Self‐Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on ...ftp.iza.org/dp9434.pdf · positive or...

46
Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES Self‐Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance in Observable and Unobservable Characteristics IZA DP No. 9434 October 2015 George J. Borjas Ilpo Kauppinen Panu Poutvaara

Transcript of Self‐Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on ...ftp.iza.org/dp9434.pdf · positive or...

  • Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der ArbeitInstitute for the Study of Labor

    DI

    SC

    US

    SI

    ON

    P

    AP

    ER

    S

    ER

    IE

    S

    Self‐Selection of Emigrants:Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance inObservable and Unobservable Characteristics

    IZA DP No. 9434

    October 2015

    George J. BorjasIlpo KauppinenPanu Poutvaara

  • Self‐Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance in

    Observable and Unobservable Characteristics

    George J. Borjas Harvard Kennedy School, NBER and IZA

    Ilpo Kauppinen

    VATT Institute for Economic Research

    Panu Poutvaara University of Munich, Ifo Institute, CESifo, CReAM and IZA

    Discussion Paper No. 9434 October 2015

    IZA

    P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn

    Germany

    Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180

    E-mail: [email protected]

    Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of IZA. Research published in this series may include views on policy, but the institute itself takes no institutional policy positions. The IZA research network is committed to the IZA Guiding Principles of Research Integrity. The Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) in Bonn is a local and virtual international research center and a place of communication between science, politics and business. IZA is an independent nonprofit organization supported by Deutsche Post Foundation. The center is associated with the University of Bonn and offers a stimulating research environment through its international network, workshops and conferences, data service, project support, research visits and doctoral program. IZA engages in (i) original and internationally competitive research in all fields of labor economics, (ii) development of policy concepts, and (iii) dissemination of research results and concepts to the interested public. IZA Discussion Papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the author.

  • IZA Discussion Paper No. 9434 October 2015

    ABSTRACT

    Self‐Selection of Emigrants: Theory and Evidence on Stochastic Dominance in Observable and Unobservable Characteristics*

    We show that the Roy model has more precise predictions about the self‐selection of migrants than previously realized. The same conditions that have been shown to result in positive or negative selection in terms of expected earnings also imply a stochastic dominance relationship between the earnings distributions of migrants and non-migrants. We use the Danish full population administrative data to test the predictions. We find strong evidence of positive self‐selection of emigrants in terms of pre-emigration earnings: the income distribution for the migrants almost stochastically dominates the distribution for the non‐migrants. This result is not driven by immigration policies in destination countries. Decomposing the self‐selection in total earnings into self‐selection in observable characteristics and self‐selection in unobservable characteristics reveals that unobserved abilities play the dominant role.

    NON-TECHNICAL SUMMARY We examine the self-selection of emigrants from Denmark, one of the richest and most redistributive European welfare states. We find strong evidence of positive self-selection of emigrants in terms of pre-emigration earnings, education and unobservable abilities. Differences in age and education can explain less than half of earnings differences between migrants and non-migrants. Strong positive self-selection of emigrants is not driven by immigration policies in destination countries. Self-selection of emigrants to other Nordic countries, which are rather similar to Denmark in having a relatively egalitarian income distribution and a generous welfare state, is also positive, but not as strong as self-selection to other EU countries, or the rest of the world. JEL Classification: F22, J61 Keywords: international migration, Roy model, self-selection Corresponding author: Panu Poutvaara Ifo Institute Poschingerstr. 5 81679 Munich Germany E-mail: [email protected]

    * We thank participants at Norface Migration Network Conference, Journées Louis‐André Gérard‐Varet, EEA and CEMIR Junior Economist Workshop in 2013, the Alpine Population Conference, UCFS Workshop, CESifo ESP area conference and VfS annual conference in 2015 and seminars at UC Irvine, ETH Zurich, Labour Institute for Economic Research, VATT, University of Linz, and University of Salzburg for valuable comments. Financial support from Leibniz Association (SAW‐2012‐ifo‐3) is gratefully acknowledged.

  • 2

    1.IntroductionAcentralfindingintheeconomicliteratureoninternationalmigrationisthatemigrantsarenotrandomlyselectedfromthepopulationofthesourcecountries.Thenatureofthenon‐randomselectionaffectsthelevelandthedistributionofwelfarethroughtwomajorchannels.First,theskilldistributionofmigrantsaffectsthewagestructureinbothsendingandreceivingcountries(Borjas2003).Asecondeffecttakesplacethroughthepublicsector.Immigrationcreatesafiscalsurplusinthereceivingcountryifandonlyifthenetpresentvalueofthetaxpaymentsofimmigrantsexceedsthenetpresentvalueofthecoststheyimpose.Boththeimmigrationofnetrecipientsandtheemigra‐tionofnetpayersposeachallengetothepublictreasury(Wildasin1991;Sinn1997).BeginningwithBorjas(1987),therehasbeenagreatdealofinterestinderivingandempiricallytestingmodelsthatpredicthowmigrantsdifferfromnon‐migrants.ManyofthesestudiesrelyonanapplicationoftheRoymodelofoccupationalself‐selection.Aslongasskillsaresufficientlytransferableacrosscountries,thesortingofpersonsacrosscountriesismainlydeterminedbyinternationaldifferencesintherateofreturntoskills.AcountryliketheUnitedStateswouldthenattracthigh‐skilledworkersfrommoreegalitariancountries(i.e.,countriesofferingrelativelylowratesofreturntoskills)andlow‐skilledworkersfromcountrieswithgreaterincomeinequality(i.e.,countriesoffer‐inghigherratesofreturntoskills).Theevidenceindeedsuggestsanegativecross‐sectioncorrelationbetweentheearningsofimmigrantsintheUnitedStatesandincomeinequalityinthesourcecountries.1AlthoughtheexistingliteratureonimmigrantselectionfocusesmainlyontheU.S.con‐textoronmigrationflowsfrompoortorichcountries,therearealsosizablemigrationflowsbetweenrichcountries.AccordingtotheUnitedNations(2013),21.9millionper‐sonsfromEU15countriesnowliveoutsidetheirbirthplace,with42percentofthesemigrantslivinginotherEU15countriesandanadditional13percentlivingintheUnit‐edStates.2Thispaperexaminestheself‐selectionofemigrantsfromDenmark,oneoftherichestandmostredistributiveEuropeanwelfarestates.In2013,overaquartermillionDaneslivedoutsideDenmark(correspondingtoabout5percentoftheDanish‐bornpopula‐tion),with50percentofthemigrantslivinginotherEU15countriesand13percentintheUnitedStates(UnitedNations,DepartmentofEconomicandSocialAffairs2013).BecausethereturnstoskillsinDenmarkarerelativelylow,thecanonicalRoymodelpredictsthattheemigrantsshouldbepositivelyselectedinthesensethattheexpectedearningsofthemigrantsexceedtheexpectedearningsofthestayers.3However,there1Relatedcross‐countrystudiesincludeCobb‐Clark(1993)andBratsberg(1995).GroggerandHanson(2011)examinetheselectionofmigrantsacrossabroadrangeofcountriesusinganalternativetheoreti‐calframeworkwhereindividualsmaximizelinearutilityandmigrationisdrivenbyabsoluteearningsdifferencesbetweenhighandlow‐skilledworkers.2TheEU15countriesrefertothememberstatesoftheEuropeanUnionpriortotheexpansiononMay1,2004.3ForcomparisonsofgrosswagepremiafromtertiaryeducationacrosscountriesseeBoariniandStraus(2010).ArecentpaperstudyingreturnstocognitiveskillsisHanusheketal.(2015).Thestudyfindssig‐nificantcross‐countrydifferences.Moreover,thereturnsarerelativelylowinDenmarkaswellasinother

  • 3

    havebeenfewsystematicstudiesoftheself‐selectionofmigrantsfromarelativelyegal‐itariancountrytoseewhetherthisisindeedthecase.4Ourtheoreticalanalysisshowsthatthecanonicalframeworkdoesnotonlyhavepredic‐tionsaboutthedifferencebetweentheexpectedearningsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants,whichisthebasisforthestandarddefinitionofpositiveornegativeselectioninthelit‐erature,butalsoaboutthestochasticorderingofthetwoearningsdistributions.Weshowthatthesameconditionsthatpredictthatmigrantsarepositivelyself‐selectedinthesenseofadifferenceinexpectedincomesalsopredictthattheincomedistributionofthemigrantswillfirst‐orderstochasticallydominatetheincomedistributionofthenon‐migrants.Thetheoryalsodistinguishesbetweenselectioninobservableandselec‐tioninunobservablecharacteristics.OurempiricalanalysisusestheDanishfullpopulationadministrativedatatoanalyzehowmigrantsandnon‐migrantsdifferintheirpre‐emigrationearningsandotherob‐servablecharacteristics.Toshedlightontheroleofunobservablecharacteristicsintheselectionprocess,weinvestigatehowmigrantsandnon‐migrantsdifferintermsofun‐observableearningsability,asmeasuredbyresidualsfromMincerianearningsregres‐sions.Ourempiricalresultsareinlinewiththepredictionsofthemodel:Danishemi‐grantsareindeedpositivelyself‐selectedbothintermsofearningsandintermsofre‐sidualsfromthewageregressions.FollowingourreframingofthecanonicalRoyframeworkintermsoftheconceptofstochasticdominance,ourstudyspecificallytestsforwhethertheearningsdistributionoftheemigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofthestayers(aswouldbepredictedbythemodel).Theevidenceconfirmsthisstrongtheoreticalpredictionovermostofthesupportoftheearningsdistribution.OurstudyisrelatedtotheflurryofrecentpapersthatexaminetheselectionofmigrantsfromMexicototheUnitedStates.ThepioneeringanalysisofChiquiarandHanson(2005)mergedinformationfromtheU.S.censusonthecharacteristicsoftheMexicanmigrantswithinformationfromtheMexicancensusonthecharacteristicsoftheMexi‐cannon‐migrants.Becausethemergeddatadidnotreporttheearningsofmigrantspri‐ortothemove,pre‐migrationearningswerepredictedbasedonobservablecharacteris‐ticsofthemigrants.This“counterfactual”empiricalexercisesuggestedthatMexicanemigrantswerelocatedinthemedium‐highrangeoftheMexicanwagedistribution.ThefindingofintermediateselectionintheMexicancontextdoesnotseemconsistentwiththebasicimplicationsoftheRoymodelbecausetherateofreturntoskillsisfarlargerinMexicothanintheUnitedStates.MorerecentstudiesbyFernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)andKaestnerandMalamud(2014)usesurveydatathatreporttheactualpre‐migrationearningsandfindevidenceofnegativeselection.Theyalsoconcludethatpartofthenegativeselectioncanbetracedtotheunobservablecharacteristicsthatdeter‐mineamigrant’searnings.Nordiccountries,andhighintheUnitedStates,GermanyandtheUnitedKingdom,whichalsoareamongthemostpopulardestinationsofDanishmigrants.4StudiesoftheselectionofmigrantsacrossdevelopedcountriesincludeLundborg(1991),Pirttilä(2004),Klevenetal.(2014),andJungeetal.(2014).Manystudiesalsoexamineselectionissuesinahistoricalcontext;seeWegge(1999,2002),AbramitzkyandBraggion(2006),Abramitzky,Boustan,andEriksson(2012),Ferrie(1996),andMargo(1990).

  • 4

    Theimportantroleplayedbyunobservablecharacteristicsimpliesthatconstructingacounterfactualearningsdistributionforthemigrantsbasedonobservablecharacteris‐ticscangreatlybiasthenatureoftheselectionrevealedbythedata.Ourfindingssug‐gestthattheuseofsuchacounterfactualdistributionwilltendtounderstatethetrueselectioninearnings,sothattheselectionimpliedbythecounterfactualdistributionisfarweakerthanthetrueselection—regardlessofwhetherthereispositiveornegativeselection.ThenumericalbiasthatresultsfromusingthecounterfactualestimationissizableintheDanishcontext:morethanhalfofthedifferencebetweentheexpectedearningsofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsarisesbecauseofdifferencesinunobservedcharacteristics.Thepaperisorganizedasfollows.Section2sketchestheeconomictheoryunderlyingtheanalysisandderivestheoreticalpredictionsconcerningtheself‐selectionofemi‐grants,usingthenotionofstochasticdominanceasaunifyingconcept.Section3intro‐ducesanddescribestheuniquepopulationdatathatweuseandreportssomesummarystatistics.Sections4and5presentthemainempiricalfindings.Insection4,weexaminetheselectionintermsofobservedpre‐migrationearnings.Wepresentastatisticalmethodfortestingthetheoreticalimplicationthattheearningsdistributionoftheemi‐grantsshouldstochasticallydominatethecorrespondingdistributionofthenon‐migrants.Section5extendstheempiricalworkbyexaminingtheselectionthatoccursintheunobservedcomponentofearnings.Section6evaluatesthebiasthatresultsfrompredictingthepre‐migrationearningsofemigrantsfromtheearningsdistributionofnon‐migrants.Section7examineswhethertheselectionofpersonsmovingtootherEU15countriesdiffersfromtheselectionofmigrantsmovingtocountrieswhereimmi‐grationrestrictionscomeintoplay.Wefindthatimmigrationrestrictionshavelittleef‐fectontheselectionofemigrants.Finally,Section8summarizesthestudyanddrawssomelessonsforfutureresearch.2.TheoreticalframeworkPreviousliteratureontheself‐selectionofmigrantshasfocusedontheconditionalex‐pectationsofearningsdistributionsamongmigrantsandstayers.Inthissection,wede‐riveanovelresult:theRoymodelimpliesthatundercertainconditions,theearningsdistributionofmigrantsfirst‐orderstochasticallydominates,orisstochasticallydomi‐natedby,theearningsdistributionofstayers.Inabivariatenormalframework,itturnsoutthattheconditionsrequiredforstochasticdominanceareidenticaltotheconditionsthatdeterminethenatureofself‐selectionintermsofexpectedearnings.Wealsodecomposeself‐selectionintotwocomponents,onethatisdeterminedbydif‐ferencesinreturnstoobservableskillsbetweensourceandhostcountry,andonethatisdeterminedbydifferencesinreturnstounobservableskills.Thedistinctionbetweenobservableandunobservableskills,ofcourse,dependsontheempiricalframeworkandonthedatathatisbeingused;observableskillsincludethevariablesexplainingearn‐ingsthatareincludedinthedata,whilethecomponentofearningsthatisleftunex‐plainedbythedataistheunobservableskillcomponent.Eventhoughthecontentofthetwocomponentsdiffersamongdatasets,itislikelythatamajorpartofmigrantself‐selectionisdeterminedbytheunobservablecomponentsimplybecause“observables”tendtoexplainarelativelysmallfractionofthevarianceinearnings.

  • 5

    Wetakeasourstartingpointthemigrationdecisionfacedbypotentialmigrantsinatwo‐countryframework,inlinewithBorjas(1987)andsubsequentliterature.Residentsofthesourcecountry(country0)considermigratingtothedestinationcountry(coun‐try1),andthemigrationdecisionisassumedtobeirreversible.Tosimplifythepresen‐tation,wefocusonasingleobservedskillcharacteristicsandsuppressthesubscriptthatindexesaparticularindividual.Forconcreteness,thevariablescanbethoughtofasgivingtheworker’syearsofeducationalattainment,butitincludesallthecharacteris‐ticsaffectingindividual’sincomethatareobservedinagivensetofdata.Residentsofthesourcecountryfacetheearningsdistribution:(1) log wherew0givesthewageinthesourcecountry;r0givestherateofreturntoobservableskills;andtherandomvariable0measuresindividual‐specificproductivityshocksre‐sultingfromunobservedcharacteristicsandisnormallydistributedwithmeanzeroandvariance .Thedistributionofobservableskillsinthesourcecountry’spopulationisgivenbys=s+s,wheretherandomvariablesisalsoassumedtobenormallydis‐tributedwithmeanzeroandvariance . Iftheentirepopulationofthesourcecountryweretomigrate,thispopulationwouldfacetheearningsdistribution:(2) log wheretherandomvariable1isnormallydistributedwithmeanzeroandvariance12 .Foranalyticalconvenience,weassumethatCov(0,s)=Cov(1,s)=0,sothattheindi‐vidual‐specificunobservedproductivityshocks(i.e.,the“residuals”fromtheregressionline)areindependentfromobservablecharacteristics.5Thecorrelationcoefficientbe‐tween0and1equals01.Itisalsoworthnotingthattherandomvariablesisindivid‐ual‐specificandhasthesamevalueforthesameindividualinbothcountries,whereas0and1arebothindividual‐andcountry‐specific. Equations(1)and(2)completelydescribetheearningsopportunitiesavailabletoper‐sonsborninthesourcecountry.AssumethatthemigrationdecisionisdeterminedbyacomparisonofearningsopportunitiesacrosscountriesnetofmigrationcostsC.Definetheindexfunction:(3) log ∆ , 5Amorerealisticassumptionwouldbethatthecorrelationbetweenobservedandunobservedskillsispositive.However,allowingforpositivecorrelationdoesnotchangethequalitativepredictionsofthemodel.

    02

    s2

  • 6

    wheregivesa“time‐equivalent”measureofmigrationcosts(=C/w0).Thecross‐countrydifferenceinearningsnetofthetime‐equivalentmigrationcostforanindividu‐alwithaverageobservedandunobservedcharacteristicsisgivenby=[(1–0)+(r1–r0)s–].Thedifferenceinearningsattributabletoindividualdeviationfromaveragecharacteristicsisgivenby ,wherevi=(ris+i)for∈ 0,1 .ApersonemigratesiftheindexI>0,andremainsintheorigincountryother‐

    wise. Migrationcostsvaryamongpersons—butthesignofthecorrelationbetweencosts(whetherindollarsorintime‐equivalentterms)andskills(bothobservedandunob‐served)isambiguousanddifficulttodetermine.Theheterogeneityinmigrationcostscanbeincorporatedtothemodelbyassumingthatthedistributionoftherandomvari‐ableinthesourcecountry’spopulationisgivenby=+,whereisthemeanlevelofmigrationcostsinthepopulation,andisanormallydistributedrandomvari‐ablewithmeanzeroandvariance .However,Borjas(1987)andChiquiarandHanson(2005)showthattime‐equivalentmigrationcostsdonotplayaroleinthealgorithmthatdeterminestheselectionofemigrantsifeitherthosecostsareconstant(sothat2 =0),orifthecostsareuncorrelatedwithskills.Foranalyticalconvenience,weassumethattime‐equivalentmigrationcostsareconstant,sothat=.6Theoutmigrationratefromthesourcecountryisthengivenby:(4) 0 ∗ ∆ ∗ 1 ∆ ∗ , wherev*=(v1v0)/visastandardnormalrandomvariable;*=/v;v2 =Var(v1–v0);andisthestandardnormaldistributionfunction.7 Inadditiontoidentifyingthedeterminantsoftheoutmigrationrateinequation(4),theRoymodelletsusexaminewhichpersonsfinditmostworthwhiletoleavethesourcecountry.8Inthefollowing,weexaminetheself‐selectionofemigrantsalongtwodimen‐sions:selectionintermsofobservableskillssandselectionintermsofunobservableskills0,whichtogethercombineintoselectionintermsoftotalproductivityorearn‐ings,asmeasuredbylogw0.LetFM(z)andFN(z)representthe(cumulative)probabilitydistributionsofskillsorearningsformigrantsandnon‐migrantsinthesourcecountry,respectively,wherez6If werenegativelycorrelatedwithskills,thenegativecorrelationwouldtendtoinducethemoreskilledtomigrate,creatingapositivelyselectedmigrantflow.Thiswouldstrengthenpositiveself‐selection,andweakennegativeself‐selection.7Itisstraightforwardtostudyequation(4)toconfirmthatthemigrationraterises,whenmeanincomeinthesourcecountryfalls,meanincomeinthehostcountryrises,returnstoobservedskillsinthesourcecountryfall,returnstoobservedskillsinthehostcountryrise,time‐equivalentmigrationcostsfallandwhenmeanobservedskillsriseifr1>r0orfallifr1<r0.8Throughouttheanalysis,weassumethat*isconstant.Themigrationflowiseffectivelyassumedtobesufficientlysmallthattherearenofeedbackeffectsonthelabormarketsofeitherthesourceordesti‐nationcountries.

    2

  • 7

    denotesaparticularmeasureofskills(e.g.,observableorunobservablecharacteristicsorincome).Bydefinition,theprobabilitydistributionofmigrantsFM(z)first‐ordersto‐chasticallydominatesthatofstayersFN(z)if:(5) ∀ ,andthereisatleastonevalueof forwhichastrictinequalityholds.9Fromnowon,wheneverwerefertostochasticdominance,wemeanfirst‐orderstochasticdominance.Equation(5)impliesthatalargerfractionofthemigrantshaveskillsaboveanythresh‐oldz*.Putdifferently,foranylevelofskillsz*,thepopulationdescribedbytheprobabil‐itydistributionFMismoreskilledbecausealargerfractionofthegroupexceedsthatthreshold.Themigrants,inshort,arepositivelyselected.Negativeselection,ofcourse,wouldoccurifthereversewastrueand z,withastrictinequalityholdingforatleastonevalueof .Iftheskilldistributionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants,thestochasticdominancethenalsoimpliesthetypicaldefinitionofpositiveselectionthatisbasedonconditionalexpectations:(6) | 0 | 0 ,sothatmigrants,onaverage,aremoreskilledthanstayers.Conversely,iftheprobabilitydistributionofstayersstochasticallydominatesthatofmigrants,andtherewasnegativeselection,itwouldalsofollowthat | 0 | 0 .Theconverse,however,isnottrueforageneraldistribution:Aclaimofpositiveselectioninexpectations,asde‐finedbyequation(6),doesnotimplythattheskilldistributionofmigrantsstochastical‐lydominatesthatofnon‐migrants.Toderivethestochasticorderingoftheskilldistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants,letf(x,v)beabivariatenormaldensityfunction,withmeans(x,v),variances ( x2,v2 ) andcorrelationcoefficient.Further,lettherandomvariablevbetruncatedfrombelowatpointaandfromaboveatpointb.Arnoldetal.(1993,p.473)showthatthe(margin‐al)momentgeneratingfunctionofthestandardizedrandomvariable(x‐x)/x,giventhetruncationofv,isgivenby:(7) / ,where=(a–v)/v;and=(b–v)v. Intermsofthemigrationdecision,thetruncationintherandomvariablev=v1–v0inthesampleofmigrantsisfrombelowandimpliesthat=–*=k,and=,wherekis

    9Analternativeandperhapsmoreintuitivedefinitionofstochasticdominanceisintermsofquantiles.Let and bethequantilefunctionsoforder oftheskilldistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants.FM(z)stochasticallydominatesFN(z)ifandonlyif forall01andthereisatleastonevalueof forwhichastrictinequalityholds.

  • 8

    thetruncationpoint.Inthesampleofstayers,thetruncationinvisfromabove,andthetruncationpointsare=–and=k.Bysubstitutingthesedefinitionsintoequation(7),itcanbeshownthatthemomentgeneratingfunctionsfortherandomvariablegiv‐ingtheconditionaldistributionsofskillcharacteristicxformigrantsandstayersreduceto:(8)

    1 Φ1 Φ

    and(9)

    ΦΦ .

    ConsideranytwodistributionfunctionsF(z)andG(z).Thistle(1993,p.307)showsthatFwillstochasticallydominateGifandonlyif:(10) , ∀ 0,wheremFisthemomentgeneratingfunctionassociatedwithdistributionF;mGisthemomentgeneratingfunctionassociatedwithG.Therankingofthemomentgeneratingfunctionsinequation(10)implieswecande‐terminethestochasticrankingofthetwodistributionsbysimplysolvingfortherele‐vantcorrelationcoefficient,andcomparingequations(8)and(9).Suchacomparisonimpliesthat:(11) , 0 , 0.Inotherwords,migrantsarepositivelyselectedif>0,andarenegativelyselectedoth‐erwise.Considerinitiallythestochasticrankinginobservablecharacteristics.Theran‐domvariablex=s,andtherelevantcorrelationcoefficientisdefinedby:(12) , 1 .Equation(12)showsthatthestochasticorderingofthedistributionsofobservableskillsofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsdependsonlyoninternationaldifferencesintherateofreturntoobservableskills.Theskilldistributionofmigrantswillstochasticallydominatethatofstayerswhentherateofreturntoskillsishigherabroad.Conversely,theskilldistributionfornon‐migrantswillstochasticallydominatethedistributionformigrantsiftherateofreturntoobservableskillsislargerathome.Considernextthestochasticorderingintheconditionaldistributionsofunobservableskills0.Therelevantcorrelationfordeterminingthistypeofselectionisgivenby:

  • 9

    (13) , 1 .Itfollowsthatthedistributionofunobservableskillsformigrantsstochasticallydomi‐natesthatfornon‐migrantswhen 1.Notethatthenecessaryconditionforposi‐tiveselectionhastwocomponents.First,theunobservedcharacteristicsmustbe“trans‐ferable”acrosscountries,sothat01issufficientlyhigh.Second,theresidualvarianceinearningsislargerinthedestinationcountrythaninthesourcecountry.Theresidualvariances02 and12 ,ofcourse,measurethe“price”ofunobservedcharacteristics:thegreatertherewardstounobservedskills,thelargertheresidualinequalityinwages.10Aslongasunobservedcharacteristicsaresufficientlytransferableacrosscountries,em‐igrantsarepositivelyselectedwhentherateofreturntounobservableskillsishigherinthedestination.Finally,considerthestochasticrankingin“total”productivity.Theearningsdistributioninthesourcecountrygivenbyequation(1)canberewrittenas:(14) log 0 α0 0μs 0ε ε0 α0 0μ 0,wherethenormallydistributedrandomvariablev0hasmeanzeroandvariancev02 .Therelevantcorrelationfordeterminingthestochasticrankingoftheearningsdistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsis:(15) , 1 1 1 ,where ⁄ and1 ⁄ .Thesignofthecorrelationinequation(15),whichdeterminesthenatureoftheselec‐tioninpre‐migrationearnings,dependsonthesignofaweightedaverageoftheselec‐tionthatoccursinobservableandunobservablecharacteristics.Interestingly,theweightisthefractionofthevarianceinearningsthatcanbeattributedtodifferencesinobservableandunobservablecharacteristics,respectively.Ifthereispositive(negative)selectioninboth“primitive”typesofskills,therewillthenbepositive(negative)selectioninpre‐migrationearnings.If,however,therearediffer‐enttypesofselectioninthetwotypesofskills,theselectionineachtypeisweightedbyitsimportanceincreatingthevarianceoftheearningsdistribution.Itiswellknownthatobservablecharacteristics(suchaseducationalattainment)explainarelativelysmallfractionofthevarianceinearnings(perhapslessthanathird).Asaresult,equation(15)impliesthatitistheselectioninunobservablesthatismostlikelytodeterminethena‐tureoftheselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofemigrants.ThisimplicationplaysanimportantroleinexplainingwhytheevidencereportedinFernández‐HuertasMora‐ga(2011)andKaestnerandMalamud(2014)conflictswiththatofChiquiarandHanson(2005).10Thisinterpretationofthevariancesfollowsfromthedefinitionofthelogwagedistributioninthehostcountryintermsofwhatthepopulationofthesourcecountrywouldearniftheentirepopulationmigrat‐edthere.Thisdefinitioneffectivelyholdsconstantthedistributionofskills.

  • 10

    Asmentionedearlier,thestochasticdominanceresultsnecessarilyimplyselectionintermsofconditionalexpectations.Inthecaseofbivariatenormaldistributions,itfol‐lowsthattheexpectationoftheearningsdistributionofmigrantsE(logw0|v*>*)isgivenby:(16) | ∗ Δ ∗ 1 Δ ∗

    1 Δ ∗ ,where*)=(*)/[1(*)]>0,andisthedensityofthestandardnor‐maldistribution.Ascanbeseenbyexaminingequation(16),theconditionsthatdeter‐minetheself‐selectionintermsofexpectationsarethesameastheconditionsthatde‐terminethestochasticorderingoftheskilldistributionsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants.InthenormaldistributionframeworkthatunderliesthecanonicalRoymodel,stochas‐ticdominanceimpliesselectioninexpectations,andviceversa.Inempiricalapplications,however,thepredictionofstochasticdominanceislikelytobemuchlessrobustthanthepredictionsconcerningexpectationsbecausetestingforsto‐chasticdominancewillrequireamorerigoroustestthansimplycomparingtheaverageincomesorskillsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants.Ifonejustcomparestheaveragestofindouthowmigrantsareself‐selected,thefindingscanbecompatiblewiththepredic‐tionsoftheRoy‐modelevenifalargenumberofindividualsinthedatabehaveagainstthestochasticdominancepredictionsofthemodel.Asaresult,establishinganempiricalpatternofstochasticdominanceprovidesverystrongevidencethatdifferencesinskillpricesareindeedimportantinmigrationdecisions.3.DataOuranalysisusesadministrativedatafortheentireDanishpopulationfrom1995to2010.ThedataismaintainedandprovidedbyStatisticsDenmarkanditderivesfromtheadministrativeregistersofgovernmentalagenciesthataremergedusingauniquesocialsecuritynumber.11Foreachyearbetween1995and2004,weidentifiedallDanishcitizensaged25‐54wholivedinDenmarkduringtheentirecalendaryear.12Werestricttheanalysistopersonswhoworkedfulltime.13Migrationdecisionsofpart‐timeworkersorofworkersoutside

    11AllresidentsinDenmarkarelegallyrequiredtohaveasocialsecuritynumber.Thisnumberisneces‐sarytomanyactivitiesindailylife,includingopeningabankaccount,receivingwagesandsalariesorsocialassistance,obtaininghealthcare,andenrollinginschool.12Aperson’sageismeasuredasofJanuary1sttheyearafterthereferenceyear.13Theadministrativedataallowsthecalculationofavariablethatmeasurestheamountof“workexpe‐riencegained”duringthecalendaryear.Themaximumpossiblevalueforthisvariableis1,000.Were‐strictoursampletoworkerswhohaveavalueof900orabove,sothatoursampleroughlyconsistsofpersonswhoworkedfulltimeatleast90percentoftheyear.Inordertomeasuretheworkexperiencegainedduringagivenyear,wesubtractthevaluefromthepreviousyearfromthecurrentvalueofthe

  • 11

    thelaborforcemaybedrivenbydifferentfactors,andtheobservedincomeoftheseworkersmaynotbeindicativeoftheirtrueearningspotential.Theincomevariableforeachyearisconstructedbyaddingtheworker’sannualgrosslaborincomeandpositivevaluesoffreelanceincome.14Wemergedthisinformationwithdatafromthemigrationregisterfortheyears1995through2010.Themigrationregisterreportsthedateofemigrationandthecountryofdestination.EventhoughitispossibleforDanishcitizenstoemigratewithoutregister‐ing,weexpectthatthenumbersofpersonswhodosoissmallasitisalegalrequire‐mentforDanishcitizenstoreportemigration.Danishtaxlawsprovidefurtherincen‐tivesformigrantstoregisterwhentheyemigrate.Afteridentifyingthepopulationofinterest,wedeterminedforeachpersonwhetherheorsheemigratedfromDenmarkduringthefollowingcalendaryear.Ifwefoundthataparticularpersonemigrated,wesearchedforthepersoninthemigrationregisterforsubsequentyearstodetermineifthemigrantreturnedtoDenmarkatsomepointinthefuture,andrecordedthedateofpossiblereturnmigration.Themigrationregisterin‐cludesnear‐completeinformationonreturnmigration,asregistrationinDenmarkisrequiredforthereturnmigranttobeeligibleforincometransfersandtobecoveredbynationalhealthinsurance.Tofocusonmigrationdecisionsthatarepermanentinnature,werestricttheanalysistomigrationspellsthatareatleastfiveyearslong.15Wedefineamigrantasanindividualwhoisfoundinoneofthe1995‐2004cross‐sections,whoemigratesfromDenmarkdur‐ingthefollowingyeartodestinationsoutsideGreenlandortheFaroeIslands,andwhostaysabroadforatleastfiveyears.16Individualswhoemigratedforlessthanfiveyearswereremovedfromthedata,andtherestofthepopulationisthenclassifiedasnon‐migrants.17Theanalysisofbothmigrantsandnon‐migrantsisfurtherrestrictedtoonlyincludeDanishcitizenswhodonothavean“immigrationbackground.”18variable.Personswhohadamissingvalueforworkexperienceineitherofthetwoyearsweredroppedfromthesample.Missingvaluesinthisvariabletypicallyindicatethatthepersonspenttimeabroad.14Theinformationonearningsistakenfromthetaxrecordsforeachcalendaryear.Thisvariableiscon‐sideredtobeofhighqualitybyStatisticsDenmark.Somepersonsalsoreportnegativevaluesforfree‐lanceincome.Thesenegativevaluesarelikelytobeduetolossesarisingfrominvestmentsanddonotreflecttheproductivecharacteristicsoftheindividual.15Havingstayedabroadforfiveyearspredictslongermigrationspells.Forexample72%ofmenand71%ofwomenwholeftDenmarkin1996andwerestillabroadafterfiveyearswerealsoabroadaftertenyears.16GreenlandandtheFaroeIslandsareautonomousregionsbutstillpartofDenmark.WehaveexcludedthesedestinationsasmanyofthesemigrantscouldhaveoriginatedinGreenlandortheFaroeIslands,andmanywouldactuallybereturninghomeratherthanemigratingfromDenmark.Theexactdurationre‐quirementswere1,825daysorlongerforlong‐termmigrants. 17Wealsoexaminedtheselectionofshort‐termmigrantsandthequalitativeresultsaresimilartothosereportedbelow,althoughtheintensityofselectionisweaker.18StatisticsDenmarkdefinesapersontohave“noimmigrantbackground”ifatleastoneoftheparentswasborninDenmarkandthepersonis/wasaDanishcitizen.Wesearchedthepopulationregistersfrom1980to2010fortheparentsofthepersonsinoursample,andifaparentwasfoundheorshewasre‐quiredtobeaDanewithnoimmigrantbackgroundaswell.

  • 12

    Table1reportssummarystatisticsfromtheDanishadministrativedata.Thepaneldatasetcontainsover6.4millionmaleand5.1millionfemalenon‐migrants.Theconstruc‐tionofthedataimpliesthatnon‐migrantsappearinthedatamultipletimes(potentiallyonceineachcross‐sectionbetween1995and2004).Wewereabletoidentify7323maleand3436femalemigrants.Byconstruction,thesemigrantsarepersonswhowefirstobserveresidinginDenmarkandwholeftthecountryatsomepointbetween1996and2005.AsTable1shows,theDanishemigrantsareyoungerthanthenon‐migrants,regardlessofgender.Despitetheagedifference,theemigrantsearnedhigherannualincomesintheyearpriortothemigrationthanthenon‐migrants.Weconstructasimplemeasureof“standardizedearnings”thatadjustsfordifferencesinage,gender,andyeareffects.Standardizedearningsaredefinedbytheratioofaworker’sannualgrossearningstothemeangrossearningsofworkersofthesameageandgenderduringthecalendaryear.19Table1showsthatemigrantsearnmorethannon‐migrantsintermsofstandardizedearnings.Inparticular,maleemigrantsearnabout30percentmorethannon‐migrants,andfemaleemigrantsearnabout20percentmore.Table2reportsthenumberofemigrantsmovingtodifferentdestinations.ThelargestdestinationsforbothmenandwomenaretwootherNordiccountries,SwedenandNorway,aswellastheUnitedStates,theUnitedKingdomandGermany.20Thesefivecountriesaccountfor57percentofallemigration.Finally,itisalsointerestingtosummarizethelinkbetweeneducationandemigration.Table3reportstheeducationdistributionsfornon‐migrantsandmigrants.Itisevidentthatthemigrantstendtobemoreeducatedthanthenon‐migrants,amongbothmenandwomen.Forexample,50percentofDanishmalenon‐migrantshaveavocationaleducation,ascomparedtoonly30percentofmigrantstonon‐Nordicdestinations.Simi-larly, the fraction of male migrants to non-Nordic destinations with a Master’s degree is 24 percent, whereas only 7 percent of male non-migrants have a Master’s degree. In order to add time dimension, the evolution of the emigration rate is presented in figure 1a for men and in figure 1b for women separately for the whole population and for those with higher education and without higher education. As we are looking at long-term migration, the emigration rates are small, but there is an upward trend. The rate is higher for men and for those with higher education. We also computed the difference between the average of the log standardized earnings, or a degree of selection, for migrants and non-migrants for each year from 1995 to 2004 for men and women separately. The results are reported in figures 2a and 2b. There is a downward trend in the difference for both men and women. The finding makes sense: when the migrants are positively self-selected and the emigration rate gets bigger the average standardized earnings of migrants should get smaller. However, the variation across years is small, so that pooling the data is justified.

    19Bothmigrantsandnon‐migrants,aswellasshorter‐termmigrants,areincludedinthesecalculations.20Ifwerelaxtheconstraintsonlabormarketstatusandagetoenterthesample,theUnitedKingdomemergesasthelargestdestinationbecauseofthelargenumberofDanishstudentswhopursuetheiredu‐cationthere.

  • 13

    Tosummarize,thedescriptivefindingssuggestastrongdegreeofpositiveselection—atleastasmeasuredbyeducationanddifferencesintheconditionalmeansofearnings. 4.Selectioninpre‐migrationearningsThissectionpresentsempiricalevidenceontheself‐selectionofemigrantsfromDen‐markintermsofstandardizedpre‐emigrationearnings.Themainempiricalfindingisthatlong‐termemigrantsfromDenmarkwere,ingeneral,muchmoreproductivepriortotheirmigrationthanindividualswhochosetostay.Ofcourse,thesummarystatisticsreportedinTable1alreadysuggestpositiveselectionamongemigrantsbecausetheirstandardizedearningsexceededthoseofnon‐migrants.However,differencesinconditionalaveragescouldbemaskingsubstantialdifferencesbetweentheunderlyingprobabilitydistributions.Ourtheoreticalframeworkpredictsthatthedistributionofearningsformigrantsshouldstochasticallydominatethatofnon‐migrants.Asaresult,ourempiricalanalysiswillmainlyconsistofcomparingcu‐mulativedistributionsofstandardizedearningsbetweenmigrantsandnon‐migrants.Anadvantageofsimplygraphingandexaminingthecumulativedistributionsisthattheanalysisdoesnotrequireanytypeofkerneldensityestimation,andthatwedonotneedtoimposeanystatisticalassumptionsorparametricstructureonthedata.Wewillalsopresentkerneldensityestimatesoftheearningsdensityfunctionsasanalternativewayofpresentingthekeyinsights.Finally,wewillderiveandreportstatisticalteststode‐termineifthedatasupportthetheoreticalpredictionofstochasticdominance.Figure3aillustratesthecumulativeearningsdistributionsformalemigrantstoNordiccountries,malemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries,andformalenon‐migrants.Thevaluesofthestandardizedearningsaretruncatedat‐2and2tomakethegraphsmoretractable.21Thefigureconfirmsthatmigrantswerepositivelyselecteddur‐ingthestudyperiod.ThecumulativedistributionfunctionofstandardizedearningsofmigrantstodestinationsoutsidetheNordiccountriesisclearlylocatedtotherightofthecorrespondingcumulativedistributionfornon‐migrants,aswouldbethecaseifthecumulativedistributionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants.ThefigurealsoshowsthatthedistributionfunctionformigrantstootherNordiccountriesislocatedtotherightofthatfornon‐migrants.However,theselectionofthemigrantstoNordiccountriesseemsweaker.ThisweakerselectionmayarisebecausetherateofreturntoskillsinNordiccountriesisrelativelylowwhencomparedtothatinotherpo‐tentialdestinations.22Figure3bpresentscorrespondingevidenceforwomen.23Themainfindingsarequalitativelysimilar,butthepositiveselectionseemsweaker.21Thetruncationdoesnotaltertheresultsconsiderablyasthesharesofobservationsbelowthelowerandabovetheuppertruncationpointsaresmall.Further,thefollowinganalysisofdifferencesbetweencumulativedistributionfunctionsdoesnotusetruncation.0.07%ofnon‐migrants,0.19%migrantstootherNordiccountriesand0.11%ofmigrantstootherdestinationsliebelowthelowertruncationpoint.Correspondingly,0.03%ofnon‐migrantsand0.21%ofmigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountrieslieabovetheuppertruncationpoint.TherearenomigrantstootherNordiccountriesabovetheuppertruncationpoint.22Moreover,someDanesmayliveinsouthernSwedenbutworkinDenmark.AsthistypeofmigrationisnotrelatedtoreturnstoskillsinthedestinationcountrythisshoulddecreasetheestimatedselectiontoNordiccountries.

  • 14

    Figure4apresentsthecorrespondingkernelestimatesofthedensityfunctionsofthelogarithmofstandardizedearningsformen,whileFigure4bpresentstherespectivegraphsforwomen.24Thedensityfunctionsagainrevealthepositiveselectionofmi‐grantsmovingoutsidetheNordiccountries,bothformenandwomen.Asisevidentfromthefigures,Kolmogorov‐Smirnovtestscomparingtheearningsdis‐tributionsfordifferentgroupsrejectthehypothesisthattheunderlyingearningsdistri‐butionsarethesameatahighlysignificantlevel.Inadditiontoshowingthatthecumu‐lativedistributionsaredifferent,itisalsoimportanttodetermineiftheevidencestatis‐ticallysupportsthetheoreticalpredictionthatthecumulativedistributionfunctionofmigrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrants.Statisticaltestsforfirst‐orderstochasticdominancearehighlysensitivetosmallchangesintheunderlyingdistribu‐tions,makingitdifficulttorankdistributionsinmanyempiricalapplications.25AsnotedbyDavidsonandDuclos(2013),itmaybeimpossibletoinferstochasticdominanceoverthefullsupportofempiricaldistributionsifthedistributionsarecontinuousinthetails,simplybecausethereisnotenoughinformationinthetailsformeaningfultestingofanystatisticalhypothesis.Itwouldthenmakesensetofocusontestingstochasticdomi‐nanceoverarestrictedrangeofthedistribution.Weapplyanapproachthatcharacter‐izestherangeoverwhichthevalueofthecumulativedistributionfunctionfornon‐migrantsisstatisticallysignificantlylargerthanthatofnon‐migrants.Inparticular,wecalculatethedifferencebetweenthecumulativedistributionfunctionswithconfidenceintervals.TocalculatetheconfidenceintervalsweusetoolsthatwereintroducedinAraar(2006)andAraaretal.(2009).26Moreformally,wetestthefollow‐ingnullhypothesisforeach ∈ ,where isthejointsupportofthetwodistributions:(17) H0:F(w))=FN(w)–FM(w) 0,againstthealternativehypothesis(18) H1:F(w))=FN(w)–FM(w) 0andcharacterizeanyrelevantrangeof whereweareabletorejectthenull.

    23Forwomen,0.06%ofnon‐migrantsliebelowthelowertruncationpointand0.00%ofnon‐migrantslieabovethehighertruncationpoint.Therearenomigrantslyingbelowthelowerorabovethehighertrun‐cationpoint.24FollowingLeibbrandtetal.(2005)andFernandes‐HuertasMoraga(2011),weuseSilverman’srefer‐encebandwidthmultipliedby0.75topreventover‐smoothing.Thesamebandwidthisusedalsoinallthekerneldensityestimatesreportedinsubsequentcalculations.25Thiscanleadtodifficultiesinempiricalwork,andlessrestrictiveconceptssuchasrestrictedfirstorderstochasticdominance(Atkinson,1987)andalmoststochasticdominance(LeshnoandKevy,2002)havebeenproposed.26ThecalculationsareimplementedusingtheDASPStatamodulepresentedinAraarandDuclos(2013).

  • 15

    Let bethestandarddeviationoftheestimator∆ w ,andletz()bethe(1–)thquantileofthestandardnormaldistribution.27DavidsonandDuclos(2000)showthattheestimator∆ w isconsistentandasymptoticallynormallydistributed.Wecanthendefinethelowerboundforaone‐sidedconfidenceintervalfor∆ as:28(19) ∆ ∆ w .WeestimatethestandarderrorsusingaTaylorlinearizationandallowforclusteringattheindividuallevel.Wethenimplementtheprocedurebycalculatingthelowerboundsoftheconfidenceintervalsfortheestimate∆ w definedinequation(19).Table4reportsthesharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantswhoseearningsareoutsidetherangeoverwhichthemigrantdistributionstochasticallydominatesata95percentconfidencelevel.Considerfirstthedistributionsofnon‐migrantmenandmenmigratingtodestinationsoutsidetheNordiccountries.Althoughitisnotclearlyvisiblefromfig‐ure3a,thecumulativedistributionfunctionscrossnearthelowertailsofthedistribu‐tions.Figure5adepicts∆ w andlowerandupperboundsfora95%confidencein‐terval.29Thelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositiveonmostoftherangecoveringthesupportsofthedistributions.Only2.0percentofthemigrantsand3.4per‐centofthenon‐migrantsliebelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,whereasthesharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsabovetheupperboundoftherangeare0.1and0.0percent.Putdifferently,theearningsofalmost98percentofmalemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountriesareontherangewherethecumulativedistributionfunctionfornon‐migrantsisstatisticallysignificantlyabovethefunctionformigrants.Figure5bdepicts∆ w andtheboundsfora95%confidenceintervalfornon‐migrantwomenandwomenmigratingtodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries.Only2.8percentofthemigrantsand4.1percentofthenon‐migrantshaveearningsbelowtherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,andanevensmaller0.2percentofthemigrantsand0.0percentofthenon‐migrantshaveearningsabovethisrange.WeinterpretthesefindingsassupportforthestochasticdominancepredictionforbothmenandwomenmigratingoutsideNordiccountries.Figures6aand6bandthebottompanelofTable4presentacorrespondinganalysisbycomparingthecumulativedistributionsofpersonswhomigratetootherNordiccoun‐trieswiththatofnon‐migrants.Almost12percentofmalemigrantsand16percentofmalenon‐migrantshaveearningsthatliebelowtherangewhere ∆ ispositive,andanother1.5percentofthemigrantsand0.7percentofthenon‐migrantshaveearn‐ingsabovetherange.Putdifferently,about87percentofthemalemigrantstoNordiccountrieshaveincomesontherangewhere ∆ ispositive.Forwomen,itcanbeseeninTable4thatalmost95percentofthemigrantsgoingtoNordiccountrieshave27Theasymptoticvarianceof∆ isderivedinAraaretal.(2009).28Chow(1989)provedthetheoremforthecaseofindependentsamples.DavidsonandDuclos(2000)showthattheresultsalsoextendtothecaseofpairedincomesfromthesamepopulation.29Theupperboundsarecalculatedsimilarlytothelowerbounds.

  • 16

    earningsontherangewhere ∆ ispositive.Tosumup,thefindingsoffersupporttothestochasticdominancepredictionformaleandfemalemigrantsregardlessoftheirdestination,althoughtheevidenceisweakerformenwhomigratedtoNordiccountries.AdditionalsupportforourtheorycomesfromMexico.OurtheorypredictsthattheearningsdistributionofmigrantsfromMexicototheUnitedStatesshouldbestochasti‐callydominatedbytheearningsdistributionofnon‐migrants.Fernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)presentsthesedistributionsformen.Althoughhedoesnotpresentcon‐fidenceintervalsaswedo,thefiguressuggestapatternthatmirrorswhatwefindforDenmark,reversingthecurvesformigrantsandnon‐migrants.InMexico,thewagedis‐tributionofnon‐migrantsstochasticallydominatesthatofmigrants,apartfromanover‐lapforafewpercentatthebottomandconvergingatthetop.5.SelectioninunobservedcharacteristicsIntheprevioussection,wedocumentedtheselectionthatcharacterizesthemigrantsusingthetotalpre‐migrationearnings(afteradjustingforageandyear).Wenowexam‐ineaspecificcomponentofearnings,namelythecomponentduetounobservedcharac‐teristics.Inparticular,wenowadjustfordifferencesineducationalattainmentbetweenmigrantsandnon‐migrants(aswellasotherobservablevariables)byrunningearningsregressions,anddeterminewhetherthedistributionoftheresidualsdiffersbetweenthetwogroups.30Byconstruction,theresidualsfromaMincerianwageregressionreflectthepartofearn‐ingsthatisuncorrelatedwiththeobservedmeasuresofskill.Obviously,thedecomposi‐tionissomewhatarbitrarybecauseitdependsonthecharacteristicsthatareobservedandcanbeincludedasregressorsinthewageequation.Nevertheless,thestudyofemi‐grantselectionintermsofwageresidualsisimportantforanumberofreasons.First,selectionintermsofunobservablecharacteristicsshedslightontheimportanceofthequalityofjobmatchesrelativetotheskillcomponentthatisinternationallytrans‐ferable.Thetheorypredictsthatthenatureoftheselectioninunobservablecharacteris‐ticsdependsonthemagnitudeofthecorrelationcoefficientmeasuringhowthesourceanddestinationcountriesvaluethesetypesofskills.Aslongasthiscorrelationisstronglypositive(sothatunobservedcharacteristicsareeasilytransferableacrosscountries),Danishemigrantswouldbepositivelyselectedinunobservables.Afterall,thepayofftothesetypesofskillsislikelytobegreaterinthedestinationcountries.However,itcouldbearguedthatthecorrelationbetweenthewageresidualsinDen‐markandabroadmaybe“small”.Forexample,theresidualsfromthewageregressionmaybelargelyreflectingthequalityoftheexistingjobmatchintheDanishlabormarket,ratherthanmeasuringtheworker’sinnateproductivity.Totheextentthatthequalityofthejobmatchplaysanimportantroleingeneratingtheresidual,thecorrelationinthisresidualacrosscountrieswouldbeexpectedtobeweak(infact,apurerandommatch‐ingmodelwouldsuggestthatitwouldbezero).Asaresult,therewouldbenegativese‐

    30Intheearningsregressionsweusenon‐standardizedannualearningsasthedependentvariable.Weincludeageandyearfixedeffectsandruntheregressionsseparatelyformenandwomen.

  • 17

    lectioninunobservedcharacteristicssimplybecauseDanishworkerswithgoodjobmatches(andhencehighvaluesoftheresidual)wouldnotmove.Second,thetheoryalsosuggeststhatthenatureoftheselectioninpre‐migrationearn‐ingsdependsonaweightedaverageoftheselectionthatoccursinobservableandun‐observablecharacteristics,withtheweightsbeingthefractionofearningsvarianceat‐tributabletoeachtypeofskill.Becauseobservablecharacteristicsplayonlyalimitedroleinexplainingthevarianceofearningsinthepopulation,itiscrucialtopreciselydelineatethenatureofselectioninunobservablecharacteristics.Table5reportstheMincerianwageregressionsthatweusetocalculatetheresiduals.Thesampleincludesthewholepopulationofprimeagedfulltimeworkerspooledovertheentire1995‐2004period.Inadditiontovectorsoffixedeffectsgivingtheworker’sageandeducationalattainment,wealsoincludetheworker’smaritalstatusandnumberofchildren.Theregressionsareestimatedseparatelyformenandwomen.Figure7apresentsthecumulativedistributionsofwageresidualsformalemigrantstoNordiccountries,malemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountries,andmalenon‐migrants.Thevaluesoftheresidualsaretruncatedat‐2and2,arangethatcoversprac‐ticallyallofthepopulation.31Thecumulativedistributionfunctionofresidualsforemi‐grantswhomovedoutsidetheNordiccountriesislocatedtotherightofthecumulativedistributionformigrantstoNordiccountries,whichinturnislocatedtotherightofthecumulativedistributionofthenon‐migrants.Thevisualevidence,therefore,providesastrongindicationthatmigrantsarepositivelyselectedintermsofunobservedcharac‐teristics.Figure7bpresentstheanalogousevidenceforwomen.32Thefigureshowsthatfemalemigrantsarealsopositivelyselectedintermsofwageresiduals.Aswasthecasewhencomparingthemeasureofpre‐migrationearningsintheprevioussection,these‐lectioninunobservedcharacteristicsislesspronouncedforwomenthanformen.Oneexplanationforthiscouldbethatmenaretypicallyprimaryearnersincouples.WealsoperformedKolmogorov‐Smirnovtestsonthedistributionsofresidualsfornon‐migrantsandmigrantstootherNordiccountriesandformigrantstootherdestinations(separatelyformenandwomen).Allthetestsclearlyrejectedthenullhypothesis,con‐firmingthatthedistributionsofresidualsindeeddifferamongthegroups.33Theevidenceonthepositiveselectionofmigrantsinunobservedcharacteristicsobvi‐ouslyimpliesthattheselectioninpre‐migrationearningsdocumentedintheprevioussectioncannotbeattributedsolelytothefactthatmigrantsaremoreeducated.Instead,wefindthatthereispositiveselectionwithineducationgroups.Thisresultalsohasim‐31Formen,0.05%ofnon‐migrants,0.19%ofmigrantstootherNordiccountriesand0.11%ofmigrantstootherdestinationsliebelowthelowertruncationpoint.Correspondingly,0.03%ofnon‐migrantsand0.23%ofmigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountrieslieabovetheuppertruncationpoint.TherearenomigrantstootherNordiccountriesabovetheuppertruncationpoint.32Forwomen,0.05%ofnon‐migrantsliebelowthelowertruncationpointand0.00%ofnon‐migrantslieabovethehighertruncationpoint.Therearenomigrantslyingbelowthelowerorabovethehighertrun‐cationpoint.33Thep‐valueforthetestbetweenwomenmigratingtootherNordiccountriesandtootherdestinationswas0.015andalltheotherp‐valueswere0.000,sothatalltestsclearlyrejectthehypothesisthattheobservationsaredrawnfromthesamedistribution.

  • 18

    plicationsontheinterpretationofearningsregressionresidualsingeneral.Theresidu‐alsfromwageregressionsaresometimesinterpretedasreflectingthevalueofthejobmatchbetweentheworkerandtheemployer.Ifahighvaluefortheresidualonlyre‐flectsagoodmatch,wewouldthenexpecttofindthatworkerswithlargeresidualswouldbelesslikelytochangejobsandlesspronetomigrate.Ourfindingsclearlyrejectthisinterpretation.Comparingresultsontheself‐selectiontootherNordiccountriesandtherestoftheworldsuggeststhatsearchforabetterjobmatchtothosewhohaveabadjobmatchinDenmarkismorepronouncedamongmigrantstootherNordiccoun‐tries.34Asintheprevioussection,wealsocalculatedthedifferencebetweenthecumulativedistributionfunctionswithconfidenceintervalstodeterminewhetherempiricalevi‐dencesupportsthestochasticdominanceprediction.ThetestresultsaresummarizedinTable6.Figure8adepicts∆ w andthelowerandupperboundsfora95%confi‐denceintervalforthecomparisonbetweennon‐migrantmenandmenmigratingtodes‐tinationsoutsideNordiccountries.Thelowerboundofthe95%confidenceintervalispositiveontherangeofresidualscoveringmostofthesupportofthetwodistributions.9.9percentofthemigrantsand15.2percentofthenon‐migrantshavewageresidualsbelowthelowerboundofthisrange,whereasthesharesofmigrantsandnon‐migrantsabovetheupperboundoftherangeare0.1and0.0percent.35Figure9adepicts∆ w andtheboundsfora95%confidenceintervalfornon‐migrantmenandmenmigratingtootherNordiccountries.A13percentshareofmi‐grantsand15percentofnon‐migrantshavevaluesofthewageresidualthatarebelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundofthe95%confidenceintervalispositive,andsharesof2percentand1percentofmigrantsandnon‐migrantshaveval‐uesoftheresidualthatwouldplacethemabovethisrange.Putdifferently,theresidualsofover84percentofmalemigrantstodestinationsoutsideNordiccountriesareontherangewherethecumulativedistributionfunctionfornon‐migrantsisstatisticallysignif‐icantlyabovethefunctionformigrants.36Interestingly,thereisasizableareainthelefttailofthedistributionofresidualswheretheupperboundoftheconfidenceintervalisnegative.37

    34Forthisgroup,returnstounobservedproductivityarenotasimportantacriterionforself‐selectionasamongmigrantstotherestoftheworld,simplybecausedifferencesinreturnstoskillsbetweenDenmarkandotherNordiccountriesareminor.Asaresult,themechanismofsearchingforabettermatchqualityismorepronounced.35Forwomen,20percentofmigrantsand25percentofnon‐migrantshaveearningsresidualsbelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,andsharesofmi‐grantsandnon‐migrantsabovetherangearelessthanonepercent.36Forwomen,20percentofmigrantsand25percentofnon‐migrantshaveearningsresidualsbelowthelowerboundoftherangewherethelowerboundoftheconfidenceintervalispositive,andsharesofmi‐grantsandnon‐migrantsabovetherangeare3percentand2percent.37A2percentshareofmigrantsand2percentshareofnon‐migrantshaveresidualsinthisarea,andtheinterpretationwouldbethatmalemigrantstootherNordiccountriesarenegativelyselectedintermsofresidualsinthelefttailofthedistribution.

  • 19

    Weconcludebysummarizingtheevidenceasfollows:thereisstrongpositiveselectioninunobservablecharacteristicsinthesampleofmigrantsthatmovedoutsidetheNordiccountriesandweakerevidenceofpositiveselectioninthesampleofmigrantswhomovedtootherNordiccountries. 6.BiasincounterfactualpredictionsThefactthatemigrantsareself‐selectedintheirunobservedcharacteristicsimpliesthatusingtheobservablecharacteristicsofmigrantstopredicttheircounterfactualearningshadtheychosennottomigratewillleadtobiasedresults.Duetodataconstraints,thisispreciselytheempiricalexerciseconductedbyChiquiarandHanson(2005),whoadoptthemethodologyintroducedbyDiNardo,Fortin,andLemieux(1996)andbuildacoun‐terfactualwagedensityofwhattheMexicanimmigrantswouldhaveearnedinMexicohadtheystayed.TheactualwagedensityofMexican“stayers”isthencomparedtothecounterfactualdensityformigrants.Byconstruction,thisapproachignorestheroleofunobservablecharacteristicsintheestimationofthecounterfactualwagedistribution.AclearadvantageoftheDanishadministrativedataisthattheearningsofemigrantscanbeobservedbeforetheyemigrate,sothereisnoneedtobuildacounterfactualden‐sity.Onejustneedstocomparetheearningsdistributionofnon‐migrantstotheactualdistributionoffuturemigrants,aswehavedoneintheprecedinganalysis.Theadminis‐trativedata,however,allowsustopreciselymeasuretheextentofthebiasresultingfromcarryingoutthecounterfactualexerciseinChiquiarandHanson(2005).Inpar‐ticular,wecancontrastthepredictedcounterfactualwagedistributionofmigrantshadtheynotmovedtotheactualwagedistributionofmigrantspriortotheirmove.Wecar‐ryoutthisexercisebypreciselyreplicatingthevariousstepsintheChiquiar‐Hansoncalculations.Itisworthemphasizingthatthistypeofbiaswillarisenotonlyinstudiesthatexaminetheselectionofmigrants,butinanystudythatreliesonobservablestopredictacounterfactualwagedistribution.Let representthelogarithmofstandardizedannualearningsasdefinedearlier(i.e.earningsadjustedforage,gender,andyeareffects).Let | bethedensityfunctionofwagesinDenmark,conditionalonasetofobservablecharacteristics .Also,let beanindicatorvariableequaltooneiftheindividualmigratesthefollowingyearandequaltozerootherwise.Definefurther | 0 astheconditionaldensityofobservedcharacteristicsamongworkersinDenmarkwhochoosenottomigrate,and | 1 bethecorrespondingconditionaldensityamongmigrants.Theobservedwagedensityforthenon‐migrantsis(20) | 0 | , 0 | 0 .Similarly,theobserveddensityforthemigrantsis(21) | 1 | , 1 | 1 .

    Uptothispoint,theanalysisreportedinthispaperconsistsofdirectlyestimatingandcomparingthedistributionfunctionsassociatedwiththedensitiesinequations(20)and(21).Supposethatthepre‐migrationearningsdensityfornon‐migrantswerenot

  • 20

    available.Wewouldinsteadattempttoestimateitfromtheobservablecharacteristicsofthemigrants.Theimpliedcounterfactualdistributionis:(23) | 1 | , 0 | 1 .Equation(23)correspondstothedensityofincomefornon‐migrants,butitisinsteadintegratedoverthedensityofobservablecharacteristicsformigrants.Notethatthecounterfactualdensityin(23)canberewrittenas:(24)

    | 1 | , 0 | 0 | 1| 0

    | , 0 | 0 , where || .Tocompute ,weuseBayes’lawtowrite:(25) | | and

    | | ,

    where istheunconditionaldensityofobservedcharacteristics.Wecanthencombinethesetwoequationstosolvefor:(26)

    1|1 1|

    01 .

    TheproportionPr(I=0)/Pr(I=1)isaconstantrelatedtotheproportionofmigrantsinthedata.Itcanbesettooneinkerneldensityestimationwithoutlossofgenerality.Theweightweuseintheestimationisthengivenby:(27)

    1|1 1| .

    AsinChiquiarandHanson(2005),theindividualweightsearecalculatedbyestimat‐ingalogitmodelwherethedependentvariableindicatesifapersonemigrated.There‐gressorsincludeavectorofagefixedeffects,avectorofschoolingfixedeffects,variablesindicatingwhethertheworkerismarriedandthenumberofchildren(andaninterac‐tionbetweenthesetwovariables),andavectorofyearfixedeffects.38Table7reportsthelogitregressionsestimatedseparatelybygender.Thecoefficientsarethenusedtocomputetheweightsforeachnon‐migrantpersoninthesample.39Figures10aand10b38Wealsotriedspecificationswithage,agesquaredandinteractionsofexplanatoryvariables,butwedonotreporttheseanalysesastheresultingcounterfactualdistributionsdidnotpracticallydifferfromthedistributionsresultingfromthissimplerspecification.39Asearlier,weuseSilverman’sreferencebandwidthmultipliedby0.75.

  • 21

    presenttheresultingcounterfactualdensityfunctionsofthelogarithmofstandardizedearningsaswellastheactualdistributionsformigrantsandnon‐migrants.40Thedifferencebetweentheactualdensityfornon‐migrantsandthecounterfactualden‐sityformigrantsreflectsthepartofself‐selectionthatisduetoobservablecharacteris‐tics.Similarly,thedifferencebetweenthecounterfactualandactualdensitiesformi‐grantsreflectsthepartofselectionthatisduetounobservedcharacteristics(i.e.,allthosevariablesthatcouldnotbeincludedinthelogitmodel).Onesimplewayofquantifyingthesedistributionaldifferencesistocomputetheaver‐agesofthevariousdistributions.ThesecalculationsarereportedinTable8.Considerinitiallytheresultsinthemalesample.Thedifferencebetweenthemeanoftheactualdistributionsformigrantsandnon‐migrantsis0.245logpoints,butthedifferencebe‐tweenthecounterfactualdistributionandthedistributionfornon‐migrantsis0.073.Thisimpliesthatonlyabout30percentofthepositiveselectioninpre‐migrationearn‐ingscanbeattributedtotheobservablecharacteristicsincludedinthelogitmodel,whileabout70percentisattributabletounobservabledeterminantsofproductivity.Thecalculationsinthefemalesampleyieldadifferenceof0.157logpointsbetweenthemeansoftheactualdistributionsformigrantsandnon‐migrantsandadifferenceof0.074pointsbetweenthecounterfactualdistributionandthedistributionfornon‐migrants.Asaresult,observableandunobservablecharacteristicseachaccountforabouthalfofthepositiveself‐selectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofwomen.41Thekeylessonisclear:selectioninunobservablecharacteristicsplaysacrucialroleinde‐terminingtheskillcompositionofemigrants.Thedistinctroleofobservablesandunobservablesindeterminingtheselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofmigrantsisevidentifwereturntotheRoymodelandequa‐tion(16),whichpresentstheconditionalexpectationE(logw0|v*>*).Equation(16)yieldsaninterestingandpotentiallyimportantinsight.Thenatureoftheselectioninpre‐migrationearnings,ofcourse,isgivenbythesumoftheselectioninobservablesandtheselectioninunobservables.Note,however,thateachoftheseselec‐tiontermshasaweightingcoefficientthatrepresentsthevarianceinearningsattribut‐abletoobservablecharacteristics( r02S2)ortounobservablecharacteristics(02 ).Asnotedearlier,observablecharacteristicsexplainarelativelysmallfractionofthevari‐anceinearnings.Putdifferently,equation(16)impliesthatitistheselectioninunob‐servablesthatismostlikelytodeterminethenatureoftheselectionthatcharacterizestheemigrantsample.40Toconductthecounterfactualanalysiswepoolthesampleofallmigrants(regardlessofwhethertheymovedtoNordiccountriesornot).41Thecomponentofself‐selectionthatisduetounobservablecharacteristicsplaysasomewhatsmallerroleforwomen.Onereasoncouldbethatwomenaremoreoftentiedmigrants,andthemigrationdeci‐sionmaybemainlybasedontheskillsofthespouse.Thevarianceinincomeisalsosmallerforwomen,whichalsomakestheselectionbothintermsofobservableandunobservablecharacteristicsweaker.

  • 22

    Totheextentthatbothtypesofselections(i.e.,inobservablesandunobservables)workinthesamedirection,thecounterfactualexercisedescribedinthissectionwillinevita‐blyunderestimatethetrueextentofpositiveselectioninpre‐migrationearnings.Con‐versely,thecounterfactualexercisewillalsoattenuatetheextentof“true”negativese‐lectionifthereisnegativeselectioninbothcomponentsofskills.Infact,Fernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)presentsacorrespondinganalysisusingsurveydatafromMexi‐coandfindsthatcounterfactualestimatesgreatlyunderestimatetheextentofnegativeselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofMexicanswhomovetotheUnitedStates.Putdifferently,thecounterfactualexercisemayleadtoqualitativelyrightconclusionsaboutthenatureoftheselection,butitmayalsogenerateasizablebias,greatlyunderestimat‐ingthetrueextentofeitherpositiveornegativeselection. 7.SelectionandimmigrationrestrictionsAsappliedintheimmigrationliterature,theRoymodelfocusessolelyontheeconomicfactorsthatmotivatelaborflowsacrossinternationalborders.Themodelingtypicallyignoresthefactthattheseflowsoccurwithinapolicyframeworkwheresomereceivingcountriesenactdetailedrestrictionsspecifyingwhichpotentialmigrantsareadmissibleandwhicharenot.WecanusetheadministrativedatafromDenmark,combinedwiththeuniquepoliticalcircumstancesthatguaranteefreemigrationwithinEurope,topartiallyaddressthequestionofwhetherimmigrationpolicyaffectsselectionallthatmuchintheend.Specif‐ically,wecansubdividethegroupofmigrantswhomovedoutsideNordiccountriesintotwogroups:thosewhomovedtoacountryintheEU15ortoSwitzerland,andthosewhomovedtoacountryoutsidetheEU15andSwitzerland.Movementoflaborwasun‐restrictedbetweenDenmarkandotherEU15countriesandSwitzerlandintheperiodunderstudy,butwasobviouslyrestrictedbyimmigrationregulationstodestinationsoutsidetheEU15,suchastheUnitedStates.ItturnsoutthatthesedifferentimmigrationpoliciespursuedbytheEU15andSwitzer‐landandtherestoftheworldbarelymatterindeterminingtheselectionofDanishemi‐grants.Figure11adepictsthecumulativedistributionfunctionsofthelogarithmofstandardizedannualincomeformenandfigure11bforwomen.Itisevidentthatthedistributionfunctionsofstandardizedearningsareverysimilarforthetwogroupsofmigrants.42Wealsoconductedtheanalysisusingthewageresiduals(notshown),andthedistributionsofresidualsarealsosimilarbetweenthetwogroups.Thereisanimportantsenseinwhichthesepolicyrestrictionscannotmattermuch.Suppose,forexample,thatareceivingcountryenactsapolicythatlimitsentryonlytohigh‐skillimmigrants.Ifthehigh‐skillimmigrantsfromasendingcountrydonotfinditoptimaltomove,thepolicycannotforcethosehigh‐skillworkerstomigrate.Allthepol‐icycandoisessentiallycutthemigrationflowfromthatparticularsendingcountrydowntozero.Thelow‐skillworkerswouldliketomovebutarenotadmitted,andthehighskillworkersareadmissiblebuttheydonotwanttomove.42Forwomen,aKolmogorov‐Smirnovtestisnotabletorejectthenull‐hypothesisthattheobservationsforthetwogroupsofmigrantscomefromthesameunderlyingdistribution.

  • 23

    Insum,thepositiveself‐selectionthatissoevidentintheDanishemigrantdatacannotbeexplainedbyimmigrationrestrictions.EventhoughlaborflowstotheEU15andSwitzerlandwereunrestricted,thereisnoevidenceofweakerpositiveselectiontothesecountriesthantotherestoftheworld.Our results also have tentative implications for the question of whether migration patterns reflect differences in rate of returns or migra-tion costs. Although it is plausible that migration costs are higher when moving to other con-tinents, our results suggest that such differences do not play a significant role in the sorting of emigrants between Europe and other continents, most notably North America. 8.Conclusion ThispapershowsthattheRoymodelhasmoredramaticpredictionsontheself‐selectionofemigrantsthanpreviouslyexamined.Thesameconditionsthathavebeenshowntoresultinemigrantsbeingpositively(negatively)self‐selectedintermsoftheiraverageearningsactuallyimplythattheearningsdistributionofemigrantsfirst‐orderstochasticallydominates(orisfirst‐orderstochasticallydominatedby)theearningsdistributionofnon‐migrants.Ourtheoreticalanalysisalsodistinguishesbetweenselec‐tioninobservableandselectioninunobservablecharacteristics.OurempiricalanalysisusestheDanishfullpopulationadministrativedatatoanalyzetheself‐selectionofemigrants,intermsofeducation,earningsandunobservableability,measuredbyresidualsfromMincerianearningsregressions.Theresultsareinlinewiththetheory;themigrantsarebettereducatedandbothpre‐emigrationearningsandwageregressionresidualsofmigrantsstochasticallydominatethoseofnon‐migrantsovermostofthesupportofthedistributions.Consider,forexample,thecaseoffull‐timeworkersaged25‐54.For98percentofmenand97percentofwomenwhomigrateout‐sideotherNordiccountriesthecumulativeearningsdistributionintheyearbeforeemi‐grationstochasticallydominatesthatofnon‐migrantswitha95%confidenceinterval.Thedifferencebetweenthecumulativedistributionsisnotstatisticallysignificantlydif‐ferentineitherdirectionfortheremaining2to3percent.Decomposingtheself‐selectionintotalearningsintoself‐selectioninobservablecharac‐teristicsandself‐selectioninunobservablecharacteristics(asmeasuredbyresidualsfromMincerianwageregressions),revealsthatunobservedabilitiesplaythedominantrole.Formen,about70percentofthepositiveself‐selectioninpre‐migrationearningsisattributabletounobservabledeterminantsofproductivity.Forwomen,thefractionisabout50percent.Thissuggeststhatrelyingoncounterfactualdistributions,basedonobservedcharacteristics,wouldstronglyunderestimatepositiveself‐selection.Thisre‐sultcomplementstheFernández‐HuertasMoraga(2011)findingthatcounterfactualestimatesalsogreatlyunderestimatetheextentofnegativeselectioninthepre‐migrationearningsofMexicanswhomovetotheUnitedStates.Inshort,theuseofcoun‐terfactualearningsdistributionsbasedonobservablecharacteristicsgreatlyunderstatethetrueextentofselectionintotalearnings.Strongpositiveself‐selectioninresidualsalsosuggeststhatunobservedabilitiesplayamuchbiggerroleinmigrationdecisionsthanmatchquality.

  • 24

    Ourfindingsalsohaveimplicationsforimmigrationpolicies.Receivingcountriescanonlybasetheiradmissionpoliciesonskillvariablesthatareobserved,whereasmuchoftheselectionofimmigrantsis“hidden”intheirunobservedcharacteristics.Itcanbeexpectedthatmigrantswillbeself‐selectedintermsofunobservedcharacteristicsevenwhenadmissionrestrictionsareapplied,andtheself‐selectionamongthosefulfillingadmissioncriteriacanbeexpectedtoreflectrelativeskillprices.Thisraisesaquestionabouttheeffectivenessofpointsystemsthatarenecessarilybasedonobservablechar‐acteristics.Theimportanceofrelativeskillpricesisalsosupportedbyourseparateanalysesofself‐selectionofDanesmigratingtothecountriesbelongingtocommonEu‐ropeanlabormarket(excludingotherNordiccountriesthathaveskillpricessimilartoDenmark)andnothavinganyimmigrationrestrictions,andtheself‐selectiontotherestoftheworld.Thereisvirtuallynodifferenceintheself‐selectiontothesedestinationareas.

  • 25

    ReferencesAbramitzky,R.,L.Boustan,andK.Eriksson(2012).“Europe’sTired,Poor,HuddledMasses:Self‐SelectionandEconomicOutcomesintheAgeofMassMigration.”AmericanEconomicReview102(5):1832‐56.Abramitzky,R.andF.Braggion(2006).“MigrationandHumanCapital:Self‐SelectionofIndenturedServantstotheAmericas.”JournalofEconomicHistory66(4):882–905.Araar,A.(2006).“Poverty,InequalityandStochasticDominance,TheoryandPractice:TheCaseofBurkinaFaso.”CahiersderecherchéPMMA2007‐087,PEP‐PMMA.Araar,A.andJ.Y.Duclos(2013).“UserManualforStataPackageDASP:Version2.3.”UniversitéLavalPEP,CIRPÉEandWorldBank.Araar,A.,J.Y.Duclos,M.Audet,andP.Makdissi(2009).“TestingforPro‐poornessofGrowth,withanApplicationtoMexico.”ReviewofIncomeandWealth55(4):853‐881.Arnold,B.C.,R.Beaver,R.A.GroeneveldandW.Q.Meeker(1993).“TheNontruncatedMarginalofaTruncatedBivariateNormalDistribution.”Psychometrika58(3):471‐488.Atkinson,A.B.(1987).“OntheMeasurementofPoverty.”Econometrica55:749‐764.Boarini,R.andH.Strauss(2010).“WhatisthePrivateReturntoTertiaryEducation?:NewEvidencefrom21OECDCountries.”OECDJournal:EconomicStudies,Vol.2010/1.Borjas,G.J.(1987).“Self‐SelectionandtheEarningsofImmigrants.”AmericanEconomicReview77:531‐553.Borjas,G.J.(2003).“TheLaborDemandCurveisDownwardSloping:ReexaminingtheImpactofImmigrationontheLaborMarket.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics118(4):1335–1374.Bratsberg,B.(1995).“TheIncidenceofNonReturnAmongForeignStudentsintheUnitedStates.”EconomicsofEducationReview14(4):373‐384.Chiquiar,D.andG.H.Hanson(2005).“InternationalMigration,Self‐Selection,andtheDistributionofWages:EvidencefromMexicoandtheUnitedStates.”JournalofPoliticalEconomy113(2):239‐281.Chow,K.V.(1989).“StatisticalInferenceforStochasticDominance:aDistributionFreeApproach.”Ph.D.Thesis,UniversityofAlabama.Cobb‐Clark,D.(1993).“ImmigrantSelectivityandWages:TheEvidenceforWomen.”AmericanEconomicReview83:986‐93.DavidsonR.andJ.Y.Duclos(2000).“StatisticalInferenceforStochasticDominanceandfortheMeasurementofPovertyandInequality.”Econometrica68:1435‐64.

  • 26

    DavidsonR.andJ.Y.Duclos(2013).“TestingforRestrictedStochasticDominance.”EconometricReviews32:84‐125.DiNardo,J.,N.M.Fortin,andT.Lemieux(1996).“LaborMarketInstitutionsandtheDis‐tributionofWages,1973–1992:ASemiparametricApproach.”Econometrica64(Sep‐tember):1001–44.Fernández‐HuertasMoraga,J.(2011).‘‘NewEvidenceonEmigrantSelection.’’ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics93(1):72–96.Ferrie,J.(1996).“ANewSampleofMalesLinkedfromthePublicUseMicroSampleofthe1850U.S.FederalCensusofPopulationtothe1860U.S.FederalCensusManuscriptSchedules.”HistoricalMethods29:141–56.Grogger,J.andG.H.Hanson(2011).“IncomeMaximizationandtheSelectionandSort‐ingofInternationalMigrants.”JournalofDevelopmentEconomics95(1):42‐57.HanushekE.A.,G.Schwerdt,S.Wiederhold,andL.Woessmann(2015).“ReturnstoSkillsaroundtheWorld:EvidencefromPIAAC.”EuropeanEconomicReview73:103‐130.Junge,M.,M.D.Munk,andP.Poutvaara(2014).“InternationalMigrationofCouples.”CESifoWP4927.Kaestner,R.andO.Malamud(2014).“Self‐SelectionandInternationalMigration:NewEvidencefromMexico,”TheReviewofEconomicsandStatistics,96(1):78‐71.Kleven,H.J.,C.Landais,E.Saez,andE.Schultz(2014).“MigrationandWageEffectsofTaxingTopEarners:EvidenceoftheForeigners’TaxSchemeinDenmark.”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics129:333–78.Leibbrandt,M.,J.Levinsohn,andJ.McCrary(2005)."IncomesinSouthAfricasincetheFallofApartheid."NBERworkingpaperno.11384.Leshno,M.andH.Kevy(2002).“PreferredbyAllandPreferredbyMostDecisionMak‐ers:AlmostStochasticDominance.”ManagementScience48:1074‐1085.Lundborg,P.(1991).“DeterminantsofMigrationintheNordicLaborMarket.”TheScan‐dinavianJournalofEconomics93(3):363‐375.Margo,R.A.(1990).RaceandSchoolingintheSouth,1880–1950:AnEconomicHistory.Chicago:UniversityofChicagoPress.Pirttilä,J.(2004).“IsInternationalLabourMobilityaThreattotheWelfareState?Evi‐dencefromFinlandinthe1990’s.”FinnishEconomicPapers17(1):18‐34.Sinn,H.‐W.(1997).“TheSelectionPrincipleandMarketFailureinSystemsCompetition.”JournalofPublicEconomics66:247‐274.

  • 27

    Thistle,P.D.(1993).“NegativeMoments,RiskAversionandStochasticnance.“JournalofFinancialandQuantitativeAnalysis28(2):301‐311.UnitedNations,DepartmentofEconomicandSocialAffairs(2013).TrendsinInterna‐tionalMigrantStock:MigrantsbyDestinationandOrigin(UnitedNationsdatabase,POP/DB/MIG/Stock/Rev.2013).Wegge,S.A.(1999).“ToPartorNottoPart:EmigrationandInheritanceInstitutionsinNineteenth‐CenturyHesse‐Cassel.”ExplorationsinEconomicHistory36(1):30–55.Wegge,S.A.(2002).“OccupationalSelf‐SelectionofEuropeanEmigrants:EvidencefromNineteenth‐CenturyHesse‐Cassel.”EuropeanReviewofEconomicHistory6(3):365–94.Wildasin,D.E.(1991).“IncomeRedistributioninaCommonLaborMarket.”AmericanEconomicReview81(4):757‐774.

  • 28

    Figure1.Evolutionoftheemigrationrate

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 29

    Figure2.Evolutionofthedifferencebetweenaveragelogstandardizedearningsofmigrantsandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 30

    Figure3.Distributionfunctionsofstandardizedannualearningsformigrantsandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 31

    Figure4.Densityfunctionsforstandardizedearningsformigrantsandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 32

    Figure5.Differenceofthecumulativedistributionfunctionsforpre‐migrationearningsbetweenmigrantsmovingoutsideNordiccountriesandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 33

    Figure6.Differenceofthecumulativedistributionfunctionsforpre‐migrationearningsofmigrantsgoingtootherNordiccountriesandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 34

    Figure7.Distributionfunctionsofresidualsfromearningsregressionformi‐grantsandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 35

    Figure8.Differenceofthecumulativedistributionfunctionsofresidualsformi‐grantsgoingoutsideotherNordiccountriesandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 36

    Figure9.Differenceofthecumulativedistributionfunctionsofresidualsformi‐grantsgoingtootherNordiccountriesandnon‐migrants

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 37

    Figure10.Counterfactualandactualdensitiesofstandardizedgrossearnings

    a.Men

    b.Women

  • 38

    Figure11.Distributionfunctionsofannualgrossearningsformigrantstothe

    EU15andSwitzerlandandmigrantstootherdestinationsa.Men

    b.Women

  • 39

    Table1.Summarystatistics

    Non‐migrantmenMigrantmen

    Non‐migrantwomen

    Migrantwomen

    Observations 6450665 7323 5163129 3436Age

    Average 39.8 33.0 40.2 35Median 40.0 35.4 40.0 33.0

    Annualearningsin2010euros

    Average 52725 68151 40299 46412Median 46675 57350 37976 42393

    Standardizedannualearnings

    Average 1.0 1.3 1.0 1.2Median 0.9 1.2 0.95 1.1

    Table2.Numbersofmigrants,bydestination

    Men WomenSweden 1466 699TheUnitedStates 763 363TheUnitedKingdom 725 432Norway 576 273Germany 560 249Spain 255 147Switzerland 233 118France 222 156Other 2523 999

  • 40

    Table3.Educationlevelsofnon‐migrantsandmigrantsgoingtoNordiccountries

    ortootherdestinations

    Men Women

    EducationNon‐mi‐

    grantsNordiccoun‐tries

    Otherdes‐tinations

    Non‐mi‐

    grantsNordiccoun‐tries

    Otherdes‐tinations

    Comprehensiveschool 21.4 19.8 8.3 21.5 15.7 8.9Highschool 3.2 7.8 8.6 3.1 6.9 8.9Vocationalschool 49.8 43.5 30.3 41.8 36.5 30.8Advancedvoca‐tional 5.6 5.7 6.6 4.9 5.1 7.8Bachelororequivalent 12.2 11.6 20.6 23.3 22.9 25.4Master’sorequivalent 7.3 10.6 23.9 5.1 12.3 17.6Doctoralorequivalent 0.5 1.0 1.7 0.2 0.7 0.7Notes:Thecategory“advancedvocational”includesallthetertiaryeducationprogramsbelowthelevelofaBachelor’sprogramorequivalent.Programsonthislevelmaybereferredtoforinstancewithsuchtermsascommunitycollegeeducation,advancedvocationaltrainingorassociatedegree.

  • 41

    Table4.Summaryoftestsofstochasticdominanceindistributionsofstandard‐izedpre‐migrationearnings

    Distributionsbeingcompared:

    Percentofsamplebelowlowerbound

    Percentofsampleaboveupperbound

    Migrants Non‐migrants

    Migrants Non‐migrants

    MigrantsoutsideNordiccountriesandnon‐migrants

    Male 2.0 3.4 0.1 0.0Female 2.8 4.1 0.2 0.0

    MigrantstoNordiccoun‐triesandnon‐migrants

    Male 11.6 15.5 1.5 0.7Female 2.6 4.1 2.6 1.3

    Notes:Lowerboundandupperboundrefertotherangeoverwhichthedifferenceofthecumulativedis‐tributionfunctionsissignificantata95percentconfidencelevel.

  • 42

    Table5.Mincerianearningsregressions,bygender

    (1)men (2)women B Se B se

    Married 0.068*** (0.00) ‐0.016*** (0.00)Children 0.025*** (0.00) ‐0.048*** (0.00)

    Highschool 0.224*** (0.00) 0.190*** (0.00)Vocationalschool 0.092*** (0.00) 0.089*** (0.00)Advancedvoca‐

    tional 0.186*** (0.00) 0.198*** (0.00)Bachelor 0.298*** (0.00) 0.225*** (0.00)Master’s 0.498*** (0.00) 0.536*** (0.00)PhD 0.490*** (0.00) 0.622*** (0.00)1996 0.020*** (0.00) 0.017*** (0.00)1997 0.043*** (0.00) 0.041*** (0.00)1998 0.078*** (0.00) 0.083*** (0.00)1999 0.103*** (0.00) 0.112*** (0.00)2000 0.141*** (0.00) 0.143*** (0.00)2001 0.175*** (0.00) 0.175*** (0.00)2002 0.207*** (0.00) 0.210*** (0.00)2003 0.236*** (0.00) 0.235*** (0.00)2004 0.252*** (0.00) 0.258*** (0.00)

    ConstantAgefixedeffects

    12.131***Yes

    (0.00)

    11.931***Yes

    (0.00)

    NR‐squared

    64707200.2597

    51737060.3062

    *p

  • 43

    Table6.SummaryoftestsofstochasticdominanceindistributionsofresidualsDistributionsbeingcom‐pared:

    Percentofsamplebelowlowerbound

    Percentofsampleaboveupperbound

    Migrants Non‐migrants

    Migrants Non‐migrants

    MigrantsoutsideNordiccountriesandnon‐migrants

    Male 9.9 15.2 0.1 0.0Female 19.6 24.7 0.4 0.0

    MigrantstoNordiccoun‐triesandnon‐migrants

    Male 13.4 15.2 2.0 0.9Female 19.5 24.7 3.4 1.8

    Notes:Lowerboundandupperboundrefertotherangeoverwhichthedifferenceofthecumulativedis‐tributionfunctionsissignificantata95percentconfidencelevel.

  • 44

    Table7.Logitestimatesoftheprobabilityofemigration,bygender

    (1)men (2)women B Se B se

    Married ‐0.110** (0.04) ‐0.191*** (0.05)Children ‐1.137*** (0.05) ‐1.232*** (0.07)

    Married*Children 0.460*** (0.07) 0.374*** (0.09)Highschool 1.377*** (0.05) 1.158*** (0.08)

    Vocationalschool 0.186*** (0.04) 0.159** (0.06)Advancedvocational 0.648*** (0.06) 0.714*** (0.08)

    Bachelor 1.097*** (0.04) 0.581*** (0.06)Master’s 1.652*** (0.04) 1.444*** (0.07)PhD 1.723*** (0.10) 1.655*** (0.21)y1996 ‐0.032 (0.06) ‐0.001 (0.08)y1997 0.002 (0.06) ‐0.016 (0.08)y1998 ‐0.024 (0.06) ‐0.001 (0.08)y1999 0.230*** (0.05) 0.131 (0.08)y2000 0.260*** (0.06) 0.238** (0.09)y2001 0.161** (0.05) 0.146 (0.08)y2002 0.208*** (0.05) 0.046 (0.08)y2003 0.198*** (0.05) 0.112 (0.08)y2004 0.246*** (0.05) 0.178* (0.08)Constant ‐6.700*** (0.08) ‐6.951*** (0.12)

    N 6470720 5173706 Pseudo 0.0540 0.0557

    *p