SGM Case Analysis HSC

6
Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A) Jon Bain-Chekal 1 Introduction: The worldwide aspartame market has enjoyed patent protected financial prosperity since the early 1980’s. In 1986 the world demand for aspartame was 5,730 tons annually with future projected world demand reaching 10,000 tons annually, a 75% increase over 1986 demand. The Monsanto Corporation, the current owner of the rights to manufacture aspartame, under the brand name NutraSweet (NS), reported 1986 sales of $711 million. The estimated ROA was approximately 8%. 1 With this being such an attractive industry, companies like Holland Sweetener Company (HSC) needed to determine whether or not to compete in the aspartame business. This paper will first analyze NS’s case for accommodating or deterring entry before turning to a discussion as to which strategy NS will actually choose. Given the above analysis the paper will briefly address what Holland Sweetener Company’s entry strategy should be. There are several industry factors that will affect how this game is played. First, the two versions of aspartame, as produced by HSC and NS, are relatively identical goods. This leaves the consumer indifferent to product attributes and only concerned with price. It is also assumed that geography is not a real strategic factor since shipping costs are so low. The shipping costs for a pound of aspartame average 15-20 cents. 2 Compared to the 1986 market price of $70 per pound shipping costs only account for 0.002% of the market price, hardly a significant factor of concern even given NS’s large volume. Lesson 1 of game theory suggests, “you must [first] understand the payoffs and objectives of the other parties you are interacting with.” 3 Therefore the next two sections explore NS’s potential objectives regarding competitor entry strategy. Thinking Ahead Reasoning backwards: Reasons for Accommodation It may seem counter intuitive why a monopolist would even consider accommodating a potential entrant into the market. Each entrant reduces market share and most commonly profits. Yet there are several important factors why NurtraSweet should seriously consider accommodating the entry of HSC. This is not a one shot game. It is a complex multi-period game with an unknown amount of potential players. Let’s assume for a minute that NS is able to induce HSC to exit with a price war. This strategy would be appealing as long as HSC was the only player. Since it is not, the game would not end. As long as the market is sufficiently attractive to entry there will be new potential entrants waiting to follow in HSC’s footsteps. If this is in fact the case, it is better for NS to accommodate one or two small 1 ROA=income/assets; 142/1883=8% 2 HBS case, Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetener Company Versus NutraSweet (A) 9-794-079, pg 3 3 Meaghan Busse, Lecture 9 & 10 Game Theory

Transcript of SGM Case Analysis HSC

Page 1: SGM Case Analysis HSC

Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A)Jon Bain-Chekal

1

Introduction:The worldwide aspartame market has enjoyed patent protected financial

prosperity since the early 1980’s. In 1986 the world demand for aspartame was 5,730

tons annually with future projected world demand reaching 10,000 tons annually, a 75%

increase over 1986 demand. The Monsanto Corporation, the current owner of the rights

to manufacture aspartame, under the brand name NutraSweet (NS), reported 1986 sales

of $711 million. The estimated ROA was approximately 8%.1 With this being such an

attractive industry, companies like Holland Sweetener Company (HSC) needed to

determine whether or not to compete in the aspartame business. This paper will first

analyze NS’s case for accommodating or deterring entry before turning to a discussion as

to which strategy NS will actually choose. Given the above analysis the paper will

briefly address what Holland Sweetener Company’s entry strategy should be.

There are several industry factors that will affect how this game is played. First,

the two versions of aspartame, as produced by HSC and NS, are relatively identical

goods. This leaves the consumer indifferent to product attributes and only concerned

with price. It is also assumed that geography is not a real strategic factor since shipping

costs are so low. The shipping costs for a pound of aspartame average 15-20 cents.2

Compared to the 1986 market price of $70 per pound shipping costs only account for

0.002% of the market price, hardly a significant factor of concern even given NS’s large

volume.

Lesson 1 of game theory suggests, “you must [first] understand the payoffs and

objectives of the other parties you are interacting with.”3 Therefore the next two sections

explore NS’s potential objectives regarding competitor entry strategy.

Thinking Ahead Reasoning backwards: Reasons for Accommodation

It may seem counter intuitive why a monopolist would even consider

accommodating a potential entrant into the market. Each entrant reduces market share

and most commonly profits. Yet there are several important factors why NurtraSweet

should seriously consider accommodating the entry of HSC.

This is not a one shot game. It is a complex multi-period game with an unknown

amount of potential players. Let’s assume for a minute that NS is able to induce HSC to

exit with a price war. This strategy would be appealing as long as HSC was the only

player. Since it is not, the game would not end. As long as the market is sufficiently

attractive to entry there will be new potential entrants waiting to follow in HSC’s

footsteps. If this is in fact the case, it is better for NS to accommodate one or two small 1 ROA=income/assets; 142/1883=8%2 HBS case, Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetener Company Versus NutraSweet (A) 9-794-079, pg 33 Meaghan Busse, Lecture 9 & 10 Game Theory

Page 2: SGM Case Analysis HSC

Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A)Jon Bain-Chekal

2

entrants otherwise it will risk expending resources (i.e. forgone profits in a price war) to

deter Holland Sweetener only to have a second company challenge NS. If there is

enough potential entrants, this scenario could play out for years eventually depleting

NutraSweet’s strength as well as eating up all future profits. There are several large food

and chemical companies in the world that could relatively easily decide to move into the

aspartame business consequently ensuring the plausibility of the above scenario.

NS may consider utilizing its customer contractual relationships to segment the

aspartame market. Considering that 80% of NS’s business is the diet soft drink market

and many of these customers are committed to long-term contracts, NS may be able to

capture the most lucrative and strategic customers for itself while leaving a small fringe

market to HSC. Relegating new entrants to pick up the scraps at the low end may be a

safe compromise to a price war. Currently NS has 20% more capacity than world

demand. Holland Sweetener is only considering adding 500 annual tons to the market or

approximately 7% (assuming they are able to produce at capacity). Giving up the less

lucrative part of the market may have other benefits as well. NS may be able to use HSC

as a strategic compliment because HSC, as a new entrant, will find the fringe market

appealing given its size and situation. So HSC will enter, but once it has entered it has an

incentive to deter other small potential entrants. By letting in one or two low-end players

the dynamics of the game change from dominant vs. fringe, to fringe vs. fringe. In this

game the price war does not affect the whole market, it only affects the smaller markets

of tabletop and food products, and HSC carries the cost burden of the price war. As I

mentioned in the introduction, I am assuming that the two versions of aspartame are

identical products. Instead this argument manipulates the rules of the game via quantity,

contracts, and size. The other way to try and differentiate a product, other than through

product attributes, is with a strong brand.

While NS has established a great brand, the actual value of that brand is in

question. NS scores high in market research tests on recognition, but does that actually

equate to high loyalty? For example aspartame’s largest market, diet soft drinks, the

consumer’s decision to buy is driven more by the downstream brand names like Diet

Coke and Diet Pepsi rather than product ingredients. As the Classic Coke debacle taught

us, consumers are driven to purchase soft drink products as a statement of

personality/identity or out of nostalgia rather than for product attributes like taste or

sweetness.4 Consequently while NutraSweet is a well known brand it does not engender

customer loyalty when faced with a comparable product. Consequently NS’s brand does

not afford them any significant advantages, especially in a price war game.

4 HBS case, Introducing New Coke, 9-500-067

Page 3: SGM Case Analysis HSC

Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A)Jon Bain-Chekal

3

NutraSweet is quickly nearing the end of its product life cycle. There are two

significant product weaknesses the company must contend with: NS has a relatively short

shelf life in soft drinks and it is unstable when exposed to high temperatures. These

weaknesses leave aspartame susceptible to product substitutes like Hoechst’s

Acesulfame-K, which is heat stable and shelf stable or Pfizer’s new Alitame which is

heat stable and 2,000 times sweeter than sugar5. Hoechst’s Acesulfame-K is currently

sold in Europe. Pfizer applied for FDA approval in 1986 meaning that Alitame could be

approved for use as early as 1995. Both of these product’s potential entry into the US

market shortens NS’s window to regain profits after a price war. Not entering into a

price war and instead directing profits toward increased R&D would better serve NS.

There is also great uncertainty as to the industry cost structure. HSC claims that

its patented natural catalyst process would be less costly and more flexible than

NutraSweet’s6. NutraSweet is claiming that it has been able to cut its manufacturing

costs by 70% over the previous decade. As long as HSC’s pronouncement is sufficiently

credible, NS would want to adopt an accommodating strategy until the cost uncertainties

could be resolved.

Finally, the often-overlooked non-market strategy issues must be factored into NS

decision process. The threat of antitrust laws is an important reason for NutraSweet to

consider an accommodating strategy. NS does not want to find itself in a protracted and

costly legal battle. Allowing HSC to enter may provide sufficient evidence to prevent NS

from violating anti-trust law. Even though Holland is considering entering the European

and Canadian markets US trust law applies outside of the US if the companies are seen as

harming US consumers.7 NS would consider this only to preempt a potential entrant

from gaining bargaining power via the court system.

Is the future too soon? Reasons to deter

Theoretically a firm wants to deter entry if it believes that the NPV of future cash

flows will exceed the present cost of deterring entry. As mentioned above though

entering into a price war to deter entry is not necessarily a profit maximizing decision, yet

there are other important considerations that affect the revenue stream.

If NS expects a series of entrants vying for the aspartame market, it may want to

incur the cost of a price war with HSC to develop a reputation as a fierce competitor.

This reputation will hopefully forestall the consideration of other entrants thereby

allowing Monsanto to recoup lost profits after HSC exits.

5 HBS Case, Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetener Company Versus NutraSweet (A) 9-794-0796 HBS Case, Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetener Company Versus NutraSweet (A) 9-794-0797 Meaghan Busse, Lecture 6 Antitrust

Page 4: SGM Case Analysis HSC

Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A)Jon Bain-Chekal

4

If HSC is allowed to enter the European and Canadian market, NS runs the risk

that HSC will grow and move up the learning curve. This could inadvertently increase

HSC’s ability to threaten NS in 1992 in the US market after the expiration of the patent.

NS may prefer to have HSC sitting on the sidelines for several years, missing out on any

production or marketing learning opportunities in order to retain NS’s knowledge

advantage when their prime market opens up in 1992.

HSC will increase buyer power. The largest aspartame customer, the diet soft

drink market which accounts for 80% of all sales, would be able to split its contracts

between the two manufacturers encouraging them to provide more favorable terms.

In the previous section I argued that the players costs structures are uncertain, yet

NS does have an advantage over HSC in size and experience. NS will have better

economies of scale, thereby being able to shift more fixed costs across all sales. The fact

that they have been in business for several years and have a culture focused on process

improvements means NS is further down the learning curve in the production of

aspartame. These two factors do not remove the uncertainty of the cost structures, but

they do give NS the upper hand. Depending on the company’s tolerance for risk this may

or may not be enough to convince them to enter into a price war.

Finally the historical entry and exit trends of the market are worth considering.

Relative to other industries the chemical and food processing industries have little entry.8

This trend reduces the threat of other potential players entering the game and raises the

effectiveness of a price war.

NutraSweet’s move

Given the above analysis of NurtraSweets potential options and interests HSC can be

relatively confident that NS will accommodate their entry. The key compelling factors

driving NS decision are: a) a homogenous product, b) with a short life-cycle due to

pending entry of new superior products, therefore insufficient time to recoup profits lost

in a price war, c) an uncertain cost structure comparison, d) a brand with high

recognition, but low loyalty, e) the looming threat of antitrust laws, f) the first mover

advantage.

Here is how the game will most likely play out. Figure 1 depicts a game tree in

which NurtraSweet’s strategic choices are to charge monopoly pricing or to use a price

limiting strategy to try and prevent HSC from even entering the market (for the purpose

of this paper I am going adopt Besanko’s argument that price limiting as a strategy is

flawed because it is not subgame perfect and therefore I will prune that option and

8 Besanko, Economics of Strategy, second edition, John Wiley & Sons, NY 2000, pg 328.

Page 5: SGM Case Analysis HSC

Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A)Jon Bain-Chekal

5

continue with the example).9 Knowing that the current monopoly pricing is $70 per

pound, it is within reason to assume for the purposes of this example that the Stackelberg

price will be $60 and the Cournot duopoly price will be $50 per pound. Because the

European and Canadian markets are at a monopoly quantity, I am assuming that actual

demand is 10% higher (i.e. it will increase from 550 tons per year to 605 tons per year).

Table 1 summarizes useful sales and pricing information for this situation. Using the

fold-back method we start from the end of the tree and work backwards. In this case

HSC will clearly choose to enter because it will make $20 million vs. making $0 by not

entering. If HSC enters NutraSweet will price accommodate because $60 million is

optimal over $33 million estimated in the price war. For this case I reasoned that the

price accommodation would take the form of a Stackelberg game where the dominant

firm derives quantity based on the residual demand curve. The subgame perfect Nash

equilibrium is depicted by the bolded lines.

While the actual payoffs may vary, it is a plausible scenario which will help

predict NutraSweet’s strategy and subsequent moves. NutraSweet should accommodate

entry because of growing demand and the looming threat of technologically superior

substitutes for aspartame. Given these facts, entry is too attractive to potential entrants.

Even if there is only one entrant to this market, NS should not waste resources trying to

deter it, given the introduction of new and superior products.

HSC puppy dog ploy:

Knowing what NurtraSweet will do, HSC should use NS’s large size to its

advantage. HSC should focus on signaling to NS that it is not a large threat to

profitability. At least not as large a threat to profitability as a price war would be. In the

above example HSC would earn $20 million in sales or only 3% of NS’s worldwide

sales. It will then depend on the true cost structures of the firms and the relevant

minimum efficient scales (MES). If HSC’s improved production process has a MES at or

near 500 tons per year HSC can stay small. If in fact the MES is closer to NS’s 2000

tons, HSC will have to grow or it will go out of business.

So let the games begin!

9 Besanko, Economics of Strategy, second edition, John Wiley & Sons, NY 2000, pg 341.

Page 6: SGM Case Analysis HSC

Bitter Competition: The Holland Sweetner Company vs. NutraSweet (A)Jon Bain-Chekal

6

Figure 1 Game Tree Form for HSC Entry

Table 1 Price and Profit Under Different Competitive ConditionsMarket Structure NS % of

MarketPrice NS Annual

Profit(millions)

HSC AnnualProfit

(millions)Monopoly 100% $70 $85 $0Cournot Duopoly—pricewar scenario

50% $50 $33 $33

Stackelberg—dominantfringe accommodatingscenerio

75% $60 $60 $20

It is assumed that the current sales in Europe and Canada do not reflect market demand due to the currentmarket structure being a monopoly which lowers the quantity below the socially optimal demanded.Therefore a conservative estimate of a 10% increase in total sales in Europe and Canada is assumed (i.e.demand will increase from 550 to 605 annual tons of aspartame).

INCUMBENT: NutraSweet

PmonopolyPlimit

PaccomodatePwar

ENTRANT: HSC

INCUMBENT: NutraSweet

IN OUT

NS: 85 millionHSC: 0

NS: 60 millionHSC: 20 million

NS: 33millionHSC: 33million

Please note that the conceptual theory of this argument was adapted from Besanko et.al, Economics of Strategy, secondedition, John Wiley & Sons, NY, 2000.