University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent...

17
1 23 Environmental and Resource Economics The Official Journal of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists ISSN 0924-6460 Volume 61 Number 1 Environ Resource Econ (2015) 61:71-85 DOI 10.1007/s10640-013-9739-7 The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels: Achieving Conservation Objectives Through Understanding the Behavior of Fishing Vessels Marc Mangel, Natalie Dowling & Juan Lopez Arriaza

Transcript of University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent...

Page 1: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

1 23

Environmental and ResourceEconomicsThe Official Journal of the EuropeanAssociation of Environmental andResource Economists ISSN 0924-6460Volume 61Number 1 Environ Resource Econ (2015) 61:71-85DOI 10.1007/s10640-013-9739-7

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels:Achieving Conservation ObjectivesThrough Understanding the Behavior ofFishing Vessels

Marc Mangel, Natalie Dowling & JuanLopez Arriaza

Page 2: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

1 23

Your article is protected by copyright and all

rights are held exclusively by Springer Science

+Business Media Dordrecht. This e-offprint

is for personal use only and shall not be self-

archived in electronic repositories. If you wish

to self-archive your article, please use the

accepted manuscript version for posting on

your own website. You may further deposit

the accepted manuscript version in any

repository, provided it is only made publicly

available 12 months after official publication

or later and provided acknowledgement is

given to the original source of publication

and a link is inserted to the published article

on Springer's website. The link must be

accompanied by the following text: "The final

publication is available at link.springer.com”.

Page 3: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

Environ Resource Econ (2015) 61:71–85DOI 10.1007/s10640-013-9739-7

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels: AchievingConservation Objectives Through Understandingthe Behavior of Fishing Vessels

Marc Mangel · Natalie Dowling · Juan Lopez Arriaza

Accepted: 29 October 2013 / Published online: 15 November 2013© Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2013

Abstract Colin Clark made seminal contributions in both resource economics and behav-ioral ecology. In the former, he showed how to link biological and economic factors ina consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco-nomics single-handedly. In the latter, he was a major contributor of the introduction of statevariable methods for modeling the behavior and life history of organisms. In this paper, weapply the methods of behavioral ecology to a problem in fisheries management and showthat understanding fisher responses to quota decrements according to fishing area (so thatthe decrement in the quota of effort from fishing in a particular area is larger than the actualeffort used there) may be as or more effective for seabird conservation than closing areas. Tobegin, we explain state variable methods in behavioral ecology, using insect parasitoids—Colin’s choice of after dinner talk at the meeting in his honor—making connections betweenbehavioral ecology and resource economics. We then turn to the pelagic longline fishery offeastern Australia and show how the same kinds of methods used in behavioral ecology canprovide new insights about this fishery. We provide a model of sufficient detail to comparethe current management practice (closures), no management, and spatial management witheffort decrements that vary over space and show that the latter management strategy is bothenvironmentally and economically more effective than closures or no management.

M. Mangel (B) · J. L. ArriazaCenter for Stock Assessment Research and Department of Applied Mathematics and Statistics,University of California, Santa Cruz, CA, USAe-mail: [email protected]

J. L. Arriazae-mail: [email protected]

M. MangelDepartment of Biology, University of Bergen, 9020 Bergen, Norway

N. DowlingCSIRO Marine and Atmospheric Research, Castray Esplanade, Hobart 7001, Tasmaniae-mail: [email protected]

123

Author's personal copy

Page 4: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

72 M. Mangel et al.

Keywords Bioeconomics · Behavioral ecology · State dependence ·Stochastic dynamic programming · Fisheries

1 Introduction

In 1973, Colin Clark published a paper in Science Clark (1973) that fundamentally changedthe way people thought about the management of natural resources. He did so with a simplemodel that was not ‘realistic’, i.e. it did not capture every operational, biological, or economicdetail and did not pertain to a particular fishery, although it had much in common withmany fisheries. Among other things, the 1973 paper showed that it could be economicallyoptimal (i.e. rational) to drive a renewable resource to extinction, whichmany people believedwas impossible. In 1976, Colin expanded those ideas in his seminal textbook MathematicalBioeconomics, which nowhasmore than 4,000 citations andwhich appeared in a fully revisedthird edition in 2010 (when Colin was 79years old!).Happy Birthday Colin!

In the early 1980s, as Colin and one of us tried to understand the behavior of fishingvessels (Mangel and Clark 1983) we were led to think about problems of animal behavior,first foraging (Clark and Mangel 1984, 1986; Mangel and Clark 1986) but then a wide arrayof topics (Fig. 1; Mangel and Clark 1988; Clark and Mangel 2000). After making manycontributions to behavioral ecology from the mid 1980s until the early twenty-first century,Colin returned to fisheries, publishing a new book (Clark 2006) and revising his classic bookas mentioned above.

In bioeconomics and behavioral ecology, Colin has taught the virtues of clear thinkingand careful writing. Simple models are not ‘realistic’, but then, of course, no science is orcan be. That is, simple models cannot, by their nature, capture all the details of a particularnatural, economic, or operational system. But if they are good, simple models can capturethe essence of many such systems and thus help us learn about them, to the point that

Fig. 1 A Colin Clark and Marc Mangel discussing dynamic modeling in behavioral ecology (Mangel andClark 1988) in Whytham Woods, Oxford, in the spring of 1988. In this book, we explained to biologists thatstochastic dynamic modeling via stochastic dynamic programming was accessible to nearly everyone.BClarkand Mangel going over the penultimate version of Clark and Mangel (2000) in Kona, Hawaii, in the summerof 1998. The objective of the latter book was to make it clear that the methods had wide application, muchbroader than just behavioral ecology and including problems in fisheries and resource management

123

Author's personal copy

Page 5: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 73

sometimes afterwards we do not need the models at all—the golden rule of bioeconomicsrelating discount rate and maximum per capita growth rate (Clark 1976; Mangel et al. 1998)is a beautiful example of this.

In this paper, we elaborate on the messages of Colin’s career, in particular to show behav-ioral responses of fishers to regulation can be used to achieve conservation goals (e.g. reducingby-catch) more effectively than classical measures such as closing areas to fishing. We begindiscussing insect parasitoids—a seemingly strange topic for a paper about fisheries but oneon which Colin chose to speak at the dinner separating the 2days of meetings in honor ofhis 80th birthday, and which will provide a gateway to using state dependent life historymodeling (dynamic state variable models) as implemented by stochastic dynamic program-ming (Mangel and Clark 1988; Mangel and Ludwig 1992; Houston and McNamara 1999;Clark and Mangel 2000). We then turn to the pelagic longline fishery off eastern Australiaand show how the methods from behavioral ecology can be applied to gain new insightsabout the effectiveness of spatial management.

2 Insect Parasitoids at a Conference Called “Developments and Challengesin Fisheries Economics”?

Colin was asked to give the after-dinner talk at the meeting and began by noting that lifeis dynamic and variable, so that dynamic, stochastic models are needed, and that averag-ing models can be misleading, even though it is often easy to derive elegant mathematicalresults from them. He then asked the question: ‘But dynamic, stochastic behavioral modelsare extremely complex, right?’, answered ‘Not necessarily’ and then proceeded to explaina simple model for insect parasitoids (which deposit their eggs on or in the eggs, larvae,or adults of other insects, called hosts, and whose offspring use the resources of thosehosts to fuel development), which he called ‘Parasitoid Economics 101’. This may seema strange choice to resource economists, so we pause and explain a bit about parasitoids here,because they help illustrate how to think about stochastic, dynamic problems in resourceeconomics.

Resource economists are generally familiar with the method of Stochastic Dynamic Pro-gramming (SDP), most likely through the famous Linear-Quadratic-Gaussian (LQG) systemfor which we assume linear state dynamics, a quadratic cost function, and normally dis-tributed stochasticity. In such a case, analytical results are obtained in a relatively directmanner (Mangel 1985) assuming that one can solve a Ricatti differential equation. However,state dynamics are often non-linear, costs are not quadratic, and stochastic factors are notGaussian. What to do then? One choice is to make assumptions about the system that force itinto the LQG framework, for example by assuming that we are not too far from steady stateso that Taylor expansions for the dynamics and cost apply and that the central limit theoremguarantees approximate normality. An alternative is to seek special cases in which analyticalsolutions can be found (e.g. Dixit and Pindyck 1994).

In the mid-1980s, it became clear that SDP could provide enormous insight into the endpoints of evolution by natural selection, andwas a natural framework for linking physiologicalstate and environment within a Darwinian framework. That is, natural and sexual selectionact to optimize from available variants, which are products of previous optimization events(Thompson 2013). SDP is the most appropriate way to formally analyze the outcomes ofliving systems at any point in evolutionary history. However, in general, the assumptions ofthe LQG or analytically tractable SDP models do not apply to living organisms.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 6: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

74 M. Mangel et al.

Colin chose insect parasitoids as an example because some of the models are simpleenough to be well-suited for an after-dinner discussion; details about them can be foundin Mangel and Clark (1988), Clark and Mangel (2000), and Mangel (2006). He used thetime after dinner to explain how such a model is constructed, based on four key features. Wedescribe them here in the context of insect parasitoids, hoping that the reader will find suchwonderful animals at least a little bit interesting. In the next section, we make the translationto the pelagic longline fishery off eastern Australia.

The EnvironmentOrganisms—and fishing vessels—respond to the environment, so it must be described. In thecase of insect parasitoids the environment is characterized by the rate of encounter with hostsof different kinds (pay-offs from laying eggs in them described below) and by the rate ofmortality experienced by the parasitoid. For example, hosts might vary in size, thus providingdifferent levels of resource to the offspring and the rate of mortality may vary in time or withhost type, determined by the suite of predators present.

Physiological State and Its DynamicsMany insects are born with all of their eggs already matured, so that a natural state variable isthe number of eggs a female harbors at the current time. If a female encounters a host and layseggs, then her state is reduced by the number of eggs laid. In other cases (see Mangel 2006;Ch. 4 for more details) females mature new eggs as life progresses, so the physiological stateis characterized by both the number of mature eggs she currently harbors and the number offuture potential eggs that she can make. In each period of time, the number of mature eggsis decremented by the size of the clutch laid and increased by the number of potential eggsmatured and in the simplest case the number of potential eggs declines by the number ofeggs matured. In other cases, females may acquire resources (protein, fat, carbohydrate) byfeeding in the environment and convert these resources to potential eggs, which are turnedinto mature eggs at some time later (Clark and Mangel 2000; Ch 4).

The Fitness Increment and Lifetime FitnessBiology iswell-suited for economic thinking because there is a natural pay-off from behavior:the representation of genes in future generations. Often, a proxy is used and in the case ofinsect parasitoids, this proxy is most effectively the expected number of grand offspring(Mangel and Clark 1988; Clark and Mangel 2000; Mangel 2006). That is, the number ofmature eggs a female can hold is generally determined by her size, and her size is determinedoften by the number of other eggswithwhomshe had to share the host inwhich she developed.Thus, encounter with a single host produces a fitness metric determined by the number ofeggs the focal parasitoid lays in that host, which determines the size of her offspring, whichdetermines the number of eggs that her female offspring can lay.

The behavioral problem to be modeled is then: when a female encounters a host of acertain type, how do we predict the number of eggs laid in this host, taking into account theincrement in fitness from this host and all future fitness, given that her physiological statechanges and that mortality discounts future expected reproductive success? The equations ofSDP allow us to formalize this question mathematically and derive many predictions—bothquantitative and qualitative—that both can be tested empirically and provide insight into thebiological world.

Thinking, Analysis, and Numerical ImplementationThe description we just gave is sufficient to derive an equation of SDP and in doing so oneis forced to think deeply about the biology. Often, some kinds of preliminary analysis canbe conducted on the model. However, and especially in the twenty-first century, numerical

123

Author's personal copy

Page 7: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 75

solution of the SDP equation can provide exceptional insight—both qualitative patterns anddetailed numerical predictions. Furthermore, in a world in which every researcher has accessto incredibly powerful computing, the limitation that numerical methods are required for SDPis mitigated by the ability to conduct sensitivity analyses and through them develop the samekinds of intuition that mathematical analysis often provides. Indeed, as noted in Mangel andClark (1988) and Clark and Mangel (2000), very often the intuition from a numerical modelcan be so powerful that one no longer needs the model to understand the phenomenon. Andthat, of course, is what we are aiming for—understanding of the world.

3 A Behavioral Model for Pelagic Longline Fishing Vessels off Eastern Australia

3.1 Overview

The Eastern Tuna and Billfish Fishery (ETBF) operates in the boundary current off the eastof Australia from the tip of Cape York to the South Australia-Victoria border. Fishers inthe ETBF target top-level predators, with a total catch of around 6,500 tonnes annually.Principal target species include yellowfin tuna (Thunnus albacares, Scombridae), albacoretuna (Thunnus alalunga, Scombridae), and broadbill swordfish (Xiphias gladius, Xiphidae).The fishery interacts with threatened species of seabirds, turtles and sharks, and with thesouthern bluefin tuna commercial and striped marlin recreational fisheries; by-catch of thesespecies typically occurs in distinct spatial regions (Hartog et al. 2011; Trebilco et al. 2010;Griffiths et al. 2010). The ETBF is therefore an ideal case study for spatial management.

Recent modifications to the ETBFmanagement plan allow for the use of spatial incentivesas an alternative to closures, which are currently used tomanage the fishery. Themanagementplan based on spatial incentives allows for the reduction of annual effort allocations to oper-ators in response to their fishing locations. For instance, fishing in a sensitive area could leadto a higher rate of reduction of the operator’s remaining effort quota. We evaluated whetherthe behavioral responses of the fishing fleet to effort incentives would result in a reductionin fishing-induced mortality of threatened seabird species.

Dowling et al. (2012) used SDPmodels of the form described above to predict how spatialincentives will affect fisher rent and location choice. They modeled a single species fisherywith three vessel types operating out of two ports (mimicking the major ports of Mooloolaba,Queensland, and Sydney, New South Wales). Here, we review the salient features of thatmodel, generalize it to multi species, and present new results, emphasizing how it can beused for conservation. In doing so, we show how the methods developed by Colin and othersfor behavioral ecology have direct application in resource economics.

3.2 The Environment

We assume the abundance of fish of species s in region with latitude i longitude j at day t ofthe current fishing season, Ni, j (t, s), (Table 1) is given exogenously and is constant withinany quarter of the fishing season, changing between quarters as the empirical data indicate(Dowling et al. 2012). We inferred the spatial distribution of the stock from standardizedcatch-per-unit-effort proxies, derived using a Generalized LinearModel (GLM) that includedyear, quarter, location, the SouthernOscillation Index,moon phase, the use of light sticks, baittype, and time of setting as explanatory variables. TheGLMstandardized for the confoundingeffects of environmenland targeting practice, to obtain seasonal abundances.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 8: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

76 M. Mangel et al.

Table 1 Variables in the model and their interpretation

Variable Interpretation Nominal value (units or unitless)

Environment

s Species Yellowfin or albacore tuna,broadbill swordfish

i, j Latitude and longitude Varies

Di, j Distance from port to cell (i, j) Varies

t Time within the fishing season t = 1 to t = 120 = T (days)

Ni, j (t, s) Abundance of fish of species s in region withlatitude i longitude j at day t

Constant within quartersstatistically determined

q(t) Catchability on day t within the season Equation 2

Vessel characteristics

v Vessel speed v = 667, 356, or 356 (km/day)

xmax Maximum number of longlineshots available to a vessel ina single fishing trip

xmax = 26, 20, or 17

Emax Maximum number of longlineshots allocated to a vesselin a the fishing season

Emax = 100

ρ Unit cost of travel in the fishing season ρ = 3, 2, or 1.4 ($AUD/km)

k Targeting strategy for species mix Table 2

r(k, s) The proportional of species obtainedwith targeting strategy k

Table 2

State dynamics

E(t) Effort remaining at the start of period t Equation 2

x Shots deployed on the current trip Decision variable

δi, j Effort multiplier in cell (i, j) δi, j = 1, 1.66, or 3

Components of the SDP

p(t, s) Unit price of landed species s at time t Equation 6

V (t, s) Total volume V (t, s) ofspecies-specific landings

Model output

p̄ Mean species-specific priceacross the season

Model output

V̄s Mean species-specific catchper trip across the season

Model output

f Price flexibility parameter f = 0.1

pb(t) Price used in the solution of the SDP Model output

pc(t) Price generated in forwardsimulation based on the SDP

Model output

S Metric for stabilization of price Equation 7

cb The cost of laying a singleshot for vessel type b

500, 400 or 200 ($AUD)

πi, j,k (t, x, b, h) The rent associated with setting x shots inregion (i, j), for vessel type b operatingout of port h using targeting strategy k

Equation 3

F(e, T | b, h) Maximum expected rent accumulatedbetween the current time t and the end ofthe season, T , for vessel type b operatingout of port h given that E(t) = e

Equations 4, 5

123

Author's personal copy

Page 9: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 77

Dowling et al. (2012) assumed that catchability was a spatially ubiquitous, given by

q(t) = 0.1 sin(0.2t) + 1 (1)

to approximate moon phase, consistent with the ETBF operators actively targeting swordfisharound the full moon (Campbell andHobday 2003). Thus one full cycle of catchability occursapproximately every 30days across a 120day season.

For simplicity, here we assume no risk to going fishing. This assumption is lifted and itsimplications explored in Dowling et al. (2013).

3.3 Vessel Characteristics

This fishery is regulated by a quota system in which each vessel receives an allocation oflongline shots at the start of the season. A longline shot comprises one set and haul of thelongline gear. We assume that the number of hooks is constant for any shot, meaning that theeffort quota could alternatively be allocated in terms of hooks.

The maximum number of shots for a trip is a fixed quantity set by vessel capacity. Sinceone shot typically takes 1day to complete, lower-capacity vessels with shorter maximumtrip durations have a corresponding lower maximum number of longline shots that can beundertaken during a trip. We assume that there are three kinds of vessels, characterized bythe velocity of the vessel (km/day), v; the maximum number of longline shots xmax availableto a vessel in a single fishing trip; the maximum number of shots per season allocated to eachvessel, Emax (which we assume to be the same for all vessel types); and the unit travel costper vessel, ρ (Table 1 for detailed values).

3.4 The State Variable and Its Dynamics

For the state variable, we choose the number of longline shots remaining at any given day inthe fishing season, denoted by E(t) (to remind us that it is remaining effort).

We determine the dynamics of effort as follows. Imagine that a vessel with speed v forwhich E(t) = e travels to cell (i, j) at distance Di, j from port. Even before doing any fishing,

this travel requires time2Di, j

v. Once on the fishing ground, deploying x shots requires x days.

Thus, a trip to cell (i, j) in which x shots are deployed requires time2Di, j

v+ x . For example,

a 12-day trip may involve 4days of travel on which no fishing occurs, and 8days of fishingactivity. The vessel is then able to commence a new trip on the 13thday after the start of atrip on day t . Consequently, time is incremented non-uniformly.

In order to capture spatial management, we assume that fishing in some locations leadsto decrements in remaining effort that are greater than the actual number of shots used. Wecall this the effort decrement multiplier and denote it by δi, j . In a cell where δi, j = 1 layingx shots reduces remaining effort by x . In a cell where δi, j > 1 using x shots reduces effortby an amount larger than the actual number of shots laid. Thus, for a vessel that has currentremaining effort e and lays x shots in cell (i, j), the remaining number of shots at the end ofthe trip will be e − δi, j x .

Combining these arguments about time and state shows that conditioned on where thevessel fishes and the number of shots laid

E

(t + 2Di, j

v+ x

)= E(t) − δi, j x (2)

In order to determine fishing location and effort, we require the SDP formulation andcalculation, but before doing so need to consider targeting strategy.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 10: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

78 M. Mangel et al.

Table 2 Relative proportions ofeach species, comprising sixtargeting strategies, rounded to 2decimal places

Cluster number Yellowfin tuna Albacore Broadbill swordfish

1 0.04 0.94 0.02

2 0.92 0.05 0.03

3 0.34 0.55 0.10

4 0.12 0.11 0.77

5 0.13 0.44 0.43

6 0.37 0.24 0.39

3.5 Interlude: A Third Decision

Thus far, we have framed the decisions facing the fisher as (1) where to fish among the areasinto which the fishery is divided (with remaining in port also being an option) and (2) howmany shots to lay once location is determined. However, as we have described earlier, this isa multi species fishery and different targeting strategies yield different proportions of species,r(k, s) (Table 2). The targeting strategies in Table 2 were determined by a cluster analysisof log-book data. Here, we assume that they are fixed, in that once on the fishing groundand given an abundance level of Ni, j (t, s), the third decision is which of the six targetingstrategies (denoted by k) to use.

3.6 The Increment in Economic Rent and Accumulated Rent

To determine the increment in rent from a single trip, conditioned on location, targetingstrategy and number of shots laid, we also require species-specific unit price for landed fishof species s at time t, p(t, s) (described below in more detail) , and the cost per shot forvessel type b, cb (Table 1).

Then the rent associated with setting x shots in region (i, j), for vessel type b operatingout of port h, using targeting strategy k, πi, j,k(t, x, b, h), is

πi, j,k(t, x, b, h) =∑s

[p(t, s) · r(k, s) · q(t, s) · Ni, j (t, s) · x] − ρb · Di, j − cb · x (3)

We let F(e, T | b, h) denote themaximum expected accumulated rent between the currenttime t and the end of the season for each vessel type b operating out of port h given thatE(t) = e. Assuming that the last trip can commence at time T , we have the end condition

F(e, T | b, h) = maxi, j,k;x≤e

{πi, j,k(T, x, b, h)

}(4)

If the maximizing value of x = 0, the vessel stays in port.For preceding times, F(e, t | b, h) satisfies the dynamic programming equation

F(e, t | b, h) = maxi, j,k;x≤e

{πi, j,k(t, x, b, h) + F

(e − δi, j x, t + 2Di, j

vb+ x | b, h

)}(5)

where F(e − δi, j x, t + 2Di, j

vb+ x | b, h

)is the cumulative future rent, accumulated after

the current trip. As we solve Eq. 5 backwards in time, we determine, conditioned on theeffort remaining at time t , the optimal fishing region (i∗(e, t), j∗(e, t)), the optimal targetingstrategy k∗(e, t), and the optimal number of shots x∗(e, t) to yield themaximum accumulatedrent from the current plus all future trips.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 11: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 79

Once Eq. 5 is solved, forward projections allow us to calculate the total remaining effort,the accumulated value, the location choice associated with each trip, and the by-catch effectson other species all depending upon the characteristics of the vessels. That is, we spec-ify a number of vessels following the behavioral rules generated by Eq. 5. Each vessel ischaracterized by home port and size. The rules determined by Eq. 5 allow us to predictwhere the vessel will go during the season, which combination of stocks it will target,and how its effort will be decremented. The solution of Eq. 5 is not a simulation; ratherit is the numerical solution of an equation for which analysis would otherwise be verylimited.

3.7 The Dynamics of Price as an Internal Game

Dowling et al. (2012) showed how to determine the dynamics of price, p(t, s) as an internalgame. In behavioral ecology this is called the stabilization of the dynamic programmingequation (Houston and McNamara 1999; Clark and Mangel 2000); it is analogous to thetrembling hand equilibrium (Selten 1975).

1. We specify the number of ports and the vessel types operating from each port.2. We solve Eq. 5 for each vessel type from each port, using the species-specific price

trajectories, p(t, s).3. Given the optimal fishing locations and number of shots to lay for each vessel type from

each port, we iterate behavior forward in time to generate landings under the currentprice trajectory. We assume that price is a function of the total volume V (t, s) of species-specific landings by all vessels each day and generate a new price trajectory accordingto

p(t, s) = p̄

(1 − f

[V (t, s) − V̄s

V̄s

])(6)

In this equation, p̄ is the season-wide average price of all species, V̄s is the mean species-specific catch per trip, calculated across all trips during the season for each forwarditeration and f is the price flexibility, relating to the price dependent demand curve (i.e.price adjusts to the quantity supplied) (Jaffry et al. 1999). For calculations, we set | f | =0.1, consistent with Hannesson and Kennedy’s (2009) conclusions about the economicsof the tuna fishery that is our focus. Equation 6 generates a new price trajectory as afunction of time, p(t, s), as the simulated vessels return to port with their catches; thusp(t, s) = p(V (t, s)).

4. We repeat Steps 2 and 3 until the price trajectory that is used to solve the dynamicprogramming equation matches the one that comes out of the forward iteration. As ametric for comparison of the two trajectories we use (with species index suppressed)

S =T∑t=1

(pb(t) − p f (t)

)2 (7)

where pb(t)is the price trajectory used in the SDP and p f (t) is the price trajec-tory generated by in the forward iteration. We considered that price had stabilizedwhen S << 1, so that the within-season price trajectory used to generate behavioris the same as that generated by the forward iteration of the behavior of the fishingvessels.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 12: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

80 M. Mangel et al.

We used this state-dependent fleet dynamics model to evaluate (1) the economic effectsof spatial incentives versus spatial closures for reducing seabird by-catch; (2) the costs of thetwo methods; that is, the rent relative to no management measure; and (3) the effectivenessof the method for conservation of seabirds, where seabird encounters per shot per area werepredicted using statistical models from historical data.

4 Results

4.1 Overview

The focus of conservation efforts in this fishery is the 5-degree region immediately offshorefrom Sydney (30–35◦S, west of 155◦E). In the past, this region has been closed at times bythe Australian Fisheries Management Authority (AFMA). Thus we set δi, j = 1 everywhereexcept the management area and consider effort decrement multipliers 1.66 or 3.00 of effortper unit spent in the management area. We chose these values to represent a moderate anda strong decrement in effort. We also considered outcomes of a no management alternativeand those under the current closure policies.

We analyzed the fishery using the spatial distribution of stocks corresponding approx-imately to 2003 and 2007 (Fig. 2). These years had two very different distributions offish. Thus, they differed in longline set types (as characterized by various targeting prac-tices, such as the number of hooks used, depth of fishing, bait configurations, the use oflight sticks, and the time of setting) and catch compositions. Offshore expansion of thefishery peaked in 2003 as a result of inshore depletion of swordfish, with the majority ofthe catch being yellowfin, swordfish and albacore. In 2007, reduced swordfish availabil-ity, high operating costs and shifting market demand resulted in vessels shifting to deep-setting techniques to target lower-value, but highly abundant, albacore in more northernlatitudes.

4.2 By-Catch Reduction Through Spatial Management

Although the application of hook decrement multipliers in the 5-degree square redistributeseffort to adjacent 5-degree squares (and some further to the north), considerable effort remainsoff Sydney, even at higher decrement multiplier levels (Fig. 2). The timing of landings drivesthe differences in price and rent, so that the outcomes depend on competition between fishers.

A 3.00 hook decrement multiplier applied to the 5-degree area immediately offshore fromSydney shows a difference in catch compositions and spatial distributions for the distributionof fish in 2003, versus that in 2007. Thus, vessels are predicted to shift differently accordingto fish abundance and distribution, and targeting practices.

We show relative rent by decrement strategy for each year and port in Fig. 3a. The rel-ative differences in overall rent are low, with the greatest decrease being approximately15% under the 3.00 decrement multiplier, assuming the pattern of abundance and distri-bution in 2003. Low-level decrements were generally cheaper than closures, while higherdecrements were generally more expensive to the fisher. That is, both years of abundanceand distribution of fish generally showed a higher rent with a lower (1.66) decrement multi-plier and a lower rent with a higher (3.00) decrement multiplier. There were slight differencesbetween years in the direction andmagnitude of the rent change. For example, rent was higherunder low decrements than under closures only for the abundance and distribution of fishin 2007.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 13: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 81

Management area

No management 1.66 decrement multiplier

3.00 decrement multiplier closure

“2007” no management

“2003” 3.00 decrement multiplier “2007” 3.00 decrement multiplier

Management area

A

B

Fig. 2 A Spatial distribution, magnitude and composition of modeled catch for the 2003 scenarios, where themanagement area is that immediately offshore from Sydney, where the size of the circles is proportional to themagnitude of the catch, and yellow= yellowfin tuna, green= albacore, blue= broadbill swordfish. B Spatialdistribution, magnitude and composition of modeled catch for 2003 versus 2007 when the effort decrement is3.00. (Color figure online)

123

Author's personal copy

Page 14: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

82 M. Mangel et al.

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

2003 M average

2003 S average

2003 overall average

2007 M average

2007 S average

2007 overall average

mea

n r

elat

ive

ren

t

Relative rent

none 1.66 3.00 closure

0.00

0.20

0.40

0.60

0.80

1.00

1.20

no management 1.66 decrement multiplier

3.00 decrement multiplier

closure

En

cou

nte

r ra

te (

rela

tive

to

scenario

Seabird encounter rate

"2003" "2007"

no

man

agem

ent)

A

B

Fig. 3 ARelative rent by decrement strategy for each port (M=Mooloolaba; S=Sydney) and yearB Seabirdencounter rate (relative to that under no management) by management scenario and year

In Fig. 3b, we show that seabird encounter rates decreased with the increasing strength ofthe management measure for the abundance and distribution of fish in 2003. Encounter rateswere actually lower under the 3.00 decrement multiplier than for the closure scenario, withless effort redistributed to the south of Sydney (an area of high modelled seabird abundance)under the former. Encounter rates showed little change under the abundance and distributionof fish in 2007, due to the different fish distributions and targeting, and hence different effortre-distributions relative to the 2003 model.

Combining the two panels in Fig. 3 allows us to illuminate the trade-off betweenbiodiversity (in terms of seabird conservation) and rent (Fig. 4; Table 3). A 3.00 hookdecrement multiplier in 2003 saves most birds, but this scenario for both years resultedin a strong decrease in rent. For both years, the smaller decrement multiplier wasthe preferable management measure. Our results show that closures were not necessar-ily superior to decrement multipliers in terms of their ability to protect seabirds, andthat the outcome depended on year through the abundance and spatial distribution offish

123

Author's personal copy

Page 15: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 83

2003_1.66

2003_3.00

2003_closure

2007_1.662007_3.00 2007_closure

-140

-120

-100

-80

-60

-40

-20

0-3.00E+08 -2.00E+08 -1.00E+08 0.00E+00 1.00E+08 2.00E+08

Seabird Encounters

– Encounters Under No

Management

Rent - Rent Under No Management

worst; more bird encounters, less rent

Good economically but not environmentally;

more bird encounters, more rent

Good environmentally but not economically;

less bird encounters, less rent

best; less bird encounters, more rent

Fig. 4 The trade-off between biodiversity (where a lower seabird encounter ratemeans to a preferable outcomein terms of biodiversity conservation) and rent to the fishery

Table 3 Cost per bird of different management strategies

Year Management strategy Cost per bird ($AUD)

2003 Closure −7.87E+05

2003 1.66 multiplier −1.89E+06

2003 3.00 multiplier 1.85E+06

2007 Closure 3.57E+06

2007 1.66 multiplier −7.50E+06

2007 3.00 multiplier 5.30E+07

Fewer seabirds are predicted to be encountered in every scenario when hook decrements were applied, so anegative sign means higher rent relative to that under no management, while a positive sign means lower rentrelative to that under no management. The best scenario both from an environmental and economic point ofview was the 1.66 effort decrement multiplier in 2007, while the worst was the 3.00 effort decrement in thesame year

5 Discussion and Conclusion

In this paper, we have illustrated how the state variable methods that Colin Clark developedfor behavioral ecology have a natural translation into problems of resource economics. Wehave intentionally made the paper short and thus, for example, did not consider the biggermaximization problem of choosing the best hook decrement multipliers δi,i over the entireregion. For example, making some of them <1 would be a means of encouraging fishing inareas that might otherwise be ignored. We have also intentionally ignored the risk of goingfishing, which would discount future expected rent in Eq. 5 since that is treated in Dowlinget al. (2013) and allowed us to focus on a simpler problem, in the spirit of what Colin hastaught over the years.

123

Author's personal copy

Page 16: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

84 M. Mangel et al.

There is much scope for analyses of the kind we have illustrated here in fisheries. Forexample, these methods enable the evaluation of the effects of reorganizing fisheries toembrace a spatial or regional management system. This includes the exploration of manage-ment measures such as bonding or offsets, in addition to environmental incentives such asthose considered here. The approaches used here could be more generally applied in a marinezone management context, with a focus on estimating the true costs of spatial managementin addition to biodiversity benefits. The outcomes of such modeling can also feed into socio-economic impact analysis, as for example, in assessing proposed marine protected areas.That is, the methods that we have described here are particularly appropriate for EcosystemBased Fishery Management (EBFM). One of the great challenges in EBFM is dealing withtrade-offs among non-commensurate values such as targeted catch and by-catch or targetedcatch and the reduction in chick production by seabirds (Richerson et al. 2010) or the densityof grizzly bears (Levi et al. 2012). Richerson et al. (2010) suggest, and Levi et al. (2012)apply, a solution that balances the relative catch (catch at a fishing level belowMSY dividedby catch atMSY ) and relative population production or size (production or size at no fishingdivided by that atMSY ). Defined this way, relative catch is an increasing function of fishingmortality and relative population production or size is a decreasing function of fishing mor-tality, so that one can consider how these balance. Our results in Fig. 4 provide another wayof computing such relative values.

To be sure, there is much work still to be done, but we all owe Colin Clark a great debt ofthanks for having started one field and contributed so deeply to another.

Acknowledgments This work was partially supported by the Center for Stock Assessment Research, apartnership between the Fisheries Ecology Division, Southwest Fisheries Science Center, NOAA Fisheriesand theUniversity of California SantaCruz, by aNSF predoctoral fellowship to JuanLopezArriaza, by fundingthrough theCommonwealthEnvironmentalResearchFacilities (CERF)MarineBiodiversityHub, and aCSIROMarine and Atmospheric Research Career Development Fund awarded to Natalie Dowling. Chris Wilcox wasthe leader of the Off-Reserve Management Program under the CERF Marine Biodiversity Hub and providedmuch valuable input to the current work, including the provision of the statistically modeled predictions ofarea-specific seabird encounter rate per shot. For comments on a previous version of the manuscript, we thanktwo anonymous referees, Larry Karp and Spiro Stefanou.

References

Campbell RA, Hobday AJ (2003) Swordfish-environment-seamount fishery interactions off eastern Australia.Report to the Australian Fisheries Management Authority, Canberra

Clark CW (1973) The economics of overexploitation. Science 181:630–634Clark CW (1976) Mathematical bioeconomics. Wiley, New YorkClark CW (2006) The worldwide crisis in fisheries: economic models and human behavior. Cambridge Uni-

versity Press, New YorkClark CW, Mangel M (1984) Foraging and flocking strategies: information in an uncertain environment. Am

Nat 123:626–647Clark CW, Mangel M (1986) The evolutionary advantages of group foraging. Theor Popul Biol 30:45–75Clark CW, Mangel M (2000) Dynamic state variable models in ecology. Methods and applications. Oxford

University Press, OxfordDixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJDowling NA, Wilcox CW, Mangel M, Pascoe S (2012) Assessing opportunity and relocation costs of marine

protected areas using a behavioural model of longline fleet dynamics. Fish Fish 13(2):139–157Dowling NA, Wilcox CW, Mangel M (2013) Risk sensitivity and the behaviour of fishing vessels. Fish Fish

(in press)Griffiths SP, Young JW, Lansdell MJ, Campbell RA, Hampton J, Hoyle SD, Langley A, Bromhead D, Hinton

MG (2010) Ecological effects of longline fishing and climate change on the pelagic ecosystem off easternAustralia. Rev Fish Biol Fish 20(2):239–272

123

Author's personal copy

Page 17: University of California, Santa Cruzmsmangel/Mangel et al ERE... · 2015. 5. 15. · a consistent mathematical framework, virtually creating the field of mathematical bioeco- ...

The Behavioral Ecology of Fishing Vessels 85

Hartog JR, Hobday AJ, Matear R, FengM (2011) Habitat overlap between southern bluefin tuna and yellowfintuna in the east coast longline fishery—implications for present and future spatial management. Deep-SeaRes Part II Top Stud Oceanogr 58(5):746–752

Hannesson R, Kennedy J (2009) Rent-maximization versus competition in the western and central pacific tunafishery. J Nat Res Policy Res 1:49–65

Houston AI, McNamara JM (1999) Models of adaptive behavior. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeJaffry S, Pascoe S, Robinson C (1999) Long run flexibilities for high valued UK fish species: a cointegration

systems approach. Appl Econ 31:473–481Levi T, Darimont CT, MacDuffee M, Mangel M, Paquet P, Wilmers CC (2012) Using grizzly bears to assess

harvest-ecosystem tradeoffs in salmon fisheries. PLoS Biol 10(4):e1001303. doi:10.1371/journal.pbio.1001303

Mangel M (1985) Decision and control in uncertain resource systems. Academic Press, NYMangel M (2006) The theoretical biologist’s toolbox. Quantitative methods for ecology and evolutionary

biology. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeMangel M, Clark CW (1983) Uncertainty, search, and information in fisheries. J Int Counc Explor Seas

43:93–103Mangel M, Clark CW (1986) Towards a unified foraging theory. Ecology 67:1127–1138MangelM, Clark CW (1988) Dynamic modeling in behavioral ecology. Princeton University Press, Princeton,

NJMangel M, Ludwig D (1992) Definition and evaluation of behavioral and developmental programs. Annu Rev

Ecol Syst 23:507–536Mangel M, Mullan A, Mulch A, Staub S, Yasukochi E (1998) A generally accessible derivation of the golden

rule of bioeconomics. Bull Ecol Soc Am 79:145–148Richerson K, Levin PS, Mangel M (2010) Accounting for indirect effects and non-commensurate values in

ecosystem based fishery management. Mar Policy 34:114–119Selten R (1975) Reexamination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games. Int J

Game Theory 4:25–55Trebilco R, Gales R, Lawrence E, Alderman R, Robertson G, Baker GB (2010) Characterizing seabird by-

catch in the eastern Australian tuna and billfish pelagic longline fishery in relation to temporal, spatial andbiological influences. Aquat Conserv Mar Freshw Ecosyst 20(5):531–542

Thompson JN (2013) Relentless evolution. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL

123

Author's personal copy