Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985,...

42
REPORT T O NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN RESEARC H TITLE : SOVIET HOUSEHOLD SAVING UNDE R QUANTITY CONSTRAINTS : EVIDENC E FROM THE SOVIET INTERVIEW PROJEC T AUTHORS : Paul R . Gregory an d Manouchehr Mokhtar i CONTRACTOR : University of Housto n PRINCIPAL INVESTIGATOR : Paul R . Gregor y COUNCIL CONTRACT NUMBER : 803-0 5 DATE : June 198 9 The work leading to this report was supported by funds provided b y the National Council for Soviet and East European Research . Th e analysis and interpretations contained in the report are those o f the author .

Transcript of Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985,...

Page 1: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

REPORT TONATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN RESEARC H

TITLE :

SOVIET HOUSEHOLD SAVING UNDE RQUANTITY CONSTRAINTS : EVIDENC EFROM THE SOVIET INTERVIEW PROJEC T

AUTHORS :

Paul R . Gregory andManouchehr Mokhtar i

CONTRACTOR :

University of Houston

PRINCIPAL INVESTIGATOR :

Paul R . Gregor y

COUNCIL CONTRACT NUMBER :

803-0 5

DATE :

June 198 9

The work leading to this report was supported by funds provided b ythe National Council for Soviet and East European Research . Theanalysis and interpretations contained in the report are those o fthe author .

Page 2: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

NOTE

This report is an incidental product of the Council Contract note don the title page . This is not the Final Report, which will b edistributed at a later date .

Page 3: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

ABSTRACT

This study uses a survey of former Soviet citizens (th eSoviet Interview Project) to investigate household savin gbehavior in the Soviet Union . We combine objective data o nincome, consumption, and wealth with respondent perceptionsof consumer market shortages to which they were subjected i nthe Soviet Union . The latter information allows us toclassify households as "severely" or "moderately" quantit yconstrained or unconstrained in consumer markets . The dataset also allows us to study the effects of privilege an dunderground economy purchases on Soviet household savingbehavior .

We present relatively conclusive evidence to supportthe proposition that marginal saving rates are positivel yrelated to the severity of quantity constraints . Soviethouseholds subject to severe quantity constraints hav emarginal saving rates more than double those o funconstrained households. Surprisingly, the high margina lsaving rate of severely constrained Soviet households i svery close to that of U .S . households during the rationingof World War II . As a consequence of including quantit yconstraints, the unconstrained marginal saving rat e(estimated from a conventional saving model) is reduced frombeing relatively high by international standards to bein grelatively low. We also find that Soviet households hav ehigher marginal saving rates out of high-variance privat eincome (in keeping with the permanent income hypothesis )when quantity-constraint variables are included .

The effects of quantity constraints on marginal savin grates are most visible at above-average income levels . Atlow levels of income, quantity-constrained households sav econsiderably less than their unconstrained counterparts . Ataverage income levels, they save slightly more . Only atabove average incomes, do the average saving rates o fconstrained Soviet households markedly exceed those o funconstrained households .

We find a relatively minor (although statisticall ysignificant) effect of underground economy purchases o nSoviet household saving . Quantity-constrained households d oparticipate more in underground markets at relatively highprices, as would be expected . Nevertheless, this differenc ein underground market participation accounts for only asmall difference in saving between constrained an dunconstrained households .

With or without adjustment for quantity constraints ,Soviet household saving behavior follows normal pattern swith respect to life-cycle effects and household size .

Page 4: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

I . SOVIET HOUSEHOLD SAVING UNDER QUANTITY CONSTRAINTS

Soviet households operate in what is generall y

perceived to be a quantity-constrained consumer market i n

which choices of key consumer goods are constrained by

formal and informal rationing devices . According to Korna i

(1980, 1982), such shortage is not explained by transitory

planning problems . Chronic excess demand is endemic to -

planned socialism, which creates what Kornai calls a

"shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p .381) . Barro and

Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantit y

constraints on the economic behavior of households, arguin g

that households substitute leisure or saving for consumptio n

when faced with quantity constraints . The Barro/Grossma n

model, hence, raises the possibility that quantit y

constraints lower Soviet economic performance by reducin g

scarce labor inputs . As a planned socialist economy ,

potentially characterized by economy-wide excess demand, the

saving behavior of Soviet households promises to shed ligh t

on the Barro/Grossman proposition .

The Soviet leadership has an intense interest i n

household saving behavior . Soviet authorities believe that

Soviet households follow the basic proposition of th e

quantity-constraint model : increases in the stock o f

household saving are attributed almost exclusively t o

economy-wide increases in excess demand . In an economy i n

which public saving is supposed to provide investment

Page 5: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

finance, private saving is viewed as a disturbing sign o f

growing disequilibrium . The stock of private saving i s

perceived as an overfull dam threatening to de-stabilize the

already fragile consumer market . The thinking of the Sovie t

leadership has been buttressed by Western analysts of the

Soviet economy [Bronson and Severin (1970, 1973), Bus h

(1973) and Schroeder (1975)], who contend that increases i n

Soviet saving are forced by general shortages of consumer

goods .

This paper estimates the effects of quantit y

constraints on the saving behavior of Soviet households . It

uses a unique micro data source -- interviews with 2,79 3

former Soviet citizens who left the Soviet Union in the late

1970s . These interviews were conducted by the Nationa l

Opinion Research Center on behalf of the Soviet Interview

Project (henceforth, SIP) . 1 Along with conventiona l

information on income, consumption expenditures, wealth an d

demographic characteristics, the Soviet Interview Project

asked a series of questions concerning consumer good s

shortages, purchases in collective farm markets and i n

underground markets, and access to "closed shops . "

The Soviet Interview Project provides rare direc t

information on excess demand that can be used to gauge th e

effects of shortage on household saving. Past studies hav e

1 Background information and first results of the Sovie tInterview Project are found in James R . Millar (1987) .

- 2 -

Page 6: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

attempted to test for economy-wide quantity constraints ;

they have not focused on the effects of quantity constraints

on household saving behavior . With direct information o n

shortages, differentiated by households, we are in a

position to estimate their effects on household behavior .

II . TESTING FOR QUANTITY CONSTRAINTS

The Barro/Grossman model has been the subject o f

considerable amplification over the years . Its theoretical

properties have been examined by Portes (1976), Malinvau d

(1977), Howard (1977), and Muellbauer and Portes (1978) .

Quandt (1978, 1982) and Portes (1986) have formulate d

empirical methods for detecting economy-wide disequilibri a

in consumer and labor markets . For a survey of applied

research on disequilibrium models, see Laffont (1985) .

Empirical testing of the Barro/Grossman model ha s

centered on the planned socialist economies of Easter n

Europe and the Soviet Union . Although virtually al l

economies have quantity-constrained markets (such as rent -

controlled housing or price-controlled medical care), the

planned socialist economies are perceived as being mos t

prone to economy-wide excess demand . Kornai (1985) provide s

a brief survey and relevant bibliographies of research on

quantity constraints in Eastern European economies .

- 3 -

Page 7: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

With the significant exception of Ofer and Pickersgil l

(1980), empirical tests of the Barro/Grossman saving mode l

have used time series data to detect consumer market

disequilibria in planned socialist economies . Ofer and

Pickersgill (1980) use a cross section sample of forme r

residents of the Soviet Union who emigrated to Israel in th e

early 1970s . Henceforth, the sample used by Ofer and

Pickersgill will be referred to as the Israel Sovie t

Interview Project, or ISIP . Empirical tests o f

disequilibrium models employ two different procedures . One

is to compare the parameters of the saving function of on e

or more planned economies with international studies o f

Western countries (where general quantity constraints do no t

prevail) . Examples are the studies of Portes and Winte r

(1978), Pickersgill (1976), and Ofer and Pickersgill (1980 )

who find that the estimated planned-economy saving-functio n

parameters are consistent with non-quantity-constraine d

economies . If the planned economies were indeed subject t o

general excess demand in consumer markets, it is argued, the

planned-economy saving functions would not be well behaved .

The second approach uses formal disequilibrium model s

(Quandt 1978) that allow for disequilibria between specifie d

aggregate consumer supply and aggregate consumer deman d

equations . Although excess demand (or supply) cannot b e

directly observed, the determinants of aggregate consume r

supply and demand can be specified and likelihood test s

- 4 -

Page 8: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

applied to test for general disequilibrium . An example o f

this second type of approach is Portes, Quandt, and Ye o

(1988), who use a disequilibrium model to reject genera l

excess demand for Poland -- the planned economy most woul d

single out as suffering from chronic excess demand .

Most empirical studies of saving in the planne d

socialist economies conclude that the hypothesis o f

sustained consumer-market disequilibrium cannot be accepte d

[Pickersgill (1976, 1977), Millar and Pickersgill (1977) ,

Portes and Winter (1977)] . 2 Although few would dispute th e

widespread presence of queues in these economies, spillove r

purchases allow notional consumer demand to be realized in

non-quantity-constrained markets, thereby eliminating

general excess demand .

Past studies of quantity-constrained economies suffe r

from three weaknesses . First, international comparison s

yield such a broad band of feasible parameter estimates that

the planned socialist estimates must be highly unusual t o

fall outside the band . Second, only asymptotic likelihoo d

tests are available when the model specification directl y

allows disequilibrium in consumer markets . Third, tests on

2 Podkaminer (1982, p .429) does find evidence of excesssaving for Poland between 1970 and 1978 . Podkaminer applieslinear expenditure models using Irish and Italian demandparameters to Poland to come to this conclusion .

- 5 -

Page 9: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

microeconomic data tend to yield more robust results tha n

those on macroeconomic time series . 3

III . SOVIET INTERVIEW PROJECT, BIASES, DATA ON CONSUMPTION ,

INCOME, SAVING, AND WEALTH

Sample Size and Biases

The Soviet Interview Project sample is described in

various publications (Millar, 1987, Swafford 1987, Gregor y

and Collier 1988) . The interviews

April and December of 1983 .

speak about their lives prior to

by the emigration decision . For most

last period of normal life in the Sovie t

1979 . The SIP sample was stratified fro m

33,000 cases according to the geographic, educational, an d

nationality characteristics of the Soviet urban populatio n

3 Time series tests are influenced by the time seriesproperties of the data ; i .e . number of unit roots in theobservations . For the usual integrated (non-stationary) dataprocess different critical values are required . For example, t-statistics do not have the usual distribution and, sometimes, t -values in excess of 3 are needed (see, for example, Hendry ,1986) . Phillips and Durlauf (1986) show that in tests o fhypotheses involving integrated processes the limitin gdistribution of F-statistics depends on nuisance parameters an d"lacks its usual rationale" (p .483) . They also show that othe rtest criteria, e .g . likelihood ratios, suffer from the sam eproblem . On empirical grounds, Nelson and Plosser (1982) showthat the U.S . macroeconomic time series follow some non -stationary process, and Mokhtari (1988) provides internationa levidence to the same effect for aggregate income and consumptio ndata .

and Kohlhase 1988, Gregory

were conducted betwee n

Respondents were asked to

the break caused

respondents, thi s

Union was 1978 or

- 6 -

Page 10: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

residing in medium to large cities . Some 90 percent of th e

SIP respondents were Jewish .

Inferences concerning the referent Soviet population

should be drawn with caution from the SIP sample . The

sample's mean values of key economic and demographic

variables such as earnings and household size are close to

the referent population (Gregory 1987), although servic e

employment is higher and respondents are more educated than

the referent population . Because of the sample's genera l

similarity to the referent population, its behavioral

parameters should be reasonably representative of th e

referent population . This would not be the case if a pur e

Jewish distortion causes Soviet Interview Project

respondents to behave differently from respondents draw n

from the referent population having the identical attribute s

except Jewishness . We seen no reason to expect strong biase s

with respect to household saving behavior .

After dropping redundant interviews conducted wit h

another members of the same household, cases with missin g

values, and 46 cases of extreme values, we were left wit h

2108 households . 4 As noted above, the sample mean value s

of income, household size, and age are close to those of th e

4 We found 46 cases, 2 percent of the responses, to showextreme values without being supported by the rest of response sto the questions for each case . This compares favorably with the52 cases, or 5 percent of the ISIP data, considered as extrem evalues by Ofer and Pickersgill . Given the size of the SIP dataand our unsuccessful attempts to adjust extreme values, w edecided to discard these observations .

- 7 -

Page 11: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

referent Soviet population . They are also close in most

cases to the mean values of the Ofer-Pickersgill Israe l

Soviet Interview Project, although the Ofer-Pickersgil l

study deals with the early 1970s .

Income Data

Household monthly income is defined as :

Y = Y 1 + Y 2 + Y 3 + Y4

where

Y 1 : monthly salary from the respondent's main state-secto rjob

Y2 : monthly salary from any second job in the state secto r

Y3 : monthly salary from any private jo b

Y4 : monthly salary of spouse from main job

The above sum may exclude some sources of househol d

income, such as from a spouse's second job or privat e

earnings or the earnings of an adult child . Respondent

confusion over the definition of family income made th e

above summation a more reliable household income measure .

than the direct answer to family income . 5

We distinguish between the income from public-sector

sources (YP = Y 1 + Y 2 + Y4 ) and private sources (YT = Y 3 ) .

Table 1 shows that private income accounts for seven percen t

of household income . Among the four types of income, YT i s

the most variable source for Soviet households .

5 Anderson and Silver (1987) have demonstrated the basi cunreliability of the SIP family income measure . Ofer andVinokur's study of SIP income distribution (Vinokur and Ofe r1987) also uses the same summation to represent household income .

- 8 -

Page 12: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Expenditure and Saving

Soviet Interview Project respondents were asked a

number of questions concerning their monthly expenditures b y

source . Monthly household saving is obtained by : S = Y - C ;

where consumer spending (C = C 1 + C 2 + C3 ) components are :

C1 : amount spent in collective farm markets (rynok)

C2 : amount spent in the underground economy (na levo )

C3 : amount spent in official state outlet s

Respondents reported total monthly expenditures alon g

with C 1 and C 2 ; therefore, C3 is a residual . Table 1

provides descriptive statistics on S, C 1 , C2 , C 3 . Table 1

shows that C 2 has the highest variation among the three

expenditure categories . Expenditures in the underground

economy and in collective farm markets, on average, account

for 16% and 27% of total spending, respectively . 6 For a

Soviet household that is quantity-constrained in official

outlets, collective farm markets and underground purchase s

provide the opportunity to convert notional demand . into

goods, but at prices that are higher than state stores .

Wealth

Liquid wealth (WL) consists of the sum of currency ,

savings, 3 percent bonds, and the resale value of valuable s

6 These figures may cause an understatement of consume rspending in state stores because some respondents apparentl yincluded goods purchased by bribes and other unofficial means i nstate stores in underground purchases .

-9 -

Page 13: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

or collectibles (like precious metals or jewels) . Illiquid

wealth (WI) consists of the resale value of furniture, cars ,

dachas, houses or cooperative apartments . Wealth (W) is the

sum of liquid and illiquid assets .

Table 1 yields a 35 percent income-wealth ratio (base d

on an annualized income) for the sample. This ratio is

slightly lower than the 43 percent ratio obtained for the

U .S . (Venti and Wise, 1986) . The 35 percent ratio is one

quarter of the income-wealth ratio found by Ofer an d

Pickersgill (p .138) . Soviet Interview respondents were, on

average, 3 .6 times as wealthy as those of Ofer an d

Pickersgill . Although there is general comparability of

mean values, the difference in wealth between the Sovie t

Interview Project and Israel Soviet Interview Project

samples is significant . Wealth (W) has a coefficient o f

variation that is about twice the coefficient of variatio n

of Y . Wealth inequality is higher than income inequality

among the Soviet households a result confirmed by Vinoku r

and Ofer (1987, p .196) .

The Average Propensity to Sav e

Table 1 shows that average saving of Soviet intervie w

project households to be 50 rubles per month . This figure i s

higher than the 33 rubles average of Ofer and Pickersgill .

- 1 0 -

Page 14: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 1

Descriptive Statistics of the Soviet Interview Projec t

Sample of Former Soviet Citizen, 1978-7 9

(Number of Households : 2108 )

Variable Mean Standard Deviation Coefficient of Variation

S 50 .0 132 .2 264 . 2C 281 .8 197 .3 70 . 0C 1 76 .7 83 .9 109 . 3C 2 46 .8 76 .9 164 . 2C3 158 .1 167 .3 105 . 8Y 331 .8 238 .1 71 . 7YP 308 .1 188 .2 61 . 1YT 23 .7 145 .7 614 . 0H 3 .2 1 .3 40 . 0W 11,425 .9 15,053 .1 131 . 7WL 5,439 .9 9,099 .1 167 . 2WI 5,985 .9 9,149 .1 152 . 8AGE 42 .2 13 .6 32 .2

S : Total savingsC : Total amount spent in all marketsC1 : amount spent in collective farm markets (rynok )C2 : amount spent in the underground economy (na levo )C3 : amount spent in official state outlet sY : Total incomeYP : Income from public sourcesYT : Income from Private sourcesH : Household sizeW : Total wealthWL : Liquid wealthWI : Non-liquid wealthAGE : Age of the responden t

Page 15: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

The higher saving figure is expected because of the wealt h

differences noted above . Moreover, our data refer to 1978-7 9

while Ofer-Pickersgill refer to 1972-73 . Nevertheless, the

higher saving figure is surprising because the negativ e

saving of 205 Soviet Interview Project households have bee n

included, unlike Ofer and Pickersgill who lacked information

on negative saving . 7

The average propensity to save (APS) of the Sovie t

Interview Project sample is 15 percent . This APS ratio i s

generally higher than those obtained from budget studies o f

other nations, but its close to a number of countries . The

15 percent ratio is only slightly higher than Germany and

Holland, 5 to 10 percentage points above Belgium, France ,

U .K ., U .S . and Switzerland (Katona, Strumpel and Zahn 1971 ,

p .89 ; Mayer 1972a, p .286-7, Mayer 1972b, p .758), and three

times larger than Israel (Liviatan 1963, p .33) . The 1 5

percent ratio is more than twice Ofer and Pickersgill' s

(1980, p .132) .

The relatively high Soviet average propensity to sav e

is consistent with the proposition that quantity constraint s

in Soviet consumer markets have "forced" an unusually hig h

saving rate from Soviet households . It fails to offer

7 Ofer and Pickersgill (p .130) "conclude that negativesavings was not reported because the respondents did no tunderstand that they could report it, not because it did no texist ." Ceteris paribus, this, lack of the data on dissaving, ca nintroduce an upward bias in the estimated intercept of savin gfunction . Indeed, we obtain smaller intercepts than those tha tare reported by Ofer and Pickersgill .

- 1 1 -

Page 16: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

decisive evidence for two reasons . First, it measures the

average rather than the relevant marginal propensity to

save, and it is marginal behavior that should be affected by

quantity constraints . Second, other factors that affec t

saving rates (age, household size, and so on) are not bein g

held constant .

IV . A CONVENTIONAL SAVING MODEL

We begin by estimating a standard microeconomic savin g

function from the Soviet Interview Project data assuming no

quantity constraints, e .g ., that no respondent had a genera l

excess demand for consumer goods . The estimated saving

function (Table 2) is specified in the conventional fashion

(Modigiliani 1975) to include household income, liquid an d

illiquid wealth (Venti and Wise, 1986), household size, and

age . The age variable enters in nonlinear form to allow fo r

life-cycle effects (Hall and Mishkin, 1982) .

For those familiar with the empirical estimates o f

saving functions using cross-sectional data, Table 2

contains no surprises (see Mayer, 1972a, Modigiliani, 1975 ,

and Thomas 1985) . The effect of age is very similar to th e

U .S . (Hall and Mishkin 1982) with Soviet household s

exhibiting familiar life-cycle behavior . As in the othe r

countries and in the Ofer and Pickersgill study, household

size negatively affects household saving . The net effect o f

- 1 2 -

Page 17: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 2Conventional Saving Model Without Quantity Constraint s

Soviet Interview Project Households

Estimation Technique : OLS

Dependent Variable : Savings

Variables Coefficient Estimates

Constant -88 . 9(3 .6 )

(Income )Y .3 3

(31 .9 )(Liquid wealth)WL .00 1

(4 .9 )(Illiquid wealth )WI - .00 1

(4 .6 )(Household size )H -17 . 3

(9 .1 )(Age )AGE 3 . 5

(3 .1 )(Age-squared )AGE2 - .0 3

(2 .6)

Page 18: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

wealth appears to be insignificant with the positive effec t

of liquid wealth cancelling the negative effect of illiqui d

wealth . Venti and Wise (1986) also find a negative effect o f

non-liquid wealth and a positive effect of liquid wealth o n

U .S . savings .

The estimated marginal propensity to save (MPS) of .3 3

falls in the higher range of MPS estimates from househol d

studies for other countries (See Table 3) . It is closest to

Canada ( .35), the United States ( .20 to .41) and Israe l

( .42) . The .33 MPS is two to 3 .5 times the range estimate d

by Ofer and Pickersgill for Israel Soviet Interview Projec t

households . Part of this difference is explained by Ofer an d

Pickersgill's lack of data on negative saving, which woul d

bias downward their MPS estimate . 8

The permanent income hypothesis (Friedman 1957 )

postulates that transitory income has a larger effect o n

marginal saving than permanent income . The conventiona l

model was also run separating income into its high-varianc e

component (private earnings) and low-variance componen t

(earnings from state jobs) . This model yielded identical MP S

coefficients . We mention this point because the MPSs differ

when quantity constraints are introduced in the next

section .

8 Lack of observations on dissavings, leading to th ecorrelation of residuals and right hand-side variables, render sthe OLS estimates inconsistent (see, Maddala, 1983 and reference stherein) .

- 1 3 -

Page 19: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 3 reveals why it is difficult to test quantity -

constraint propositions by comparing Soviet parameters wit h

other countries . To fall within bounds set by internationa l

studies, the Soviet MPS need only fall within the wide range

of .12 (lower estimate for the U .K .) to .46 (Belgium) .

V . AN UNCONVENTIONAL SAVING MODEL WITH QUANTITY CONSTRAINT S

The conventional model of Soviet household savin g

reported in Table 2 was estimated assuming the absence o f

quantity constraints . It ignored as well other importan t

Soviet institutional arrangements associated with quantit y

constraints . No distinction was drawn between purchases i n

state stores at official prices and in collective farm

markets and in the underground economy at higher market -

clearing prices . Moreover, no allowance was made fo r

households with privileged access to state stores . Household

income was not differentiated according to whether it wa s

earned in private (illegal) activities or in state jobs .

Identifying Quantity-Constrained Households

The Soviet Interview Project asked a series o f

questions about how respondents perceived consumer-marke t

shortages . In the Soviet Union, household experience wit h

consumer-market disequilibria would be expected to vary .

Some households live in cities and regions (such as capita l

cities or where key industrial sites are located) where

- 14 -

Page 20: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 3

Household Budget Studie s

Marginal Propensity to Save out of Income= MPS

Country MPS Source

U .S .S .R (1978-79) .33 Current pape r

U .S .S .R (early 1970s) .09- .17 Offer and Pickersgill (1980 )

Belgium .46 Moulaert and Canniere (1988 )

Israel .42 Sadan and Tropp (1973 )

India .15 Ramanathan (1968 )

Canada .35 Agarwala and Drinkwater (1971 )

Germany .17 Mayer (1972b )

Swiss .15 Mayer (1972b )

U .K .12- .27 Parry (1967 )

U .S .A .20- .41 Husby (1971 )

U .S .A .21- .43 Friedman (1957)

Page 21: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

"deficit goods" are less prominent . 9

Others, through

privileged professions or positions, are less likely t o

encounter shortages . Still others are particularl y

"information rich" and have developed skills to circumvent

shortages .

The Soviet Interview Project asked each respondent :

"how satisfied were you with the availabilit y

(accessibility) of consumer goods in your town ." 10 A random

subset of one third of the respondents was asked about

shortages (defitsity) of meat and dairy products in stat e

stores (at official prices) and about shortages of luxury

items (cars, fashionable clothing, furniture) in thei r

community . 1 1

More than fifty percent (53 percent) reported bein g

"extremely dissatisfied" with consumer goods availability

(accessibility) . Another 23 percent were "somewha t

9 Soviet respondents clearly understand in meaning o f"deficit goods" (defitsitnye tovary) in the economist's sense o fexcess demand at prevailing prices .

10 The Russian term for "availability" is dostupnost' whichconveys the meaning of availability-accessibility . A follow-upsurvey of ten persons drawn from the universe of potential SI Prespondents showed that respondents interpret "availability" a sthe ability to purchase in state stores at established prices ."Unavailability" means that goods that they are prepared to buyin state stores cannot be purchased .

11 The questions are : "Thinking about the city or townwhere you lived, would you say that the state stores usually ha da large enough supply of meat and dairy products, or that usuallythere was a shortage (defitsit)? "We have heard that in th eSoviet Union there are some goods, such as cars, fashionabl eclothing, and furniture, that are frequently in short supply . Wa sthis true in your town or not?"

- 1 5 -

Page 22: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

dissatisfied ." Twenty four percent fell in the "somewhat" o r

"very satisfied" category . Although the vast majority o f

respondents expressed dissatisfaction with good s

availability, about one quarter did not consider consume r

goods shortages to be significant . The experiences of

respondent households with consumer-market shortages wer e

not uniform . Over 80 percent of the subsample asked abou t

"deficits" of specific goods agreed that meat and dair y

products were in short supply in state stores, and

virtually all (96 percent) agreed that luxury goods (cars ,

furniture, etc .) were in short supply . Again, although most

respondents agreed on the presence of shortages, some twent y

percent did not consider shortages of meat and dair y

products in state stores to be significant .

Our unconventional model of household saving partitions

households into different quantity-constraint groupings .

Group I respondents, who reported "extreme dissatisfaction "

with goods availability, are classified as experiencing

"severe quantity constraints" in consumer markets . In Tabl e

4, group I respondents are assigned D1 = 1 . Group I I

respondents (D 2 = 1), who reported being "somewha t

dissatisfied," are classified as experiencing "moderate

quantity constraints . The residual Group III respondent s" ,

(D 1 = D2 = 0) are classified as being free of genera l

quantity constraints in consumer markets .

- 1 6 -

Page 23: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Characteristics of Quantity-Constrained Household s

Soviet Interview Project respondents self-identifie d

themselves according to their perceptions of the severity o f

quantity constraints they faced in Soviet consumer markets .

Table 4 shows the characteristics of severely

constrained (Group I), moderately constrained (Group II) ,

and unconstrained households (Group III) . The basic

proposition of the Barro/Grossman model is that quantity -

constrained households substitute saving or leisure fo r

unfulfilled notional demand . Group I's S and S/Y should b e

higher than Group II's and its Y should be lower holding

other factors constant . Similarly, Group II's S and S/Y

should be higher and its Y lower than Group III's . The

higher S and S/Y reflect the notion that the more severe th e

quantity constraint, the greater the "forced saving," an d

the lower Y reflects the substitution of leisure for

consumption by the quantity-constrained household .

The average values for saving (S), consumption (C) ,

income (Y) for the three groups of households in Table 4 d o

not support these propositions . The ruble value of househol d

saving rises from 44 rubles to 50 rubles and then to 6 4

rubles as quantity constraints are relaxed from Group I t o

Group III . The average propensity to save rises from 1 3

percent to 16 percent to 20 percent . There is no

significant difference in income levels between constrained

and unconstrained households .

- 1 7 -

Page 24: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 4

Average Values for Data Grouped by Quantity Constraints

Group I Group II Group II INumber o fHouseholds (1132) (493) (483 )

Variables D 1=1 D2=1 D1=D2= 0

S 43 .8 50 .1 64 . 4C 294 .1 270 .3 264 . 6C1 81 .1 69 .2 74 . 3C2 60 .1 37 .7 24 . 5C3 152 .6 163 .3 165 . 8S/Y 13 .0 15 .6 19 . 6Y 337 .9 320 .4 329 . 0YP 313 .3 306 .5 297 . 4YT 24 .6 13 .9 31 . 6H 3 .3 3 .2 3 . 1W 10,775 .2 10,417 .1 13,980 . 4WL 4,990 .2 5,187 .7 675 . 5WI 5,785 .0 5,229 .3 7,228 . 8AGE 39 .4 44 .8 46 . 2C2/C .18 .12 .0 8CS .04 .05 .05

Group I : Households with Severe Quantity ConstraintGroup II : Households with Some Quantity ConstraintGroup III : Households with No Quantity ConstraintS : Total savingsC : Total amount spent in all market sC 1 : amount spent in collective farm markets (rynok )C 2 : amount spent in the underground economy (na levo )C 3 : amount spent in official state outlet sY : Total incomeYP : Income from public source sYT : Income from Private source sH : Household siz eW : Total wealthWL : Liquid wealthWI : Non-liquid wealthAGE : Age of the respondentCS : Households with access to closed shop s

Page 25: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Comparisons of average values serve as a poor test o f

the quantity-constraint model . The theory of quantity

constraints predicts the effects of shortages on margina l

behavior, not on average behavior . The issue is the effect

of quantity constraints on marginal behavior, not on average

behavior . Moreover, other variables that affect averag e

saving are not being held constant . Table 4 shows that the

most severely quantity-constrained households average seve n

years younger than unconstrained households . Severely

quantity constrained households make 18 percent of their

purchases in the underground economy, while unconstraine d

households make only 8 percent of their purchases there .

Unconstrained households have higher average wealth .

Insofar as age, wealth, and propensity to purchase i n

underground markets may systematically affect household

saving, the lower average saving of quantity-constrained

households may be the consequence of these differences .

Higher dissaving by younger households is a well-established

empirical phenomenon and adjustment for age difference s

would reduce the average saving differential . Adjustment for

the greater propensity of constrained households to purchase

in underground markets (a predictable result of quantity

constraints) would also be expected to reduce the

differential because of the higher underground marke t

prices . The empirical literature makes no uniform

predictions about the effects of wealth on saving . Although

- 1 8 -

Page 26: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

some elegant specifications allowing for wealth and it s

composition have been put forward (Pesaran and Evans, 1984 ) ,

reliable wealth data is not available for estimation . 1 2

Table 4 does not show mean differences among the thre e

groups in access to closed shops (respondents having acces s

to closed shops are recorded as CS=1 and CS=0 otherwise) .

some five percent of each group had access to closed shops .

Closed shops can have a significant effect on househol d

saving because preferential access to shortage market s

relaxes quantity constraints . Although closed shops are not

important in explaining mean differences, they are

potentially important in explaining individual househol d

behavior .

Estimating a Model With Quantity Constraint s

The above discussion illustrates the importance of

enforcing the ceteris paribus assumption in investigatin g

the effects of quantity constraints on Soviet househol d

saving behavior. Table 5 shows the results of reestimatin g

the conventional model, allowing for three categories o f

quantity-constrained households ( D 1 , D2 , D3 ), differentia l

access to closed shops (CS), and for purchase in the

12 The evidence that is available suggests that th ecomposition of wealth is a significant determinant of saving(Pesaran and Evans, 1984 ; Venti and Wise, 1986 ; Hadjimatheaou ,1987) .

- 19 -

Page 27: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

underground economy (C2 /C) . We also distinguish betwee n

high-variance privately-earned income (YT) and low -

variance income from jobs in the public sector (YP) to allow

for different propensities to save out of permanent an d

transitory income .

Our main focus is whether marginal saving propensitie s

vary significantly and positively with the severity o f

quantity constraints . Table 5's specification allows bot h

intercept differences and interactions between quantit y

constraints and income . The D*Y interaction coefficient s

measure differences in the slope of the income-saving curve

(by YP and YT) among the three quantity-constraint groups .

The model specification also allows for interaction s

between quantity constraints and liquid and illiquid wealth .

Tests for interactions between closed shops (CS) an d

quantity constraints failed to yield significant interactio n

terms ; hence, these interactions were not included . Access

to closed shops was found to interact significantly with

income, and these interactions are reported in Table 5 .

Table 5 presents parameter estimates (t values i n

parentheses) and their standardized coefficients . The

unconventional saving model yields an MPS out of income o f

.19 (as compared to the conventional model's .33) . 13 Thi s

13 Income is not divided into private and public source sbecause the two coefficients are nearly identical . It is only i nthe interaction terms that differences between YT and YP can b efound .

- 2 0 -

Page 28: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 5Unconventional Saving Model Allowing For Quantity Constraint s

Estimation Technique : OLSDependent Variable :

Savings

Coefficient CoefficientVariables

Estimates B Variables Estimates B

Intercept

-29 .3 D 1 *YP .25 [ .39 ](1 .2) (11 .0 )

(Total Income )Y

.19 [ .34] D1 *YT .40 [ .25 ](12 .8) (12 .9 )

(Liquid Wealth )WL

.0009 [ .06] D1*WL - .00006 [ .00 ](2 .1) ( .1 )

(Illiquid Wealth )WI

.0007 [ .05] D1*WI - .002 [ .14 ](1 .5) (4 .4 )

(Household Size )H

-18 .2 [ .18] D2 *YP .10 [ .13 ](10 .0) (3 .8 )

(Age )AGE

3 .3 [ .34] D2 *YT .33 [ .08 ](3 .0) (4 .8 )

(Age-squared )AGE2

- .03 [ .30] D2 *WL .0006 [ .02 ](2 .6) ( .9 )

(Severely Quantity Constrained )D1

-84 .5

[ .30] D2 *WI - .003 [ .11 ](9 .0) (4 .0 )

(Moderately Quantity Constrained )D2

-30 .9

[ .09] CS*YP .16 [ .10 ](2 .9) (3 .0 )

(Underground Expenditure Ratio )C 2/C

-33 .6

[ .05] CS*YT .33 [ .06 ](2 .8) (3 .4 )

(Access to Closed Shops )CS

-63 .5 [ .10] CS*WL - .0005 [ .O1 ](3 .0) ( .7 )

CS*WI .001 [ .02 ](1 .2 )

R2 .4 3

*

: Interaction term s[ .] : Absolute values of standardized coefficient estimates (B) .( .) : Absolute values of t-statistics .

sourcessource s

YP

:YT

:Income from publicincome from private

Other variables are given in the table .

Page 29: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

MPS is to be interpreted as the marginal propensity to sav e

of households that are not quantity constrained . The

unconstrained MPS is close to the upper bound value ( .17 )

found by Ofer and Pickersgill (see Table 3), and it i s

similar to the lower bound value ( .21) found by Friedman

(1957) for U .S . "peacetime" cross-section data .

International comparisons (Table 3) show that th e

unconstrained Soviet MPS moves from the upper to the lowe r

range of marginal saving propensities estimated fro m

household data .

Table 5 reveals that household size, age, and liqui d

wealth effects are scarcely changed by the revise d

specification (although illiquid wealth become s

insignificant) . The standardized coefficients (in brackets )

emphasize the importance of life-cycle effects in explaining

Soviet household saving . Age effects are as prominent a s

income in accounting for variation in saving .

The introduction of quantity constraints raises th e

proportion of variance explained (R 2 rises by 20 percent

between Tables 2 and 5) . The D*Y parameters support the key

proposition of the quantity-constraint model : quantity

constrained households have higher MPSs than unconstraine d

households . Severely quantity constrained households ( D 1=1 )

have an MPS out of public-sector income (YP) 25 percentag e

points above and an MPS out of private income (YT) 4 0

percentage points higher than unconstrained households .

- 2 1 -

Page 30: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Households with moderate quantity constraints have MPSs 1 0

and 33 percentage points higher than unconstraine d

households for public-sector and private incomes ,

respectively .

Table 6 summarizes the marginal propensities an d

elasticities for different household types with respect t o

income and wealth . The MPS of unconstrained households o f

.19 (elasticity of 1 .25) is smaller than that o f moderately.

constrained households (MPS out of YP = .29, elasticity =

1 .77) . The MPS of severely constrained households is mor e

than double that of unconstrained households (MPS out of Y P

= .44, elasticity = 2 .24) . Table 6 also detects systematic

permanent income effects for constrained households . The

MPSs out of high-variance private income are uniforml y

higher than those out of low-variance public-secto r

earnings .

Soviet Interview Project households earn more than 9 0

percent of their income from jobs in the state sector ;

therefore, the MPS out of income from public jobs is th e

most relevant measure of marginal saving propensities . Th e

MPS of severely constrained households is .44 (more tha n

double that of unconstrained households) . Friedman's study

of U .S . marginal saving propensities during the Second Worl d

War (Friedman, 1957) provides a frame of reference due t o

the extensive rationing in effect at that time . It i s

noteworthy that the 44 percent Soviet MPS is virtually th e

- 2 2 -

Page 31: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Table 6

Marginal Propensities to Sav e[Income and Wealth Elasticities to Save ]

Variable

Household Type

No

SomeQuantity

QuantityConstraint

Constraint

SevereQuantityConstraint Privileged

(Total income )Y

.1 9[1 .25 ]

(Income from public sources )YP .29 .44 .3 5

[1 .77] [2 .76] [2 .24 ](income from private sources )YT

.52 .59 .5 2[1 .51] [1 .97] [1 .82 ]

(liquid wealth )WL

.0009 .001 .0008 .0004[ .09] [ .18] [ .10] [ .08 ]

(Illiquid wealth )WI

.0007 - .002 - .001 .001[ .08] [ .21] [ .12] [ .18]

[ .] : Elasticities measured at the means .

Page 32: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

I

same as Friedman's wartime cross-section MPS of 43 percent .

The closeness of the two MPS figures suggests that quantit y

constraints have similar effects even in quite differen t

institutional settings .

The D 1 intercept (Table 5) shows that being severely

quantity-constrained lowers household saving by a

substantial 85 rubles per month. Being moderatel y

constrained lowers household saving by 31 rubles per month .

It is unclear what these intercept shifts reflect -- tast e

differences, institutional effects, pension provisions, an d

so on . What they do show is that severely constraine d

households save less than unconstrained households at lo w

levels of income . As income rises, the higher MPS cause s

constrained households to increase their saving at a faste r

'rate than unconstrained households . When severely

constrained households earn the average income, their savin g

is slightly higher than unconstrained households also

earning average income . As their income rises above th e

average, severely-constrained households save much more tha n

unconstrained households earning the same income . The same

pattern holds for moderate quantity constraints . Moderatel y

constrained households save less at low levels of incom e

than their unconstrained counterparts ; they save more at

average income ; and much more at above average incomes .

The combination of negative intercept shifts and higher

MPSs dictates a distinctive pattern of average saving rate s

- 2 3 -

Page 33: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

for quantity-constrained households . At low incomes, thei r

saving rate is below unconstrained households ; at averag e

income, it is slightly above ; and at above average incomes ,

their saving rate is well above that of unconstraine d

households . The effect of quantity constraints on th e

average saving rates of Soviet households is most visible at

above average incomes. This pattern appears to make sense :

Quantity constraints should be most binding at high level s

of income. Quantity constraints are more likely to "force "

saving from high income families than from low incom e

families, and this is what our empirical results show .

International studies fail to yield substantial wealth

effects with respect to household saving, and the same i s

true for this study . The liquid wealth standardize d

coefficient is small for unconstrained families and th e

illiquid wealth coefficient is insignificant . However, for

constrained households, illiquid wealth yields statisticall y

significant but small effects on savings . Constrained

households with an extra 1,000 rubles of illiquid wealth

save 2 to 3 rubles less per month .

Soviet households that encounter shortages in officia l

markets do have the option of spilling over into private

markets characterized by higher market-clearing prices . The

fact that quantity constraints have such significant effect s

on Soviet household saving demonstrates that undergroun d

markets serve as an imperfect substitute for officia l

- 2 4 -

Page 34: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

markets . In fact, underground markets would not exist b y

definition if they were perfect substitutes .

Table 5 shows that the effect of underground purchase s

on Soviet household saving is relatively small, although i t

is statistically significant . The negative underground

expenditure share (C 2/C) coefficient shows that highe r

prices paid in underground markets depress household savin g

ceteris paribus . Table 4 showed that severely constraine d

households spent 18 percent of their budgets in th e

underground economy as compared with 8 percent for

unconstrained households . Applying these shares to the C 2/ C

coefficient (-33 .6) reveals that greater underground

purchases depress the saving of severely constraine d

households by approximately 3 rubles per month relative t o

unconstrained households . The small standardized C 2 /C

coefficient ( .05) confirms that the relatively slight effec t

of underground purchases on Soviet household saving .

Table 4 showed that a relatively small share of Soviet

Interview respondents had access to closed shops and tha t

this privilege was uniform across the three groups .

Surprisingly, access to closed shops did not preclud e

respondents from reporting severe quantity constraints .

Insofar as privilege would be expected to relax quantit y

constraints, the closed shop interaction with income shoul d

have a negative coefficient . Table 5, however, shows tha t

access to closed shops raises the MPS out of private an d

- 2 5 -

Page 35: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

public income . This perverse result can be interpreted i n

different ways . First, it may suggest that quantit y

constraints apply in closed shops as well as in officia l

outlets . A second interpretation is that respondents are

reporting a mixed bag of closed-shop privileges, rangin g

from access to factory supplies to being allowed to buy in

stores reserved only for the truly privileged . In other

words, the privilege measure is subject to serious '

measurement error . In any case, the previously reporte d

results are unchanged by the inclusion or exclusion of th e

closed shop variable, and the standardized coefficients show

that its relative effect is slight .

SUMMARY OF FINDINGS

This study uses a survey of former Soviet citizens (th e

Soviet Interview Project) to investigate household savin g

behavior in the Soviet Union . We combine objective data o n

income, consumption, and wealth with respondent perception s

of consumer market shortages to which they were subjected in

the Soviet Union . The latter information allows us t o

classify households as "severely" or "moderately" quantit y

constrained or as unconstrained in consumer markets . The

data set also allows us to study the effects of privileg e

and underground economy purchases on Soviet household savin g

behavior .

- 2 6 -

Page 36: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

We present relatively conclusive evidence to suppor t

the proposition that marginal saving rates are positivel y

related to the severity of quantity constraints . Soviet

households subject to severe quantity constraints hav e

marginal saving rates more than double those o f

unconstrained households . Surprisingly, the high margina l

saving rate of severely constrained Soviet households i s

very close to that of U .S . households during the rationing'

of World War II . As a consequence of including quantity

constraints, the unconstrained marginal saving rat e

(estimated from a conventional saving model) is reduced from

being relatively high by international standards to bein g

relatively low. We also find that Soviet households hav e

higher marginal saving rates out of high-variance privat e

income (in keeping with the permanent income hypothesis )

when quantity-constraint variables are included .

The effects of quantity constraints on marginal savin g

rates are most visible at above-average income levels . At

low levels of income, quantity-constrained households save

considerably less than their unconstrained counterparts . At

average income levels, they save slightly more . Only at

above average incomes, do the average saving rates o f

constrained Soviet households markedly exceed those o f

unconstrained households .

We find a relatively minor (although statisticall y

significant) effect of underground economy purchases o n

- 2 7 -

Page 37: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Soviet household saving . Quantity-constrained households d o

participate more in underground markets at relatively hig h

prices, as would be expected . Nevertheless, this differenc e

in underground market participation accounts for only a

small difference in saving between constrained and

unconstrained households .

With or without adjustment for quantity constraints ,

Soviet household saving behavior follows normal patterns '

with respect to life-cycle effects and household size .

Page 38: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

REFERENCES

Agarwala, R . and Drinkwater, J . "Consumption Function withShifting Parameters Due to Socio-Economic Factors . "Review of Economics and Statistics, LIV, (February1971) : 89-96 .

Anderson, B . and Silver, B . "The Validity of SurveyResponses From Interviews of Married Couples in aSurvey of Soviet Emigrants ." Social Forces, 65, 1987 .

Barro, R . J. and Grossman, H . I . "A General DisequilibriumModel of Income and Employment ." American EconomicReview 61 (1971) : 82-93 .

Bronson, D . W. and Severin, B . S . "Recent Trends i nConsumption and Disposable Money Income in th eU .S .S .R ." in U .S . Congress, Joint Economic Committee ,New Directions in the Soviet Economy Part II-B ,Washington, DC : U .S . Government Printing Office, 1966 .

and "Soviet Consumer Welfare :The Brezhnev Era" in U .S . Congress, Joint Economi cCommittee, Soviet Economic Prospects for the Seventie sWashington, DC : U .S . Government Printing Office, 1973 .

Bush, K. " Soviet Inflation" in Yves Laulan, ed ., Banking ,Money and Credit in Eastern Europe Brussels : NATO ,1973 .

Friedman, M . A Theory of the Consumption Function PrincetonUniversity Press, 1957 .

Gregory, P . R . "Productivity, Slack, and Time Theft in th eSoviet Economy ." in Politics, work and daily life inthe USSR : A survey of former Soviet citizens, edited byJ . R . Millar, Cambridge : Cambridge University Press ,1987 .

Gregory, P . R . and Collier Jr ., I . L . "Unemployment in th eSoviet Union : Evidence From the Soviet InterviewProject ." American Economic Review, forthcoming ,(1988) .

Gregory, P . R. and Kohlhase, J. "The Earnings of SovietWorkers : Human Capital, Loyalty, and Privilege ." Reviewof Economics and Statistics, forthcoming, (1988) .

Hadjimatheou, G . Consumer Economics After Keynes : Theory andEvidence of the Consumption Function, New York : St ,Martin's Press, 1987 .

- 2 9 -

Page 39: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Hall, R . E . and Mishkin, F . S . "The Sensitivity o fConsumption to Transitory Income : Estimates From Pane lData on Households ." Econometrica 50 (March 1982) :461-81 .

Hendry, D. F . "Econometric Modelling with Cointegrate dVariables'"

Oxford Bulletin of Economics andStatistics 48 (1986) : 201-212 .

Howard, D . H . "Rationing, Quantity Constraints, andConsumption Theory ." Econometrica 45, (March 1977) :399-412 .

Husby, R . D . "A Nonlinear Consumption Function Estimate dFrom Time-Series and Cross-Section Data ." Review ofEconomics And Statistics LIII (February 1971) : 76- 9

Katona, G., Strumpel, B. and Zahn, E . "Aspirations andAffluence : Comparative Studies in the United States andWestern Europe . New York : McGraw-Hill, 1971 .

Kornai, J . Economics of Shortage . Amsterdam : North-Holland ,1980 .

Kornai, J . Growth, Shortage and Efficiency : Yrjo JahnssonLectures . Oxford/Berkeley, and Los Angeles : BasilBlackwell/University of California Press, 1982 .

Kornai, J . "Comment ." In Frontiers of Economics, edited byK . J . Arrow and S . Honkapohja . Oxford : Basil Blackwell ,1985 .

Laffont, J . J . "Fix-Price Models : a Survey of RecentEmpirical Work." (with comments) In Frontiers o fEconomics, edited by K . J . Arrow and S . Honkapohja .Oxford : Basil Blackwell, 1985 .

Liviatan, N . "Tests of the Permanent-Income Hypothesis Base don a Reinterview Savings Survey ." in Measurement i nEconomics : Studies in Mathematical Economics andEconometrics in Memory of Yehuda Grunfeld, edited by C .Christ, Stanford : Stanford University Press, 1963 .

Maddala, G . S . Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variablesin Econometrics, New York : Cambridge University Press ,1983 .

Malinvaud, E . The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered, Basi lBlackwell, Oxford, 1977 .

Mayer, T ., Permanent Income, Wealth and Consumption ,Berkeley : University of California Press, 1972a .

- 3 0 -

Page 40: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Mayer, T . "Tests of the Permanent Income Theory withContinuous Budgets ." J . of Money, Credit, and Banking ,IV, (November 1972b) : 757-778 .

Millar, J . R . "History, Method, and the Problem of Bias ." inPolitics, work and daily life in the USSR : A survey o fformer Soviet citizens, edited by J . R. Millar ,Cambridge : Cambridge University Press, 1987 .

Millar, J . R. and Pickersgill, J ."Aggregate EconomicProblems in Soviet-Type Economies ." ACES Bulletin, XIX ,(Spring 1977) .

Modigiliani, F . "The Life Cycle Hypothesis of Saving TwentyYears Later." in Contemporary Issues inEconomics,edited by M . Parkin and A . R . Nobay, Manchester :Manchester University Press 1975 .

Mokhtari, M . "International Evidence on the Random Walk andError Correction Models of Consumers' Expenditure "Unpublished, University of Houston, 1988 .

Moulaert, F. and Canniere, L . D. "Income Inequality andConsumptive Spending Behavior : Empirical Evidence Fromthe 1978-79 Household Budget Survey in Belgium ." J . ofPost Keynesian Economics, X, (Winter 1987-88) : 225-249 .

Muellbauer, J . and Portes, R . "Macroeconomic Models withQuantity Rationing ." Economic Journal, 88 (1978) : 788 -821 .

Nelson, R . and Plosser, C . I . "Trends and Random Walks i nMacroeconomic Time Series : Some Evidence an dImplications ." J . of Monetary Economics, 10, (1982) :139-62 .

O'er, G . and Pickersgill, J . "Soviet Household Saving : ACross-Section Study of Soviet Emigrant Families, "Quarterly Journal of Economics, XCV, (August 1980) :121-44 .

Parry, R . "Separation of Normal and Transitory Components o fIncome From Cross-Section Data ." Unpublished Ph . D .dissertation, University of Pennsylvania, 1967 .

Peseran, M . H . and Evans, R . A . "Inflation Capital gains andUK Personal Savings : 1953-81 ." Economic Journal, (June1984) : 237-57 .

Phillips, P . C . B . and Durlauf, S . N . "Multiple Time SeriesRegression With Integrated Processes ." Review o fEconomic Studies, LIII, (1986) : 473-95 .

- 3 1 -

Page 41: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Pickersgill, J . "Soviet Household Saving Behavior ." Reviewof Economics and Statistics, LVIII, (May 1976) : 139-47 .

Pickersgill, J . "Soviet Inflation : Causes and Consequences, "Soviet Union, IV, 1977 .

Podkaminer, L . "Estimates of the Disequilibrium in Poland' sConsumer Markets 1965-1978," Review of Economics andStatistics, 64, (1982) : 423-32 .

Portes, R . "Macroeconomic Equilibrium and Disequilibrium i nCentrally Planned Economies : A Model for Empirica lImplementation ." Discussion Paper in Economics No . 45 ,Birkbeck College, University of london, 1976 .

Portes, R . "The Theory and Measurement of Macroeconomi cDisequilibrium in Centrally Planned Economies ." CEPRDiscussion Paper No . 91, London, (January 1986) .

Portes, R . and Winter, D . "The Supply of Consumption Good sin Centrally Planned Economies ." Journal of ComparativeEconomics, 1, (1977) : 351-365 .

Portes, R. and Winter, D . "The Demand for Money and fo rConsumption Goods in Centrally Planned Economies, "Review of Economics and Statistics, 60 (February 1978) :8-18 .

Portes, R. and Winter, R . "Disequilibrium Estimates fo rConsumption Goods Markets in Centrally Planne dEconomies ." Review of Economic Studies, XLVII, (1980) :137-159 .

Portes, R ., Quandt, R . E . and Yeo, S . "Tests of the Chroni cShortage Hypothesis : The Case of Poland ." Review o fEconomics and Statistics, LXX, (May 1988) : 288-9 5

Quandt, R . E . "Tests of Equilibrium vs . DisequilibriumHypothesis," International Economic Review, 19, (1978) :435-452 .

Quandt, R . E . "Econometric Disequilibrium Models, "Econometric Review, 1, (1982) : 1-63 .

Ramanathan, R . "Estimating the Permanent Income of aHousehold : An Application to Indian Data ." Review o fEconomics and Statistics, L, (August 1968) : 383-8 .

- 3 2 -

Page 42: Soviet Household Saving Under Quantity Constraints ... · "shortage equilibrium" (Kornai 1985, p.381) . Barro and Grossman (1971) focused attention on the effects of quantity constraints

Sadan, E . and Tropp, Z . "Consumption Function Analysis in aCommunal Household : Cross Section and Time Series . "Review of Economics and Statistics, LV, (1973) : 475 -481 .

Schroeder, G . "Consumer Goods Availability and RepressedInflation in the Soviet Union ." in Economic Aspects o fLife in the USSR, Brussels : NATO, 1975 .

Swafford, M ., Zeiss, C . A ., Breda, C . S ., Bullock, B . P ."Response Effects in SIP's General Survey of Sovie tEmigrants ." Soviet Interview Project Working Paper ,1987 .

Thomas, R . L . Introductory Econometrics : Theory andApplications, New York : Longman Inc, 1985 .

Venti, S . F . and Wise, D. A. "Tax-Deferred Accounts ,Constrained Choice and Estimation of Individua lSaving ." Review of Economics Studies, LIII, (1986) :579-601 .

Vinokur, A . and Ofer, G . "Inequality of Earnings, Househol dIncome and Wealth in the Soviet Union in the 70's," i nPolitics, work and daily life in the USSR : A survey o fformer Soviet citizens, edited by J . R. Millar ,Cambridge : Cambridge University Press, 1987 .