Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter...

34
Lecture 3: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory Spring 2017 Lars Calmfors Literature: Chapter 5 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 269-270, 280-287) Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 377-383) 1

Transcript of Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter...

Page 1: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Lecture 3: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Spring 2017

Lars Calmfors

Literature: Chapter 5 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 269-270, 280-287) Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 377-383)

1

Page 2: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Topics

• The reservation wage

• Unemployment duration

• Compensating wage differentials

• Effort and social norms

2

Page 3: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Eligibility and unemployment

• Eligibility for unemployment insurance first after havinghad a job

• The reservation wage of ineligible unemployed falls whenbenefits increase: stronger incentive to get a job in order toqualify for benefits

Two types of job seekers

1. Those eligible for unemployment benefits2. Those not eligible for unemployment benefits

Behaviour of the non-eligible

Vun = discounted value of unemployed non-eligible worker Vu = discounted value of unemployed eligible worker

Value of employment for an unemployed non-eligible worker:

rVe(w) = w + q [Vu – Ve(w)] (13)

xn = reservation wage of non-eligible worker

Ve(xn) = Vun (13a)

Before we had (for eligible unemployed workers)

x = rVu (13b)

3

Page 4: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

From (13), (13a) and (13b):

(14)

( )

un n un

un n

n

un

xrV x q V

r

qxV r q x

rrx qx

rVr q

= + −

+ = +

+=

+

⎡ ⎤⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

[ ] (15) ( ) ( ) n

un n e unx

rV z V w V dH wλ∞

= + −∫

4

Page 5: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Find ( )e un

V w V− .

From (13) : (

( )

Since and

( )

( )

From (14):

( )

)e u e

e u

u u

e

e

n

un

rV w q V V

V r q w qV

xrV x V

rqx

V r q wr

w qxV

r q r r q

rx qxV

r r q

= + −

+ = +

= =

+ = +

= ++ +

+=

+

Hence:

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )

(A)

n

e un

n

rxw qx qxV w V

r q r r q r r q r r q

xw

r q r q

− = + − − =+ + + +

= −+ +

5

Page 6: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Using (15), (14), and (A):

( )

( ) ( ) ( ) (B)

n

n

n n

nx

n n nx

rx qx xwz dH w

r q r q r q

rx r q z qx w x dH w

λ

λ

+= + −

+ + +

= + − + −

⎡ ⎤⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

0, 0

Hence: 0

n

n n

x x

x z

x x x

z x z

∂ ∂< >

∂ ∂

∂ ∂ ∂= <

∂ ∂ ∂i

Interpretation

• Higher unemployment benefit for eligible workers implylarger value of having a job (since this qualifies for thehigher benefit in case of future unemployment )

• This creates an incentive to lower the reservation wage toget a job faster

6

Page 7: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Define:

( , , , , , ) ( )

( ) ( ) 0n

n n n n

nx

x x z r q rx r q z qx

w x dH w

λ

λ∞

Φ = − + +

− − =∫

7

Page 8: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

( )

( )

0

0

'( ) ( ) '( )

'( ) 0

0

n

n

x n n

n x

n

x

n n n n

n X

n

x

x

dx dx

dx

dx

q

r H w dw x x H x

r H w dw

dx

dx

λ λ

λ

+

+

Φ + Φ =

Φ= −

Φ

Φ = >

Φ = − − + − =

= + >

Φ=− <

Φ

8

Page 9: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Econometrics of duration models

• Empirical studies of duration of unemploymentT = duration of unemployment (random variable)F(t) = cumulative distribution functionf(t) = F ′(t) = probability density function

F(t) = Pr{T < t} = probability that T is smaller than t

• Hazard function = instantaneous conditional probability of exitingfrom unemployment after having been unemployed for a period oflength t

• If reservation wage is time-dependent, so that x = x(t), the hazard isλ[1 - H(x(t))]

• Let ϕ(·) denote the hazard function

• If an individual has been unemployed for a period of length t, theconditional probability ϕ(t)dt that the duration of unemployment islocated within the interval [t, t + dt] is:

ϕ(t)dt = Pr{t ≤ T < t + dt T ≥ t}

• Use math for conditional probabilities:

Pr(A ∩ B) = Pr(B) · Pr(AB)

• Conditional probability of exiting from unemployment = Unconditionalprobability of exiting / Probability of having being unemployed at time t.

• Unconditional probability of exiting = Pr{t ≤ T ≤ t + dt} = f(t)dt

• Probability of having being unemployed at time t = Pr{T ≥ t} = 1 - Pr{T < t}= 1 - F(t)

9

Page 10: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

10

Page 11: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Duration dependence

• How does the probability of exiting from unemploymentdepend on time already spent in unemployment?

• ϕ′(t) > 0: positive duration dependence. Exit probabilityincreases with duration of unemployment.

• ϕ′(t) < 0: negative duration dependence. Exit probabilitydecreases with duration of unemployment.

• ϕ(t) = λ[1-H(x(t))]. Positive duration dependence if x′(t) < 0.Reservation wage falls over time if unemployment benefit isreduced over time.

• If x′(t) = 0 as in basic model there is no duration dependence.

Estimation of hazard function

ϕ(t, x, θ)

x = now a set of explanatory variables (unemployment benefits,

unemployment rate, sex, age, education etc.)

θ = parameters

Proportional hazard model

ϕ(t, x, θ) = ρ(x, θx)ϕ0(t, θ0)

Two sets of parameters θx and θ0

ϕ0 = baseline hazard (identical for all individuals)

Explanatory factors multiply the baseline hazard by the scale factor ρ(x, θx) independently of duration of unemployment t.

11

Page 12: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

= θx

If x has been defined as (natural) logarithm, then θx gives the elasticity of the exit rate w.r.t. the explanatory variable.

ρ(x,θx)= ex θx⇒ ψ(t,x,θ) = ex θx ψ0(t,θ0)

Hence:

ln ψ = xθx ln e + ln ψ0

ln ψ = xθx + ln ψ0

12

Page 13: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Exponential: No duration dependence

Weibull: Duration dependence depends on

13

Page 14: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Empirical studies

• Studies of reservation wages- Can one believe survey studies?- Close to previous wages- Small elasticity with respect to unemployment benefit

• Studies of unemployment duration (exits fromunemployment)- Small effects of unemployment benefit level: elasticity

with respect to the replacement rate 0.4 – 1.6- Larger effect of potential (maximum) duration:

increase by 1 week raises actual duration by 0.1 – 0.4weeks

- Some evidence on negative duration dependence- Increase in exit rates before benefit exhaustion- Effects of job search assistance and monitoring of

search effort (sanctions)- But difficult to disentangle the effects of assistance and

monitoring

14

Page 15: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

15

Page 16: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

16

Page 17: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Study for Sweden by Carling, Holmlund and Vejsiu (2001)

• Natural experiment

• Benefit cut from 80 to 75 per cent of earlier wage in 1995

• Ceiling for benefits (in kronor)– those above the ceiling receive less than 80 per cent– control group not receiving benefit cut

• Difference-in-differences approach

• Estimated elasticity 1.6

• Later study of benefit hikes showed reduction of jobfinding rate for men but increase for women.

17

Page 18: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

18

Page 19: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

19

Page 20: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Compensating wage differentials

• Wage differentials may depend on differences in workers’skills (theory of human capital)

• But they can also depend on differences in workingconditions- Adam Smith: compensating wage differentials- Harvey Rosen: hedonic theory of wages

• Important to distinguish between(1) conditions of work (differ between jobs)(2) disutility of work (differs among individuals)

20

Page 21: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Perfect competition with jobs of equal difficulty

• Transparency: perfect information

• Free entry: agents may enter and exit the market without costs

• One unit of labour produces y

• Each worker supplies one unit of labour and receives thewage w

Utility function: u(R, e, θ)

R is income R = w if the worker is employed R = 0 if the worker does not work

e is the effort (disagreeability) of a job e = 1 on a job e = 0 if no job

θ ≥ 0 is the disutility (opportunity cost) of work for an individual

All jobs have the same disagreeability, but individuals’ disutility of work differs.

G(θ) is the cumulative distribution function of the parameter θ.

u(R, e, θ) = R - eθ

21

Page 22: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Profit of a firm

π = y – w for each job

Ld =

Utility of a worker

u = w - θe = w - θ if working (since e = 1) u = 0 if not working

• Hence, only individuals with θ < w decide to work

• Normalise labour supply to 1

• Then labour supply is G(w)

Labour market equilibrium

• w = y; labour supply = G(y)• Zero profits for firms• Only individuals for which θ ≤ y choose to work• The allocation is thus efficient

Decision problem of a social planner

The competitive equilibrium is efficient!

{ +∞ if y > w [0, +∞] if y = w 0 if y < w

22

Page 23: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

23

Page 24: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Compensating wage differentials when jobs are heterogeneous

A continuum of jobs, each requiring a different level of effort e > 0

y = f(e) with f′(e) > 0, f″(e) < 0 and f(0) = 0

u = u (R, e, θ) = R - eθ

e > 0 on a job, e = 0 if no job

Free entry assumption: profits are zero for every type of job

Hence w(e) = f(e)

Decision problem of a worker

Find a job with effort e that gives the largest utility

Max u[f(e), e, θ] = f(e) - eθ e

s.t. participation constraint: u(w, e, θ) ≥ u(0, 0, θ) = 0

FOC

f′(e) = θ ⇔ e = e((-)

θ ) if f[e(θ)] - θ[e(θ)] ≥ 0

e = 0 if f[e(θ)] - θ[e(θ)] < 0

• Choose a job in which the marginal return on effort is equalto the disutility of work

• Optimal effort is decreasing with the disutility of work

• Since w[e(θ)] = f[e(θ)], the wage increases with effort andworkers with less aversion to effort obtain a higher wage (acompensating wage differential).

24

Page 25: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Equation of an indifference curve

• The higher the disutility of effort, the steeper is theindifference curve

• Choose a level of effort such that an indifference curve istangent to “production function” (its slope is equal to θ)

• Individuals with a strong aversion to effort choose low-effortjobs with low wages

• Individuals whose aversion to effort is too large, i.e. withθ > f[e(θ)] /e(θ), choose not to work. This is the case ifθ > f′(0)

25

Page 26: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

26

Page 27: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

• Again an efficient allocation

• For each worker the difference between the wage and thedisutility is maximised

Problem of a social planner

where θ* is the threshold beyond which individuals no longer participate.

FOC

• e(θ*) = 0 by definition and so θ* = f′ (0)

• Same allocation as in competitive equilibrium- f′ [e(θ)] = θ- No work if θ > θ* = f′ (0)

27

Page 28: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

28

Page 29: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

• Regulation to prohibit “dangerous jobs” (modelled asrequiring effort above a certain level) is undesirable

- welfare loss for everyone with e > e+ if e+ is maximumeffort level allowed

- lower wage, lower effort and lower utility for theseindividuals

• But this is based on the assumption of perfect competition

29

Page 30: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

A model of social norms

• Fair wages• Gift exchange (Akerlof 1982)• Many employees exceed work standards• Employers pay a wage above “the reference wage”

Assumptions Size of labour force is normalised to 1 ω = average wage Utility of a worker is: u = u(R, e, ω )= R[1 + β(e/ω] – (e2/2) with β ≥ 0 e = level of effort if working e = 0 if not working R = income R = w = the wage if working R = θ = the opportunity cost of working otherwise θ = characterised by the cumulative distribution function G(·).

Interpretation: The worker takes more satisfaction from her effort if the relative wage w/ω is high.

Output f(e) = e

Free entry requires zero profits, i.e. w = f(e) = e

30

Page 31: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

No fairness considerations: β = 0

31

Page 32: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Fairness matters: β > 0

32

Page 33: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

• Utility of an employed worker is

• Employment rises to

• So, here social norms increase effort, the wage, utility andemployment

• But the employment result is not general

With social norms, the competitive equilibrium is no longer efficient.

33

Page 34: Lecture 3: Labour economics - s uperseus.iies.su.se/~calmf/L3 Labour Economics 2017.pdf · Chapter 3 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg: (pp 153-156, 169-174) Chapter 6 Cahuc-Carcillo-Zylberberg:

Social optimum

• Choose effort such that utility of an individual worker ismaximised under the assumption that e = ω

• Since all workers supply the same effort level, this maximises thesum of utilities

• The socially optimal effort level increases in the degree ofconsideration of fairness but it is lower than the competitive level.

• The explanation is that effort on the part of an individual has anegative externality, which is internalised by a social planner.

• Fairness considerations are being given larger weight in economictheory.

• No general consensus on how to introduce them.

• Tendency to regard fairness assumptions as very much ad hoc.

• But neglecting them as in traditional theory is just as ad hoc – weare just more used to them.

34