Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for...

9
Research Article Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for Online Video Services Zhi Li 1,2 and De-qing Tan 3 1 School of Management, Tianjin Polytechnic University, Tianjin 300387, China 2 College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin 300072, China 3 School of Economics & Management, Southwest Jiaotong University, Chengdu 610031, China Correspondence should be addressed to Zhi Li; [email protected] Received 4 May 2017; Revised 26 August 2017; Accepted 29 August 2017; Published 18 October 2017 Academic Editor: Cemıl Tunc ¸ Copyright © 2017 Zhi Li and De-qing Tan. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. As the demands for online video services increase intensively, the selection of business models has drawn the great attention of online providers. Among them, pay-per-view mode and advertising mode are two important resource modes, where the reasonable fee charge and suitable volume of ads need to be determined. is paper establishes an analytical framework studying the optimal dynamic pricing and advertising strategies for online providers; it shows how the strategies are influenced by the videos available time and the viewers’ emotional factor. We create the two-stage strategy of revenue models involving a single fee mode and a mixed fee-free mode and find out the optimal fee charge and advertising level of online video services. According to the results, the optimal video price and ads volume dynamically vary over time. e viewer’s aversion level to advertising has direct effects on both the volume of ads and the number of viewers who have selected low-quality content. e optimal volume of ads decreases with the increase of ads-aversion coefficient, while increasing as the quality of videos increases. e results also indicate that, in the long run, a pure fee mode or free mode is the optimal strategy for online providers. 1. Introduction Apart from text and images, video is the most important form of online media, which has been widely regarded as the future of media on the Internet. According to Cisco Visual Networking Index 2015–2020 prediction, by 2020, 82% of viewer Internet traffic will be video and total global Internet traffic will increase at 22% per year. High-quality online video service brings not only profits but also reputation and user reliability to the companies. e latter is rather more impor- tant for company’s long term life cycle. For example, Youtube has attracted over a billion users all over world, because it offers free video services, selected advertising options, and a much faster streaming ability thanks to its great technologies such as Content Delivery Network (CDN) and Google File System (GFS). In other words, Youtube has paid a lot of attention to user experience and thus gains a large and stable user group, which makes Youtube one of the most famous video websites in the world. However, in 2014 Youtube annual revenue was posted at about $4 billion, which accounted for about 6% of Google’s overall sales, which increased to $9 billion in 2015. is indicates that there will be a large potentiality for Youtube to be more profitable. Not only does Youtube exist, but also there are various Internet video sites such as Vimeo (US), Hulu (US), Youku (China), Dailymotion (France), Niconico (Japan), and Pandora TV (South Korea), competing in the online video market all over the world. As the online video service has a glorious future, it is attractive and important to investigate its business models. ere are several profiting modes, which mainly include three patterns: sales or redistribution of copyrights for certain films, charges for video services, and advertising revenue. In this paper, we will discuss the two latter cases dealing with online video users. Many video websites adopt the strategy of providing free video services to maximize membership. e revenues of this mode mainly depend on advertising. However, recent studies report that, with only advertising revenue, it is not sufficient for Internet-based Hindawi Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Volume 2017, Article ID 1349315, 8 pages https://doi.org/10.1155/2017/1349315

Transcript of Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for...

Page 1: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

Research ArticleTwo-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies forOnline Video Services

Zhi Li1,2 and De-qing Tan3

1School of Management, Tianjin Polytechnic University, Tianjin 300387, China2College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, Tianjin 300072, China3School of Economics & Management, Southwest Jiaotong University, Chengdu 610031, China

Correspondence should be addressed to Zhi Li; [email protected]

Received 4 May 2017; Revised 26 August 2017; Accepted 29 August 2017; Published 18 October 2017

Academic Editor: Cemıl Tunc

Copyright © 2017 Zhi Li and De-qing Tan. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons AttributionLicense, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properlycited.

As the demands for online video services increase intensively, the selection of business models has drawn the great attention ofonline providers. Among them, pay-per-viewmode and advertisingmode are two important resourcemodes, where the reasonablefee charge and suitable volume of ads need to be determined. This paper establishes an analytical framework studying the optimaldynamic pricing and advertising strategies for online providers; it shows how the strategies are influenced by the videos availabletime and the viewers’ emotional factor. We create the two-stage strategy of revenue models involving a single fee mode and amixed fee-free mode and find out the optimal fee charge and advertising level of online video services. According to the results,the optimal video price and ads volume dynamically vary over time. The viewer’s aversion level to advertising has direct effects onboth the volume of ads and the number of viewers who have selected low-quality content. The optimal volume of ads decreaseswith the increase of ads-aversion coefficient, while increasing as the quality of videos increases.The results also indicate that, in thelong run, a pure fee mode or free mode is the optimal strategy for online providers.

1. Introduction

Apart from text and images, video is the most importantform of online media, which has been widely regarded as thefuture of media on the Internet. According to Cisco VisualNetworking Index 2015–2020 prediction, by 2020, 82% ofviewer Internet traffic will be video and total global Internettrafficwill increase at 22% per year. High-quality online videoservice brings not only profits but also reputation and userreliability to the companies. The latter is rather more impor-tant for company’s long term life cycle. For example, Youtubehas attracted over a billion users all over world, because itoffers free video services, selected advertising options, and amuch faster streaming ability thanks to its great technologiessuch as Content Delivery Network (CDN) and Google FileSystem (GFS). In other words, Youtube has paid a lot ofattention to user experience and thus gains a large and stableuser group, which makes Youtube one of the most famousvideo websites in the world. However, in 2014 Youtube annual

revenue was posted at about $4 billion, which accountedfor about 6% of Google’s overall sales, which increased to$9 billion in 2015. This indicates that there will be a largepotentiality for Youtube to be more profitable. Not only doesYoutube exist, but also there are various Internet video sitessuch as Vimeo (US), Hulu (US), Youku (China), Dailymotion(France), Niconico (Japan), and Pandora TV (South Korea),competing in the online video market all over the world.

As the online video service has a glorious future, it isattractive and important to investigate its business models.There are several profiting modes, which mainly includethree patterns: sales or redistribution of copyrights forcertain films, charges for video services, and advertisingrevenue. In this paper, we will discuss the two latter casesdealing with online video users. Many video websites adoptthe strategy of providing free video services to maximizemembership. The revenues of this mode mainly depend onadvertising. However, recent studies report that, with onlyadvertising revenue, it is not sufficient for Internet-based

HindawiDiscrete Dynamics in Nature and SocietyVolume 2017, Article ID 1349315, 8 pageshttps://doi.org/10.1155/2017/1349315

Page 2: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

2 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

companies [1, 2]. According to Weiss [3], fee charge modeis necessary and becoming more popular in web contentmarket. Hence, the strategy of combining fee charge andadvertising has emerged, which has been regarded as themainstream business model, such as Youku, the most famousvideo service website in China, which offers free videos withads as well as a paid membership with a higher priorityand no ads. Although the mixed strategy is popular, it alsoraises the problem of how to balance the revenue from feecharging and advertising. For Internet video services, higherprices result in fewer viewers, and a large amount of ads willalso scare them away. In this sense, there exists a trade-offbetween video service price and the amount of ads.

In order to deal with this trade-off, some video websitesadopt strategy that allows viewers to preview samples beforebuying. It might be feasible, because online video is a sort ofinformation goods as well as experience goods, which couldbe valued according to viewers’ perceived experience [4].Hence, free samples are introduced into the business modelswith the purpose of ensuring that viewers have an actualexperience with information goods [5, 6]. This humanizedexperience mode is helpful to set up reasonable price and adsvolume for information goods. With significant increasingnumber of the Internet users, the pricing and advertisingmodels have attracted attention of many researchers. Riggins[7] develops a separating equilibrium model for fee-basedand ads sponsored-based websites and examines a monop-olist’s choice of web content price and quality. In anotherstudy, Prasad et al. [8] suggest different optimal strategies forcontent firms depending on the context: pure pay-per-viewstrategy for high income users, who are willing to pay theadvertising avoidance fee, and free strategy based on adver-tisement for high advertising sales with low-quality content.The study derives the optimal condition for each strategy.Halbheer et al. [9] investigates digital content strategies: thesampling, paid content, and free content strategies for onlinepublishers. Results show that the optimal strategy is deter-mined by the relationship between advertising effectivenessand content quality. Chellappa and Shivendu [1] examinepricing and sampling strategies for digital experience goods;through a two-stage viewer piracy behavior model theyobtain the optimal price and sample size. Peitz and Valletti[10] introduce the factor of viewer’s favorite type into pay-tv and free-to-air models in the two-side market. The resultsindicate that the more sensitive the viewers are to adsthe more the differentiated content should be. Kwon [11]constructs a stochastic model for online display advertisingcontracts and explores how pricing and contract componentsaffect the optimal display strategies. Lin et al. [12] assert that amixed strategy of paid and free content is most favorable forcontent firms in a monopoly position, and in a duopoly state,only one firm is able to employ the mixed strategy.

The papers mentioned above apply static models andoptimize the maximum revenue using simple first-orderand second-order conditions without considering the effectof time on the optimal strategy. However, a few papersdo take into consideration the time periods in differentways and provide a dynamic analysis to study the optimalcontent price and the volume of ads in websites. For instance,

Dewan et al. [13] develop an advertising revenue model andobtain the optimal dynamic ads volume for the managerof Internet. Kumar and Sethi [2] study dynamic pricingand advertising for web content providers and test theinfluence of parameters such as horizon length, cost ofserving, natural growth rate, and content’s utility factor onthe optimal strategies. Based on the pricing strategy, Na etal. [14] categorize Korea’s digital content firms’ strategies intothree groups: pure pay-per-view strategy, free strategy basedon advertisement, and a mixed strategy; then they applythe metafrontier analysis method to estimate each group’sefficiency value. As extension, our model differs from theirsby further considering the hybrid business models with thetype of viewers and emotional factor varying over time. Inthis paper, we will introduce two business models includingthe fee mode and the free mode that allow viewers to select.There are two cases under consideration, the single fee modecase and the mixed fee-free mode case. In the mixed fee-freemode, viewers could maximize their utility by selectingwithin the two modes. Based on the emotional factor, thetype of viewers, and the perceived value, we propose a modelfor finding the optimal dynamic fee charge and ads level overa finite time interval, to maximize the total profit of onlinevideo providers. To the best of our knowledge, it is the firstanalysis with a continuous time model and emotional factorin this setting. The paper is innovative and new, which firstlyapplies Hamilton maximum principle to solve the optimalpricing and advertising strategies for online video services.

2. The Model

Consider that the online provider offers two types of Internetvideo contents: high-quality content without ads requiringa fee to access and low-quality content with ads but free ofcharge. There will be previews for viewers to have a generaljudge over the video service. Assume that for high-qualityand low-quality video services, the viewer’s average perceivedvalues are Vℎ and V𝑙, respectively, where Vℎ > V𝑙 > 0 [15].Since different viewers react differently to the same videocontent, they can be classified further by their types. Forthis model, we define high-quality type preferred viewers asthose who are more sensitive to video quality; thus they havemore willingness to choose the fee mode. Similarly, definedeconomy preferred viewers are those who are unwilling topay for online videos but may tolerate advertising; thus theyprefer to choose the freemode.Meanwhile we assume that (aswell as in [16]) viewer’s type 𝜃 follows a uniform distributionon [0, 1], which is a factor indicating viewers’ willingness topay for service. When 𝜃 is close to 1, the viewers are morelikely to choose the fee mode, and vice versa.

In this paper, the price of online video services and theamount of ads are functions of time 𝑡 denoted by 𝑝𝑡 and 𝑞𝑡,respectively. Based on above assumptions, define the viewerexpected utility such that a viewer of type 𝜃ℎ receiving fromhigh-quality content is𝑈ℎ(𝑡) = 𝜃ℎVℎ−𝑝𝑡 and from low-qualitycontent is𝑈𝑙(𝑡) = 𝜃𝑙V𝑙 −𝛽𝑞𝑡. In the free mode, viewers have toview ads that come with video content. Thus, the advertisingis regarded as a nuisance that could reduce viewers’ utility[17, 18]. Based on this fact, considering viewers’ emotional

Page 3: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 3

factor that could affect the viewingmode, we define 𝛽 ∈ (0, 1)as a constant representing ads-aversion coefficient. When 𝛽value gets closer to 1, it means viewers are less tolerant to ads.We assume that the marginal cost of producing a product orintroducing an advertisement is zero. Viewers have to viewads that come in order to access the free product. To mirrorthe properties of pricing and advertising strategies, let the costof setting ads be zero [7], and the producing cost of contentis negligible on Internet.

In the following part, we will introduce the single feemode and the mixed fee-free mode, where the optimal videoprice and ads volume are resolved to obtain the optimalbusiness strategies for online video services.

2.1. Case I: Fee Mode in Time Interval (0, 𝑡1). At time 𝑡, when𝑈ℎ(𝑡) = 𝜃ℎVℎ − 𝑝𝑡 ≥ 0, 𝜃ℎ ≥ 𝑝𝑡/Vℎ, viewers choose the feemode. Define the total volume of viewers as 1. Let 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 be thenumber of viewers who have selected high-quality content.The current density of viewers ��ℎ,𝑡 = 𝑑𝑥ℎ,𝑡/𝑑𝑡 is expressed as

𝐷ℎ,𝑡 = ∫𝜃ℎ

𝑝𝑡/Vℎ𝑑𝜃 = 𝜃ℎ − 𝑝𝑡Vℎ = 1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 −

𝑝𝑡Vℎ,

��ℎ,𝑡 = 1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 − 𝑝𝑡Vℎ .(1)

Let ��ℎ,𝑡 = 𝑑𝑥ℎ,𝑡/𝑑𝑡 be the change rate of the number ofhigh type viewers and define ��ℎ,𝑡 = 𝐷ℎ,𝑡. We denote thatonline providers make profits over the planning horizon withlength 𝑡1, and then the profit is given as

ΠI = ∫𝑡1

0𝑝𝑡��ℎ,𝑡𝑑𝑡. (2)

In case I, it needs to find out the optimal price 𝑝∗𝑡whichmaximizes the profitΠI.The objective function for theprovider is

𝐽1 = max∫𝑡10𝑝𝑡��ℎ,𝑡𝑑𝑡, (3)

This is a dynamic optimization problem, which can besolved by the modern control theory Hamiltonian Method.In the model, a dot above a variable is defined as the firstderivative with respect to time. We formulate Hamiltonianfunction as follows:

𝐻1 = 𝑝𝑡 (1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 − 𝑝𝑡Vℎ) + 𝜆0,𝑡 (1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 −𝑝𝑡Vℎ) , (4)

where 𝑝𝑡 is a control variable and 𝜆0,𝑡 is a time-varyingconstructor variable. According toHamiltonian principle [19,20], the necessary conditions for the optimal control are listedas follows:

𝜕𝐻1𝜕𝑝𝑡 = 0,

��0,𝑡 = − 𝜕𝐻1𝜕𝑥ℎ,𝑡 .(5)

Since 𝑝𝑡 is unconstrained, the optimal price should satisfy thefirst-order condition 𝜕𝐻1/𝜕𝑝𝑡 = 0, from which we obtain

𝑝𝑡 = Vℎ (1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡) − 𝜆0,𝑡2 . (6)

From (1) and (6), the increment rate of viewers who selecthigh-quality content ��ℎ,𝑡 is given by

��ℎ,𝑡 = 𝜆0,𝑡 + Vℎ (1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡)2Vℎ . (7)

Since Lagrangian multiplier satisfies the condition ��0,𝑡 =−𝜕𝐻1/𝜕𝑥ℎ,𝑡, we have the following equation:��0,𝑡 = 𝜆0,𝑡 + Vℎ (1 − 𝑥ℎ,𝑡)2 . (8)

Deduced from (7) and (8), we obtain

��0,𝑡 = Vℎ��ℎ,𝑡. (9)

Equation (9) is a first-order differential equation.With borderconditions 𝑥ℎ,𝑡=0 = 0 and 𝜆0(𝑡0) = 0, final solutions areachieved as 𝜆0,𝑡 = Vℎ(𝑡 − 𝑡1)/(2 + 𝑡1), 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 = 𝑡/(2 + 𝑡1).

We substitute the values of 𝜆0,𝑡 and 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 into (6) and derivethe optimal price of online video services 𝑝∗𝑡 = Vℎ(1 + 𝑡1 −𝑡)/(2 + 𝑡1) that could make the maximum profit in fee modewith time interval (0, 𝑡1).2.2. Case II: Mixed Fee-Free Mode in Time Interval (0, 𝑡1).In this case, there exists both fee and free modes in onlinevideo service market. Viewers could choose any mode astheir willingness. Since the newly arriving video contentsare more attractive, viewers prefer to pay for the new ones.With this consideration, introduce a critical time point 𝑡0,which divides the whole business time into two stages: intime interval (0, 𝑡0), providers employ the fee mode; in timeinterval (𝑡0, 𝑡1), providers employ the mixed fee-free mode.

Stage 1 (fee mode (0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡0)). Here wemake an assumptionthat the optimal solution for fee model is the same as caseI. This assumption stands when 𝑡1 is not infinite and forthe purpose of simplifying the model. It means that in timeinterval 0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡0, the optimal price of online video servicesis 𝑝∗𝑡 = Vℎ(1 + 𝑡1 − 𝑡)/(2 + 𝑡1).Stage 2 (fee-free mode (𝑡0 < 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡1)). At time 𝑡0, introducethe freemode into the single feemode in online videomarket,and therefore there exists both fee and freemodes at the sametime. The advertising in free mode will attenuate viewers’selection. In the fee mode, we adopt a scaled price of Stage 1for Stage 2 for simplicity. Denote 𝛾 as a regular factor in (0, 1],which determines the price in Stage 2 as 𝛾𝑝𝑡. For viewers, if𝑈ℎ(𝑡) > 𝑈𝑙(𝑡) fee mode is preferred, otherwise, free mode isbetter. Furthermore, we have the following results:

If 0 ≤ 𝜃V𝑙−𝛽𝑞𝑡 < 𝜃Vℎ−𝛾𝑝𝑡, 𝜃 > (𝛾𝑝𝑡−𝛽𝑞𝑡)/(Vℎ−V𝑙) ≥ 0,viewers prefer the fee mode.If 0 ≤ 𝜃Vℎ − 𝛾𝑝𝑡 ≤ 𝜃V𝑙 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡, 𝛽𝑞𝑡/V𝑙 < 𝜃 < (𝛾𝑝𝑡 −𝛽𝑞𝑡)/(Vℎ − V𝑙), viewers prefer the free mode.

Page 4: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

4 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

It can be found that 𝜃 = (𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡)/(Vℎ − V𝑙) is the criticalpoint of viewer type.

Denote 𝑥𝑙,𝑡 as the number of viewers who have viewedlow-quality content; thus the current densities of differentviewers are defined as

𝐷ℎ,𝑡 = 𝜃ℎ − 𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙,

𝐷𝑙,𝑡 = 𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙− 𝛽𝑞𝑡

V𝑙.

(10)

Since ��ℎ,𝑡 = 𝐷ℎ,𝑡, ��𝑙,𝑡 = 𝐷𝑙,𝑡, we have��ℎ,𝑡 = 1 − 𝑡02 + 𝑡0 −

𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙

− 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 − 𝑥𝑙,𝑡,

��𝑙,𝑡 = 𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙− 𝛽𝑞𝑡

V𝑙,

(11)

where ��ℎ,𝑡 is the density of arriving viewers who select feemode and ��𝑙,𝑡 is the density of viewers who select free mode.The profit of fee-free mode is given as

ΠII = ∫𝑡1

𝑡0

(𝛾𝑝𝑡��ℎ,𝑡 + 𝑘𝑞𝑡��𝑙,𝑡) 𝑑𝑡, (12)

where 𝑘 is the price of ads per unit. In Stage 2, it needs to findthe optimal ads volume 𝑞∗𝑡 to maximize profitΠII. Over timeperiod 𝑡0 < 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡1, the objective function for the provider is

𝐽2 = max∫𝑡1𝑡0

(𝛾𝑝𝑡��ℎ,𝑡 + 𝑘𝑞𝑡��𝑙,𝑡) 𝑑𝑡, (13)

subject to (14) and (15):

��ℎ,𝑡 = 1 − 𝑡02 + 𝑡0 −𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙

− 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 − 𝑥𝑙,𝑡, (14)

��𝑙,𝑡 = 𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙− 𝛽𝑞𝑡

V𝑙. (15)

The Hamiltonian function is given as follows:

𝐻2 = (𝛾𝑝𝑡 + 𝜆1,𝑡) ( 22 + 𝑡0 −

𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙

− 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 − 𝑥𝑙,𝑡)

+ (𝜆2,𝑡 + 𝑘𝑞𝑡) (𝛾𝑝𝑡 − 𝛽𝑞𝑡Vℎ − V𝑙− 𝛽𝑞𝑡

V𝑙) ,

(16)

where 𝑞𝑡 is the variable, and 𝑝𝑡 = Vℎ(1 + 𝑡1 − 𝑡)/(2 + 𝑡1) isgiven in Stage 1. 𝜆1,𝑡 and 𝜆2,𝑡 are the two constructor variablescorresponding to the state variables 𝑥ℎ,𝑡 and 𝑥𝑙,𝑡 [20]. BasedonHamiltonian principle, 𝑞𝑡, 𝜆1,𝑡, 𝜆2,𝑡, 𝑥ℎ,𝑡, and 𝑥𝑙,𝑡 satisfy thefollowing equations:

𝜕𝐻2𝜕𝑞𝑡 = 0,

��1,𝑡 = − 𝜕𝐻2𝜕𝑥ℎ,𝑡 ,

��2,𝑡 = −𝜕𝐻2𝜕𝑥𝑙,𝑡 .

(17)

Since 𝑞𝑡 is unconstrained, 𝜕𝐻2/𝜕𝑞𝑡 = 0, the number of ads 𝑞𝑡is obtained by

𝑞𝑡 = 𝛾2𝛽𝑘 (2 + 𝑡1) ((𝛽 + 𝑘) V𝑙 + (𝑡1 − 𝑡) (𝑘V𝑙 + 𝛽Vℎ)) . (18)

Since Lagrange’s equation satisfies ��1,𝑡 = −𝜕𝐻2/𝜕𝑥ℎ,𝑡, ��2,𝑡 =−𝜕𝐻2/𝜕𝑥𝑙,𝑡, we have the following equations:��1,𝑡 = − 𝜕𝐻2𝜕𝑥ℎ,𝑡 = 𝛾𝑝𝑡 + 𝜆1,𝑡,

��2,𝑡 = −𝜕𝐻2𝜕𝑥𝑙,𝑡 = 𝛾𝑝𝑡 + 𝜆1,𝑡.(19)

Through solving first-order differential equations (19) andwith border condition 𝜆1,𝑡 = 𝜆2,𝑡 = 0, we obtain

𝜆1,𝑡 = 𝜆2,𝑡 = −𝛾Vℎ (𝑡1 − 𝑡)2 + 𝑡1 . (20)

From (14), (15), (18), (20), and𝑝𝑡 wehave the following results:𝑞𝑡 = 𝛾

2𝛽 (2 + 𝑡1) ((𝛽 + 𝑘) V𝑙 + (𝑡1 − 𝑡) (𝛽Vℎ + 𝑘V𝑙)) , (21)

𝑥𝑙,𝑡 = 𝛾Vℎ2 (Vℎ − V𝑙) (2 + 𝑡1) [(1 −𝛽𝑘) (𝑡 − 𝑡0)

+ (1 − 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 )(𝑡1 (𝑡 − 𝑡0) −𝑡2 − 𝑡202 )] .

(22)

In addition, from the existing results, we can resolve 𝑥ℎ,𝑡considering (6), (14), (18), (22), and the border condition𝑥ℎ,𝑡(𝑡0) = 𝑡0/(2 + 𝑡1); the following formulation is given:

𝑥ℎ,𝑡 = 𝛾Vℎ2 (Vℎ − V𝑙) (2 + 𝑡1) [12 (1 −

𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 ) 𝑡2

+ (𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 −V𝑙Vℎ− 𝑡1 + 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 𝑡1) 𝑡 − 2 + (

𝛽𝑘 + 2)

V𝑙Vℎ

− 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 + (V𝑙Vℎ+ 𝛽𝑘 − 1 −

𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 ) 𝑡1 + (1 −𝛽𝑘) 𝑡0

+ (1 − 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 )(𝑡0𝑡1 −𝑡202 )] + 𝐶ℎ𝑒−𝑡 +

22 + 𝑡0 ,

(23)

with

𝐶ℎ = 𝑒−𝑡0 ( 𝑡02 + 𝑡1 −2

2 + 𝑡0− 𝛾Vℎ2 (Vℎ − V𝑙) (2 + 𝑡1) [

12 (1 −

𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 ) 𝑡20

+ (𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 −V𝑙Vℎ− 𝑡1 + 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 𝑡1) 𝑡0 − 2 + (

𝛽𝑘 + 2)

V𝑙Vℎ

− 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 + (V𝑙Vℎ+ 𝛽𝑘 − 1 −

𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 ) 𝑡1 + (1 −𝛽𝑘) 𝑡0

+ (1 − 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 )(𝑡0𝑡1 −𝑡202 )]) .

(24)

Page 5: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 5

Finally, we obtain the optimal trajectories for 𝑥𝑙,𝑡, 𝜆1,𝑡, and𝜆2,𝑡 in (20) and (22) and the optimal number of ads 𝑞∗𝑡 =(𝛾/2𝛽(2 + 𝑡1))((𝛽 + 𝑘)V𝑙 + (𝑡1 − 𝑡)(𝛽Vℎ + 𝑘V𝑙)) that makes themaximization of profit.

3. The Optimal Strategy

Based on the hybrid business models discussed in the abovesection, we can draw the following conclusions on optimalstrategies, which are useful to gain insights into factorsaffecting the optimal price and quantity.

3.1. The Optimal Pricing Strategy for Case I

Proposition 1. In the single fee mode, it is optimal to set 𝑝∗𝑡 =Vℎ(1 + 𝑡1 − 𝑡)/(2 + 𝑡1), 0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡1, in order to attend themaximum profit.

Proposition 1 shows that the optimal pricing strategy isdetermined by the relation between high-quality value andtime.

Lemma 2. The optimal price 𝑝∗𝑡 is increasing as perceivedvalue Vℎ of high-quality video increases, but it is decreasing astime t increases.

Proof. By taking the high-quality value and time partialderivatives of the optimal price, we obtain 𝜕𝑝∗𝑡 /𝜕Vℎ = Vℎ(1 +𝑡1−𝑡)/(2+𝑡1) ≥ 0, 𝜕𝑝∗𝑡 /𝜕𝑡 = −Vℎ/(2+𝑡1) ≤ 0, which supportsLemma 2.

Lemma 2 says, as higher perceived value obtained fromhigh-quality content video, the higher fee charge could berealized.

3.2. The Optimal Pricing-Advertising Strategy for Case II

Proposition 3. In the mixed fee-free mode of online videomarket, it is optimal for online providers to adopt a paid contentstrategy as 𝑝∗𝑡 = 𝛾Vℎ(1+𝑡1−𝑡)/(2+𝑡1), 0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡1; it is optimalto adopt a free content strategy as 𝑞∗𝑡 = (𝛾/2𝛽(2+𝑡1))((𝛽+𝑘)V𝑙+(𝑡1 − 𝑡)(𝑘V𝑙 + 𝛽Vℎ)), 𝑡0 < 𝑡 ≤ 𝑡1.

Proposition 3 shows the mixed fee-free strategy withthe optimal price of online video services and the optimalnumber of ads. This proposition is validated in Section 2discussion by means of Hamiltonian principle. As in thebenchmark case, if viewers care more about the high-qualityvalue of online video content, it is optimal for providers toemploy the fee strategy; if the viewers are notwilling to pay forthe online content, meanwhile, they would rather accept ads(the value of ads-aversion coefficient is small); it is optimalfor providers to employ the free strategy.

Lemma4. Theoptimal number of ads 𝑞∗𝑡 is increasing as eitherhigh-quality value Vℎ or low-quality value V𝑙 increases, whileit is decreasing as either ads-aversion coefficient 𝛽 or time tincreases.

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.8 0.85 0.9 0.95 10.55t

= 0.2

= 0.4

= 0.6

= 0.8

= 1

Opt

imal

num

ber o

f ads

Figure 1: The optimal number of ads with respect to time 𝑡.

Proof. For the optimal number of ads 𝑞∗𝑡 , we take the firstderivative of 𝑞∗𝑡 versus Vℎ, V𝑙, and 𝑡 and then obtain 𝜕𝑞∗𝑡 /𝜕Vℎ =𝛾Vℎ(𝑡1−𝑡)/2(2+𝑡1) ≥ 0, 𝜕𝑞∗𝑡 /𝜕V𝑙 = (𝛾(𝛽+𝑘)+(𝑡1−𝑡)𝑘)/2𝛽(2+𝑡1) ≥ 0, 𝜕𝑞∗𝑡 /𝜕𝑡 = −𝛾(𝛽Vℎ + 𝑘V𝑙)/2𝛽(2 + 𝑡1) < 0.

Through simple transform 𝑞∗𝑡 = (𝛾/2𝛽(2+ 𝑡1))((𝛽+𝑘)V𝑙 +(𝑡1 − 𝑡)(𝛽Vℎ + 𝑘V𝑙)) = (𝛾/2(2 + 𝑡1))((1 + 𝑘/𝛽)V𝑙 + (𝑡1 − 𝑡)(Vℎ +𝑘V𝑙/𝛽)), it is clear that 𝑞∗𝑡 decreases with the increase of 𝛽. Allthe above can support Lemma 4.

The result of Lemma 4 is illustrated in Figure 1 usingnumerical computations, where we plot the optimal adsvolume with different values of 𝛽. As can be seen in Figure 1,the high ads-aversion coefficient corresponds to the lowvolume ads. For each curve of ads volume, the optimalnumber of ads is decreasing with the increase of time 𝑡. Thisresult is rational in real online video market case. The longerthe video available time lasts, the less attractive the videocontent is. Therefore, to get the sustainable profit in the longrun, it is optimal for online providers to reduce ads volume.

Lemma 5. The number of viewers who select low-qualitycontent 𝑥𝑙,𝑡 increases as time 𝑡 increases, if 𝑘V𝑙 > 𝛽Vℎ, whent is in the time interval (𝑡0, 𝑡1).Proof. In case II Stage 2, we obtain

𝑥𝑙,𝑡 = 𝛾Vℎ2 (Vℎ − V𝑙) (2 + 𝑡1) [(1 −𝛽𝑘) (𝑡 − 𝑡0)

+ (1 − 𝛽Vℎ𝑘V𝑙 )(𝑡1 (𝑡 − 𝑡0) −𝑡2 − 𝑡202 )] .

(25)

Take the first derivative of 𝑥𝑙,𝑡 with respect to 𝑡, which leads to𝜕𝑥𝑙,𝑡/𝜕𝑡 = 𝛾Vℎ/2(Vℎ−V𝑙)(2+𝑡1)[(1−𝛽/𝑘)+(1−𝛽Vℎ/𝑘V𝑙)(𝑡1−𝑡)],given the condition 𝛽/𝑘 < V𝑙/Vℎ, and then obtain 𝜕𝑥𝑙,𝑡/𝜕𝑡 > 0,which supports Lemma 5.

Lemma 5 shows that, under the condition of 𝛽/𝑘 < V𝑙/Vℎ,if advertising price is high and the actual high-quality value isrelatively low, viewers tend to prefer the freemode.Therefore,

Page 6: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

6 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 10

0.020.040.060.08

0.10.120.14

Opt

imal

pro

fit

t1

Figure 2: The optimal profit of case I with respect to time 𝑡1.

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1t0

k = 1

k = 0.5

k = 2

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

Opt

imal

pro

fit

Figure 3: The optimal profit of case II with different ads prices 𝑘.

it is beneficial for online providers to adopt free strategyto generate advertising revenue. Taking this into account issignificant for providers when fixing the optimal video priceand ads volume.

To have a better understanding of parameters influenceon 𝑥𝑙,𝑡, we draw the curve of 𝑥𝑙,𝑡 with respect to 𝛽/𝑘 and Vℎ/V𝑙in Figures 2 and 3. With generality, we set parameters valuesas 𝑡0 = 0.5, 𝑡1 = 1, and 𝛾 = 0.7. Please see the explanations inthe following section.

4. The Optimal Profit

According to the Hamiltonian principle and the previousanalysis, we calculate the maximum profits taking intoconsideration the optimal strategies of fee charge and amountof ads. For case I fee mode, the optimal profit ΠI(𝑡1) equalsΠI (𝑡1) = ∫

𝑡1

0𝑝𝑡��ℎ,𝑡𝑑𝑡 = ∫

𝑡1

0

Vℎ (1 + 𝑡1 − 𝑡)2 + 𝑡1 ⋅ 12 + 𝑡1 𝑑𝑡

= Vℎ𝑡12 (2 + 𝑡1) .(26)

Figure 2 reflects the changing trend of the optimal profitfor case I. We observe in this figure that the optimal profitincreased as the time 𝑡1 increased, but the increase is notvery sharp. When 𝑡1 tends to infinity, the maximum profitis obtained as ΠI = Vℎ/2. Also, we can observe fromthe equation of ΠI(𝑡1) that it is always optimal for online

providers to adopt the single fee mode in time period 𝑡1when the high-quality value Vℎ is increasing. For case II, themixed fee-free mode, we calculate the total profit ΠII(𝑡0) as afunction of the critical time 𝑡0, separating into two stages.Therespective profits are noted as ΠII,1(𝑡0) and ΠII,2(𝑡0):ΠII,1 (𝑡0) = ∫

𝑡0

0𝑝𝑡��ℎ,𝑡𝑑𝑡 = ∫

𝑡0

0

Vℎ (1 + 𝑡1 − 𝑡)2 + 𝑡11

2 + 𝑡1 𝑑𝑡

= Vℎ (2 + 2𝑡1 − 𝑡0) 𝑡02 (2 + 𝑡1)2 ,

(27)

and for Stage 2 profit, from the above obtained equations, wecan have the following formulation:

ΠII,2 (𝑡0) = ∫𝑡1

𝑡0

(𝛾𝑝∗𝑡 ��ℎ,𝑡 + 𝑘𝑞∗𝑡 ��𝑙,𝑡) 𝑑𝑡

= 𝛾2V204 (V0 − V1) (2 + 𝑡1)2 ((1 + 𝑡1) (−

V1V0− 𝑡1

+ 𝛼V0𝑘V1 𝑡1 +𝛼V0𝑘V1 ) (𝑡1 − 𝑡0) + [(1 −

𝛼V0𝑘V1 ) (1 + 𝑡1)

− (−V1V0− 𝑡1 + 𝛼V0𝑘V1 𝑡1 +

𝛼V0𝑘V1 )]𝑡21 − 𝑡202 − (1

− 𝛼V0𝑘V1 )𝑡31 − 𝑡303 ) + 𝛾V0 (1 + 𝑡1)2 + 𝑡1 𝐶ℎ (𝑒−𝑡1 − 𝑒−𝑡0)

− 𝛾V0𝐶ℎ2 + 𝑡1 [𝑒−𝑡1 (𝑡1 + 1) − 𝑒−𝑡0 (𝑡0 + 1)]

+ 𝛾2V0V1𝑘4𝛼 (V0 − V1) (2 + 𝑡1)2 [(1 −

𝛼2𝑘2) (𝑡1 − 𝑡0)

+ 2(1 − 𝛼2V0𝑘2V1) 𝑡1 (𝑡1 − 𝑡0) − (1 −𝛼2V0𝑘2V1)(𝑡

21

− 𝑡20) + (1 − 𝛼2V20𝑘2V21 ) 𝑡

21 (𝑡1 − 𝑡0) − (1 − 𝛼

2V20𝑘2V21 )

⋅ 𝑡1 (𝑡21 − 𝑡20) + 13 (1 −𝛼2V20𝑘2V21 )(𝑡

31 − 𝑡30)] .

(28)

Because the formulation is complicated, we investigatenumerically the influence of critical time 𝑡0 on the total profitΠII(𝑡0) in case II. Without losing generality, set the totalinterval 𝑡1 = 1, 𝛾 = 0.7, 𝛽 = 0.4, V𝑙 = 4, and Vℎ = 8, and 𝑡0belongs to [0, 𝑡1]. The following shows numerically how theparameter of ads unit price 𝑘 influences the optimal profit ofcase II of the mixed fee-free mode in Figure 3.

It can be found that no matter how the unit ads incomevaries, the optimal profit strategy is to take into action onlyone business model, either the single fee mode or the mixedfee-free mode, as the profit reaches a maximum value atthe ends of the interval. The optimal profit increases as 𝑘increases. When the value of ads price 𝑘 is small, it suggeststhat the mixed fee-free mode profiting ads revenue is less

Page 7: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 7

efficient than the revenue of the single fee mode, which issupported in case 𝑘 = 0.5 in Figure 3. Clearly, when 𝑡0 = 0,there exists the mixed fee-free mode; for 𝑡0 = 1, there onlyexists the single fee mode. Please see the optimal profit curvewith 𝑘 = 0.5; the profit at 𝑡0 = 0 is less than that at 𝑡0 =1, which means the single fee mode is optimal. Conversely,when the value of ads price 𝑘 is large, the mixed fee-freemode with ads revenue will create more profit. As shown incase 𝑘 = 2 in Figure 3, 𝑡0 = 0 reaches the maximum profit,which means the mixed fee-free mode outperforms in thiscase. At the same time, when 𝑘 = 1, the profits at both ends ofthe interval are nearly equal, while the profit decreases as 𝑡0varying in the interval.Thismeans, for online providers, thereis no difference between the single fee mode and mixed fee-free mode. Therefore, the optimal strategy is to adopt eitherof them. Finally, from the above analysis, it can be concludedthat the online providers should set their strategies accordingto the unit ads price 𝑘, but the strategy should always be onesingle business model.

5. Conclusion

This paper has investigated the optimal strategy for onlinevideo service business. Considering the dynamic decisions inreal video market, we divide the whole period into the singlefee phase and mixed fee-free phase and then, respectively,create continuous time model for each. Our models havepresented a straightforward way to study the provider’spricing strategy and advertising decision based on viewers’emotional factor. There is a significant influence amongapplied price, ads volume, and video content quantity. In thesingle fee mode, we have obtained the optimal time-varyingprice which maximizes the profit from video service withina certain time interval. The result implies that the optimalprice of online video increases with high-quality value whiledecreasing with time. In the mixed fee-free mode, we havefound out the optimal fee and ads volume. It is beneficial foronline providers to choose higher charge fee and advertisingintensity. Besides, the price and the number of ads decreaseas ads-aversion coefficient increases. It has turned out that, ina long run period of time, taking one strategy either fee modeor free mode is optimal for the online providers.

For future research, the following subjects can be carriedout in three aspects:

(i) Accomplishment of themodel:There are other factorswhich determine the revenue model. For example, inRen et al. [21], the authors point out that the onlinepopularity is a significant effecting factor on videosin online systems; in Iveroth et al. [22], competitors’price is a base factor for deciding; in Choi et al. [23],they imply that discount on price can have effect onthe sales of information goods; in another study, Niuand Li [24] suggest for the Internet service providers aprice model depending on the congestion of Internet.

(ii) Model validation: our time-continuous model shouldfit the data collected in real world, identify modelcoefficients, and validate other sets of data. As men-tioned in Walz et al. [25], the uncertainty analysis

could be carried out in two aspects: the modelform uncertainty and the parameters uncertainty.Theparameters standard error is investigated and thevalues should fall into the confidence interval. Inthis way, the optimal time-varying price solutions arevalidated.

(iii) Another path to investigate online video services ispredicting and analyzing based on a fitted nonpara-metric model. There are several advanced regressionmethods to be investigated, such as multivariateadaptive regression splines (MARS) or its alternativeCMARS proposed by Weber et al. [26] or RCMARSproposed by Ozmen et al. [27]. The prediction modelcan be used for simulation and cross validation withrespect to our models.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.

References

[1] R. K. Chellappa and S. Shivendu, “Managing piracy: Pricingand sampling strategies for digital experience goods in verticallysegmented markets,” Information Systems Research, vol. 16, no.4, pp. 400–417, 2005.

[2] S. Kumar and S. P. Sethi, “Dynamic pricing and advertisingfor web content providers,” European Journal of OperationalResearch, vol. 197, no. 3, pp. 924–944, 2009.

[3] T. R.Weiss, “Fees for online content proliferating, but will usersbuy,” Computer World, 2002.

[4] C. Shapiro and H. R. Varian, Information rules: A strategy guideto the network economy, Harvard Business School Press, Boston,MA, 1998.

[5] H. K. Cheng and Q. C. Tang, “Free trial or no free trial: Optimalsoftware product designwith network effects,”European Journalof Operational Research, vol. 205, no. 2, pp. 437–447, 2010.

[6] D. Halbheer, F. Stahl, O. Koenigsberg, and D. R. Lehmann,“Choosing a digital content strategy: How much should befree?” International Journal of Research inMarketing, vol. 31, no.2, pp. 192–206, 2014.

[7] F. J. Riggins, “Market segmentation and information develop-ment costs in a two-tiered fee-based and sponsorship-basedweb site,” Journal of Management Information Systems, vol. 19,no. 3, pp. 69–86, 2002.

[8] A. Prasad, V.Mahajan, and B. Bronnenberg, “Advertising versuspay-per-view in electronic media,” International Journal ofResearch in Marketing, vol. 20, no. 1, pp. 13–30, 2003.

[9] D. Halbheer, F. Stahl, O. Koenigsberg, and D. R. Lehmann,“Digital content strategies,”Marketing Letters, vol. 25, no. 3, pp.331–341, 2013.

[10] M. Peitz and T. M. Valletti, “Content and advertising inthe media: Pay-tv versus free-to-air,” International Journal ofIndustrial Organization, vol. 26, no. 4, pp. 949–965, 2008.

[11] C. Kwon, “Single-period balancing of pay-per-click and pay-per-view online display advertisements,” Journal of Revenue andPricing Management, vol. 10, no. 3, pp. 261–270, 2011.

[12] M. Lin, X. Ke, and A. Whinston, “Vertical differentiationand a comparison of online advertising models,” Journal of

Page 8: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

8 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

Management Information Systems, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 195–236,2012.

[13] R. M. Dewan, M. L. Freimer, and J. Zhang, “Managementand valuation of advertisement-supported web sites,” Journal ofManagement Information Systems, vol. 19, no. 3, pp. 87–98, 2002.

[14] H. S. Na, J. Hwang, J. Y. J. Hong, and D. Lee, “Efficiencycomparison of digital content providers with different pricingstrategies,” Telematics and Informatics, vol. 34, no. 2, pp. 657–663, 2017.

[15] H. L. Vogel, Entertainment Industry Economics, CambridgeBooks, New York, NY, USA, 2015.

[16] R. Casadesus-Masanell and F. Zhu, “Strategies to fight ad-sponsored rivals,”Management Science, vol. 56, no. 9, pp. 1484–1499, 2010.

[17] K. C. Wilbur, “A two-sided, empirical model of televisionadvertising and viewingmarkets,”Marketing Science, vol. 27, no.3, pp. 356–378, 2008.

[18] S. P. Anderson and S. Coate, “Market provision of broadcasting:a welfare analysis,”Review of Economic Studies, vol. 72, no. 4, pp.947–972, 2005.

[19] D. W. Yeung and L. A. Petrosyan, Cooperative Stochastic Dif-ferential Games, Springer Series in Operations Research andFinancial Engineering, Springer, New York, NY, USA, 2006.

[20] S. P. Sethi and G. L. Thompson, Optimal Control Theory:Applications to Management Science and Economics, SpringerScience & Business Media, 2006.

[21] Z.-M. Ren, Y.-Q. Shi, and H. Liao, “Characterizing popularitydynamics of online videos,” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics andits Applications, vol. 453, pp. 236–241, 2016.

[22] E. Iveroth, A. Westelius, C.-J. Petri, N.-G. Olve, M. Coster, andF. Nilsson, “How to differentiate by price: Proposal for a five-dimensional model,” EuropeanManagement Journal, vol. 31, no.2, pp. 109–123, 2013.

[23] H. Choi, D. Medlin, and S. Hunsinger, “The effects of discountpricing strategy on sales of software-as-a-service (SaaS): onlinevideo game market context,” Journal of Information SystemsApplied Research, vol. 10, no. 1, pp. 55–64, 2017.

[24] D. Niu and B. Li, “Congestion-aware internet pricing for mediastreaming,” in Proceedings of the 2014 IEEE Conference onComputer Communications Workshops, INFOCOM WKSHPS2014, pp. 571–576, Toronto, ON, Canada, May 2014.

[25] N. Walz, M. Burkhardt, P. Eberhard, and M. Hanss, “AComprehensive Fuzzy Uncertainty Analysis of a ControlledNonlinear System With Unstable Internal Dynamics,” ASCE-ASME Journal of Risk and Uncertainty in Engineering Systems,Part B: Mechanical Engineering, vol. 1, no. 4, Article ID 041008,pp. 1–12, 2015.

[26] G. W. Weber, I. Batmaz, G. Koksal, P. Taylan, and F. Yerlikaya-Ozkurt, “CMARS:Anewcontribution to nonparametric regres-sion with multivariate adaptive regression splines supportedby continuous optimization,” Inverse Problems in Science andEngineering, vol. 20, no. 3, pp. 371–400, 2012.

[27] A. Ozmen, G. W. Weber, I. Batmaz, and E. Kropat, “RCMARS:Robustification of CMARS with different scenarios under poly-hedral uncertainty set,” Communications in Nonlinear Scienceand Numerical Simulation, vol. 16, no. 12, pp. 4780–4787, 2011.

Page 9: Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies for ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/ddns/2017/1349315.pdf · ResearchArticle Two-Stage Dynamic Pricing and Advertising Strategies

Submit your manuscripts athttps://www.hindawi.com

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

MathematicsJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Mathematical Problems in Engineering

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com

Differential EquationsInternational Journal of

Volume 2014

Applied MathematicsJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Probability and StatisticsHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Mathematical PhysicsAdvances in

Complex AnalysisJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

OptimizationJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

CombinatoricsHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

International Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Operations ResearchAdvances in

Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Function Spaces

Abstract and Applied AnalysisHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

International Journal of Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 201

The Scientific World JournalHindawi Publishing Corporation http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Algebra

Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Decision SciencesAdvances in

Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com

Volume 2014 Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Stochastic AnalysisInternational Journal of