PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

39
PART THREE Product Markets

Transcript of PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Page 1: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

PART THREE

Product Markets

Page 2: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs

Page 3: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The Business Population

In the economy, there are different types of businesses which are organized in several ways and vary in size.

Page 4: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The Business Population

A plant is an establishment that performs one or more functions in fabricating and distributing goods and services.

A firm is a business organization that owns and operates plants.

An industry is a group of firms that produce the same, or similar, products.

Page 5: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The Business Population

Firms can be organized vertically or horizontally. Vertical integration means that firms own plants

that perform different functions in the various stages of the production process.

Multiplant firms may be organized horizontally, with several plants that perform much the same function.

Conglomerates are firms that own plants that produce products in several separate industries.

Page 6: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Advantages of Corporations

Although only 20 percent of all U.S. firms are corporations, they account for 84 percent of all sales.

The corporation is the most effective form of business organization for raising money to finance the expansion of its facilities and capabilities. Two ways to accomplish this are to sell stocks and bonds.

Page 7: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Advantages of Corporations

A common stock represents a share in the ownership of a corporation. Corporations provide limited liability to owners,

who risk only what they paid for their stock. Corporate bonds represent certificates

indicating obligations to pay the principal and interest on loans at a specific time in the future.

Page 8: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The Principal-Agent Problem

The principle-agent problem is a conflict of interest that occurs when agents (managers) pursue their own objectives to the detriment of the principals’ (stockholders’) goals.

This problem arises in corporations where the owners (principals) usually do not manage it; they hire others to do so.

Page 9: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economic Costs

Costs exist because resources are scarce and productive and have alternative uses.

An economic cost, or opportunity cost, is the value of the best alternative use of a resource.

From the firm’s perspective, an economic cost is the payment it must make to attract the resources it needs away from alternative production opportunities.

Page 10: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Explicit and Implicit Costs

Payments to resource suppliers are explicit or implicit. Explicit costs are the monetary payments a

firm must make to an outsider to obtain a resource.

Implicit costs are the monetary income a firm sacrifices when it uses a resource it owns rather than supplying the resource in the market.

Page 11: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Normal Profit as a Cost

Normal profit is a payment that must be made by a firm to obtain and retain entrepreneurial ability. It is also an implicit cost.

If a business owner does not realize at least the minimum payment for her effort, she can withdraw from her business and shift to a more attractive endeavor.

Page 12: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economic Profit(or Pure Profit)

Economic profit, or pure profit, is a firm’s total revenue less economic costs, where:

economic costs = explicit + implicit costs

and implicit costs include a normal profit to the entrepreneur.

Economic profit = total revenue – economic cost

Page 13: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short Run and Long Run

When the demand for a firm’s product changes, it must adjust the amount of resources it employs. Some firms can easily adjust the quantities of certain resources it uses, while other may need more time. Because of these differences in time

adjustments, economists distinguish between two time periods: the short run and the long run.

Page 14: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short Run and Long Run

The short run is a time period in which producers are able to change the quantities of some but not all of the resources they employ. A firm can adjust the number of workers but

not the plant’s capacity in the short run. The long run is a time period sufficiently

long to enable producers to change the quantities of all the resources they employ.

Page 15: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short-Run Production Relationships

A firm’s cost of producing a specific output depends on the prices of the needed resources and the quantities of those resources needed to produce that output. Technologies determine the resources

needed. Resource prices are determined by resource

supply and demand.

Page 16: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short-Run Production Relationships

Total product (TP) is the total output of a particular good or service produced by a firm.

Marginal product (MP) is the extra output or added product associated with adding a unit of a variable resource to the production process.

Average product (AP) is output per unit of input.

Page 17: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short-Run Production Relationships

The law of diminishing returns is the principle that as successive units of a variable resource are added to a fixed resource, the marginal product of the variable resource will eventually decline. This is assume that technology is fixed and

thus the technique of production do not change.

Page 18: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short-Run Production Relationships

For production within firms, the law of diminishing returns is highly relevant.

When a firm adds more labor to the production process with a fixed amount of capital equipment, the marginal product of labor eventually declines. Total product eventually will rise at a diminishing rate, then reach a maximum, and finally decline.

Page 19: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Tabular and GraphicalRepresentations

The table in Figure 6.2 shows a numerical illustration of the law of diminishing returns followed by the graphs of TP, AP and MP. Column (3) illustrate increasing marginal

returns initially, followed by diminishing marginal returns, and then negative marginal returns as the variable resource increases by 1 unit.

Column (4) gives the average product which equals total product divided by labor (input).

Page 20: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Tabular and GraphicalRepresentations

Page 21: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short-Run Production Costs

Production information must be coupled with resource prices to determine the total and per-unit costs of producing various levels of output.

These costs are either fixed or variable depending on whether they can change as output changes.

Page 22: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Short-Run Production Costs

Fixed costs are cost that do not change in total when the firm changes its output.

Variable costs are costs that increase or decrease with a firm’s output.

Total cost is the sum of fixed cost and variable cost.

TC = TFC + TVC

Page 23: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Per-Unit, or Average, Costs

Average-cost data allows a firm to make comparisons with product price, which is always stated on a per-unit basis.

Average fixed cost (AFC) is a firm’s total fixed cost divided by output.

Average variable cost (AVC) is a firm’s total variable cost divided by output.

Average total cost (ATC) is a firm’s total cost divided by output.

Page 24: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Per-Unit, or Average, Costs

AFC = (TFC/Q) Average fixed cost decline as output

increases. This is because the total fixed cost is spread over a larger and larger output.

AVC = (TVC/Q) As added variable resources increase output,

average variable cost declines initially, reaches a minimum, and then increases again. As a result, AVC is U-shaped.

Page 25: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Per-Unit, or Average, Costs

ATC = (TC/Q) or ATC = AFC + AVC Graphically, ATC can be found by

vertically adding the AFC and AVC curves.

Page 26: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Marginal Cost

Marginal cost (MC) is the extra or additional cost of producing one more unit of output.

change in TC change in Q

Marginal cost can also be calculated as the change in total variable cost divided by the change in quantity. As output rises, total cost increases due to variable cost increases only.

MC =

Page 27: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Marginal Cost

A firm’s decisions as to how much to produce are typically marginal decisions.

When coupled with marginal revenue (the change in total revenue from 1 more or 1 less unit of output), marginal cost allows a firm to determine if it is profitable to expand or contract its production.

Page 28: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Relation of MCto AVC and ATC

The marginal cost curve intersect the AVC and ATC curves at their minimum points.

When the amount added to total cost is less than the current average total cost, ATC will fall, and vice versa.

As long as MC lies below ATC, ATC will fall; whenever MC lies above ATC, ATC will rise.

Page 29: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Long-Run Production Costs

In the long run, an industry and the individual firms it comprises can adjust all resources employed. Growing firms can construct larger plants or expand existing one. For a time, successively larger plants will lower average total cost. However, eventually the building of a still larger plant may cause ATC to rise.

Page 30: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Firm Size and Costs

Page 31: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The Long-Run Cost Curve The long-run average total cost curve is

made up of segments of the short-run ATC curves for the various plant sizes that can be constructed.

The long-run ATC curve represents the lowest average total cost at which any output level can be produced after the firm has had time to make all appropriate adjustments in its plant size.

Page 32: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economies andDiseconomies of Scale

The U-shaped long-run average total cost curve can be explained in terms of economies of scale and diseconomies of large-scale production.

Page 33: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The Long-Run Cost Curve

Page 34: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economies of Scale

Economies of scale explain the downward part of the long-run ATC curve. As plant size increases, a number of factors

will for a time lead to lower average costs of production.

Page 35: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economies of Scale

Factors that contribute to lower average total cost for the firm, allowing it to expand its scale of operation, include: Labor specialization Managerial specialization Efficient capital Learning by doing

Page 36: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Diseconomies of Scale

Diseconomies of scale explain the upward part of the long-run ATC curve. As plant size increases, a firm experiences

higher average total costs of production. The main factor contributing to

diseconomies of scale is the difficulty of efficiently controlling and coordinating a firm’s operation as it becomes a large-scale producer.

Page 37: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Constant Returns to Scale

In some industries, there may be a range of output in which long-run average cost does not change. This is known as constant returns to scale. This begins where economies of scale end

and ends where diseconomies of scale begin.

Page 38: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economies andDiseconomies of Scale

Page 39: PART THREE Product Markets. Chapter 6: Businesses and Their Costs.

Copyright 2007 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Minimum Efficient Scaleand Industry Structure

Minimum efficient scale (MES) is the lowest level of output at which a firm can minimize long-run average total cost. Minimum efficient scale varies for each

industry and depends on the shape of the industry’s long-run average total cost curve.

Industries that experience constant returns to scale over an extended range of output will have multiple sizes of firms that are equally efficient.