· PDF fileLeveling the Playing Field: Financial Regulation and Disappearing Local Bias of...

67
Leveling the Playing Field: Financial Regulation and Disappearing Local Bias of Institutional Investors Gennaro Bernile, University of Miami Alok Kumar, University of Miami Johan Sulaeman, Southern Methodist University July 5, 2012 Abstract – This study examines whether exogenous regulatory shocks induced by Regulation Fair Disclosure and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduce the local bias and the local informational advantage of institutional investors. We find that, following regulatory changes, the local bias and local informational advantage of institutional investors around corporate headquarters declines sharply as their selective access to private information is curtailed. The decline in local institutional ownership is more salient among firms that had more opaque information environments prior to the regulatory changes. Even at the aggregate market-level, the degree of informed trading attributed to local investors declines. The local informational advantage of sell-side equity analysts who are more likely to have selective access exhibits a similar declining pattern and disappears in the post-regulation period. In contrast, regulatory changes have minimal impact on the local informational advantage of institutions in economically relevant regions as they are unlikely to have selective access to management. These findings indicate that regulatory changes affected institutional behavior primarily by curtailing their selective access to management rather than adversely affecting their information processing advantages. Please address all correspondence to Alok Kumar, Department of Finance, School of Busi- ness Administration, 514G Jenkins Building, University of Miami, Coral Gables, FL 33124; Phone: 305-284-1882; email: [email protected]. Gennaro Bernile can be reached at 305- 284-6690 or [email protected]. Johan Sulaeman can be reached at 214-768-8284 or [email protected]. We thank an anonymous referee, Anup Agrawal, Warren Bailey, Scott Bauguess, Vidhi Chhaochharia, Larry Fauver, Rocco Huang, George Korniotis, S. P. Kothari, Kelvin Law, Evgeny Lyandres, Kumar Venkataraman, Peter Wysocki, Scott Yonker, and seminar participants at University of Miami, University of Tennessee, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), and 22nd Annual Conference on Financial Economics and Accounting for helpful comments and valuable suggestions. We are very grateful to Jefferson Duarte and Lance Young for allowing us to use their PIN decomposition data, and Hongping Tan for sharing the analyst location data. We also thank the Financial Markets Research Center at Vanderbilt University for providing the effective spread data. We are responsible for all remaining errors and omissions.

Transcript of · PDF fileLeveling the Playing Field: Financial Regulation and Disappearing Local Bias of...

Leveling the Playing Field: Financial Regulation and

Disappearing Local Bias of Institutional Investors∗

Gennaro Bernile, University of Miami

Alok Kumar, University of Miami

Johan Sulaeman, Southern Methodist University

July 5, 2012

Abstract – This study examines whether exogenous regulatory shocks induced by Regulation Fair

Disclosure and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduce the local bias and the local informational advantage of

institutional investors. We find that, following regulatory changes, the local bias and local informational

advantage of institutional investors around corporate headquarters declines sharply as their selective

access to private information is curtailed. The decline in local institutional ownership is more salient

among firms that had more opaque information environments prior to the regulatory changes. Even at

the aggregate market-level, the degree of informed trading attributed to local investors declines. The

local informational advantage of sell-side equity analysts who are more likely to have selective access

exhibits a similar declining pattern and disappears in the post-regulation period. In contrast, regulatory

changes have minimal impact on the local informational advantage of institutions in economically

relevant regions as they are unlikely to have selective access to management. These findings indicate

that regulatory changes affected institutional behavior primarily by curtailing their selective access to

management rather than adversely affecting their information processing advantages.

∗Please address all correspondence to Alok Kumar, Department of Finance, School of Busi-ness Administration, 514G Jenkins Building, University of Miami, Coral Gables, FL 33124;Phone: 305-284-1882; email: [email protected]. Gennaro Bernile can be reached at 305-284-6690 or [email protected]. Johan Sulaeman can be reached at 214-768-8284 [email protected]. We thank an anonymous referee, Anup Agrawal, Warren Bailey, ScottBauguess, Vidhi Chhaochharia, Larry Fauver, Rocco Huang, George Korniotis, S. P. Kothari, KelvinLaw, Evgeny Lyandres, Kumar Venkataraman, Peter Wysocki, Scott Yonker, and seminar participantsat University of Miami, University of Tennessee, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), and22nd Annual Conference on Financial Economics and Accounting for helpful comments and valuablesuggestions. We are very grateful to Jefferson Duarte and Lance Young for allowing us to use theirPIN decomposition data, and Hongping Tan for sharing the analyst location data. We also thank theFinancial Markets Research Center at Vanderbilt University for providing the effective spread data.We are responsible for all remaining errors and omissions.

Leveling the Playing Field: Financial Regulation and DisappearingLocal Bias of Institutional Investors

Abstract – This study examines whether exogenous regulatory shocks induced by Regulation

Fair Disclosure and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduce the local bias and the local informational

advantage of institutional investors. We find that, following regulatory changes, the local bias

and local informational advantage of institutional investors around corporate headquarters de-

clines sharply as their selective access to private information is curtailed. The decline in local

institutional ownership is more salient among firms that had more opaque information envi-

ronments prior to the regulatory changes. Even at the aggregate market-level, the degree of

informed trading attributed to local investors declines. The local informational advantage of

sell-side equity analysts who are more likely to have selective access exhibits a similar declin-

ing pattern and disappears in the post-regulation period. In contrast, regulatory changes have

minimal impact on the local informational advantage of institutions in economically relevant

regions as they are unlikely to have selective access to management. These findings indicate

that regulatory changes affected institutional behavior primarily by curtailing their selective

access to management rather than adversely affecting their information processing advantages.

1. Introduction

Financial regulatory reforms such as the Regulation Fair Disclosure (Reg FD) and the Sarbanes-

Oxley Act (SOX) generated exogenous shocks to the information environments of publicly-traded

firms in the U.S. These regulatory changes were designed to influence the perceived quality of

financial information that firms are required to disclose publicly. Those new rules also affected

the flow and timing of information dissemination.

For example, Reg FD was aimed at “leveling the playing field” among different types of

investors. Its rules were designed to curb selective disclosure of information to market par-

ticipants and mandated the disclosure of all material information to all investors at the same

time. Similarly, SOX mandated the implementation of new rules for financial reporting by pub-

lic companies with the intent to improve its transparency, reliability, and accountability. In

particular, SOX addressed issues such as enhanced financial disclosure, auditor independence,

and corporate governance (Coates (2007)).

In this study, we examine whether financial regulatory reforms affected the local ownership

patterns and local informational advantage of institutional investors.1 Our analysis is motivated

by the recent research in local bias, which demonstrates that institutional investors may have

superior information about local stocks. Consequently, those investors earn higher return from

their local stock investments (e.g., Coval and Moskowitz (1999, 2001), Baik, Kang, and Kim

(2010), Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012)).

While the evidence of local bias and superior local performance is robust and economi-

cally significant, the channels through which institutions improve the performance of their local

investments is less clear. For example, do local institutions have selective access to superior pri-

vate information? Or, do they earn superior returns from their local investments by processing

publicly available information more effectively?

If selective access to value relevant information was an important determinant of institutional

preferences for local firms, then Reg FD should reduce the local informational advantage and the

local bias in institutional portfolios.2 Moreover, if local institutions had no other competitive

advantage in processing their privately available information, the local ownership-performance

1Ideally, we would also like to study the impact of regulation on the local bias of retail investors. Unfortunately,data on the portfolio holdings of U.S. retail investors around the period of regulatory changes are not available.

2We do not use the term “local bias” to strictly imply that the local stock preference is “irrational”. The“bias” towards local investments could be induced by a familiarity bias or may arise from informational reasons.

1

relation should decline following the implementation of Reg FD.

Local investors, however, could also have a competitive advantage in exploiting publicly

disclosed information, especially if this information is perceived to be of low quality. For example,

to compensate for low disclosure quality, local investors may be able to directly inspect local

firms and could acquire information about local firms’ operations more easily. They may also be

able to collect information from local sources (e.g., customers and suppliers) at a lower cost. In

principle, various provisions of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) affected this potential source of

local informational advantage by mandating improvements in the transparency, reliability, and

accountability of financial reporting.

If proximity to the firm’s headquarters and operations indeed reduces investors’ costs of pro-

cessing lower quality public disclosures, then the local informational advantage would be further

weakened following the passage of SOX. And, by the same logic, the perceived improvement

in the reliability of firms’ financial reports should induce investors to tilt their portfolios more

heavily toward non-local investments, which they may have previously shunned.

We use the natural experiment of regulatory changes in the U.S. to identify whether in-

stitutions are able to generate superior returns from their local investments through selective

access to private information or superior processing of publicly-available information. The two

regulatory changes (Reg FD and SOX) affected the access to private information and the quality

of publicly available information. However, these changes had no impact on investors’ ability

to interpret the publicly available information. If local bias of investors is induced by access

to private information, following the regulatory changes the local bias and local performance of

institutions would decline.

Our empirical analysis focuses on the behavior of local investors around corporate head-

quarters as selective access to private information is likely to be more prevalent. However,

motivated by the finding in Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012), who demonstrate that in-

stitutions in economically relevant regions earn superior returns although they are unlikely to

have selective access, we also examine whether investors in regions where firms have economic

rather than physical presence are affected by regulatory changes. This analysis allows us to

determine whether selective access to management or superior information processing abilities

is the dominant channel through which local institutions earn higher returns from their local

investments.

2

To further distinguish between selective access and information processing based explana-

tions, we examine the role of other local market participants such as local sell-side equity ana-

lysts. Specifically, we examine whether sell-side analysts who are more likely to have selective

access to firm management also exhibit a declining trend in local coverage and local forecast

accuracy. In this context, we also investigate whether local analysts facilitate the information

gathering activities of local institutional investors.

We test these hypotheses using the quarterly portfolio holdings of 13(f) institutions during

the 1996 to 2008 period. First, we conduct our analysis in a static setting and examine whether

certain features of the information environment in which a firm operates, including local analyst

coverage, can explain the variation in the level of local ownership. Consistent with our main

conjecture, we find that excess local holdings of institutional investors decline sharply following

the regulatory changes. The average excess local institutional ownership (LOCOWN) is cut by

almost one half. In the pre-regulation period (1996-2000), the average excess LOCOWN is 7.68%

and it drops to 3.98% in the post-regulation period (2003-2008).3 Further, the sharp decline in

local institutional ownership around the adoption of Reg FD and SOX does not continue after

2004. The average excess local institutional ownership stabilizes at a level of about 4% in the

post-SOX period.

This observed pattern in excess local ownership is inconsistent with alternative explanations

of our findings that rely on secular time-series patterns in technological advancement, which

could systematically affect firm transparency or institutional preferences and “level the playing

field”. In particular, secular trends in disclosure practices induced by technological innovations

(e.g., cheaper access to the Internet) are unlikely to explain our findings since it is not obvious

why those trends would suddenly stop in the post-regulation period. Similarly, it would be

hard to explain why a trend in institutional preferences would suddenly stop and coincide

with regulatory changes. In particular, we show that our findings do not reflect the changing

preferences of institutional investors during the rise and fall of the technology sector around the

year 2001.

The investment behavior of non-local investors also changes significantly following the regula-

tory reforms. Specifically, during the post-regulation period, non-local ownership levels increase

3These shifts in excess local ownership mainly reflect changes in actual local ownership levels since the expectedlocal ownership levels do not vary significantly over time.

3

and firm ownership becomes more diffused geographically as the information environment im-

proves. This evidence is consistent with the notion that non-local investors avoid stocks of firms

for which they may be at an informational disadvantage and that the new rules reduce those

concerns.

Next, in a dynamic setting, we test whether the relation between information environment

and local bias varies across the regulatory regimes. To ensure that the causal link is from

firm-level information environment to local institutional ownership and not vice versa, we also

estimate a series of difference-in-difference regressions. These tests are designed to identify

whether the impact of the new regulation on the portfolio decisions of local institutional investors

is greater for firms that operated in a more opaque and less competitive information environment

prior to regulatory changes.

We find that while excess local ownership levels vary inversely with the quality of firms’

information environments prior to Reg FD, this relation is significantly weaker in the post-SOX

regime. Finally, consistent with the information environment causing excess local ownership

prior to Reg FD, the firm-level decline in local ownership is more pronounced among firms that

operated in more opaque and less competitive information environments (e.g., large discretionary

accruals, no major auditor, low liquidity, high skewness, no analyst following) prior to the

reforms.

In the second part of the paper, we investigate whether the ability of institutions to generate

abnormal returns from their local investments and their impact on the trading environment are

affected by the reforms. A natural implication of our arguments is that the relation between

excess local ownership and future stock performance should be weaker in the post-regulation

period. In addition, the strength of the relation between excess local ownership and market-wide

measures of adverse selection should decline.

Consistent with these conjectures, we find that there is a sharp decline in the ability of

institutional investors to generate abnormal returns from their local investments. In the pre-

regulation period, there is a significant positive relation between local ownership levels and

subsequent quarter performance of local stocks. But during the post-SOX period, the infor-

mational advantage of local investors disappears. Further tests using market-wide measures

of informed trading indicate that the relation between local bias and subsequent incidence of

informed trading is weaker in the new regulatory regime.

4

Specifically, we use the decomposition of the probability of informed trading (PIN) measure

proposed in Duarte and Young (2009) and find that there is a strong direct relation between the

adverse selection component of PIN (i.e., adjusted PIN or ADJPIN) and local bias in the pre-

FD regime. However, this relation becomes statistically and economically insignificant following

SOX. By contrast, the relation between local bias and the liquidity component of PIN (i.e., the

estimated probability of symmetric order flow shocks) remains strongly positive and significant

throughout the sample period. These results suggest that while the role of local investors as

liquidity providers was not affected by the new rules, their ability to engage in information-based

trading was significantly curtailed in the post-regulation period.

For robustness, we examine the impact of local ownership on subsequent effective trading

spreads based on the assumption that these spreads are directly related to the adverse selec-

tion component of stock prices (e.g., Eleswarapu, Thompson, and Venkataraman (2004)). Once

again, consistent with the idea that local investors possess an informational advantage, we find

that during the pre-regulation period there is a strong direct relation between local bias and sub-

sequent trading spreads. The local bias-spread relation, however, becomes significantly weaker

in the post-regulation period, and particularly outside of earnings announcement windows where

local investors’ ability to exploit local information sources may have been most valuable.

These results indicate that institutional preferences for local stocks is strongly influenced

by the characteristics of firms’ information environments. The unprecedented changes in the

information environment induced by Reg FD and SOX influence the portfolio decisions of in-

stitutional investors significantly. Prior to Reg FD and SOX, institutions seek local investment

opportunities for which they are likely to enjoy a competitive advantage in gathering and pro-

cessing of information. Following the implementation of regulations aimed at “leveling the

information playing field” and designed to improve the quality and reliability of public disclo-

sures, the informational advantage of local institutions disappears and the bias of their portfolios

toward local firms is greatly reduced. As a result, local institutional ownership declines and firm

ownership becomes more diffused geographically.

In the last part of the paper, we investigate whether regulatory changes affect informational

advantage of local investors by curtailing selective access to private information or reducing the

potential information processing advantages of institutional investors. Specifically, we examine

the impact of regulatory changes on two groups of market participants that are ex ante expected

5

to have different degrees of selective access to management. On the one hand, institutions in

regions where firms have economic rather than physical presence are less likely to have selec-

tive access to management as these economically relevant (ER) regions are often physically far

away from the firm headquarters.4 But on the other hand, sell-side analysts around corporate

headquarters are more likely to have benefited from selective access to firm management.

If the main effect of regulatory changes is to curtail selective access to management, we

expect to observe a weaker effect on institutions in economically relevant states and a stronger

effect among sell-side equity analysts. Consistent with this conjecture, we find that the local

informational advantage of sell-side equity analysts who are more likely to have selective access

exhibits a similar declining pattern and disappears in the post-regulation period. In contrast,

regulatory changes have minimal impact on the local informational advantage of institutions

in economically relevant regions as they are less likely to have selective access to management.

These findings indicate that regulatory changes affected institutional behavior primarily by cur-

tailing their selective access to management rather than by adversely affecting their information

processing advantages.

Beyond this identification method, we use a market-based test to further attempt to identify

whether selective access to private information or superior information processing yields greater

local informational advantage to institutional investors. The evidence from this test suggests

that informed trading ahead of earnings announcements, which are likely to be driven by selective

access to private information, are less likely to be associated with local ownership following the

regulatory reforms. This finding is consistent with the conjecture that financial regulation

curtailed local institutional investors’ preferential access to private information.

Collectively, our findings contribute to both the local bias and the regulation literatures. We

show that the local bias of investors around headquarters is likely to be influenced by selective

access to information rather than superior processing of information. At a more fundamental

level, we show how access to different types of information (private and public) and disclosure

policies affect the behavior of market participants (institutions and sell-side analysts) and market

4We identify states that are economically relevant for a firm through a textual analysis of the firm’s annualaccounting reports. This economic relevance measure of a U.S. state for a firm is based on the citation share ofthe state in the firm’s annual accounting reports. The citation share of a firm-state pair is defined as the numberof times the U.S. state is cited in the relevant sections of the annual financial statement of a firm divided by thetotal number of citations of all U.S. locations. Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012) provide additional detailsabout this measure.

6

prices.

While some of these findings may appear “obvious” in light of the stated intent of regula-

tory reforms introduced by Reg FD and SOX, the documented link between financial regulation

and local ownership is novel and makes a fundamental contribution to the local bias litera-

ture. In particular, we demonstrate that access to superior private information is an important

determinant of the local bias phenomenon around corporate headquarters.

Further, in a new economic setting, we show that the regulatory reforms have been effective,

although our analysis does not speak to their efficiency. In particular, the declines in the

level of local bias and local informational advantage of institutional investors indicate that

consistent with their stated intent the new rules substantially changed the competitive landscape

of the information acquisition process. Of course, the consequences of regulatory changes on the

behavior of local investors may have been unintended or unanticipated.

Our paper is related to Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012) but there are several key

differences between the two studies. Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012) examine whether

economic proximity between firms and investors is more valuable than physical proximity. They

find that institutional preference for local firms that are economically present is stronger than

local firms with physical presence. Further, institutional investors in economically relevant

regions outperform investors around firm headquarters. These findings suggest that institutional

investors in economically relevant regions are relatively more sophisticated and they may be able

to use local information more effectively than local investors around corporate headquarters.

In contrast, the primary focus of the current paper is to examine how regulatory changes

affect the information channels of institutions in headquarters states and economically relevant

states. We exploit the observation that the degree of selective access to firm management dif-

fers at these two locations and examine whether selective access to management or superior

processing of publicly available information is the primary source of local informational ad-

vantage of institutional investors. Overall, our findings complement the evidence in Bernile,

Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012) and provide new insights into the channels through which equity

market participants around corporate headquarters and in economically relevant states gather

information.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, we present a brief review

of the related literature and summarize our main testable hypotheses. In Section 3, we describe

7

our data sources. We present our main empirical findings in Sections 4 and 5. We conclude in

Section 6 with a brief summary of the paper.

2. Related Literature and Testable Hypotheses

Our study is motivated by recent studies in financial regulation and local bias. In this section,

we summarize the related regulation and the local bias literatures and use the findings from

those studies to develop our main testable hypotheses.

2.1. Financial Regulation and the Information Environment

Public companies regularly hold conference calls when their quarterly earnings reports are re-

leased to communicate issues that are not covered in those reports. Until the late 1990s, these

conference calls were typically restricted to equity analysts and investors with substantial capi-

tal. Additionally, communication access to top-level corporate executives was severely restricted

to only these large market players. Companies argued that providing the same level of access

to all investors would be too costly.

As cheap access to conference calls proliferated with the advent of the Internet in the late

1990s, this cost argument became less relevant. In response, the U.S. Securities and Exchange

Commission (SEC) initially proposed the Regulation Fair Disclosure (Reg FD) in December

1999. The proposal included new rules prohibiting publicly-traded companies from selectively

disclosing material non-public information to securities markets professionals ahead of general

public disclosure. The general principle advocated by the new rules was that the disclosure of

material information should be made to all investors at the same time.

A debate occurred before the adoption of the new rules as small investors supported the

regulation while large investors argued that forcing managers to provide equal access to all

investors would lead to less access to value-relevant information for all investors (e.g., Weber

(2000a, 2000b), Shiller (2000), SEC (2000), Hasset (2000), Bushee, Matsumoto, and Miller

(2004), Duarte, Han, Harford, and Young (2008)). While acknowledging some of the concerns,

the SEC approved Regulation FD in October 2000. Although the new rules affect all mar-

ket participants to some degree, their impact may have been amplified for particular classes of

investors who enjoyed selective access to value-relevant information in the pre-Reg FD environ-

8

ment. In particular, if proximity to management facilitated selective access to value relevant

information, curbing of selective disclosures may have reduced the competitive advantage of

local institutional shareholders.

The available empirical evidence on the consequences of Reg FD is somewhat mixed. Several

studies find no significant changes in stock price volatility (e.g., Bailey, Li, Mao, and Zhong

(2003)), analysts’ forecast accuracy (e.g., Heflin, Subramanyam, and Zhang (2003)), and effective

trading spreads (Eleswarapu, Thompson, and Venkataraman (2004)), which suggests that Reg

FD did not adversely affect the overall market quality. Consistent with these findings, Bushee,

Matsumoto, and Miller (2004) conclude that Reg FD did not have a large adverse effect on

the disclosure policies of firms that previously allowed selective access to conference calls and

that small investors benefited from the new rules. Duarte, Han, Harford, and Young (2008),

however, document that Reg FD is associated with a slight increase in the typical firm’s cost of

capital. This finding suggests that the benefits to small investors may have come at the expense

of reduced price efficiency.

Around the time of Reg FD, the public’s confidence in the financial market was considerably

affected by fraudulent accounting scandals at Enron, WorldCom, and several other companies.

For example, in the case of WorldCom, fraudulent accounting practices resulted in over-reporting

of assets by around $11 billion. These highly-publicized scandals exposed significant conflicts

of interest problems in the relation between corporations and their financial auditors. At least

partially motivated by these scandals, several new proposals were introduced to curb fraudulent

accounting practices (Holmstrom and Kaplan (2003), Coates (2007)).

The Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX) was enacted in July 2002 with widespread approval by

individual investors and investment groups, and large opposition by companies and industry

groups (Hochberg, Sapienza, and Vissing-Jorgensen (2009)). The proponents of these rules

advocated them as necessary to restore the smooth functioning of capital markets, which had

been undermined by the deteriorating quality of accounting information as attested by the series

of unprecedented accounting scandals. In particular, SOX mandated new rules that would

lead to enhanced financial disclosure, greater auditor independence, and improved corporate

governance with the intent to improve the transparency, reliability, and accountability of firms’

financial reports (Coates (2007)).5

5For example, most notably, Sections 101-109 created the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board

9

While the impact of SOX on overall efficiency is still debatable (e.g., Cohen, Dey, and Lys

(2008)), the available evidence indicates that the enhanced quantity and quality of financial

disclosure advocated by this regulation increased the confidence of the public, especially the

confidence of relatively uninformed investors. These improvements in turn should decrease

investors’ perceived costs of relying on firms’ periodic financial reports.

For example, although they reach different conclusions regarding overall efficiency, the evi-

dence in Zhang (2007), Chhaochharia and Grinstein (2007), Li, Pincus, and Rego (2008), and

Iliev (2010) consistently indicates that SOX requirements are likely to be most beneficial to firms

that operated in more opaque information environments prior to the new rules. These conclu-

sions are supported by the recent analysis in Bauguess, Bernile, Lee, Marietta-Westberg, and

Alexander (2012). They find that although compliance costs remain a concern among smaller

firms, corporate insiders’ views on the benefits of SOX rules largely support the notion that they

improve the quality of financial reporting and control processes and, thus, increase investors’

confidence of investors.

Overall, the supporters of the new regulation argue that both Reg FD and SOX lead to

a more level playing field for relatively uninformed investors. At least to some extent, these

regulations should make the information environment more competitive and reduce the infor-

mation asymmetry among investors. In particular, Reg FD prevents companies from disclosing

information to selected market participants and SOX provides confidence to investors as they

examine the financial reports of publicly-traded firms.

2.2. Financial Regulation and Behavior of Local Institutions

Do these regulatory changes adversely affect the informational advantage of local market partic-

ipants such as institutional investors and sell-side equity analysts? Anecdotal evidence suggests

that physical proximity to firm management is likely to yield informational advantage to local

institutional investors. In fact, in its release of Reg FD, the SEC explicitly mentioned that firms

(PCAOB) to provide for auditors’ oversight; Sections 302, 401-406, 408-409, and 906 mandated new disclosurerules pertaining to internal control systems and officer certifications; Sections 201-209 and 303 further regulatedpublic company auditors and auditor-client relationship; Sections 301, 304, 306, and 407 introduced requirementsfor listed companies pertaining to the composition of audit and control committees, and banned officer loans;Sections 802, 807, 902-905, 1102, 1104, and 1106 introduced criminal penalties for fraudulent misreporting; andSections 806 and 1107 introduced new whistle-blower protections.

10

often disclose non-public information to both securities analysts and institutional investors.6

Beyond this anecdotal evidence, previous research on local and home bias suggests that

excess local holdings of institutional investors may reflect superior local information (e.g., Coval

and Moskowitz (1999, 2001), Baik, Kang, and Kim (2010), Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman

(2012)). Similarly, sell-side equity analysts may have relatively better information about local

firms (e.g., Malloy (2005)). Local market participants may be able to extract greater benefits

from local stocks with high information asymmetry either due to selective access to local private

information or because geographical proximity reduces their public information gathering and

processing costs.

In this paper, our main objective is to examine whether the exogenous shocks generated by

regulatory changes (Reg FD and SOX) influenced the ownership patterns and informational ad-

vantage of institutional investors. Our identification strategy uses exogenous regulatory changes

as a natural experiment and relies on the time-series properties of local institutional ownership

and local informational advantage as the information environment experiences these large regu-

latory shocks. We focus on the behavior of institutional investors, but we also examine whether

sell-side equity analysts affect institutional local bias and their local informational advantage.

We organize our empirical analysis around three broad sets of hypotheses. These conjectures

summarize the potential impact of regulatory changes on (i) local ownership levels, (ii) local

information advantage, and (iii) various channels through which local market participants obtain

information about local firms.

6Two subsequent SEC enforcement cases provide evidence of selective disclosure practices that may havebenefited local institutional investors. In November 2001, the SEC contested that the CEO of Siebel Systems,a California-based technology company, disclosed nonpublic information to selected investors at an invitation-only technology conference hosted by Goldman Sachs & Company in California. In response to questions froma Goldman Sachs analyst, the CEO announced that he was optimistic about the firm since the business wasreturning to normal. This announcement was opposite to the negative statements made by the CEO threeweeks earlier. Following the disclosure at the conference, attendees purchased Siebel’s stocks or communicatedthe information to others who purchased Siebel’s shares. Following the conference, Siebel experienced a one-day stock return of about 20% and trading volume twice as its daily average. Thus, investors who attendedthe conference enjoyed a substantial informational advantage. In another relevant enforcement case, the SECcontested in March 2002 that the CEO of Secure Computing (John McNulty) disclosed nonpublic informationabout a significant contract to two portfolio managers in violation of the Reg FD. The SEC took exception tothe fact that Secure actively promoted its stock to institutional investors through in-person presentations, inaddition to a series of conference calls and email exchanges with selected investors. Source: Secure ComputingCorporation and John McNulty, Exchange Act Release No. 46895, 2002 WL 310948 (November 25, 2002).

11

2.2.1 Impact on Local Ownership

Before examining the impact of regulatory shocks on the behavior of local market participants,

we identify the types of stocks where local institutional ownership and local informational ad-

vantage of institutional investors are likely to be stronger. Basic economic intuition suggests

that local investors would gravitate toward firms with high information asymmetry to exploit

their potential local informational advantage. Based on this insight, we posit that:

H1a: If institutions exhibit an abnormal preference for local stocks mainly due to an

informational advantage, firms with lower information quality and less competitive

information environments would have stronger local institutional ownership.

If institutional local preferences at least partially reflect investors’ attempts to exploit the

potentially uneven playing field, regulatory changes designed to level the playing field among

different types of investors would influence the local institutional ownership patterns. In par-

ticular, exogenous adverse shocks to the sources of local informational advantage would induce

institutions to reduce their holdings of local stocks. Our specific conjecture is:

H1b: Following regulatory changes, as the information environment becomes more

competitive, local ownership levels around corporate headquarters would decrease

and the overall firm ownership would become more diffused.

If more opaque and less competitive information environments generate higher levels of local

ownership, then the reduction in local holdings resulting from the new rules should be more

pronounced among certain types of firms. This set would include firms for which the local

information advantage was likely higher prior to the adoption of the new rules and, thus, whose

information environment is more likely to be affected by the regulatory changes. More formally,

we posit that:

H1c: The regulatory changes would most strongly affect the local ownership levels

and the local informational advantage among firms that have the worst information

environments during the pre-regulation period.

12

2.2.2 Impact on Local Informational Advantage

While a more opaque and less competitive information environment may attract investors who

can access local sources of information, this effect on local investors’ portfolios should be greatly

reduced or muted if the new regulatory rules level the competition for information acquisition.

Thus, the relation between firms’ information environments and investors’ portfolio performance

should fundamentally change following the passage of the new rules because the rules greatly

reduce or altogether eliminate at least some sources of local investors’ competitive advantage.

To determine whether financial regulation eliminated the local informational advantage of

institutional investors, we perform a series of market-based tests. First, to test whether the

informational advantage of local investors changes around the regulatory reforms, we estimate

the relation between local investors’ holdings and future stock performance conditional on the

regulatory regime. We posit that:

H2a: If the regulatory shocks have a positive impact on the information dissemina-

tion process and an adverse effect on the ability of local investors to obtain private

information, local ownership levels should contain less information about future stock

returns in the post-regulation period.

Second, based on a similar logic, we perform additional tests to assess the conditional relation

between excess local holdings and two common microstructure measures (PIN and effective

spread) that capture the adverse selection component of stock prices. Similar to the performance

tests, we conjecture that:

H2b: Prior to the implementation of the new rules, institutional local bias would

be more strongly related to the subsequent levels of adverse selection measures.

Following regulatory changes, this relation would weaken.

2.2.3 Impact on Local Informational Channels

In the next set of hypotheses, we investigate which source of informational advantage is more

adversely affected by regulatory changes. Regulatory changes could curtail selective access to

private information and they can also reduce the potential superior information processing ability

of institutional investors. Identifying which of these two informational advantage channels is

13

affected more by regulatory changes is an empirical question. Our next two hypotheses aim to

identify the dominant source of local informational advantage of institutional investors.

The first hypothesis related to information channels is based on the assumption that institu-

tions in regions where firms have economic rather than physical presence are less likely to have

selective access to management. These economically relevant (ER) regions are often physically

far away from the firm headquarters. However, institutions in economically relevant regions

may use bits of locally-generated information that could get lost in the information aggregation

process. Overall, the potential informational advantage of institutions in economically relevant

non-HQ locations is unlikely to emerge from selective access to management.

Our specific conjecture is:

H3a: If regulatory changes affect selective access to private information more than

information processing advantage, local ownership and local informational advan-

tage of institutions would be more strongly affected in headquarters states than in

economically relevant states.

We use an additional identification method to determine whether regulatory changes cur-

tailed selective access to information or reduced the information processing advantages of local

market participants. Specifically, we examine how the coverage of stocks by local sell-side equity

analysts and their forecast accuracy change over time. Previous studies use multiple approaches

to demonstrate that a significant determinant of the forecasting behavior of sell-side equity ana-

lysts is selective access to firm management (e.g., Bailey, Li, Mao, and Zhong (2003), Gintschel

and Markov (2004), Agrawal, Chadha, and Chen (2006)). If regulatory changes affect local

informational advantage through the selective disclosure channel more than the information

processing channel, we expect to find similar declining trend in the local coverage of equity

analysts and their local informational advantage, as their selective access to firm management

is curtailed.

H3b: If regulatory changes affect selective access to private information more than

information processing advantage, local coverage of equity analysts and their local

informational advantage would also decline during the post-regulation period.

Beyond testing this conjecture, our empirical tests examine the interactions among local ana-

lysts and local institutional investors. Specifically, we investigate whether regulatory changes

14

influence the distinct information-gathering activities of local analysts and local institutions

separately or whether local analysts are the primary source of institutions’ local informational

advantage. In this scenarios, the declining local informational advantage of institutions could

merely reflect the declining informational advantage of local analysts.

Last, we use a market-based test to further attempt to identify whether selective access to

private information or superior information processing yields greater local informational advan-

tage to institutional investors. If the effects of regulatory changes are mostly due to the reduction

in selective access, the attenuating effect of regulatory changes on the local ownership-adverse

selection relation should be stronger in the period prior to public disclosures such as earnings

announcements. However, if the effects of regulatory changes are mostly due to a reduction in

local investors’ superior ability to process information after it is disclosed, we should observe

a stronger attenuating effect in the period subsequent to public disclosures. To summarize, we

posit that:

H3c: The local ownership-effective spread relation would become weaker in pre-

disclosure periods if regulatory changes affect selective access to private information

more than information processing advantage of publicly available information.

In the next section, we briefly describe the datasets used to test these empirical predictions.

3. Data and Measures

3.1. Main Data Sources

Our core dataset contains all Compustat firms with available 10-K filings in Electronic Data

Gathering, Analysis, and Retrieval system (EDGAR), with fiscal years ending between 1996 and

2008. There are 47,625 firm-year observations in our core dataset. Our second main dataset

is the quarterly common stock holdings of 13(f) institutions compiled by Thomson Reuters.

We identify the institutional location (zip code) using the Nelson’s Directory of Investment

Managers and by searching the SEC documents and web sites of institutional managers. Our

last main dataset is the research coverage of sell-side equity analysts obtained from Thomson

Reuters’ I/B/E/S database. We augment this dataset with analyst location data.

15

In addition to these main data sources, we use several other standard datasets. We obtain

price, volume, return, and industry membership data from the Center for Research on Security

Prices (CRSP). The firm headquarters location data are from the CRSP-Compustat merged

(CCM) file. We obtain the performance benchmarks for computing characteristic-adjusted stock

returns from Russell Wermers’ web site.7 Data on auditors’ identity and various other firm

attributes are from Compustat.

We also use state-level Presidential elections data to identify the political orientation of

U.S. states.8 We obtain additional state-level demographic characteristics from the U.S. Census

Bureau. Specifically, we consider state population density and the state education level (the

proportion of state population above age 25 that has completed a bachelor’s degree or higher) in

our local ownership regressions. Further, using the religious adherence data from the “Churches

and Church Membership” files available through the American Religion Data Archive (ARDA),

we compute the proportion of Catholics (CATH) and the proportion of Protestants (PROT) in

a state. Using the two religion variables, we define the Catholic-Protestant ratio (CPRATIO)

to capture the relative proportions of Catholics and Protestants in a state. We also measure the

overall religiosity of a region.

3.2. Excess Local Ownership Measure

The level of local institutional ownership is at the core of all our testable hypotheses. Thus,

the first set of key measures used in our empirical analysis are the abnormal local ownership

levels of each firm in the headquarters (HQ) state and in the most economically relevant (ER)

non-headquarters states. Following Korniotis and Kumar (2012), we measure the quarterly local

institutional ownership for each firm-state pair as the ratio of the number of firm shares held

by institutions located within the state and the total institutional share ownership at the end

of the quarter.

To provide a benchmark for comparison, we calculate the percentage weight of local institu-

tions in the aggregate institutional portfolio, which is constructed by combining the portfolios

of all institutions. The weight in the aggregate portfolio represents the expected level of owner-

ship by local institutions if they did not exhibit an abnormal preference for firms with physical

7The web site is http://www.smith.umd.edu/faculty/rwermers/ftpsite/Dgtw/coverpage.htm.8The election data are obtained from David Leip’s web site: http://www.uselectionatlas.org.

16

or economic presence in their state and, therefore, their portfolio weights merely reflect the

“market portfolio” weights. We use the state-level benchmarks to account for the non-uniform

geographical distribution of institutions across the U.S. The local ownership benchmarks are

higher for states with greater concentration of institutional investors.

Using the two measures, we define each firm-state pair’s excess local institutional ownership

level (LOCOWN) as the difference between the quarterly local institutional ownership level

of that firm-state pair and the percentage weight of the state’s institutional investors in the

aggregate institutional portfolio:

LOCOWNij =State j institutional ownership in firm i

Total institutional ownership in firm i

− Dollar value of institutional portfolios in state j

Dollar value of aggregate institutional portfolios(1)

In addition to firm-level local ownership measure, we use an institution-level local bias

measure in the empirical analysis. Motivated by previous local bias studies (e.g., Coval and

Moskowitz (2001), Ivkovic and Weisbenner (2005)), we use the following equation to measure

the local bias of institution i around firm headquarters:

HQ Local Biasi = Weight allocated to firms with headquarters in the state

− Market portfolio weight of firms headquartered in the state. (2)

Here, “weight allocated to firms with headquarters in the state” is the dollar value of the

institutional holdings in firms that are headquartered in the state in which institution i is

located divided by the total dollar value of all of holdings of institution i. The second term is

the benchmark weight and is defined as the total market value of firms headquartered in the

state in which institution i is located divided by the aggregate market value of all firms in the

market portfolio. If institution i follows the prescriptions of the traditional portfolio theory and

holds the well-diversified market portfolio, the HQ local bias measure would be zero.

3.3. Information Environment Proxies

Beyond local ownership levels, most of our testable hypotheses relate to the information envi-

ronment of publicly-traded firms. To characterize a firm’s information environment, motivated

17

by the previous literature, we use multiple firm attributes. Our first set of proxies are market-

based measures of information asymmetry. Specifically, we consider the stock turnover measure

(a proxy for liquidity) as better disclosure policies should reduce information asymmetry among

investors and, therefore, increase liquidity (e.g., Glosten and Milgrom (1985), Leuz and Ver-

recchia (2000)). Our second market-based information environment measure is idiosyncratic

volatility since firms with low quality earnings have higher idiosyncratic return volatility (e.g.,

Diamond and Verrecchia (1991), Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2011)).9 Last, we consider

idiosyncratic skewness to characterize a firm’s information environment because higher informa-

tion ambiguity induces higher volatility and skewness in stock returns (Epstein and Schneider

(2008)).

Our second set of proxies for a firm’s information environment are based on the presence

of information intermediaries. This choice is based on the assumption that the presence of

reputable auditors and other information intermediaries is associated with more transparent

and competitive information environments (e.g., Healy and Palepu (2001)). For instance, ana-

lyst following is directly related to availability of management forecasts (e.g., Soffer, Walther,

and Thiagarajan (2000)) and disclosure quality (e.g., Lang and Lundholm (1993)). In partic-

ular, Malloy (2005) demonstrates that analysts located near firm headquarters have additional

informational advantage.

Further, auditors provide assurance that financial statements comply with accounting stan-

dards. They also alleviate potential concerns about the quality of information disclosed, as

attested by the evidence that hiring a reputable auditor can be beneficial even when not re-

quired by regulation (e.g., Leftwich (1983), Menon and Williams (1991)).

Our last information environment proxy is based on accounting data. Specifically, following

common practice, we use the absolute modified-Jones discretionary accruals as a proxy for

earnings quality. Higher values of this measure are likely to be associated with greater earnings

management and worse information environments (e.g., Cohen, Dey, and Lys (2008)).

Table 1 provides the summary statistics for the main variables used in the empirical analysis.

We report the key statistics for the full sample, pre-Reg FD period (1996 to 2000), post-Reg FD

9Although low earnings quality can lead to higher idiosyncratic volatility, recent work by Hutton, Marcus,and Tehranian (2009) may indicate otherwise. Hutton et al. find that opaque (low quality) financial reports areassociated with higher R2 and, thus, lower scaled idiosyncratic volatility. While we use the unscaled measureof idiosyncratic volatility in our tests similar to Rajgopal and Venkatachalam (2011), we admit that the recentevidence in Hutton et al. suggests that its interpretation may be ambiguous.

18

and pre-SOX period (2001 to 2002), and post-SOX period (2003-2008). The Appendix provides

brief definitions of all these variables.

4. Empirical Results

4.1. Aggregate Time-Series Patterns in Local Ownership

We begin our empirical analysis by presenting a time-series plot of the local ownership level

around firm headquarters. Figure 1 shows the mean excess local ownership (LOCOWN) com-

puted at the end of each fiscal year using the portfolio holdings of all institutional investors in

our sample. These results are also presented in Table 2.10

We find that although the overall level of institutional ownership exhibits an increasing trend

(see Column (1)), the level of local institutional ownership exhibits a significant decline following

the regulatory changes. Consequently, the average level of nonlocal institutional ownership

increases around these changes. The average local ownership level is consistently around 8%

in each year of the pre-regulation period (see Table 2, Column (2)). It drops sharply to below

6% immediately following the passage of Reg FD and then stabilizes at a level of about 4%

in the post-SOX period. Thus, around the regulatory reforms, the excess local ownership of

institutional investors drops by half. These shifts in excess local ownership mainly reflect changes

in actual local ownership levels since the expected local ownership levels do not vary significantly

over time (see Column (3)).

In absolute terms, the drop in the level of local ownership is larger for smaller firms. Specif-

ically, the local ownership levels for small, medium, and large firms drop from 14.42%, 5.86%,

and 2.98% in 2000 to 8.46%, 2.80%, and 1.91% in 2004, respectively. However, in relative terms,

excess local ownership levels drops by about half across all size groups (see Columns (4) to (6)).

We also observe that there is a structural break in the local ownership time series around the

year 2000. Using Chow (1960) tests to identify potential breakpoints during the 1999 to 2007

period, we find that the most significant breaks occur between 2000 and 2001. Our analysis also

indicates that the break seems to happen earlier for larger stocks than for smaller stocks. This

10Discrepancies in mean LOCOWN across Tables 1 and 2 arise because the sample in Table 1 is restrictedto firm-year observations for which we could obtain information environment variables. For the full sample inTable 2, mean LOCOWN by subperiod is: 7.86% prior to Reg FD; 6.252% after Reg FD but prior to SOX; and4.405% after SOX.

19

evidence is consistent with larger firms complying with RegFD earlier than smaller firms due to

their lower relative fixed cost of conducting open calls and their relative lack of concern about

attracting analysts coverage (Goshen and Parchomovsky (2001)).

When we examine local ownership patterns in states where firms have economic rather than

physical presence (see Table 2, Column (7)), we find that the local ownership levels also exhibit

a declining time trend but the drop is less pronounced.11 This evidence indicates that investors

around headquarters and in economically relevant regions are likely to exhibit an abnormal

preference for local stocks for different reasons. Specifically, the local preference of investors

around headquarters is more likely to be induced by access to private information signals. In

contrast, institutions in economically relevant states may hold local stocks because they are

able to generate abnormal returns from their local investments due to their superior ability to

process public information signals.

We also examine the overall geographical shifts in the composition of firm ownership induced

by regulatory changes. We measure geographical ownership concentration of firms using state-

level institutional ownership data. Specifically, we compute two ownership concentration indices.

The Herfindahl-Hirschman concentration index (HHI) of firm ownership is calculated using state-

level institutional ownership levels across all U.S. states. To account for the “natural” level of

concentration in ownership due to the variation in institutional investors’ presence across the

U.S. states, we use a geographical concentration index (GCI), which captures the “abnormal”

level of ownership concentration.12

We find that firm ownership becomes more diffused geographically following regulatory re-

forms. The mean state-level geographic concentration measure declines from 0.171 in 2000 to

0.115 in 2004, which represents a 32.75% decline between the pre- and post-regulation peri-

ods (see Table 2, Column (10)). Beyond 2004, the GCI measures stabilizes around the 2004

level. This evidence supports the notion that the competitiveness of the information envi-

ronment affects the geographical dispersion in ownership. In particular, non-local institutions

appear significantly more reluctant to invest in distant firms due to their potential information

disadvantage in the pre-regulation period. However, following the implementation of Reg FD

11We compute the change in local ownership around regulatory reforms for headquarters states and economi-cally relevant states. The results are reported in Appendix Table A.1. While the local ownership levels aroundcorporate headquarters decline for almost all U.S. states, the changes in economically relevant states exhibit noconsistent pattern.

12This measure is similar to the industry concentration index of Kacperczyk, Sialm, and Zheng (2005).

20

and SOX, institutional ownership becomes geographically more dispersed due to a decline in

information asymmetry induced by regulatory changes.

Collectively, the time-series patterns in local ownership and concentration measures reveal

that regulatory changes are followed by a decline in local ownership levels and a corresponding

increase in non-local ownership levels. As a result, firm ownership becomes more diffused. While

these time-series trends are consistent with our broad conjecture, we exploit the cross-sectional

variation in the information environment to gather additional support for our key hypotheses.

4.2. Information Environment and Local Ownership

We estimate a series of pooled cross-sectional regressions. To set the stage for subsequent

analyses, we first consider a static setting and examine whether features of the information

environment in which a firm operates affect the level of local ownership. The dependent variable

in these regressions is the excess local ownership in a firm. The main explanatory variables are

firm attributes that characterize the firm’s information environment. In addition, following

Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012), we include year and state fixed effects to account for the

effects of other firm-level (e.g, firm size, stock price, firm age, etc.) and state-level factors (e.g.,

education, religiosity, population density, etc.) that may be important determinants of local

ownership patterns.

In these regressions, the level of excess local institutional ownership in a firm is measured at

the end of the quarter of the fiscal year end date, while all explanatory variables are measured

during the same fiscal year. Following Petersen (2009), we compute the t-statistics using stan-

dard errors that are adjusted for clustering by year and state. In most of our tests, the sample

period is from 1996 to 2008.13

The regression estimates from models with constant coefficients are presented in Table 3.

Consistent with our conjecture H1a, we find that local ownership levels are higher for firms with

worse information environments. In particular, firms with a major auditor and analyst coverage

have lower levels of local ownership. Interestingly, local ownership level is not significantly asso-

ciated with coverage by local analysts. This evidence suggests that local institutional ownership

levels are not high merely because local institutions are influenced by local analysts.

13The PIN decomposition data from Duarte and Young (2009) are only available for the 1996 to 2004 period.

21

When we consider sets of information environment proxies separately, most information

environment variables are significant determinants of excess local ownership. However, when

we include all information environment proxies in the same specification, not all information

environment proxies have significant coefficient estimates because some of these variables are

correlated. Among the seven information environment proxies, three measures have strongly

significant coefficient estimates (turnover, major auditor, and analyst coverage), two measures

have marginally significant coefficient estimates (idiosyncratic volatility and discretionary ac-

cruals), and two measures have insignificant coefficient estimates (idiosyncratic skewness and

local analyst coverage).

In economic terms, the coefficient estimates are meaningful. For example, having a major

auditor reduces the local ownership level by 3.17% (see Column (5)). Similarly, a one standard

deviation increase in analyst coverage is associated with a 6.394 × 3.34/100 = 0.21% reduction

in local ownership. Relative to the mean local ownership level of 5.39% for the full sample, these

ownership shifts are economically meaningful.

Taken together, the constant coefficients regression estimates broadly support conjecture

H1a, which posits that local institutions find firms with lower quality information environments

more attractive because such firms likely provide them greater opportunities to exploit their

superior information gathering and processing abilities. In addition, we find that local institu-

tions do not merely rely on local information intermediaries such as sell-side analysts for their

investment decisions.

4.3. Impact of Regulatory Reforms on Local Ownership Levels

Next, in a dynamic setting, we investigate whether financial regulation affects the relation be-

tween the information environment and local institutional preferences. These regression models

with time-varying coefficients test our second conjecture (H1b), which posits that the exogenous

shocks to the competitiveness of the information environment generated by regulatory reforms

such as Reg FD and SOX reduces the local informational advantage of institutional investors.

As a result, local ownership levels decline. These effects are expected to be stronger for firms

with worse information environments (H1c).

The regression estimates from models with time-varying coefficients are presented in Table 4.

Consistent with conjecture H1b, we find that local ownership levels fall after the implementation

22

of Reg FD and SOX (see Column (1)). There is a significant (1.74%) drop in local ownership

following Reg FD. This decline gets amplified (average incremental decline is 3.45%) as both

regulatory changes jointly affect the interactions between firm management and investors.

When we include all variables in the regression specification (see Column (3)), consistent with

Hypothesis H1c, the coefficient estimates of most information environment proxies have the pre-

dicted signs and most estimates are statistically as well as economically significant. Specifically,

we find that firms with worse information environments (i.e., those with low turnover, high

volatility, absence of major auditor, no analyst following, or high discretionary accruals) have

significantly higher local ownership levels prior to the rule changes. However, these relations

become significantly weaker after Reg FD and SOX. Two out of seven information environment

proxies have insignificant coefficient estimates but this evidence is not very surprising as these

variables are correlated.

For example, during the pre-regulation period, all else equal, the presence of a major auditor

reduces the local bias by 7.25%. But, after regulatory changes, presence of a major auditor is

associated with a statistically insignificant reduction of 7.25− 6.13 = 1.12% in local ownership.

Similarly, a one standard deviation increase in idiosyncratic volatility is associated with 0.15 ×6.699 = 1.00% higher local ownership in the pre-regulation period. Again, relative to the mean

local ownership level of 5.39%, this effect is economically meaningful. In the post-regulation

period, this positive relation no longer exists. In economic terms, the effect of the presence of a

major auditor on local ownership levels is the strongest but the other information environment

proxies such as turnover, idiosyncratic volatility, and analyst coverage reveal qualitatively similar

patterns.

This overall weakening of the relation between information environment proxies and local

ownership provides support to our first set of conjectures and highlights the adverse impact of

regulatory changes on local stock preferences of institutional investors. Further, the insignificant

relation between local ownership level and local analyst coverage demonstrates that the excess

local analyst coverage and excess local ownership levels of institutional investors are likely to be

induced by distinct sets of factors.

23

4.4. Identifying Causality Using Difference-in-Difference Tests

The evidence so far is consistent with our conjecture that features of the information environment

affect the level of local institutional ownership because local investors may be able to exploit

their informational advantage more effectively when a firm’s information environment is more

opaque. However, the causality may be in the other direction since a firm’s ownership structure

can also potentially affect its information environment. For example, it is possible that a firm

with high local ownership concentration does not require a major auditor because it can easily

communicate with a large proportion of its investor base directly. Similarly, the demand for

analyst services may be lower when a firm’s local ownership levels are high, which make their

services less valuable and reduces analysts’ incentives to cover the firm.

To ensure that the information environment determines excess local ownership and not

vice versa, we adopt a difference-in-difference experimental approach typical of other studies

that examine the effects of financial regulation (e.g., Bushee, Matsumoto, and Miller (2004),

Chhaochharia and Grinstein (2007)). These tests are designed to identify whether the regula-

tory changes have a greater impact on the investment decisions of local investors among firms

that were less transparent prior to the reforms.

The estimates from difference-in-difference regression models are presented in Table 5. The

analysis in this table focuses on the change in firm-level excess local ownership in the years

following the regulatory changes relative to the local ownership level prior to the regulatory

changes. Since our main goal is to characterize the impact of information environment on

ownership composition, the information environment variables in these regressions are measured

at the end of fiscal year 2000.14 We also include state fixed effects in these regressions to control

for anticipated geographical variation in changes in local ownership levels.

Consistent with our main conjecture and our earlier results, we find that the level of local

ownership decreases after regulatory changes. Further, we find that local ownership decreases

more prominently among stocks with poor information environment prior to the regulatory

changes. This set includes firms with low stock turnover, high discretionary accruals, without a

major auditor, or no analyst following.

For example, the estimate of major auditor in Column (3) suggests that the decline in local

14We obtain qualitatively similar results when we repeat the analysis using the 1996-2000 time-series averagesfor the relevant pre-FD information environment and local ownership variables.

24

bias in the 2001-2002 period relative to its 2000 level for firms without a major auditor is about

2.90% more than the corresponding decline for firms with a major auditor. Moreover, there

is an additional incremental decline of 3.07% during the 2003-2008 period. In sum, following

regulatory changes, firms without a major auditor experience a 6.07% greater decline in local

ownership compared to firms with a major auditor.

The results are qualitatively similar with other information environment proxies but not all

estimates are statistically significant. Similar to the evidence in Table 4, idiosyncratic skewness

yields the weakest results. Further, once we account for the overall level of analyst coverage,

local analyst coverage does not incrementally affect local institutional ownership patterns in an

economically meaningful way.

Overall, these results from difference-in-difference regressions provide additional support for

Hypothesis H1c. They indicate that the information environment of a firm affects its local

ownership and not the reverse.

4.5. Regulation and Local Informational Advantage

In the next set of tests, we examine the relation between local institutional ownership and

portfolio performance. Our main objective is to determine whether the local informational

advantage of institutional investors declines following regulatory reforms that were designed to

curb selective dissemination of information and improve the reliability of financial reports.

We estimate a series of performance regressions where the quarterly stock return in the next

quarter is the dependent variable and local ownership level is the main independent variable.

The results are reported in Table 6. Consistent with our Hypothesis H2a, we find that firms

with higher local ownership earn statistically significant higher returns in the future. The results

are similar irrespective of our choice of raw or characteristics-adjusted performance measure. In

economic terms, a one standard deviation increase in local ownership is on average associated

with a quarterly return increase between 0.41% and 0.71% depending on the return measure and

the benchmark. Compared to the means of the various performance measures, these performance

changes are sizeable and economically meaningful.

When we estimate the performance regression with time-varying coefficients to directly cap-

ture the effects of regulation on ownership-performance relation, we find that prior to Reg FD,

the degree of local excess ownership strongly predicts subsequent quarter raw and abnormal

25

returns (see Table 7). The ownership-performance relation is equally strong in the post-Reg

FD, pre-SOX environment. However, as expected, the relation between excess local ownership

and subsequent stock performance disappears in the post-SOX environment. During this period,

local excess ownership has no ability to predict future returns.

The performance regression estimates suggest that while Reg FD may have curbed the set

of profitable investment opportunities enjoyed by local investors, those investors continued to

earn superior risk-adjusted returns on a smaller set of local investments that they continued to

overweight in their portfolios prior to SOX. However, higher quality and more reliable public

disclosures following SOX reduce the local informational advantage of institutional investors.

Overall, the time-series variation in institutional performance supports Hypothesis H2a,

which posits that regulatory changes increase the competitiveness of the information environ-

ments of firms and reduce the informational advantage of institutions around corporate head-

quarters.

4.5.1 Regulation and Ownership-Adverse Selection Relation

In the next set of tests, we examine the relation between local ownership and stock market-

based measures of adverse selection. Similar to the performance tests, our main objective is to

determine whether excess local ownership is associated with the likelihood of future informed

trading and whether this relation is affected by the implementation of Reg FD and SOX rules. A

natural implication of our arguments is that the local ownership-adverse selection relation should

be positive prior to Reg FD and should become significantly weaker or disappear altogether after

the reforms.

To conduct this analysis we rely on two microstructure constructs intended to proxy for

adverse selection in equity trading. The first of these measures is based on the probability of

informed trading (PIN) introduced by Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O’Hara (2002). This measure has

been subsequently refined by Duarte and Young (2009), who decompose PIN into the probabil-

ity of private information-related trade (i.e., ADJPIN) and the probability that a given trade

happens during a symmetric order flow shock (i.e., PSOS).

The second set of microstructure measures is based on trading spreads. Our main measure

is the effective spread, which is the difference between the executed price and the midpoint of

the bid-ask spread. The effective spread captures the price impact of trades, which is related to

26

the market-maker’s (or liquidity provider’s) expectation of trading against informed agents.

Consistent with Hypothesis H2b, we find that the adverse selection components of stock

prices are on average directly and significantly related to prior year-end excess local ownership

levels across the sample period (see Table 8, Panel A). When we condition on the regulatory

regime, however, we find significant differences in the strength of those relations. The results

reported in Table 8, Panel B indicate that after SOX, the relation between ADJPIN and local bias

is weaker compared to the pre-FD period and becomes statistically insignificant. In contrast,

the relation between PSOS and local ownership is positive and significant prior to Reg FD

and appears to be largely unaffected by the new rules. Therefore, while the positive relation

between PIN and the degree of local ownership reflects both adverse selection and liquidity

considerations prior to Reg FD, it is predominantly driven by liquidity consideration in the

post-SOX environment.

The trading spread-based tests support a similar inference. The results from these tests are

reported in Columns (4) to (6) of Table 8, Panels A and B. In the pre-reform period, there is a

significant positive relation between local ownership and subsequent spreads, and this relation

becomes weaker after the reforms. When the spread measure is separately computed during the

3-day window (i.e., −1:+1) around earnings announcements (SPDEARN) and during the non-

earnings-announcement periods (SPDOTH), the results are qualitatively similar. However, there

is some evidence that the attenuating effects of regulatory changes on local ownership-adverse

selection relation may be more acute during periods of less intense public disclosures.

Taken together, the results from these microstructure-based tests indicate that market par-

ticipants expected local investors to exhibit a higher propensity to engage in informed trading

prior to the regulatory reforms.

4.5.2 Institution-Level Performance Estimates

In our performance analysis, we use the firm as the observation unit because our main objective

is to examine the effects of firm characteristics on the decline in local bias around regulatory

changes. For robustness, we use an alternative method where each institutional investor is the

observation unit. Using this alternative approach, Coval and Moskowitz (2001) reports that

mutual fund managers tend to have a higher portfolio weight assigned to local stocks. In our

next set of tests, we examine the local bias and local performance at the institution level. We

27

repeat the Coval and Moskowitz (2001) analysis for our sample of institutional investors.

Specifically, we calculate the Excess Local Weight of each institutional investor’s quarterly

portfolio snapshot as the percentage of the investor’s portfolio invested in stocks located in

the investor’s state (local stocks) minus the percentage of the “market portfolio” located in the

investor’s state. We compute the average of excess local weights across all institutional investors’

portfolios each quarter, and then report the time-series average of those quarterly averages over

various subperiods in Table 9. The quarterly averaging across institutions is either weighted by

the total dollar value of the institution’s holdings at the beginning of the quarter (Panel A) or

weighted equally (Panel B).

Using holdings-weighted average, we find that the excess local weights of institutional in-

vestors’ portfolios decline by more than 35 percent in the post-regulation period (2003-2008)

relative to the pre-regulation subperiod (1996-2000). These results are similar to the evidence

obtained using firm-level analysis (e.g., see Figure 1).

We also repeat the analysis in Coval and Moskowitz (2001) regarding the performance of

institutional investors’ local and non-local holdings. For each institution with non-zero portfolio

weight in local stocks, we calculate the quarterly characteristics-adjusted returns of its local

and non-local portfolios, as well as the performance differential (local minus non-local). Local

Portfolio is comprised of stocks in the institutional investor’s portfolio that are located in the

investor’s state, while Non-Local Portfolio is comprised of the rest of the institution’s holdings.

The portfolio returns are adjusted using the Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman, and Wermers (1997)

approach to control for variations in size, book-to-market, and past 12-month return.

As reported in Table 9, local holdings of institutional investors outperformed their non-local

holdings by a significant margin prior to regulatory changes (1996-2000). Using dollar-weighted

average, local holdings outperform non-local holdings by about 54 basis points each quarter

or about 2 percent annually. However, the superior performance of local holdings disappears

following the regulatory changes. The performance differential is not significantly different from

zero and the point estimates are generally negative in the post-regulation subperiod. These

results are consistent with our evidence obtained using firm-level observations and provide ad-

ditional support to Hypothesis H2a. Thus, our performance results are not driven by the choice

of unit of aggregation (i.e., firm or institution).

28

4.6. Robustness Checks

In this section, we examine the robustness of our main results. In the first set of tests, we examine

whether our findings indicate an increased awareness against holding employer stocks rather than

regulation-induced decline in local ownership. To alleviate concerns about the incidence of firm

employees’ stock holdings on our findings, we recalculate the excess local ownership measure

after excluding institutional investors that are classified as public or corporate pension funds,

university endowments, or miscellaneous. We repeat our main tests using this more restrictive

measure of local ownership and report the results in columns labeled “No PF” in Tables 4 to

7. Our conclusions remain unaffected and some of the earlier results become more significant

statistically.

Next, we focus on the effect of low priced stocks on our results. Low priced stocks are

typically characterized by more volatile and skewed returns, and are more likely to be subject to

potential microstructure biases (e.g., large bid-ask spread), which may have a disproportionate

impact on our empirical findings. To assess the extent to which our main results are driven

by the unique attributes of low-priced stocks, in Column (6) of Tables 4 and 5, and Column

(7) of Table 7, we report the regression estimates for the subsample of stocks that are priced

above $2. As shown in the tables, we find that our results are fairly robust to imposing this

restriction. This evidence indicates that the patterns of disappearing local ownership and local

informational advantage are not restricted to the subsample of low priced stocks.15

Another potential concern stems from the uneven geographical distribution of firms’ head-

quarters and centers of economic activity across the U.S. The top two states, California and

New York, on average account for approximately 11% of the firms in our sample on an annual

basis. The economic forces at play at these locations may be unique. In particular, there is a

high concentration of technology firms in California, for which information asymmetries may be

more severe. In addition, the pre-regulation period corresponds to the Internet frenzy period,

which could also influence our results. Further, the high concentration of financial institutions

and large brokerage houses in New York suggests that the effects of Reg FD may have stronger

impact on the ability of New York based analysts and institutions to have direct access to

corporations located in the state of New York.

15We also restricted the sample using a $5 price filter and obtain qualitatively similar results, although thepower of our tests diminishes because the sample size decreases by approximately 15%.

29

To ensure that our results do not primarily reflect the unique information environment in

the states of New York and California, in Column (7) of Tables 4 and 5, and Column (8) of

Table 7, we report the regression estimates for subsamples of firms whose headquarters are not

in California or New York. These subsample results are qualitatively similar to the full-sample

results, which indicates that the phenomenon of disappearing local information is not restricted

to the two most business populated states.

As mentioned above, the adoption of Reg FD in October 2000 coincides with the burst

of the tech bubble. To ensure that our results do not reflect the sharp reduction in (local)

institutional ownership in technology firms around this burst, we repeat our main tests by

excluding technology firms and report the results in columns labeled “No Tech” in Tables 4

to 7. Our conclusions remain unaffected and the magnitudes and statistical significances of

regression estimates are similar.

5. Dominant Local Information Channel

Our results so far indicate that exogenous regulatory shocks induced by Reg FD and SOX reduce

both the local bias and the local informational advantage of institutional investors. In this sec-

tion, we investigate whether selective access to management or superior information processing

is the primary channel through which institutions acquire local information. Our strategy is to

examine the impact of regulatory changes on two groups of local market participants that are

ex ante expected to have different degrees of private access to management.

On the one hand, institutions in regions where firms have economic rather than physical

presence are less likely to have selective access to management as these economically relevant

(ER) regions are often physically far away from the firm headquarters.16 On the other hand, sell-

side analysts are more likely to have benefited from private access to firm management. Thus,

if regulatory changes curtail selective access to management, we expect to observe a weaker

effect on institutions in economically relevant states and stronger effect among sell-side equity

analysts. These conjectures are summarized as Hypotheses H3a and H3b.

16See footnote 4 for a definition of economically relevant region.

30

5.1. Impact of Regulation in Economically Relevant States

To test Hypothesis 3a, we examine the ownership shifts and changes in local informational

advantage of institutions in economically relevant (ER) regions following the regulatory changes.

We replace the local ownership and local performance measures computed using institutional

holdings around firm headquarters by corresponding measures computed using the portfolio

holdings of institutions located in the firm’s most economically relevant non-HQ state. The

results are presented in “ER” columns in Tables 2 to 7.

In comparison to the headquarters locations, economically relevant regions exhibit a consid-

erably weaker shift in the local ownership levels. The excess local ownership level exhibits a

mild decline from about 2% to 1% (see Table 2, Column (7)). Since the mean expected level

of ownership in ER states is 8.37%, which does not exhibit much time variation, the total local

ownership drops from about 10% to 9%.

Examining the impact of firm-level information environment on local institutional owner-

ship in ER locations, we find that local ownership in ER states is not systematically higher for

firms that operate in worse information environments. The evidence in Table 3, Column (6)

indicates that two information proxies (analyst coverage and discretionary accruals) are statisti-

cally significant but they portray an inconsistent picture. Further, following regulatory changes,

unlike the headquarters location, the local ownership level at the ER locations does not exhibit

a sharper decline for firms that operate in worse information environments (see Tables 4 and 5,

Column (4)). Last, we find that following regulatory changes the decline in local informational

advantage in ER states is imperceptible (see Tables 6 and 7, Column (5)).

These ER results are different from the evidence obtained using local ownership levels around

headquarters. Consistent with our conjecture that institutions at ER locations are less likely

to have selective access to management, the local institutional ownership levels and local infor-

mational advantage of institutions are minimally affected by regulatory changes. Overall, these

findings provide support to Hypothesis H3a.

5.2. Regulation, Local Analysts, and Local Investors

To further identify the channels through which institutions around headquarters gather informa-

tion about local firms, we study the behavior of local equity analysts and test Hypothesis H3b.

31

If regulatory changes curtail selective access to management, sell-side analysts are likely to ex-

perience a stronger adverse effect as past evidence indicates that they have often benefited from

access to management. This analysis also investigates whether the local informational advan-

tage of institutional investors merely reflect the known local informational advantage of equity

analysts (Malloy (2005)). If institutions merely follow the recommendations of local analysts

and regulatory changes affect the local informational advantage of equity analysts, then follow-

ing the implementation of financial regulation, the local informational advantage of institutional

investors would be reduced and their preferences for local stocks would weaken.

5.2.1 Regulation and the Behavior of Local Analysts

We start by examining analysts’ propensity to cover local stocks. We define the sell-side analyst’s

excess local coverage as the fraction of local stocks covered by the analyst minus the fraction of

local stocks available to the analyst. Unlike institutional investors, there is no obvious weighting

scheme for analyst coverage. Therefore, we examine both equal- and value-weighted fractions.

The last two columns of Table 2 report the annual mean excess local coverage estimates

for both headquarters states and the most economically relevant states. We find that sell-side

analysts around corporate headquarters have excess propensity to provide local coverage and

their excess propensity to cover local stocks declines with the regulatory changes. Prior to

RegFD, we find that the value- (equal-)weighted excess local coverage is about 8% (11%) and,

following SOX, the excess local coverage declines by about two-fifths to 4.5% (value-weighted)

or about 7% (equal-weighted). During this period, the expected local coverage measure does not

exhibit much time variation and has a mean of 7.40%. In contrast, the local analyst coverage

in economically relevant states is not significantly affected by regulatory changes (see Table 2,

Column (12)).

In Table 10, we perform formal statistical tests of this decline by regressing excess local

coverage on indicator variables for FDSOX (2001-2002) and POSTSOX (2003 onwards), analyst

characteristics, and state fixed effects. The analyst characteristics include analyst tenure, past

performance, the number of firms covered, and an indicator variable for analysts employed by

prestigious brokerage houses. The average excess local coverage throughout our sample period

is 9.63 (6.30) percent using equal- (value-) weighting.

Further, the coefficient estimates of FDSOX and POSTSOX suggest that, relative to the

32

pre-regulatory period, excess local coverage declines by 1.24 to 1.75 percentage points during

FDSOX and by 3.21 to 4.68 percentage points after SOX. Focusing on the analysts employed

by prestigious brokerage houses, we find that they are less likely to cover local stocks. However,

their excess local coverage after SOX is similar to that of analysts employed by less prestigious

brokerage houses.

We next examine the forecasting performance of local analysts. In particular, we examine

their forecast accuracy and the stock price impact of revisions in their quarterly earnings fore-

casts. As analysts are evaluated against their peers, we employ two relative accuracy measure

that compares an analyst’s forecast against all forecasts on the same earnings report. The first

measure is whether or not the analyst’s forecast error is below the median error, while the sec-

ond measure is the percentile ranking of the analyst’s forecast error. Following Malloy (2005),

we also use the demeaned absolute forecast error (DAFE) to measure forecast accuracy, where

a negative DAFE implies better than average forecast accuracy and a positive DAFE reflects

below-average forecast accuracy. In addition, we use the short-term market reaction during the

three-day (−1, 0, 1) window around quarterly forecast revisions to measure the informativeness

of analyst forecasts. Specifically, it is calculated as the three-day buy-and-hold return of the

firm’s stock minus the buy-and-hold return of the equal-weighted CRSP index.

Table 11 reports the coefficient estimates from regressing these accuracy and market reaction

measures on a LOCAL indicator variable that takes the value of one if the analyst and the firm

headquarters are located in the same state and zero otherwise, its interaction with indicator

variables for FDSOX (2001-2002) and POSTSOX (2003 onwards), and time-varying analyst

fixed effects to capture variation in analysts’ skill and characteristics.17 We do not include

stand-alone regime variables or time fixed effects in the specifications as they are subsumed by

the time-varying analyst fixed effects. We cluster the errors for all forecasts issued for the same

earnings report as they are correlated due to the way our measures are constructed.

The coefficient estimates in Table 11 suggest that local analysts are more accurate prior

to the introduction of Reg FD, consistent with the findings in Malloy (2005). However, the

superior accuracy of local analysts decline significantly following Reg FD. Adding up the point

estimates of LOCAL and LOCAL × POSTSOX in Columns (1), (2), or (5), we find that superior

17The LOCAL indicator is defined in an analogous manner for economically relevant states. It takes the valueof one if the analyst is located in the economically most relevant state for the firm and, zero otherwise.

33

local performance is at most negligible after the introduction of SOX. In contrast, local analysts

in economically relevant states did not exhibit higher local accuracy during the pre-regulation

period and their local forecast accuracy is not significantly affected by regulatory changes (see

Columns (3) and (4)).

When we estimate the accuracy regressions for different subperiods, similar to the evidence

in Malloy (2005), LOCAL has a significantly negative coefficient estimate in the pre-regulation

period (see Column (6)), and negative but insignificant coefficient estimate during the period

immediately following Reg FD (see Column (7)). However, when we extend the time period

and consider the forecast accuracy of local analysts during a longer 2003-08 period, we find that

LOCAL has a positive but insignificant coefficient estimate. This evidence indicates that local

analysts no longer possess a local informational advantage and, in fact, on average they are less

accurate than nonlocal analysts although this relation is not statistically significant.

Collectively, the results in Tables 10 and 11 are consistent with our conjecture (H3b) that Reg

FD and SOX affect local sell-side equity analysts since prior to the introduction of these financial

regulation, like local institutional investors, they were more likely to rely on selective access to

management in their information-gathering activities. Following the regulatory changes, like

institutional investors, their local informational advantage disappears.

5.2.2 Local Analysts and Local Investors

In this section, we examine whether the local informational advantage of analysts and insti-

tutional investors are related. Specifically, we investigate whether the recommendations from

local analysts drive the local informational advantage of institutional investors. We estimate

the local bias and performance of institutional investors, conditional upon the presence of local

analysts. We sort states into three groups based on the number of analysts in the state: top 5

states, 6th to 20th, and others. This grouping is done to ensure that institutional investors are

spread as evenly as possible across the three groups. within each group, we measure the local

bias of institutional investors as well as their portfolio performance during different subperiods.

The results are presented in Table 12.

We find that the pattern of declining local bias is similar, irrespective of the level of local

analyst coverage (see Panel A). However, the time-series patterns in local performance is quite

different. In states with high number of local analysts, institutional investors do not display

34

superior performance both before and after the regulatory changes. In contrast, institutions

exhibit superior local performance in states with low analyst presence prior to the regulatory

changes. The superior performance of local institutional investors weakens significantly following

the regulatory changes as access to superior local information becomes harder to obtain.

This evidence suggests that local informational advantage of institutional investors do not

merely reflect the local informational advantage of equity analysts. They are likely to compete

for local information prior to the regulatory changes rather than share it. The relative increase

in the local coverage by analysts at prestigious brokerage firms (see Table 10, Columns (2) and

(4)) is also consistent with our conjecture that the local biases of analysts and institutions are

not directly related.

For comparison, we examine the performance of institutional investors among stocks with

local economic presence (see Panel B).18 We find that the superior performance of institutional

investors among these stocks is not significantly affected by the regulatory changes, irrespective

of the level of local analyst coverage. This evidence indicates that the informational advantage

of institutional investors in economically relevant regions is distinct from their local informa-

tional advantage around corporate headquarters. Neither the presence of local analysts nor the

introduction of financial regulation completely eliminated this informational advantage.

5.3. Identifying Selective Access Using a Microstructure Test

In our last set of tests, we use a market-based tests to further identify whether selective access to

firm management is the primary channel through which local investors around corporate head-

quarters obtain a local informational advantage. The evidence in Panels A and B of Table 8

indicates that the attenuating effects of regulatory changes on local ownership-adverse selection

relation may be more acute during periods of less intense public disclosures. This attenuating

effect may be due to the reduction in selective disclosure (i.e., preferential access to firm infor-

mation) provided to local investors. Alternatively, it may be a result of the reduction in local

investors’ superior ability to process information after it is publicly disclosed by the firm. The

former suggests that the attenuating effect should be more severe prior to public disclosure,

while the latter suggests that the effect should more severe following the disclosure.

18The results are reported for the five most economically relevant states but the results are very similar whenwe only consider the most economically relevant states.

35

In Table 8, Panel C, we report results from spread-based tests that allow us to distinguish

between these two potential explanations. Specifically, we report the relation between local own-

ership and spreads in the periods before and after earnings announcements. While local own-

ership is associated with higher spreads both before and after earnings announcement, we find

that the attenuating effects of regulatory changes on local ownership-adverse selection relation

are restricted to the pre-earnings announcement period. This finding suggests that regulatory

changes reduced local investors’ preferential access to firm information, which is one of the main

objectives of Reg FD. The evidence also suggests that informed trading by local institutional

investors prior to regulatory reforms may be driven by preferential access to private information,

which was curbed following the introduction of Reg FD. These results provide support for our

last Hypothesis (H3c).

Overall, we use three different methods to demonstrate that the local informational advantage

of institutional investors is more likely to reflect selective access to firm management prior

to regulatory changes. This type of local informational advantage disappeared following the

implementation of Reg FD, although it took several years before the impact of Reg FD was

fully realized. In contrast, the improvement in the informational environment due to SOX had

minimal impact on the information processing advantage of institutional investors. Specifically,

the informational advantage of institutions in economically relevant regions was not adversely

affected in spite of an improvement in the information environment.

6. Summary and Conclusion

This study examines whether exogenous regulatory shocks induced by Regulation Fair Disclo-

sure and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act reduce the local bias and the local informational advantage

of institutional investors. We also investigate whether regulation affects the informational ad-

vantage of institutions by curtailing selective access to management or adversely affecting their

information processing advantages. Although we focus on the behavior of institutional investors,

we study how the behavior of local analysts affects local institutional ownership patterns and

local performance.

We find that following the adoptions of Reg FD and SOX average firm-level local bias is cut

by about half and firm ownership becomes more diffused geographically. Further, the local in-

36

formational advantage of institutional investors around corporate headquarters declines sharply

as their selective access to private information is curtailed. The decline in local institutional

ownership is more salient among firms that had more opaque information environments prior

to the regulatory changes. Even at the aggregate market-level, the degree of informed trading

attributed to local investors declines.

The local informational advantage of sell-side equity analysts who are more likely to have

selective access exhibits a similar declining pattern and disappears in the post-regulation period.

In contrast, regulatory changes have minimal impact on the local informational advantage of

institutions in economically relevant regions as they are unlikely to have selective access to

management.

Taken together, these findings indicate that regulatory changes affected institutional behavior

primarily by curtailing their selective access to management rather than adversely affecting their

information processing advantages. Our results contribute to both the regulation and the local

bias literatures. We demonstrate that selective access to firm management is an important

determinant of institutional local bias and also show in a new economic setting that financial

regulation can be effective.

These results provide several pointers for future research. For example, while we present

evidence of sharp decline in local ownership levels, a significant level of local institutional pref-

erences remain. While a significant proportion of this “residual” excess local ownership may

be induced by the familiarity, some sophisticated institutional investors might overweight local

stocks even after the leveling of the playing field due to their superior abilities to process publicly

available information. It would be useful to quantify these clientele shifts and examine their

potential impact on asset prices.

It would also be interesting to investigate whether and to what extent the staggered imple-

mentation of SOX-like regulations in several major capital markets around the world affected

home bias – the international counterpart of the local bias phenomenon. If, like in the United

States, the information environment affects both domestic and foreign institutional investors’

participation in equity markets, we should observe a substantial decline in home bias and a

concurrent inflow of foreign investors’ capital in those countries that adopted SOX-like rules.

37

References

Agrawal, A., S. Chadha, and M. A. Chen, 2006, “Who Is Afraid of Reg FD? The Behavior

and Performance of Sell-Side Analysts Following the SEC’s Fair Disclosure Rules,” Journal

of Business, 79, 2811–2834.

Baik, B., J. Kang, and J. Kim, 2010, “Local Institutional Investors, Information Asymmetries,

and Equity Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 97, 81–106.

Bailey, W., H. Li, C. X. Mao, and R. Zhong, 2003, “Regulation Fair Disclosure and Earnings

Information: Market, Analyst, and Corporate Responses,” Journal of Finance, 58, 2487–2515.

Bauguess, S., G. Bernile, A. Lee, J. Marietta-Westberg, and C. Alexander, 2012, “The Economic

Effects of SOX Section 404 Compliance: A Corporate Insider Perspective,” Working Paper,

University of Miami.

Bernile, G., A. Kumar, and J. Sulaeman, 2012, “Home Away From Home: Eco-

nomic Relevance and Local Investors,” Working Paper (December); Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=1711653.

Bushee, B., D. Matsumoto, and G. Miller, 2004, “Managerial and Investor Responses to Dis-

closure Regulation: The Case of Reg FD and Conference Calls,” The Accounting Review, 79,

617–643.

Chhaochharia, V., and Y. Grinstein, 2007, “Corporate Governance and Company Value: The

Impact of the 2002 Governance Rules,” Journal of Finance, 62, 1789–1825.

Chow, G. C., 1960, “Tests of Equality Between Sets of Coefficients in Two Linear Regressions,”

Econometrica, 28, 591–605.

Coates, J., 2007, “The goals and promise of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act,” Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 21, 91–116.

Cohen, D. A., A. Dey, and T. Z. Lys, 2008, “Real and Accrual-Based Earnings Management in

the Pre- and Post-Sarbanes Oxley Periods,” The Accounting Review, 83, 757–787.

38

Coval, J. D., and T. J. Moskowitz, 1999, “Home Bias at Home: Local Equity Preference in

Domestic Portfolios,” Journal of Finance, 54, 2045–2073.

Coval, J. D., and T. J. Moskowitz, 2001, “The Geography of Investment: Informed Trading and

Asset Prices,” Journal of Political Economy, 109, 811–841.

Daniel, K. D., M. Grinblatt, S. Titman, and R. Wermers, 1997, “Measuring Mutual Fund

Performance with Characteristic-Based Benchmarks,” Journal of Finance, 52, 1035–1058.

Dechow, P. M., R. G. Sloan, and A. P. Sweeney, 1995, “Detecting Earnings Management,”

Accounting Review, 70, 193–225.

Diamond, D. W., and R. E. Verrecchia, 1991, “Disclosure, Liquidity, and the Cost of Capital,”

Journal of Finance, 46, 1325–1359.

Duarte, J., X. Han, J. Harford, and L. Young, 2008, “Information Asymmetry, Information

Dissemination and the Effect of Regulation FD on the Cost of Capital,” Journal of Financial

Economics, 87, 24–44.

Duarte, J., and L. Young, 2009, “When is PIN Priced?,” Journal of Financial Economics, 91,

119–138.

Easley, D., S. Hvidkjaer, and M. O’Hara, 2002, “Is Information Risk a Determinant of Asset

Returns?,” Journal of Finance, 57, 2185–2221.

Eleswarapu, V., R. Thompson, and K. Venkataraman, 2004, “The Impact of Regulation Fair

Disclosure: Trading Costs and Information Asymmetry,” Journal of Financial and Quantita-

tive Analysis, 39, 209–225.

Epstein, L. G., and M. Schneider, 2008, “Ambiguity, Information Quality, and Asset Pricing,”

Journal of Finance, 63, 197–228.

Gintschel, A., and S. Markov, 2004, “The Effectiveness of Regulation FD,” Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 37, 293–314.

Glosten, L. R., and P. R. Milgrom, 1985, “Bid, Ask and Transaction Prices in a Specialist Market

with Heterogeneously Informed Traders,” Journal of Financial Economics, 14, 71–100.

39

Goshen, Z., and G. Parchomovsky, 2001, “On Insider Trading, Markets, and “Negative” Prop-

erty Rights in Information,” Virginia Law Review, 87, 1229–1277.

Hasset, K., 2000, Outlaw Selective Disclosure? No, the More Information the Better, The Wall

Street Journal (August 10): A18.

Healy, P. M., and K. G. Palepu, 2001, “Information Asymmetry, Corporate Disclosure, and the

Capital Markets: A Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature,” Journal of Accounting

and Economics, 31, 405–440.

Heflin, F., K. R. Subramanyam, and Y. Zhang, 2003, “Regulation FD and the Financial Infor-

mation Environment: Early Evidence,” The Accounting Review, 78, 1–37.

Hochberg, Y., P. Sapienza, and A. Vissing-Jorgensen, 2009, “A Lobbying Approach to Evaluat-

ing the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002,” Journal of Accounting Research, 47, 519–583.

Holmstrom, B., and S. Kaplan, 2003, “The State of U.S. Corporate Governance: What’s Right

and What’s Wrong?,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15, 8–20.

Iliev, P., 2010, “The Effect of SOX Section 404 Compliance on Audit Fees, Earnings Quality

and Stock Prices,” Journal of Finance, 65, 1163–1196.

Ivkovic, Z., and S. Weisbenner, 2005, “Local Does as Local Is: Information Content of the

Geography of Individual Investors’ Common Stock Investments,” Journal of Finance, 60,

267–306.

Kacperczyk, M., C. Sialm, and L. Zheng, 2005, “On the Industry Concentration of Actively

Managed Equity Mutual Funds,” Journal of Finance, 60, 1983–2011.

Korniotis, G. M., and A. Kumar, 2012, “State-Level Business Cycles and Local Return Pre-

dictability,” Journal of Finance, Forthcoming.

Kumar, A., 2009, “Who Gambles in the Stock Market?,” Journal of Finance, 64, 1889–1933.

Lang, M., and R. Lundholm, 1993, “Cross-sectional Determinants of Analyst Ratings of Corpo-

rate Disclosures,” Journal of Accounting Research, 31, 246–271.

40

Leftwich, R., 1983, “Accounting Information in Private Markets: Evidence from Private Lending

Agreements,” The Accounting Review, 58, 23–42.

Leuz, C., and R. E. Verrecchia, 2000, “The Economic Consequences of Increased Disclosure,”

Journal of Accounting Research, 38.

Li, H., M. Pincus, and S. O. Rego, 2008, “Market Reaction to Events Surrounding the Sarbanes-

Oxley Act of 2002 and Earnings Management,” Journal of Law and Economics, 51, 111–134.

Malloy, C. J., 2005, “The Geography of Equity Analysis,” Journal of Finance, 60, 719–755.

Menon, K., and D. D. Williams, 1991, “Auditor Credibility and Initial Public Offerings,” The

Accounting Review, 66, 312–332.

Newey, W. K., and K. D. West, 1987, “A Simple, Positive semi-Definite Heteroskedasticity and

Auto-Correlation Consistent Variance-Covariance Matrix,” Econometrica, 55, 703–708.

Petersen, M. A., 2009, “Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets: Comparing

Approaches,” Review of Financial Studies, 22, 435–480.

Rajgopal, S., and M. Venkatachalam, 2011, “Financial Reporting Quality and Idiosyncratic

Return Volatility,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 51, 1–20.

SEC, 2000, Selective Disclosure and Insider Trading, Release No. 33-7881 and 34-43154; Avail-

able at http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/33-7881.htm.

Shiller, R., 2000, Outlaw Selective Disclosure? Yes, Markets Must be Fair, The Wall Street

Journal (August 10): A18.

Soffer, L. C., B. R. Walther, and S. R. Thiagarajan, 2000, “Earnings Pre-Announcement Strate-

gies,” Review of Accounting Studies, 5, 5–26.

Weber, J., 2000a, Full Disclosure For All, Business Week (September 18): 106.

Weber, J., 2000b, Why Should Analysts be Told More Than You? Business Week (March 13):

42.

Zhang, I., 2007, “Economic Consequences of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002,” Journal of Ac-

counting and Economics, 44, 74–115.

41

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 20080

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

Exc

ess

Loc

al O

wne

rshi

p

Year

All FirmsSmall FirmsLarge Firms

Figure 1. Excess local ownership around firm headquarters. This figure shows the mean excess equal-weighted local ownership time series for the full sample of firms. Excess local ownership is the state institutionalownership of a firm’s HQ state minus that state’s average state institutional ownership. Small and large firmssubsamples contain firms in the lowest and highest firm size quartiles, respectively. Additional details about thevariables are available in the Appendix.

42

Table

1

Sum

mary

Sta

tist

ics

Thi

sta

ble

repo

rts

the

sum

mar

yst

atis

tics

for

mai

nva

riab

les

used

inth

eem

piri

cal

anal

ysis

.T

heva

riab

les

are

defin

edin

the

App

endi

x.T

hefu

llsa

mpl

epe

riod

isfr

om19

96to

2008

.P

RE

SOX

peri

odin

clud

esfir

m-fi

scal

year

sen

ding

star

ting

in19

96an

den

ding

prio

rto

orin

cale

ndar

year

2000

.FD

SOX

peri

odin

clud

esfir

m-fi

scal

year

sen

ding

inca

lend

arye

ars

2001

and

2002

.P

OST

SOX

peri

odin

clud

esfir

m-fi

scal

year

sen

ding

inca

lend

arye

ar20

03on

war

d.T

hede

finit

ions

ofal

lvar

iabl

esar

epr

ovid

edin

the

App

endi

x.*,

**,an

d**

*in

dica

test

atis

tica

lsi

gnifi

canc

eat

the

1%,5%

,an

d10

%le

vels

,res

pect

ivel

y.

Full

Sam

ple:

1996

-200

8P

RE

SOX

:19

96-2

000

FD

SOX

:20

01-0

2P

OST

SOX

:20

03-0

8

Var

iabl

eSh

ort

Nam

eN

Mea

nM

edia

nSt

dD

evM

ean

Med

ian

Mea

nM

edia

nM

ean

Med

ian

Owne

rshi

p,C

once

ntra

tion

,an

dPer

form

ance

Mea

sure

s

Loc

alO

wne

rshi

pH

QLO

CO

WN

47,6

255.

390

0.30

016

.870

6.76

00.

660

5.25

00.

190

4.27

00.

140

Loc

alO

wne

rshi

pE

RR

ER

LO

CO

WN

44,0

401.

300

−0.3

4012

.590

1.77

0−0

.330

1.26

0−0

.370

0.93

0−0

.330

Ow

ners

hip

Her

finda

hlH

HI

47,6

250.

246

0.19

90.

174

0.26

40.

213

0.25

10.

202

0.22

90.

190

Ow

ners

hip

Geo

.C

onc.

GC

I47

,625

0.13

10.

075

0.16

10.

151

0.09

90.

142

0.08

10.

110

0.05

8

Nex

tQ

uart

erR

etur

n:

Raw

Ret

urn

RAW

RE

T44

,546

3.29

00.

700

32.5

705.

110

0.85

01.

500

−0.2

702.

200

0.90

0

CR

SP-E

WA

dj.

EW

RE

T44

,546

−0.3

80−2

.760

31.0

50−0

.550

−4.4

30−0

.490

−2.2

10−0

.170

−1.8

00

CR

SP-V

WA

dj.

VW

RE

T44

,546

2.34

0−0

.450

31.5

602.

670

−1.9

803.

240

1.28

01.

680

0.00

0

DG

TW

Cha

r.A

dj.

CA

DJR

ET

38,0

621.

200

−1.0

5029

.320

1.71

0−1

.550

1.86

00.

020

0.48

0−1

.020

Info

rmat

ion

Env

iron

men

tVar

iabl

es

Tur

nove

rT

UR

N47

,625

1.40

60.

933

1.43

21.

247

0.79

01.

495

0.95

91.

512

1.07

5

Idio

.V

olat

ility

IVO

L47

,625

9.56

27.

762

6.69

910

.103

8.50

012

.981

11.2

427.

987

6.44

4

Idio

.Sk

ewne

ssIS

KE

W47

,625

0.13

90.

133

0.70

60.

164

0.16

90.

159

0.14

10.

111

0.09

9

Maj

orA

udit

orM

AJA

UD

47,6

250.

847

1.00

00.

360

0.92

51.

000

0.91

71.

000

0.75

81.

000

Ana

lyst

Cov

erag

eA

NC

OV

47,6

256.

006

4.00

06.

394

5.62

74.

000

5.67

04.

000

6.43

85.

000

Num

.of

Ana

lyst

sN

UM

AN

A47

,625

0.82

11.

000

0.38

30.

812

1.00

00.

814

1.00

00.

831

1.00

0

Abs

.D

isc.

Acc

rual

sA

BSD

AC

C38

,678

0.27

30.

071

0.64

40.

125

0.05

50.

418

0.13

50.

361

0.07

9

Con

tinued

...

43

Full

Sam

ple:

1996

-200

8P

RE

SOX

:19

96-2

000

FD

SOX

:200

1-02

PO

STSO

X:20

03-0

8

Var

iabl

eSh

ort

Nam

eN

Mea

nM

edia

nSt

dD

evM

ean

Med

ian

Mea

nM

edia

nM

ean

Med

ian

Oth

erFir

mC

hara

cter

istics

log(

Mar

ket

Cap

)M

CA

P47

,625

12.8

2312

.760

1.94

112

.544

12.4

5012

.491

12.4

7113

.169

13.0

98

Boo

k-To-

Mar

ket

BM

47,5

530.

583

0.47

20.

584

0.58

20.

458

0.67

20.

536

0.55

50.

468

Fin

anci

alLev

erag

eFIN

LE

V47

,500

0.18

00.

115

0.20

10.

193

0.13

60.

184

0.11

10.

168

0.10

2

Fir

mA

geA

GE

47,6

2514

.848

9.00

015

.507

13.6

158.

000

14.1

198.

000

16.1

3411

.000

6mLag

ged

Ret

urn

RE

T6M

46,2

960.

083

0.03

40.

419

0.11

70.

054

0.04

40.

008

0.06

60.

026

Stoc

kP

rice

PR

ICE

47,6

2521

.884

17.3

6518

.180

21.1

8916

.726

20.9

6715

.620

22.7

7318

.484

Lot

tery

-Typ

eSt

ock

LO

TT

47,6

040.

335

0.00

00.

472

0.32

50.

000

0.33

30.

000

0.34

40.

000

Loca

lA

ttri

bute

s

Edu

cati

onE

DU

47,6

2525

.490

26.1

003.

701

24.7

5225

.320

26.0

9226

.600

25.9

2026

.600

Pop

.D

ensi

tyP

OP

DE

N47

,625

313.

783

217.

998

455.

044

305.

148

211.

515

319.

088

217.

998

319.

392

217.

998

Cat

h.-P

rot.

Rat

ioC

PR

AT

IO47

,625

0.49

90.

521

0.10

80.

505

0 .52

30.

495

0.52

00.

497

0.52

0

Rel

igio

sity

RE

L47

,625

1.42

60.

956

1.23

61.

405

0.95

61.

493

1.02

01.

423

0.89

0

Rep

ublic

anR

EP

UB

47,6

250.

731

1.00

00.

443

0.81

51.

000

0.70

61.

000

0.66

81.

000

Mic

rost

ruct

ure

Var

iabl

es

PIN

PIN

12,4

830.

177

0.15

10.

096

0.18

50.

159

0.17

30.

145

0.15

20.

123

Adv

.Se

lect

ion

AD

JPIN

1248

30.

145

0.12

70.

070

0.15

10.

135

0.14

10.

121

0.12

50.

108

Liq

uidi

tyP

SOS

12,4

830.

257

0.21

60.

136

0.26

30.

219

0.25

90.

223

0.23

10.

193

Effe

ctiv

eSp

read

SPR

EA

D35

,057

0.40

40.

186

0.54

10.

617

0.39

90.

384

0.18

80.

256

0.09

0

Aro

und

Ear

ning

sSP

DE

AR

N35

,057

0.42

20.

199

0.58

10.

626

0.40

80.

414

0.20

60.

275

0.11

0

Exc

l.E

arni

ngs

SPD

OT

H35

,057

0.40

30.

185

0.54

10.

616

0.39

80.

383

0.18

70.

255

0.09

0

Ana

lyst

-Rel

ated

Mea

sure

s

Hig

hPer

form

ance

HIG

HP

ER

F23

,566

0.34

50.

333

0.20

80.

346

0.33

30.

331

0.31

60.

351

0.33

3

Ten

ure

TE

NU

RE

23,5

6623

.626

17.0

0020

.218

23.3

5918

.000

23.3

3217

.000

24.1

8318

.000

Pre

stig

ious

Bro

ker

PB

RO

KE

R23

,566

0.33

40.

000

0.47

20.

342

0.00

00.

376

0.00

00.

302

0.00

0

Num

.of

Fir

ms

Cov

ered

NFC

OV

ER

23,5

6610

.995

10.0

006.

175

11.1

1710

.000

10.3

2910

.000

11.1

5111

.000

Dem

eane

dA

bs.Fo

re.E

rr.

DA

FE

786,

605

−0.0

93−0

.008

0.34

4−0

.132

−0.0

05−0

.172

−0.0

08−0

.025

−0.0

12

Mar

ket

Rea

ctio

n,U

pR

ev.

RE

TU

P28

3,00

10.

345

0.15

27.

370

0.22

20.

085

−0.1

89−0

.097

0.59

50.

232

Mar

ket

Rea

ctio

n,D

n.R

ev.

RE

TD

N26

4,19

9−1

.072

−0.6

768.

350

−1.2

66−0

.820

−1.1

56−0

.740

−0.8

59−0

.560

44

Table 2

Annual Local Ownership and Ownership Concentration Estimates

This table reports annual averages for local ownership, ownership concentration, and local analyst coveragemeasures. All measures are multiplied by 100 to improve readability. For comparison, in Column (1), wereport the mean equal-weighted institutional ownership (IO) across all CRSP firms. Column (2) reports thefull-sample annual excess local ownership estimates for firm headquarters (HQ) states. To provide a benchmark,the mean expected level of local ownership is reported in Column (3). Columns (4) to (6) report the excesslocal ownership estimates for small, mid-sized, and large firms, respectively. Column (7) reports the excess localownership estimates for most economically relevant (ER) states. In Columns (8) to (10), we report the meanstate-level ownership concentration indices. Specifically, Columns (8) and (9) report the Herfindahl-Hirschmanconcentration index (HHI) of state-level institutional ownership across all U.S. states. HH1 is based on the fullsample, while HQ states are excluded when we compute HH2. Column (10) reports the geographical concentrationindex (GCI) of state-level institutional ownership across all U.S. states adjusted for the natural level of ownershipconcentration resulting from the geographical clustering of institutional investors. In Columns (11) and (12), wereport the excess local analyst coverage around corporate headquarters and in the most economically relevantstates. The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix.

HQ Local Ownership (2-6) ER (7) Ownership Conc. (8-10) Loc An Cov (11-12)

IO Excess Exp SmlCap MidCap LgCap All HHI1 HHI2 GCI HQ ER

Year (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

1996 26.89 8.02 7.37 14.65 5.76 3.77 1.62 27.76 32.96 15.92 12.35 2.10

1997 27.96 7.87 7.35 13.73 5.88 3.94 1.75 26.56 31.37 14.97 12.97 1.47

1998 28.41 7.64 7.19 13.47 5.76 3.73 2.02 27.15 32.16 16.12 11.94 3.31

1999 28.27 7.90 7.58 14.31 5.50 3.51 1.70 27.44 32.00 16.23 11.34 2.78

2000 29.07 7.86 8.00 14.42 5.86 2.98 2.11 27.90 32.26 17.14 10.94 2.87

2001 30.56 6.80 7.84 12.37 5.05 2.91 1.75 26.01 30.61 15.64 10.44 2.96

2002 33.19 5.75 7.77 10.68 4.18 2.36 0.96 25.70 29.99 14.77 10.83 1.69

2003 36.09 5.53 7.46 10.53 3.74 2.26 1.18 23.39 26.57 13.38 10.55 1.70

2004 40.71 4.38 7.52 8.46 2.80 1.91 0.57 23.84 27.22 11.50 7.32 2.95

2005 42.70 4.28 7.59 8.29 3.06 1.55 0.52 23.64 27.16 11.20 7.13 2.80

2006 44.53 3.65 7.63 7.21 2.59 1.20 0.88 22.73 25.84 10.22 6.18 2.59

2007 48.46 3.66 7.84 6.61 3.11 1.30 1.16 23.09 26.30 10.54 5.53 1.77

2008 48.03 3.96 7.77 7.46 2.98 1.45 1.17 23.72 27.81 11.34 5.49 1.91

45

Table 3

Information Environment and Excess Local Ownership:Estimates From Constant Coefficients Specifications

This table reports pooled cross-sectional regression coefficient estimates and corresponding t-statistics for therelation between firm-level excess local ownership (LOCOWN) and the characteristics of the firm informationenvironment, controlling for time varying firm and/or state characteristics and year and state fixed effects. Thelevel of firm local excess institutional ownership is measured as of the fiscal year end, and all explanatory variablesare measured during the same fiscal year. In Columns (1) to (5), we use the portfolio holdings of institutions inthe headquarters (HQ) state while in Column (6) we use the holdings of institutions located in most economicallyrelevant (ER) states. The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix. Following Petersen (2009),the t-statistics reported in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by year and state. The sampleperiod is from 1996 to 2008.

Dependent Variable: Excess Local Ownership (in %)

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Information Environment Variables

TURN −0.44 −0.27 0.05

(−6.2) (−3.7) (0.9)

IVOL 0.05 0.04 −0.01

(1.8) (1.8) (−0.6)

ISKEW 0.22 0.07 0.00

(1.5) (0.5) (0.0)

MAJAUD −2.87 −3.17 0.07

(−3.9) (−6.4) (0.2)

ANCOV −3.80 −3.31 −1.16

(−10.8) (−7.4) (−3.4)

ABSDACC RANK 0.26 0.16 −0.38

(2.0) (1.9) (−4.2)

LOCANCOV −0.98 0.08 0.10

(−3.6) (0.4) (0.6)

Continued . . .

46

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Other Firm Characteristics

MCAP RANK −2.37 −1.77 −2.48 −2.33 −1.68 −0.82

(−10.6) (−7.6) (−11.2) (−11.5) (−8.7) (−8.9)

FINLEV −0.89 −0.45 −0.70 −1.22 −0.771 0.544

(−1.3) (−0.6) (−1.0) (−2.3) (−1.5) (1.4)

AGE 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.017 0.001 −0.008

(2.2) (0.3) (3.8) (2.7) (0.3) (−1.9)

BM −0.11 −0.03 −0.13 −0.35 −0.16 0.25

(−0.4) (−0.1) (−0.5) (−1.1) (−0.5) (1.4)

RET6M 0.10 −0.03 0.22 0.13 −0.15 0.04

(0.3) (−0.1) (0.7) (0.5) (−0.6) (0.2)

PRICE 0.01 0.00 0.01 −0.00 0.00 −0.01

(1.7) (0.7) (1.1) (−0.1) (0.0) (−2.1)

LOTT −0.40 −0.07 −0.09 −0.11 −0.26 −0.09

(−2.1) (−0.3) (−0.4) (−0.5) (−1.0) (−0.4)

Local Attributes

EDU −4.37 −4.31 −4.40 −2.84 −2.77 0.79

(−6.2) (−6.2) (−6.2) (−3.0) (−2.9) (2.2)

POPDEN 0.07 0.07 0.07 0.03 0.04 −0.02

(3.2) (3.1) (3.2) (0.8) (0.9) (−1.0)

CPRATIO 5.56 5.50 5.63 9.44 8.58 2.26

(2.3) (2.4) (2.3) (1.5) (1.3) (0.9)

REL −28.45 −28.34 −27.01 −28.06 −31.57 10.15

(−1.1) (−1.1) (−1.1) (−1.2) (−1.3) (0.8)

REPUB −0.54 −0.66 −0.50 −0.82 −0.96 −0.52

(−1.2) (−1.5) (−1.1) (−1.5) (−1.7) (−1.5)

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 37,876 37,876 37,876 37,782 37,782 35,214

Adj. R2 0.113 0.121 0.112 0.117 0.127 0.065

47

Table 4

Information Environment and Excess Local Ownership:Estimates From Time-Varying Coefficients Specifications

This table reports pooled cross-sectional regression coefficient estimates and corresponding t-statistics for therelation between firm-level excess local ownership (LOCOWN) and the characteristics of the firm informationenvironment conditional on the regulatory regime. We also control for time-varying firm and state characteristicsand consider regime as well as state fixed effects. The level of firm local excess institutional ownership is measuredas of the fiscal year end, and all explanatory variables are measured during the same fiscal year. FDSOX(POSTSOX) is an indicator variable equal to one for fiscal years ending in calendar years 2001 and 2002 (2003and onward). In Columns (1) to (3) and (5) to (8), we use the portfolio holdings of institutions in the headquarters(HQ) state while in Column (4) we use the holdings of institutions located in most economically relevant (ER)states. The excess local ownership dependent variable in Column (5) is recalculated after excluding institutionalinvestors that are classified as public or corporate pension funds, university endowments, or miscellaneous. Theresults in Columns (6) through (8) are based on samples that exclude stocks priced below $2, firms located inCalifornia or New York states, and high-tech firms, respectively. The definitions of all variables are provided inthe Appendix. Following Petersen (2009), the t-statistics reported in parentheses are based on standard errorsclustered by year and state. The sample period is from 1996 to 2008.

48

Dependent Variable: Excess Local Ownership (in %)

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER Robustness (5-8)

No PF Pr>$2 No CA/NY No Tech

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

FDSOX −1.74 −2.32 −2.77 −0.80 −2.28 −2.97 −3.34 −3.13

(−5.0) (−2.5) (−2.3) (−0.6) (−1.9) (−1.8) (−1.8) (−2.1)

POSTSOX −3.45 −6.07 −6.10 −2.09 −5.46 −5.63 −7.48 −6.35

(−16.4) (−5.5) (−3.2) (−1.7) (−3.0) (−2.8) (−4.4) (−3.1)

TURN −0.67 −0.56 0.05 −0.71 −0.44 −0.94 −0.71

(−6.5) (−3.2) (0.4) (−3.3) (−2.8) (−4.1) (−3.4)

TURN × FDSOX 0.22 0.06 0.07 0.28 −0.03 0.08 −0.32

(2.1) (0.3) (0.6) (1.0) (−0.1) (0.3) (−0.9)

TURN × POSTSOX 0.51 0.46 −0.04 0.48 0.39 0.80 0.71

(3.6) (2.2) (−0.3) (1.9) (2.0) (3.1) (2.9)

IVOL 0.15 0.15 −0.02 0.18 0.12 0.15 0.15

(2.6) (3.0) (−0.6) (3.8) (2.5) (2.3) (2.8)

IVOL × FDSOX −0.13 −0.10 −0.01 −0.15 −0.05 −0.13 −0.08

(−1.8) (−1.5) (−0.4) (−1.8) (−0.8) (−1.6) (−1.2)

IVOL × POSTSOX −0.22 −0.24 0.03 −0.25 −0.24 −0.22 −0.21

(−3.6) (−3.9) (0.9) (−3.9) (−3.9) (−2.9) (−3.2)

ISKEW 0.12 −0.03 −0.13 −0.02 −0.00 −0.01 −0.10

(1.2) (−0.1) (−0.7) (−0.1) (−0.0) (−0.1) (−0.4)

ISKEW × FDSOX −0.85 −0.42 0.35 −0.14 −0.47 0.12 −0.35

(−2.8) (−1.0) (1.3) (−0.3) (−1.0) (0.3) (−0.9)

ISKEW × POSTSOX 0.34 0.37 0.18 0.38 0.28 0.34 0.63

(2.4) (1.3) (0.8) (1.2) (0.9) (1.2) (2.1)

MAJAUD −6.88 −7.25 0.43 −7.86 −6.65 −8.83 −7.01

(−12.8) (−7.2) (0.7) (−7.2) (−6.3) (−6.0) (−7.6)

MAJAUD × FDSOX 1.87 1.69 −1.50 1.82 1.74 1.96 1.96

(3.5) (1.3) (−1.4) (1.1) (1.2) (0.9) (1.1)

MAJAUD × POSTSOX 6.26 6.13 −0.40 6.47 5.59 6.81 5.63

(10.4) (5.7) (−0.5) (5.6) (4.8) (4.2) (5.4)

Continued . . .

49

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER Robustness (5-8)

No No No

PF Pr>$2 CA/NY Tech

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

ANCOV −4.01 −3.91 −1.91 −3.67 −3.37 −4.37 −4.36

(−8.0) (−5.6) (−3.8) (−6.0) (−4.5) (−6.6) (−5.9)

ANCOV × FDSOX 1.86 1.98 1.10 1.68 1.47 4.01 2.11

(3.7) (1.2) (1.0) (0.9) (0.9) (4.3) (1.1)

ANCOV × POSTSOX 0.49 0.96 1.42 0.22 0.76 2.54 0.72

(0.8) (0.8) (1.9) (0.2) (0.7) (2.8) (0.6)

ABSDACC RANK 0.56 0.50 −0.39 0.26 0.46 0.15 0.27

(1.7) (2.4) (−2.7) (1.2) (2.2) (0.8) (1.4)

ABSDACC RANK × FDSOX −0.33 −0.17 0.09 0.02 −0.22 0.18 0.01

(−1.0) (−0.6) (0.3) (0.1) (−0.7) (0.6) (0.0)

ABSDACC RANK × POSTSOX −0.66 −0.73 0.00 −0.35 −0.64 −0.20 −0.43

(−1.9) (−2.9) (0.0) (−1.4) (−2.5) (−1.0) (−1.7)

LOCANCOV 0.57 −0.05 0.44 0.61 0.54 0.77

(1.1) (−0.2) (0.3) (0.7) (0.8) (1.5)

LOCANCOV × FDSOX −0.55 0.16 −0.75 −0.38 −0.60 −0.75

(−0.6) (0.4) (−0.6) (−0.7) (−0.4) (−0.6)

LOCANCOV × POSTSOX −0.83 0.34 −0.63 −0.61 −0.56 −1.18

(−1.0) (0.8) (−0.4) (−0.7) (−0.6) (−1.6)

Firm Controls No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State Controls No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 38,834 37,876 37,782 35,212 37,782 36,101 26,025 28,695

Adj. R2 0.149 0.133 0.133 0.067 0.115 0.130 0.149 0.128

50

Table 5

Change in Local Ownership and Pre-Regulation Information Environment

This table reports pooled cross-sectional regression coefficient estimates and corresponding t-statistics for therelation between firm-level changes in excess local ownership relative to end of fiscal year 2000 level of the samemeasure and the characteristics of the firm information environment at the end of fiscal year 2000. We alsocontrol for time-varying firm and state characteristics and consider regime as well as state fixed effects. The levelof firm local excess institutional ownership is measured as of the fiscal year end, and all explanatory variablesare measured during the same fiscal year. FDSOX (POSTSOX) is an indicator variable equal to one for fiscalyears ending in calendar years 2001 and 2002 (2003 and onward). In Columns (1) to (3) and (5) to (8), we usethe portfolio holdings of institutions in the headquarters (HQ) state while in Column (4) we use the holdingsof institutions located in most economically relevant (er) states. The excess local ownership dependent variablein Column (5) is recalculated after excluding institutional investors that are classified as public or corporatepension funds, university endowments, or miscellaneous. The results in Columns (6) through (8) are basedon samples that exclude stocks priced below $2, firms located in California or New York states, and high-techfirms, respectively. The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix. Following Petersen (2009), thet-statistics reported in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by year and state. The sample periodis from 1996 to 2008.

Dependent Variable: Change in Excess Local Ownership relative to FYE 2000 (in %)

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER Robustness

No PF Pr>$2 No CA/NY No Tech

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

FDSOX −2.94 −15.33 −14.79 −0.06 −5.12 −20.02 −10.31 −21.04

(−5.6) (−2.0) (−1.9) (−0.0) (−0.7) (−2.9) (−1.2) (−1.9)

POSTSOX −4.01 −15.16 −14.56 −1.89 −3.87 −20.53 −6.89 −21.42

(−9.3) (−2.0) (−1.9) (−0.3) (−0.6) (−3.0) (−0.9) (−2.0)

TURN 0.32 0.39 −0.41 0.54 0.34 0.38 0.56

(3.8) (4.2) (−2.4) (4.3) (2.8) (2.9) (2.2)

TURN × POSTSOX 0.44 0.44 −0.22 0.69 0.4 0.39 0.85

(3.5) (3.4) (−1.6) (6.3) (3.3) (3.1) (3.8)

IVOL 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.02 0.08 0.01 0.04

(3.0) (2.7) (1.8) (0.7) (2.8) (0.2) (0.8)

IVOL × POSTSOX 0.06 0.06 0.05 −0.03 0.04 0.03 0.01

(2.5) (2.0) (1.7) (−1.2) (1.1) (0.8) (0.2)

ISKEW 0.01 0.05 −0.58 0.49 0.04 −0.14 −0.27

(0.1) (0.2) (−1.3) (1.2) (0.1) (−0.3) (−0.6)

ISKEW × POSTSOX −0.15 −0.26 0.16 −0.02 −0.34 −0.46 −0.95

(−1.6) (−1.5) (0.6) (−0.1) (−1.8) (−2.2) (−3.5)

Continued . . .51

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER Robustness

No No No

PF Pr>$2 CA/NY Tech

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

MAJAUD 3.15 2.90 −3.18 3.17 2.29 4.59 5.14

(2.2) (2.1) (−2.5) (2.2) (1.5) (2.2) (2.6)

MAJAUD × POSTSOX 2.99 3.07 −1.92 3.13 3.81 2.33 5.32

(4.5) (4.7) (−2.3) (4.3) (5.3) (2.4) (5.8)

ANCOV 0.58 0.98 −0.9 2.06 0.84 2.01 0.27

(1.0) (1.0) (−0.9) (2.3) (1.1) (2.3) (0.3)

ANCOV × POSTSOX 0.05 0.05 −1.37 0.56 −0.50 0.40 0.75

(0.6) (0.1) (−2.4) (1.0) (−1.1) (0.7) (0.3)

ABSDACC RANK −0.74 −0.72 0.44 −0.54 −0.65 −0.10 −0.09

(−1.9) (−1.9) (1.5) (−1.4) (−1.7) (−0.4) (−0.2)

ABSDACC RANK × POSTSOX −1.21 −1.36 0.98 −1.25 −1.14 −0.31 −1.26

(−5.1) (−5.0) (5.3) (−4.7) (−4.5) (−2.1) (−3.7)

LOCANCOV 0.00 0.34 0.36 0.07 −0.08 0.05

(0.0) (0.9) (0.8) (0.2) (−0.2) (0.1)

LOCANCOV × POSTSOX 0.14 −0.65 0.47 0.09 −0.54 −0.38

(0.3) (−1.6) (1.1) (0.2) (−2.2) (−1.4)

Firm Controls No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State Controls No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 16,476 16,074 16,045 16,045 16,045 15,256 10,806 11,837

Adj. R2 0.030 0.050 0.053 0.040 0.068 0.059 0.066 0.081

52

Table 6

Local Ownership and Local Performance:Estimates From Constant Coefficients Specifications

This table reports pooled cross-sectional regression coefficient estimates and corresponding t-statistics for therelation between firm-level returns in the quarter following the fiscal year end and the level of excess localinstitutional ownership as of the fiscal year end. We also control for time-varying firm and state characteristicsand consider regime as well as state fixed effects. The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix.Following Petersen (2009), the t-statistics reported in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by yearand state. The sample period is from 1996 to 2008.

Dependent Variable: Subsequent Quarter Return (in %)Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER

RAWRET EWRET VWRET CADJRET CADJRETIndependent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)LOCOWN 3.65 3.78 4.21 2.45 0.98

(2.6) (2.6) (2.8) (2.4) (0.8)

Other Firm CharacteristicsMCAP RANK −0.57 −0.71 −0.59 −0.09 −0.21

(−1.8) (−2.3) (−2.1) (−0.4) (−1.0)

FINLEV −0.67 −1.22 −0.57 −3.20 −3.21(−0.3) (−0.5) (−0.2) (−1.7) (−1.4)

AGE 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.01 0.02(1.4) (1.7) (1.5) (0.6) (0.8)

BM 4.00 3.39 3.68 3.13 2.7(2.0) (1.7) (1.8) (2.6) (2.1)

RET6M 0.00 0.37 −0.15 −0.74 −0.76(0.0) (0.2) (−0.1) (−1.3) (−1.2)

PRICE −0.06 −0.06 −0.05 −0.02 −0.02(−1.5) (−1.5) (−1.4) (−0.9) (−0.7)

LOTT 0.77 0.92 0.84 0.71 0.48(0.6) (0.7) (0.7) (0.7) (0.5)

Local AttributesEDU 0.71 0.75 0.65 0.18 −2.31

(0.4) (0.5) (0.4) (0.1) (−3.4)

POPDEN 0.00 0.01 0.00 −0.04 −0.01(0.0) (0.1) (0.0) (−0.8) (−0.1)

CPRATIO −4.37 −5.65 −3.90 1.76 0.95(−0.3) (−0.4) (−0.3) (0.2) (0.2)

REL −14.19 −11.56 −19.46 −33.94 −12.56(−0.7) (−0.6) (−1.1) (−1.8) (−0.5)

REPUB −1.88 −1.56 −1.84 −1.23 −0.67(−0.7) (−0.6) (−0.7) (−0.6) (−0.8)

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes YesYear FE Yes Yes Yes Yes YesN 46,433 46,433 46,433 40,035 37,645Adj. R2 0.057 0.012 0.034 0.006 0.006

53

Table 7

Local Ownership and Local Performance:Estimates From Time-Varying Coefficients Specifications

This table reports pooled cross-sectional regression coefficient estimates and corresponding t-statistics for therelation between firm-level returns in the quarter following the fiscal year end and the level of excess localinstitutional ownership as of the fiscal year end conditional on the regulatory regime. We also control for time-varying firm and state characteristics and consider regime as well as state fixed effects. FDSOX (POSTSOX) isan indicator variable equal to one for fiscal years ending in calendar years 2001 and 2002 (2003 and onward).We interact these indicator variables with LOCOWN, but do not include the standalone variables since theyare subsumed by the year fixed effects. In Columns (1) to (4) and (6) to (9), we use the portfolio holdingsof institutions in the headquarters (HQ) state while in Column (5) we use the holdings of institutions locatedin most economically relevant (ER) states. The excess local ownership independent variable in Column (6)is recalculated after excluding institutional investors that are classified as public or corporate pension funds,university endowments, or miscellaneous. The results in Columns (7) to (9) are based on samples that excludestocks priced below $2, firms located in California or New York states, and high-tech firms, respectively. We useequal-weighted returns in all four robustness tests. The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix.Following Petersen (2009), the t-statistics reported in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by yearand state. The sample period is from 1996 to 2008.

Dependent Variable: Subsequent Quarter Return (in %)

Firm Headquarters (HQ) ER Robustness (using EWRET)

RAW EW VW CADJ CADJ No No No

RET RET RET RET RET PF Pr>$2 CA/NY Tech

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

LOCOWN 5.40 5.76 6.25 3.99 0.75 7.26 4.84 3.54 2.86

(2.1) (2.1) (2.3) (2.4) (0.5) (2.5) (2.2) (2.0) (1.8)

LOCOWN × FDSOX 0.74 0.15 −0.02 0.36 −3.68 −1.84 0.81 3.74 3.66

(0.2) (0.1) (−0.0) (0.2) (−2.3) (−0.6) (0.3) (1.4) (2.0)

LOCOWN × POSTSOX −6.69 −7.14 −7.25 −5.50 2.68 −9.41 −5.92 −10.85 −5.74

(−1.9) (−2.0) (−2.0) (−2.5) (0.9) (−2.8) (−1.9) (−4.5) (−2.5)

Firm Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 46,433 46,433 46,433 40,035 37,645 46,433 44,660 31,269 35,159

Adj. R2 0.058 0.013 0.034 0.007 0.006 0.013 0.012 0.020 0.018

54

Table 8

Local Ownership and Informed Trading:Estimates From Constant and Time-Varying Coefficients Specifications

This table reports pooled cross-sectional regression coefficient estimates and corresponding t-statistics for therelation between firm-level measures of informed trading in the year following the fiscal year end and the level ofexcess local institutional ownership as of the fiscal year end. In Panels B and C this relation is conditioned on theregulatory regime. We also control for time-varying firm and state characteristics and include year as well as statefixed effects. FDSOX (POSTSOX) is an indicator variable equal to one for fiscal years ending in calendar years2001 and 2002 (2003 and onward). We interact these indicator variables with LOCOWN, but do not includethe standalone variables since they are subsumed by the year fixed effects. Among the dependent variables,PIN is the probability of private information related trade from Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O’Hara (2002) model.ADJPIN and PSOS are PIN’s components from Duarte and Young (2009). ADJPIN is the probability of privateinformation related trade from the extended model in Duarte and Young (2009), while PSOS is the probabilitythat a given trade happens during a symmetric order flow shock. Effective Spread (SPREAD) is the differencebetween the actual execution price and the midpoint of market quotes. We provide separate measurements ofthe spread around earnings announcements (SPDEARN) and excluding earnings announcements (SPDOTH).The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix. Following Petersen (2009), the t-statistics reportedin parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by year and state. The sample is restricted to 1996 to 2004period due to the availability of PIN components.

Panel A: Estimates Using Constant Coefficients Specifications

Dependent Variable: Subsequent Year PIN or Spread (in %)

PIN-Based Spreads-Based

PIN ADJPIN PSOS SPREAD SPDOTH SPDEARN

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

LOCOWN 5.65 2.15 3.73 0.35 0.35 0.38

(10.0) (4.8) (9.9) (10.6) (10.6) (8.4)

Firm Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 12,406 12,406 12,406 34,785 34,785 34,785

Adj. R2 0.321 0.486 0.476 0.524 0.523 0.474

55

Panel B: Estimates Using Time-Varying Coefficients Specifications

Dependent Variable: Subsequent Year PIN or Spread (in %)

PIN-Based Spreads-Based

PIN ADJPIN PSOS SPREAD SPDOTH SPDEARN

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

LOCOWN 3.59 2.24 3.23 0.46 0.46 0.46

(4.2) (4.6) (6.2) (7.8) (8.1) (8.1)

LOCOWN × FDSOX 2.20 −0.43 −0.22 −0.17 −0.18 −0.10

(1.6) (−0.6) (−0.3) (−3.6) (−3.8) (−1.1)

LOCOWN × POSTSOX 4.40 −1.43 0.25 −0.19 −0.20 −0.15

(3.0) (−1.7) (0.3) (−3.0) (−3.1) (−1.4)

Firm Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 12,406 12,406 12,406 34,785 34,785 34,785

Adj. R2 0.326 0.507 0.495 0.528 0.528 0.478

Panel C: Estimates Using Time-Varying Coefficients Specifications Around Earnings Announcements

Dependent Variable: Spread Around Earnings Announcement (in %)

Pre-Announcement Post-Announcement

(−5:−1) (−10:−1) (−20:−1) (+1:+5) (+1:+10) (+1:+20)

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

LOCOWN 0.37 0.37 0.36 0.32 0.32 0.31

(5.9) (5.9) (5.7) (5.0) (5.2) (5.2)

LOCOWN × FDSOX −0.20 −0.22 −0.22 −0.04 −0.04 −0.04

(−2.2) (−2.6) (−2.6) (−0.4) (−0.5) (−0.5)

LOCOWN × POSTSOX −0.20 −0.21 −0.18 −0.06 −0.07 −0.07

(−2.2) (−2.3) (−2.1) (−0.6) (−0.7) (−0.8)

Firm Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State Controls Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 41,001 41,007 41,009 41,055 41,059 41,060

Adj. R2 0.413 0.437 0.453 0.432 0.454 0.462

56

Table 9

Local Bias and Local Performance: Institution-Level Estimates

This table reports the abnormal fraction of institutional investors’ equity holdings invested in local stocks aswell as the average performance of institutional investors’ local and non-local holdings. Excess Local Weight isthe percentage of the investor’s portfolio invested in stocks located in the investor’s state (local stocks) minusthe percentage of the “market portfolio” located in the investor’s state. For each institution with non-zeroportfolio weight in local stocks, we calculate the quarterly characteristics-adjusted returns of its local and non-local portfolios, as well as the performance differential (local minus non-local). Local Portfolio is comprised ofstocks in the institutional investor’s portfolio that are located in the investor’s state, while Non-Local Portfolio iscomprised of the rest of the institution’s holdings. The portfolio returns are adjusted for the following three stockcharacteristics using the Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman, and Wermers (1997) method: size, book-to-market, and past12-month return. We take the average of excess weights and adjusted returns across all institutions each quarter,and then report the time-series average of those quarterly averages. The quarterly averaging across institutionsis either weighted by the total dollar value of the institution’s holdings at the beginning of the quarter (PanelA) or weighted equally (Panel B). The t-statistics reported in parentheses are adjusted for autocorrelation andheteroscedasticity following the Newey and West (1987) method. The sample period is from 1996 to 2008.

Panel A: Holdings-Weighted Average

PRESOX FDSOX POSTSOX

Measure 1996-2000 2001-2002 2003-2008 2001-2008

Excess Local Weight 3.54% 2.71% 2.24% 2.35%

Char. Adj. Quarterly Returns

Local Portfolio 1.11% −0.32% −0.20% −0.23%

Non-Local Portfolio 0.58% 0.05% −0.08% −0.04%

Local − Non-Local 0.54% −0.38% −0.12% −0.19%

(3.5) (−1.0) (−0.7) (−1.0)

Panel B: Equal-Weighted Average

PRESOX FDSOX POSTSOX

Measure 1996-2000 2001-2002 2003-2008 2001-2008

Excess Local Weight 5.93% 5.17% 4.22% 4.45%

Char. Adj. Quarterly Returns

Local Portfolio 1.08% 0.12% −0.08% −0.03%

Non-Local Portfolio 0.83% 0.04% 0.03% 0.04%

Local − Non-Local 0.27% 0.06% −0.13% −0.08%

(2.9) (0.3) (−1.1) (−0.8)

57

Table 10

Local Analyst Coverage Regression Estimates

This table reports the estimates from local coverage regressions of sell-side equity analysts. The dependentvariable is the excess coverage of local stocks, which is the difference between the fraction of local stocks in ananalyst’s stock coverage portfolio and the fraction of local stocks that the analyst can potentially cover withinthe CRSP universe. In the first two columns, we use equal-weighted fractions, while in the last two columns, weuse value-weighted fractions. The independent variables include indicator variables for FDSOX (2001-2002) andPOSTSOX (2003 onward), analyst characteristics (tenure, past performance, and number of firms covered), andan indicator variable for analysts employed by prestigious brokerage houses. All specifications include state fixedeffects. The definitions of all variables are provided in the Appendix. Following Petersen (2009), the t-statisticsreported in parentheses are based on standard errors clustered by year and state. The sample period is from1996 to 2008.

Dependent Variable: Excess Coverage of Local Stocks (in %)

Equal-Weighted Value-Weighted

Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)

FDSOX −1.24 −2.08 −1.75 −2.22

(−2.7) (−3.1) (−1.8) (−2.0)

POSTSOX −4.68 −5.79 −3.21 −4.64

(−5.6) (−8.6) (−3.8) (−7.0)

PBROKER −1.83 −3.31 −1.38 −3.00

(−2.8) (−4.5) (−1.9) (−4.9)

PBROKER × FDSOX 2.33 1.39

(2.5) (1.2)

PBROKER × POSTSOX 3.41 4.43

(2.3) (2.7)

HIGHPERF 0.54 0.52 1.23 1.19

(0.6) (0.6) (1.3) (1.2)

TENURE 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.01

(0.3) (0.4) (0.5) (0.6)

NFCOVER −0.17 −0.17 −0.13 −0.14

(−5.1) (−5.0) (−3.9) (−3.9)

State FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

N 23, 569 23,569 23,567 23,567

Adj. R2 0.209 0.210 0.231 0.233

Mean of Excess Coverage 9.63 9.63 6.30 6.30

58

Table

11

LocalFore

cast

Accura

cy

Regre

ssio

nEst

imate

s

Thi

sta

ble

repo

rts

the

esti

mat

esfr

omfo

reca

stac

cura

cyan

dm

arke

tre

acti

onre

gres

sion

s.In

Col

umns

(1)

to(8

),th

ede

pend

ent

vari

able

ison

eof

the

mea

sure

sof

anal

yst

quar

terl

yea

rnin

gsfo

reca

ster

ror,

whi

lein

Col

umns

(9)

and

(10)

,th

ede

pend

ent

vari

able

isth

esh

ort-

term

mar

ket

reac

tion

mea

sure

com

pute

dse

para

tely

for

upw

ard

(RE

TU

P)

and

dow

nwar

d(R

ET

DN

)fo

reca

stre

visi

ons.

The

inde

pend

ent

vari

able

sin

clud

ean

indi

cato

rva

riab

leLO

CA

Lan

dit

sin

tera

ctio

nsw

ith

FD

SOX

(200

1-20

02)an

dP

OST

SOX

(200

3on

war

d).

InC

olum

ns(4

)an

d(5

),th

eLO

CA

Lin

dica

torva

riab

leis

set

toon

eif

the

anal

yst

islo

cate

din

the

stat

eth

atis

econ

omic

ally

mos

tre

leva

ntfo

rth

efir

m.

Inot

her

colu

mns

,LO

CA

Lis

set

toon

eif

the

anal

yst

and

the

firm

head

quar

ters

are

inth

esa

me

stat

e.W

edo

not

incl

ude

the

stan

d-al

one

regi

me

vari

able

ssi

nce

they

are

subs

umed

byth

eti

me-

vary

ing

anal

yst

fixed

effec

ts.

The

defin

itio

nsof

allv

aria

bles

are

prov

ided

inth

eA

ppen

dix.

Follo

win

gPet

erse

n(2

009)

,the

t-st

atis

tics

repo

rted

inpa

rent

hese

sar

eba

sed

onst

anda

rder

rors

clus

tere

dby

firm

and

quar

ter.

The

sam

ple

peri

odis

from

1996

to20

08.

Dep

ende

ntV

aria

ble:

Fore

cast

Err

oror

Mar

ket

Rea

ctio

n(i

n%

)

Fore

cast

Err

or(1

-8)

Mar

ket

Rea

ctio

n(9

-10)

HQ

HQ

ER

ER

Full

PR

ESO

XFD

SOX

PO

STSO

X

ER

RM

DN

ER

RP

CT

LE

RR

MD

NE

RR

PC

TL

DA

FE

DA

FE

DA

FE

DA

FE

RE

TU

PR

ET

DN

Inde

pend

ent

Var

iabl

e(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)

LO

CA

L0.

81−0

.34

−0.0

40.

12−0

.44

−0.4

4−0

.18

0.13

0.19

0.02

(2.6

)(−

2.6

)(−

0.1

)(0

.8)

(−1.9

)(−

1.9

)(−

0.4

)(0

.8)

(2.2

)(0

.2)

LO

CA

FD

SOX

−0.5

90.

13−0

.43

0.49

0.26

0.21

−0.0

6

(−1.0

)(0

.5)

(−0.7

)(1

.7)

(0.6

)(1

.2)

(−0.4

)

LO

CA

PO

STSO

X−1

.15

0.27

0.44

−0.1

20.

57−0

.19

−0.1

0

(−2.5

)(1

.3)

(0.9

)(−

0.5

)(2

.0)

(−1.9

)(−

0.8

)

Ana

lyst

×Q

uart

erFE

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

N81

1,66

981

1,66

981

1,66

981

1,66

978

6,60

533

3,16

311

9,73

933

3,70

328

3,00

126

4,19

9

Adj

.R2

0.15

60.

164

0.15

60.

164

0.12

10.

107

0.16

70.

138

0.33

60.

350

59

Table 12

Local Bias and Local Performance: Institution-Level Estimates,Conditional Upon Local Analyst Presence

This table reports the local bias and local performance of institutional investors, sorted by the presence of localequity analysts. States are sorted into three groups based on the number of local analysts in the state: top5 states, 6th-20th states, and the rest of the states. For each group, we report the excess local holdings andthe average performance of institutional investors’ local and non-local holdings. Excess Local HQ Weight isthe percentage of the investor’s portfolio invested in stocks whose HQ are located in the investor’s state (localHQ stocks) minus the percentage of the “market portfolio” located in the investor’s state. For each institutionwith non-zero portfolio weight in local stocks, we calculate the quarterly characteristics-adjusted returns of itslocal and non-local portfolios, as well as the performance differential (local minus non-local). Local Portfolio iscomprised of stocks in the institutional investor’s portfolio whose HQ are located in the investor’s state, whileNon-Local Portfolio is comprised of the rest of the institution’s holdings. The portfolio returns are adjusted forthe following three stock characteristics using the Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman, and Wermers (1997) method: size,book-to-market, and past 12-month return. We take the average of excess weights and adjusted returns acrossall institutions each quarter, and then report the time-series average of those quarterly averages. The quarterlyaveraging across institutions is weighted by the total dollar value of the institution’s holdings at the beginningof the quarter. Panel B examines local ER1−5 stocks rather than local HQ stocks. Local ER1−5 stocks arethose for which the investor’s state is one of the five most economically relevant states. The definitions of allvariables are provided in the Appendix. The t-statistics reported in parentheses are adjusted for autocorrelationand heteroscedasticity following the Newey and West (1987) method. The sample period is from 1996 to 2008.

Panel A: Institutions Around Firm Headquarters

Quarterly Char. Adj. Returns (in %)

Analyst Presence Time Period Excess ER Wt (in %) Local HQ Non-Local HQ−NL (t-stat)

High (Top 5 States) 1996-2000 3.04 −0.55 0.52 −1.07 (−1.8)

2001-02 1.75 0.04 −0.22 0.26 (0.4)

2003-08 1.84 −0.38 −0.06 −0.32 (−0.9)

2001-08 1.82 −0.28 −0.10 −0.18 (−0.5)

Medium (States 6-20) 1996-2000 3.32 1.35 0.48 0.87 (1.2)

2001-02 2.64 0.15 0.04 0.21 (0.7)

2003-08 2.16 0.16 0.04 0.12 (0.6)

2001-08 2.28 0.18 0.04 0.14 (0.6)

Low (Other States) 1996-2000 3.01 1.48 0.70 0.78 (2.9)

2001-02 1.93 −0.50 0.19 −0.69 (−1.7)

2003-08 2.23 −0.38 0.18 −0.56 (−1.0)

2001-08 2.15 −0.41 0.18 −0.60 (−1.3)

60

Panel B: Institutions in Economically-Relevant States

Quarterly Char. Adj. Returns (in %)

Analyst Presence Time Period Excess ER Wt (in %) Local ER Non-Local ER−NL (t-stat)

High (Top 5 States) 1996-2000 2.84 1.55 0.52 1.03 (3.2)

2001-02 3.00 −0.17 −0.22 0.04 (0.2)

2003-08 2.61 0.66 −0.06 0.72 (2.2)

2001-08 2.71 0.45 −0.10 0.55 (2.7)

Medium (States 6-20) 1996-2000 4.38 1.48 0.48 1.00 (3.5)

2001-02 3.78 0.77 0.04 0.73 (2.9)

2003-08 3.75 0.28 0.04 0.24 (1.4)

2001-08 3.76 0.48 0.04 0.44 (1.9)

Low (Other States) 1996-2000 5.37 0.99 0.70 0.29 (1.0)

2001-02 5.40 0.77 0.19 0.57 (2.1)

2003-08 5.10 0.54 0.18 0.36 (1.2)

2001-08 5.17 0.60 0.18 0.41 (1.7)

61

Appendix: Variable Definitions

Ownership, Concentration, and Performance Measures

HQ State is the U.S. state or the District of Columbia in which the firm headquarters are

located. ER State is the economically most relevant state for a firm and refers to the U.S.

location that is not the firm HQ state but has the highest number of citations in a given

firm-year financial statement (10-K), as defined in Bernile, Kumar, and Sulaeman (2012). HQ

Excess Ownership (LOCOWN) is the state institutional ownership of a firm’s HQ state minus

that state’s average institutional ownership. ER Excess Ownership (ERLOCOWN) is the state

institutional holdings of a firm’s most economically relevant state minus that state’s average state

ownership. State Ownership is the state’s institutional investors’ share in the total institutional

ownership. Ownership Herfindahl is the Herfindahl-Hirschman concentration index (HHI) of

state-level institutional ownership across all U.S. states. Ownership GCI is the concentration

of state-level institutional ownership across all U.S. states adjusted for the “natural” level of

ownership concentration resulting from the geographical clustering of institutional investors.

Next Quarter Return (RAWRET) is the raw stock return in the first quarter following the firm

fiscal year end date. We adjust this raw return using equal-weighted CRSP (EWRET), value-

weighted CRSP (VWRET), and characteristics-based (CADJRET, Daniel, Grinblatt, Titman,

and Wermers (1997)) benchmarks. Institutional ownership (IO) in a firm is the total number of

shares owned by all 13(f) institutions as a proportion of the total number of shares outstanding

for the firm.

Information Environment Variables

Turnover (TURN) is trading volume divided by shares outstanding. Idiosyncratic Volatility

(IVOL) and Idiosyncratic Skewness (ISKEW) are calculated from residuals of annual market-

model regressions of monthly stock returns. Major Auditor (MAJAUD) is an indicator variable

equal to one if the firm hires a major auditor (AU code 01 to 08 in Compustat) in the relevant

fiscal year. Analyst Coverage (ANCOV) is an indicator variable equal to one if the firm is fol-

lowed by at least one equity analyst during the relevant fiscal year according to IBES records.

Number of Analysts (NUMANA) is the number of unique equity analysts providing earnings

forecasts or recommendations for the company stock during the relevant fiscal year. Absolute

Discretionary Accruals (ABSDACC) is the absolute value of the residual from the modified

Jones model of discretionary accruals estimated separately for each year/two-digit SIC code

combination, following Dechow, Sloan, and Sweeney (1995). Local Analyst Coverage (LOCAN-

COV) is an indicator variable equal to one if the firm is followed by at least one equity analyst

located in the firm’s HQ state during the relevant fiscal year. LOCAL is a dummy variable that

62

is set to one if the firm headquarters and the analyst are located in the same state and, zero

otherwise. It is defined in an analogous manner for economically relevant states.

Other Firm Characteristics and Local Attributes

Log(Market Cap) (MCAP) is the stock price multiplied by the number of shares outstanding.

Book-to-Market (BM) is the ratio of book and market equity. Financial Leverage (FINLEV)

is defined as (Total Long Term Debt + Preferred Equity Liquidation Value)/(Market Value of

Equity at Fiscal Year End + Total Long Term Debt + Preferred Equity Liquidation Value).

Firm Age (AGE) is the number of years since a firm’s first appearance in the CRSP database

(i.e., since it becomes a publicly traded firm). 6m Lagged Return (RET6M) is the raw stock

return in the six months leading up to the beginning of the institutional ownership measurement

quarter. Stock Price (PRICE) is the stock price at the beginning of the institutional ownership

measurement quarter. Following Kumar (2009), Lottery-Type Stock (LOTT) is an indicator

variable for firms that are not in the bottom third of volatility, the bottom third of skewness,

or the top third of price. Among the local attributes, Education (EDU) is the fraction of

college graduates in the state. Population Density (POPDEN) is the state’s population divided

by its land area. Catholic-Protestant Ratio (CPRATIO) is the ratio of Catholic adherents to

Protestant adherents in the state. Religiosity (REL) is the fraction of religious adherents in the

state. Republican (REPUB) is the percentage of the state’s registered voters that voted for the

presidential candidate from the Republican party in the last election.

Microstructure Variables

PIN is the probability of private information related trade from Easley, Hvidkjaer, and O’Hara

(2002) model. ADJPIN and PSOS are PIN’s components from Duarte and Young (2009).

ADJPIN is the probability of private information related trade from the extended model in

Duarte and Young (2009), while PSOS is the probability that a given trade happens during a

symmetric order flow shock. Effective Spread (SPREAD) is the difference between the actual

execution price and the midpoint of market quotes. We measure the spread in the [−1:+1]

window around earnings announcements (SPDEARN) and excluding earnings announcements

(SPDOTH).

Analyst-Related Measures

High Performance (HIGHPERF) is the fraction of analyst forecasts in the past year with below-

median forecast errors. Tenure (TENURE) is the number of quarters since the analyst’s first

appearance in the I/B/E/S dataset. Prestigious Broker (PBROKER) is an indicator variable

63

that takes the value of one if the analyst is employed by a prestigious brokerage house. Number

of Firms Covered (NFCOVER) is the number of stocks covered by the analyst in a particular

quarter. The excess coverage of local stocks (EXCOVLOC) is the difference between the fraction

of local stocks in an analyst’s stock coverage portfolio and the fraction of local stocks that the

analyst can potentially cover within the CRSP universe. Equal-weighted excess local coverage

is defined as the number of covered local stocks divided by the number of all covered stocks

minus the number of available local stocks divided by the number of all stocks. Value-weighted

excess local coverage is defined as the total market capitalization of covered local stocks divided

by the total market capitalization of all covered stocks minus the total market capitalization

of all local stocks divided by the total market capitalization of all stocks. Error Below Median

(ERRMDN) is an indicator variable that is set to one if the analyst forecast error is below

the median forecast error of all analyst forecasts for the same firm-quarter. Error Percentile

(ERRPCTL) is the percentile ranking of a given analyst forecast error within the universe of

all forecasts for the same firm-quarter. Following Malloy (2005), demeaned absolute forecast

error (DAFE) is calculated as the absolute forecast error (AFE) for an analyst’s forecast of a

particular firm’s annual earnings minus the mean absolute forecast error for that earnings report.

Absolute forecast error is calculated as the absolute value of an analyst’s latest forecast, minus

the actual earnings, as a percentage of the stock price one-year prior to the beginning of the fiscal

year. Market Reaction (MKTREACT) is the buy-and-hold abnormal return over the three-day

(−1, 0, 1) window around quarterly forecast revisions, calculated as the three-day buy-and-hold

return of the firm’s stock, minus the buy-and-hold return of the equal-weighted CRSP index.

We compute this separately for upward (RETUP) and downward (RETDN) forecast revisions.

64

Table A.1

State-Level Local Bias Estimates

This table reports the local bias for each state in the sub-periods before and after the introduction of Reg FD andSarbanes-Oxley. Missing rows indicate that either there is no publicly-traded firm headquartered in the state orthe state is not an economically relevant state for any publicly-traded firm. The definitions of all variables areprovided in the Appendix. The sample period is from 1996 to 2008.

Headquarters State Economically Relevant StatePREREGFD POSTSOX Change PREREGFD POSTSOX Change

State (1996-2000) (2003-2008) (1996-2000) (2003-2008)AL 8.13% 4.74% −3.39% 0.25% 0.33% 0.08%AK 0.08% 0.12% 0.05%AZ 3.06% −0.08% −3.14% 0.28% 0.64% 0.36%AR 3.18% 2.73% −0.45% 0.68% 0.35% −0.33%CA 12.08% 8.03% −4.05% 9.42% 10.09% 0.68%CO 3.71% 0.02% −3.69% 0.30% 0.32% 0.02%CT 2.30% 4.09% 1.78% 2.29% 8.67% 6.38%DE 3.96% 2.28% −1.68% 1.79% 1.06% −0.73%DC 0.23% 0.58% 0.35% 1.52% 0.36% −1.16%FL 4.75% 3.50% −1.26% 4.94% 1.45% −3.48%GA 1.83% 4.53% 2.70% 0.45% 0.66% 0.21%HI 16.69% 6.48% −10.21% −0.02% 0.05% 0.07%IL 3.00% 1.44% −1.56% 0.18% 4.71% 4.53%IN 7.33% 4.25% −3.07% 0.59% 0.13% −0.46%IA 11.17% 1.22% −9.96% 1.29% 3.12% 1.83%KS 2.00% 3.46% 1.46% 1.46% 1.66% 0.21%KY 14.47% 5.51% −8.96% 1.04% 1.06% 0.02%LA 2.91% 2.47% −0.44% 1.02% 0.40% −0.62%ME 15.62% 13.05% −2.57% 0.91% 0.61% −0.31%MD 5.60% 5.02% −0.58% 2.44% 4.48% 2.03%MA 2.60% −1.22% −3.81% 7.33% 9.18% 1.85%MI 8.94% 3.34% −5.60% 0.98% 0.12% −0.86%MN 19.75% 7.78% −11.97% 4.21% 1.99% −2.22%MS 16.11% 5.21% −10.90% 0.15% 0.02% −0.13%MO 6.17% 2.58% −3.59% 1.95% 1.41% −0.54%MT 0.04% 0.07% 0.03%NE 3.14% 2.48% −0.66% 13.17% 18.32% 5.15%NV 0.81% 0.65% −0.16%NH −0.11% 0.84% 0.94% 2.39% 0.18% −2.21%NJ 3.72% 2.70% −1.02% 2.41% 1.27% −1.15%NM −0.01% 0.13% 0.14%NY 6.75% 2.66% −4.08% 12.74% 12.75% 0.02%NC 10.81% 1.48% −9.33% 2.79% 2.20% −0.59%OH 13.85% 5.33% −8.52% 2.89% 0.65% −2.25%OK 13.80% 1.63% −12.17% 0.04% 0.12% 0.07%OR 5.82% 2.19% −3.63% 4.12% 1.23% −2.89%PA 6.98% 3.91% −3.06% 0.78% 2.41% 1.62%RI 4.42% 1.75% −2.66% 15.81% 0.30% −15.51%SC 17.40% 3.18% −14.22% 0.51% 1.83% 1.32%TN 3.69% 1.95% −1.74% 4.73% 1.46% −3.28%TX 2.06% 3.18% 1.12% −0.81% 0.44% 1.25%UT 7.62% 0.01% −7.61% 0.19% 0.09% −0.10%VT 7.81% 1.14% −6.66%VA 13.26% 7.08% −6.18% 4.63% 5.50% 0.87%WA 6.18% 3.11% −3.08% 2.38% 0.37% −2.02%WV 30.12% 23.21% −6.92% 3.51% 8.23% 4.72%WI 16.30% 5.78% −10.52% 11.02% 8.31% −2.71%Average 8.12% 3.83% −4.29% 2.82% 2.60% −0.22%

65