Economics of the Firm

64
Economics of the Firm Some Introductory Material

description

Economics of the Firm. Some Introductory Material. Introducing homo economicus ….also known as “Economic Man”. Economic man is a RATIONAL being. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of Economics of the Firm

Page 1: Economics of the Firm

Economics of the Firm

Some Introductory Material

Page 2: Economics of the Firm

Introducing homo economicus….also known as “Economic Man”

Economic man is a RATIONAL being

Page 3: Economics of the Firm

Every decision we make involves both incremental benefits and costs…if we are acting rationally, we will undertake any action where the benefits outweigh the costs.

Example:

Suppose that you have been wandering in the desert for 5 days when you come across a lemonade stand. How much would you pay for a glass of lemonade?

Page 4: Economics of the Firm

Suppose that you have been wandering in the desert for 5 days when you come across a lemonade stand. How much would you pay for a glass of lemonade?

,LU

“Utility” is a function of lemonade (among other things)

A glass of lemonade will raise your utility…

LMU

A glass of lemonade isn’t free..it has a price

LP

You will buy a glass of lemonade as long as the benefits are greater than the costs

Page 5: Economics of the Firm

We can complicate the example by adding an alternative choice…a hot dog stand

,,HLU

“Utility” is a function of lemonade and hot dogs (among other things)

L

L

P

MU

H

H

P

MU

A glass of lemonade will raise your utility…

Every dollar spent on lemonade is a dollar that won’t be spent on hot dogs

You will buy a glass of lemonade as long as the benefits are greater than the costs

Page 6: Economics of the Firm

In either case, we can say that, given a representation of individual tastes, price should have a negative relationship with quantity purchased

,,HLU

“Utility” is a function of lemonade and hot dogs (among other things)

Rational Behavior

HLD PPDQ ,(-)

Purchases of lemonade are negatively related to the price of lemonade and positively related to the price of hot dogs

(+)

Page 7: Economics of the Firm

We can easily add another variable to our demand story…most of us are constrained by our disposable income.

IHPLP HL

Expenditures on Lemonade

Expenditures on Hot Dogs Available

Income

(Constraint)

,,HLU (Preferences)

Rational Behavior

IPPDQ HLD ,,(-)

Purchases of lemonade are negatively related to the price of lemonade and positively related to income and the price of hot dogs

(+)

+

(+)

Page 8: Economics of the Firm

We have a similar situation on the supply side…with one complication.

Managers receive compensation from the firm

Managers provide effort to the firm

Stockholders/Bondholders provide capital for the firm

Stockholders/Bondholders receive payments from the firm

Stockholders own the company, but managers make the decisions…how do we align their incentives?

Page 9: Economics of the Firm

If we assume that the institutional details have been worked out, then the job of the decision maker is to maximize firm value

...

111 33

221

0

rrr

FV

Current Profits

Profits one year in the future

Risk adjusted rate of return

Profits two years in the future

Page 10: Economics of the Firm

While it is not necessary, it is sufficient to say that maximizing each year’s profits will maximize firm value

FCVCQPL

Price times quantity equals current revenues

Fixed costs (overhead) is not affected by the level of sales and, hence, has no impact on sales decisions

Variable costs are influenced by sales decisions

As with the average consumer, a firm’s decisions are made at the margin!!!

Page 11: Economics of the Firm

For each sale that is made, it must be profitable at the margin. For now, lets assume that the firm has no control over the price it charges

FCVCQPL

As with the average consumer, a firm’s decisions are made at the margin!!!

How does an additional sale affect revenues?

How does an additional sale affect costs?

LP MC

A sale will be made as long as it has a bigger impact on revenues than costs.

Page 12: Economics of the Firm

In either case, we can say that, given a representation of a firm’s cost structure, price should have a positive relationship with sales (higher price raises profit margin) while anything that influences costs at the margin should have a negative relationship with sales

Rational Behavior

MCPSQ LS ,(-)

Sales of lemonade are positively related to the price of lemonade and negatively related to marginal costs

FCVCQPL

Costs are a function of wages, material prices, etc.

(+)

Page 13: Economics of the Firm

A Demand Function represents the rational decisions made by a representative consumer(s)

IPDQ LD ,Quantity Purchased

“Is a function of”

Market Price (-)

Income (+)

For example, suppose that at a market price of $2.50, an individual with an annual income of $50,000 chooses to buy 5 glasses of lemonade per week.

000,50,$50.2$5 D

Page 14: Economics of the Firm

A Demand Curve is simply a graphical representation of a demand function

For example, suppose that at a market price of $2.50, an individual with an annual income of $50,000 chooses to buy 5 glasses of lemonade per week.

000,50,$50.2$5 D

Quantity

Price

$2.50

5

000,50$ID

Page 15: Economics of the Firm

A Demand Curve is simply a graphical representation of a demand function

Suppose that an increase in the market price from $2.50 to $2.75 causes this individual to reduce his/her lemonade purchases to 4 glasses per week

000,50,$75.2$4 D

Quantity

Price

$2.50

5

000,50$ID

$2.75

4

Page 16: Economics of the Firm

Demand curves slope downwards – this reflects the negative relationship between price and quantity. Elasticity of Demand measures this effect quantitatively

Quantity

Price

$2.50

5

000,50$ID

$2.75

4

%20100*5

54

%10100*50.2

50.275.2

210

20

%

%

P

QD

Page 17: Economics of the Firm

A Supply Function represents the rational decisions made by a representative firm(s)

MCPSQ LS ,Quantity Supplied

“Is a function of”

Market Price (+)

Marginal Costs (-)

For example, suppose that at a market price of $2.00, a firm facing a wage rate of $6/hr will supply 200 glasses per week.

6,$00.2$200 S

Page 18: Economics of the Firm

A Supply Curve is simply a graphical representation of a supply function

Quantity

Price

$2.00

200

6$CS

For example, suppose that at a market price of $3.00, a firm facing a wage rate of $6/hr will supply 200 glasses of lemonade per week.

6,$00.3$200 S

Page 19: Economics of the Firm

A Supply Curve is simply a graphical representation of a supply function

Suppose that an increase in the market price from $3.00 to $3.90 causes this firm to increase it’s lemonade sales to 250 cups per week

Quantity

Price

$2.00

200

6$CS

$3.00

250

6,$50.3$250 S

Page 20: Economics of the Firm

Supply curves slope upwards – this reflects the positive relationship between price and quantity. Elasticity of Supply measures this effect quantitatively

%25100*200

200250

%50100*00.2

00.200.3

5.50

25

%

%

P

QSs

Quantity

Price

$2.00

200

6$CS

$3.00

250

Page 21: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

$2.00

6$CS

$3.00

Quantity

Price

25,000

000,50$ID

20,000 25,000

$2.50

$2.75

20,000

Suppose that the overall market consists of 5,000 identical lemonade drinkers and 100 lemonade suppliers

At a price of $2.50, each of the 5,000 lemonade drinkers buys 5 glasses per week.

At a price of $3.00, each of the 100 lemonade suppliers is willing to sell 250 glasses per week.

Page 22: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Given the behavior of suppliers and consumers, the market price would need to settle in between $2.50 and $2.75

6$CS

$2.00

20,000 Q>25,000At a price of $2.00, total supply is 20,000, but demand is at least 25,000

Page 23: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Given the behavior of suppliers and consumers, the market price would need to settle in between $2.50 and $2.75

6$CS

$3.00

Q<20,000 25,000

At a price of $3.00, total supply is 25,000, but demand is less than 20,000

Page 24: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Given the behavior of suppliers and consumers, the market price would need to settle in between $2.50 and $2.75

6$CS

$2.60

22,500

We would call the $2.60 price the equilibrium price

000,50$,60.2$6$,60.2$500,22 IDCS

Page 25: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Suppose that average income in the area rose to $75,000. Higher income levels should raise demand at any market price

6$CS

$2.60

22,500

000,75$ID

28,000

At the current $2.60 market price, supply is still 22,500, but with a higher level of income, demand has risen to 28,000

At the new income level of $75,000, $2.60 can no longer be the equilibrium price

Page 26: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Suppose that average income in the area rose to $75,000. Higher income levels should raise demand at any market price

6$CS

$2.60

22,500

000,75$ID

25,000

The increase in income causes a rise in sales and a rise in market price

$3.00 000,75$,00.3$6$,00.3$000,25 IDCS

Page 27: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Suppose that lemonade store wages rose to $10/hr. Higher wages should lower supply at any market price

6$CS

$2.60

22,50018,000

At the current $2.60 market price, supply has fallen to 18,000, but demand is still at 22,500

At the wage level of $10, $2.60 can no longer be the equilibrium price

Page 28: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

000,50$ID

Suppose that lemonade store wages rose to $10/hr. Higher wages should lower supply at any market price

6$CS

$2.60

22,50020,000

Higher wages cause a rise in market price and a drop in sales

$2.75 000,50$,75.2$10$,75.2$000,20 IDCS

Page 29: Economics of the Firm

Supply, Demand, and equilibrium prices/sales

IHPLP HL

,,HLU (Preferences)

Rational Behavior

IPDQ LD ,(-) (+)

+(Constraint)

MCPSQS ,(-)

FCVCPQ

(+)

Rational Behavior

With the additional assumption that prices adjust and that markets clear (equilibrium), we have the following…

MCIPP

MCIQQ

,

,

(+) (-)

(+) (+)

Sales are related to average income and marginal costs

Prices are related to average income and marginal costs

Page 30: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price S

D

60.2$* P

500,22* Q

If we truly believe in competitive markets, we can sleep well at nigh knowing several things…goods are being produced by the most efficient producers (i.e. those with the lowest costs) and given to individuals with the highest values.

750,17Q

Somebody who bought a glass of lemonade paid $2.60 when they actually valued it at much higher. We call this consumer surplus

Somebody who sold this glass of lemonade collected $2.60 when the marginal production cost was much lower. We call this producer surplus (a.k.a Profit)

Page 31: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price S

D

60.2$* P

500,22* Q

We also can rest assured that we are producing exactly the right goods and services

Quantity

Price S

D

60.2$* P

500,22* Q

Hot DogsLemonade

If consumer preferences suddenly shifted away from lemonade and towards hot dogs, the lemonade market would shrink (as the price of lemonade falls) while the hot dog market expands (and the price rises)

'D

'D

Page 33: Economics of the Firm

Microsoft’s new Xbox 360 gaming console was released in North America on November 22 at a retail price of $299.99. Available supply sold out almost immediately as Christmas shoppers stood in line for this year’s hot item. (Microsoft has increased its sales target from 3M units to 6M units).

What’s odd about this??

Page 34: Economics of the Firm

Quantity

Price

D

3M

Clearly, $299.99 is not an equilibrium price !

S

???

$299.99

Why didn’t Microsoft raise their price?

Page 35: Economics of the Firm

When do our rationality assumptions begin to break down?

Situations involving interactions among small groups of people: Example: How to split $20.

Situations involving the immediate present vs. the future: Example: Instant gratification and the time value of money

Situations involving uncertaintyExample: The Monty Hall Problem

Page 36: Economics of the Firm

And now for something completely different….

Page 39: Economics of the Firm

The distribution for temperature in south bend is a bit more complicated because there are so many possible outcomes, but the concept is the same

Probability

Temperature

We generally assume a Normal Distribution which can be characterized by a mean (average) and standard deviation (measure of dispersion)

Mean

Standard Deviation

Page 40: Economics of the Firm

Probability

Temperature

Without some math, we can’t find the probability of a specific outcome, but we can easily divide up the distribution

Mean Mean+1SD Mean+2SDMean -1SDMean-2SD

2.5% 2.5%13.5% 34% 34% 13.5%

Page 41: Economics of the Firm

Annual Temperature in South Bend has a mean of 59 degrees and a standard deviation of 18 degrees.

Probability

Temperature59 77 954123

95 degrees is 2 standard deviations to the right – there is a 2.5% chance the temperature is 95 or greater (97.5% chance it is cooler than 95)

Can’t we do a little better than this?

Page 42: Economics of the Firm

Conditional distributions give us probabilities conditional on some observable information – the temperature in South Bend conditional on the month of July has a mean of 84 with a standard deviation of 7.

Probability

Temperature84 91 987770

95 degrees falls a little more than one standard deviation away (there approximately a 16% chance that the temperature is 95 or greater)

95

Conditioning on month gives us a more accurate forecast!

Page 43: Economics of the Firm

5.PrPr TailsHeads

We know that there should be a “true” probability distribution that governs the outcome of a coin toss (assuming a fair coin)

Suppose that we were to flip a coin over and over again and after each flip, we calculate the percentage of heads & tails

FlipsTotal

Headsof

#5.

That is, if we collect “enough” data, we can eventually learn the truth!

(Sample Statistic) (True Probability)

Page 44: Economics of the Firm

We can follow the same process for the temperature in South Bend

Temperature ~ 2,N

We could find this distribution by collecting temperature data for south bend

N

iixN

x1

1

2

1

22 1

N

ii xx

Ns

Sample Mean

(Average)

Sample Variance

Note: Standard Deviation is the square root of the variance.

Page 45: Economics of the Firm

Conditional Distributions

Obviously, the temperature in South Bend is different in the winter and the summer. That is, temperature has a conditional distribution

Temp (Summer) ~ 2, ssN

Temp (Winter) ~ 2, WWN

Regression is based on the estimation of conditional distributions

Page 46: Economics of the Firm

Mean = 1

Variance = 4

Std. Dev. = 2

Probability distributions are scalable

22

2

σ,kkNy

kxy

μ,σNx

3 X =

Mean = 3

Variance = 36 (3*3*4)

Std. Dev. = 6

Some useful properties of probability distributions

Page 47: Economics of the Firm

Mean = 1

Variance = 1

Std. Dev. = 1

Probability distributions are additive

xyyxyx

yy

xx

σ,σNyx

,σNy

,σμNx

cov222

2

2

+Mean = 2

Variance = 9

Std. Dev. = 3

COV = 2

=Mean = 3

Variance = 14 (1 + 9 + 2*2)

Std. Dev. = 3.7

Page 48: Economics of the Firm

Mean = 8

Variance = 4

Std. Dev. = 2

Mean = $ 12,000

Variance = 4,000,000

Std. Dev. = $ 2,000

Suppose we know that the value of a car is determined by its age

Value = $20,000 - $1,000 (Age)

Car Age Value

Page 49: Economics of the Firm

We could also use this to forecast:

Value = $20,000 - $1,000 (Age)

How much should a six year old car be worth?

Value = $20,000 - $1,000 (6) = $14,000

Note: There is NO uncertainty in this prediction.

Page 50: Economics of the Firm

Searching for the truth….

You believe that there is a relationship between age and value, but you don’t know what it is….

1. Collect data on values and age

2. Estimate the relationship between them

Note that while the true distribution of age is N(8,4), our collected sample will not be N(8,4). This sampling error will create errors in our estimates!!

Page 51: Economics of the Firm

Value = a + b * (Age) + error 20,σNerror

We want to choose ‘a’ and ‘b’ to minimize the error!

a

Slope = b

Page 52: Economics of the Firm

Regression Results

Variable Coefficients Standard Error t Stat

Intercept 12,354 653 18.9

Age - 854 80 -10.60

Value = $12,354 - $854 * (Age) + error

We have our estimate of “the truth”

Intercept (a)

Mean = $12,354

Std. Dev. = $653

Age (b)

Mean = -$854

Std. Dev. = $80

T-Stats bigger than 2 in absolute value are considered statistically significant!

Page 53: Economics of the Firm

Regression Statistics

R Squared 0.36

Standard Error 2250

Error Term

Mean = 0

Std, Dev = $2,250

Percentage of value variance explained by age

Page 54: Economics of the Firm

We can now forecast the value of a 6 year old car

Salary = $12,354 - $854 * (Age) + error

6

Mean = $12,354

Std. Dev. = $653

Mean = $854

Std. Dev. = $ 80

Mean = $0

Std. Dev. = $2,250

errorVarbaXCovbVarXaVarStdDev ,22

bVarXbaCov , (Recall, Shoe size has a mean of 6)

259,2$225080862806653 22222 StdDev

Page 55: Economics of the Firm

8x

+95%

-95%

Age

Value

Note that your forecast error will always be smallest at the sample mean! Also, your forecast gets worse at an increasing rate as you depart from the mean

6Age

Forecast Interval

259,2$225080862806653 22222 StdDev

230,7$6*854354,12 Value

Page 57: Economics of the Firm

The Strategy: Estimate a conditional distribution for Pat Buchanan’s votes using every county EXCEPT Palm Beach

Using Palm Beach data, forecast Pat Buchanan’s vote total for Palm Beach

Page 58: Economics of the Firm

The Data: Demographic Data By County

County Black (%)

Age 65 (%)

Hispanic (%)

College (%)

Income (000s)

Buchanan Votes

Total Votes

Alachua 21.8 9.4 4.7 34.6 26.5 262 84,966

Baker 16.8 7.7 1.5 5.7 27.6 73 8,128

IaCaHaAaBaaPLN 54365221

Parameters to be estimated

Error termBuchanan Votes

Total Votes*100

Page 59: Economics of the Firm

Side note: Why logs?

BP 5.3

P = Buchanan’s Vote PercentageB = Percentage Black

Option #1: Linear

BPLN 5.3

Option #2: Semi –Log Linear

BLNPLN 5.3

Option #3: Log Linear

A 10% increase in the black percentage (say, from 30% to 40%) increases Pat Buchanan’s vote percentage by 5% (Say, from 1% to 6%)

A 10% increase in the black percentage (say, from 30% to 40%) increases Pat Buchanan’s vote percentage by 5% (Say, from 1% to 1(1.05) = 1.05%)

A 10% increase in the black percentage (say, from 30% 30(1.10) = 33% increases Pat Buchanan’s vote percentage by 5% (Say, from 1(1.05) = 1.05%)

Page 60: Economics of the Firm

The Results:

Variable Coefficient Standard Error t - statistic

Intercept 2.146 .396 5.48

Black (%) -.0132 .0057 -2.88

Age 65 (%) -.0415 .0057 -5.93

Hispanic (%) -.0349 .0050 -6.08

College (%) -.0193 .0068 -1.99

Income (000s) -.0658 .00113 -4.58

Now, we can make a forecast!

ICHABPLN 0658.0193.0349.0415.0132.146.2 65

Page 61: Economics of the Firm

County Black (%)

Age 65 (%)

Hispanic (%)

College (%)

Income (000s)

Buchanan Votes

Total Votes

Palm Beach 21.8 23.6 9.8 22.1 33.5 3,407 431,621

004.2PLN

%134.004.2 eP

578621,43100134. This would be our prediction for Pat Buchanan’s vote total!

ICHABPLN 0658.0193.0349.0415.0132.146.2 65

Page 62: Economics of the Firm

Probability

LN(%Votes)

There is a 95% chance that the log of Buchanan’s vote percentage lies in this range

-2.004 – 2*(.2556) -2.004 + 2*(.2556)= -2.5152 = -1.4928

004.2PLN We know that the log of Buchanan’s vote percentage is distributed normally with a mean of -2.004 and with a standard deviation of .2556

Page 63: Economics of the Firm

Probability

% of Votes

There is a 95% chance that Buchanan’s vote percentage lies in this range

%134.004.2 eP

%08.5152.2 e %22.4928.1 e

Next, lets convert the Logs to vote percentages

Page 64: Economics of the Firm

Probability

Votes

There is a 95% chance that Buchanan’s total vote lies in this range

348621,4310008. 970621,4310022.

Finally, we can convert to actual votes 578621,43100134.