. Kiang (2001) Efficiency, performance and changing corporate

    governance in Chinas township-village enterprises since the 1990s, Asian-Pacific

    Economic Literature, 30-41.

    Yusuf, S. Nabeshima, K and Perkins, D. (2006), Under New Ownership: Privatizing Chinas

    State-Owned Enterprises, (Washington: Stanford University Press and the World Bank)