Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

download Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

of 41

Transcript of Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    1/41

    1

    ANALYSING THE EVOLUTION OF INDUSTRY: THE

    RELEVANCE OF THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY1

    Martin Fransman

    Department of Economics and

    Institute for Japanese-European Technology Studies

    University of Edinburgh

    25 Buccleuch Place

    Edinburgh EH8 9LN

    Phone: +44-131-650-4061

    Fax: +44-131-667-4340

    e-mail: [email protected]

    1 Several scholars have influenced this study, though are not implicated by its conclusions. Dick Nelsonand the group working with him on the long term evolution of a number of key industries have, throughtheir discussions, helped me to formulate and clarify some of the issues discussed here. Brian Loasby, alsothrough discussion, has stimulated my thinking and influenced the direction of my thought. SteveKleppers work on industrial shakeouts and Dick Langlois and Paul Robertsons on modular systems andthe economics of networks have also been sources of stimulation. Finally, I am endebted to the work of

    G.B. Richardson, particularly his 1972 article in The Economic Journal.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    2/41

    2

    There is a fundamental unity of action between the laws of nature in thephysical and moral world. This central unity is set forth in the general rule, towhich there are not very many exceptions, that the development of the organism,whether social or physical, involves an increasing subdivision of functionsbetween its separate parts on the one hand, and on the other a more intimateconnection between them. Each part gets to be less and less self-sufficient, todepend for its wellbeing more and more on the other parts, so that any disorder inany part of a highly-developed organism will affect other parts also.

    This increased subdivision of functions, or differentiation, as it is called,manifests itself with regard to industry in such forms as the division of labour,and the development of specialised skill, knowledge and machinery: whileintegration, that is, a growing intimacy and firmness of the connectionsbetween the separate parts of the industrial organism, shows itself in such formsas the increase of security of commercial credit, and of the means and habits of

    communication by sea and road, by railway and telegraph, by post and printing-press. (p.201)

    we say broadly that while the part which nature plays in production shows atendency to diminishing return, the part which man plays shows a tendency toincreasing return. The law of increasing return may be worded thus: An increasein labour and capital leads generally to improved organization, which increasesthe efficiency of the work of labour and capital. (p. 265, emphasis added)

    Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics.

    INTRODUCTION

    What does an analysis of the telecommunications industry have to offer the growing

    literature on industry evolution from an evolutionary/institutional perspective? The first

    answer is that it provides another example of industry evolution to compare with the

    increasing number of industries that are receiving attention from this perspective. A

    number of scholars have called for just such an extension. For example, reacting to the

    strong body of literature in this field which emphasizes the product life cycle model and

    the related concept of a dominant design in a number of industries, Nelson (1998) has

    argued: Some writers clearly believe [that the applicability of these ideas is] universal.

    I confess some skepticism about that. The story seems to fit best industries where the

    product is a system, and where customers have similar demands. It is not at all clear if

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    3/41

    3

    the notion of a dominant design fits the experience of the chemical products industry

    where often a variety of quite different products are produced for similar uses, or

    pharmaceuticals where customer needs are divergent and specialized. (p.324) Theimplication is that more detailed studies are needed of other industries, a point that is

    supported by Klepper (1997) who has made major contributions to this literature:

    Additional products need to be studied, particularly less traditional products whose

    evolution might be more likely to depart from the product life cycle. (p.176)2

    A second benefit from studying the evolution of the telecoms industry, as the present

    study emphasizes, follows from the role played in this industry by specialist suppliers.

    Kleppers (1997) study suggests that various processes of specialization may be causally

    connected to the absence of typical product life cycle patterns in a number of industries

    and, correspondingly, to the absence of shakeouts as he defines them, although Klepper

    does not reach any definitive conclusions on this matter. Nevertheless, he concludes that

    a particularly fertile area for further research is tracing the evolution of firm

    specialisation, including the circumstances underlying it, in a range of products.If, in

    fact, the horizontal structure of the market co-evolves with the vertical structure, as the

    review of the products [in this paper] would suggest, then this research would be

    particularly valuable for understanding why some products do not evolve according to the

    product life cycle. (p.177) The present paper deals with the issue of specialisation

    through the study of the telecoms industry.

    Thirdly, the study of the telecoms industry raises in a rather stark way the conceptually

    difficult questions of what is meant by an industry and how we should define that

    industrys boundaries, which in turn will determine the limits of the analysis of any

    industry (i.e. to put it more concretely, what needs to be included, and what can

    legitimately be left out, in an evolutionary analysis of any industry?) An examination of

    the evolutionary/institutional literature reveals that, while the concepts of the firm and

    market are widely used (even though on closer inspection there is often lack of clarity

    2 The implicit equation of product and industry in the quotation is an issue that is taken up later in this

    paper.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    4/41

    4

    or even overt disagreement regarding what is meant with the use of these concepts), and

    while there is a well-developed literature on the boundaries of the firm, the same cannot

    be said for industry and industry boundaries. This matter is closely related to that ofthe level of aggregation that is appropriate in the evolutionary analysis of industries

    (whether the analysis is statistical or formal-theoretical or appreciative-theoretical) that

    Dosi, Malerba, and Orsenigo (1997) have recently raised: there is a problem of

    interpretation of statistical data and in particular of aggregation. The data that are

    available and the regularities that are observed refer actually to entities and phenomena

    that are defined at different levels of aggregation and at different time scales. For

    example, in the life cycle approach, the emphasis is sometimes on narrowly defined

    products and other times on industries. But how would this approach consider, for

    example, mainframes and personal computers? Are they to be taken as different products

    with distinct life cycles or as variants of the same basic product and of the same life

    cycle? Probably the interpretation of patterns of evolution would turn out to be quite

    different in the two cases. (p.17)

    Other examples of aggregation problems also need to be considered. For instance, to go

    back to our earlier quotation from Klepper regarding the importance of specialisation, is

    it necessary to include an analysis of specialist suppliers, if they exist, in order to

    understand the evolution of even an industry that is narrowly defined around a product?

    The issue of appropriate industry boundaries is obviously central here. For example, in

    one of the few studies that explicitly poses the problem of industry boundary his

    subheading reads Defining The Boundaries Of The Traded Software Industry

    Mowery (1996) opts for traded software in three areas: operating systems, applications

    tools, and applications solutions. But this, as he points out, presents problems. To begin

    with, determining the boundaries between computer services and computer software,

    even in the traded software sector, may be virtually impossible. (p.5) Even more

    problematical is his observation that Rapid hardware diffusionhas tended to erode

    vertical integration between hardware and software and until recently appears to have

    reduced the competitive significance of economies of scope among different standardized

    applications, limiting the tendencies toward producer concentration that might otherwise

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    5/41

    5

    be even stronger in an industry such as this, whose costs are primarily

    fixed.[Furthermore,] the expanding installed base of ever cheaper computers has been

    an important source of dynamism in and entry into the traded software industry. (p.6)

    For these and other reasons, Mowery concludes that applications software is an example

    of an industry that does not adhere to a model of technology life cyclesin which the

    emergence of a dominant design in an industry is followed by a gradual decline in

    entry. (p.11) These issues, it seems, raise in stark form the question of where the

    boundaries of this particular industry should be drawn, and, if appropriate boundaries

    are thought to be problem-contingent, what kinds of problems require what kinds of

    boundaries. For example, Groves (1996) account of the new horizontal computer

    industry and its boundaries driven by his own purpose to make sense of the

    competition problems that Intel faces - includes not only operating systems and

    application software in his definition of the industry, but also semiconductors and sales

    and distribution.

    As these examples make clear, a key question is how far we need to go in terms of the

    boundary that is appropriate for the analysis of any industry. This question is central in

    the present study of the telecoms industry. The approach that is taken here, to anticipate

    the crux of this paper, is that this question can only be answered with reference to what

    Schumpeter has called (though in a more general context) the prime movers or

    fundamental impulses or engines of the system3. It is not claimed, however, that this

    approach offers a panacea. Apart from the additional complexity that it adds, it raises the

    difficult problem of how the industrys dynamics or driving forces are to be identified.

    At present, the authors only answer to this problem is that a good deal of knowledge of

    the industry is necessary. But this, clearly, is inadequate in view of the interpretive

    ambiguity that is likely to arise, even among those knowledgeable about the industry,

    regarding what the driving forces of the industry are.

    3

    Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (1966), p.82-3.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    6/41

    6

    THE EVOLUTION OF THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY

    The analysis of the evolution of the telecoms industry is divided into two parts. In thefirst, the evolution of the industry is briefly described. The second part contains an

    analysis of the dynamics or driving forces of the industry as well as an analysis of the

    implications for industrial structure.

    PART ONE: DESCRIBING THE EVOLVING TELECOMMUNICATIONS

    INDUSTRY

    Natural Monopolies With Different Forms Of Organization Governing The Relationship

    Between Carriers And Their Suppliers

    Until the 1980s the conventional wisdom was that the telecoms industry should be

    regarded as a natural monopoly. This meant that for reasons of efficiency, namely the

    primacy of economies of scale, telecommunications services should be provided by a

    single monopoly carrier. Although this was the conventional wisdom in all countries,

    fundamentally different forms of organization evolved governing the relationship

    between the government-owned monopoly telecoms carrier and the supplier/s of its

    equipment (mainly switches and transmissions systems). Amongst those countries that

    were industrially large and sophisticated enough to have their own telecoms equipment

    suppliers, the U.S. and Japan represented the polar extremes.

    More specifically, while vertical integration was the dominant form of organization in the

    U.S., a characteristic that was only to end in September 1995 when AT&T voluntarily

    trivested itself, in Japan a cooperative form of organization evolved whereby a family

    of four main suppliers catered for the needs of the monopoly carrier, NTT. Britain was

    more similar to the Japanese pattern, although its experience with cooperation was not

    nearly as happy as the Japanese. (For an analysis of the origins of these different forms

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    7/41

    7

    of organization, see Fransman (1995).4 Most smaller industrialized countries (Sweden

    being a major exception) and developing countries, lacking indigenous equipment

    companies, obtained their telecoms equipment from the major global suppliers whocompeted vigorously in these markets.

    Dynamism Under Natural Monopoly

    Whilst the conventionally-trained economist might suppose that the industrial structure

    just described would be un-innovative and inefficient, it is worth stressing that this was

    not the case. For example, the real cost and price of calls tended to fall significantly in

    most countries, telecommunications services were rapidly diffused and included universal

    service, and, most significantly, there was a rapid rate of both incremental and radical

    innovation. Indeed, most of the fundamental innovations that are driving the so-called

    Information and Communications Revolution of the 1990s were made during the natural

    monopoly period up to the mid-1990s. Examples include digital switching, optical fiber

    (although some of the fundamental breakthroughs came from the glass industry), digital

    transmissions systems, cellular mobile systems, packet-switched networks (though some

    of the key initial innovations come from the computer community), and satellite

    communications.

    Why was there so much innovation under natural monopoly? Part of the answer has to

    do with the success of long term fundamental but mission-oriented research undertaken in

    places like AT&Ts Bell Laboratories, NTTs Electrical Communications Laboratories,

    BTs Martlesham Laboratories, and France Telecoms CNET. Another part of the

    answer lies in the non-market competition, but competition nevertheless, that existed

    between the carriers of the major countries and their laboratories, vying for the prestige

    of being first and best in particular areas. Coinciding with this competition were

    4 G. B. Richardsons (1972) comment are relevant apropos this apparently conflicting choice of form oforganization in the U.S. and Japan: Theories of industrial organization, it seems to me, should not try todo too much. Arguments designed to prove the inevitability of this or that particular form of organizationare hard to reconcile, not only with the difference between the capitalist and socialist worlds, but also withthe differences that exist within each of these. We do not find the same organization of industryin the

    United States and Japan. We ought to think in terms of the substitutability of industrial structures. (p.896)

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    8/41

    8

    important forms of international cooperation, such as the regular international switching

    conferences, which were important sources of information and stimulated processes of

    search and experimentation.

    A further part of the explanation lies in the political and other pressures that were put on

    national carriers to improve their provision of telecoms services which were, after all,

    vital, though in different ways, for everyone. Finally, the institutions of regulation were

    also important. In addition to constituting a source of pressure for improvement,

    regulation also helped to make knowledge created in the telecoms industry more open

    than it would have been in a market-regulated industry. One notable example is

    AT&T/Western Electrics patents for the transistor which were made almost freely

    available to whoever wanted them (including small and then-insignificant companies like

    Sony). (See Fransman (1995) for further details.)

    Part-Liberalization In Some Countries From The Mid-1980s

    In the mid-1980s a sea-change occurred with part-liberalization of the telecoms industry

    in the U.S., Japan and Britain. In the U.S. AT&T was broken up into one long-distance

    company, the reconstituted AT&T, and seven regional holding companies providing

    regional services, the so-called Baby Bells. Furthermore, long-distance competition was

    admitted with MCI and Sprint being the main original new-entrants. In Japan, three long-

    distance competitors emerged to challenge NTT, namely DDI, Japan Telecom, and

    Teleway Japan. In the U.K. a duopoly was established with Mercury, a subsidiary of

    Cable and Wireless, as the new entrant.

    However, although some competition was introduced, the liberalization was only partial.

    While there was some competition in long-distance services it was limited by regulatory

    restrictions on the number of new entrants and the absence of regulations requiring the

    incumbent to open its networks to interconnection by new entrants at cost-based prices.

    In general, local access (access to offices and homes) and local services remained

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    9/41

    9

    monopolized by the incumbents. International accounting rate agreements ensured that

    international rates were determined by an international oligopoly of national incumbents.

    Although liberalization was only partial, this stage produced some important structural

    changes that were to become important influences shaping the further evolution of the

    telecoms industry. Amongst these were the new business opportunities that were opened

    up, largely for powerful national business organizations hitherto denied openings in the

    telecoms industry. As Douglas North (1996) has argued, organizations such as these are

    also action groups which, through their actions, drive institutional change. And this

    they did, helping to shape the new rules of the game that influenced the subsequent

    evolution of the telecoms industry.5

    The Context Provided By The Information And Communications Revolution

    The decade from the mid-1980s was marked by an explosion in demand for new

    information and communication products and services. From the point of view of the

    telecoms industry, most important were mobile telecoms services and the Internet. Both

    created rapid growth in relatively new markets and at the same time generated new

    business opportunities for incumbents, original new entrants, and new new entrants

    alike. From the late 1990s, the Internet became particularly important and, indeed,

    became a new paradigm within both the communications and the information industries.

    5 Institutions are the rules of the game of a society or more formally are the humanly-devised constraintsthat structure human interaction. They are composed of formal rules (statute law, common law,regulations), informal constraints (conventions, norms of behavior, and self imposed codes of conduct), and

    the enforcement characteristics of both. Organizations, too, specify the constraints that structure humaninteraction inside the organization but in addition they are action groups. They are composed of groups ofindividuals bound by a common purpose to achieve objectives. They include [firms and other economic,political, social, and educational bodies]. Organizations in pursuit of their objectives are the primarysource of institutional change. (North, 1996, p.12, emphasis added) While there are many problems withNorths conceptualization of institutions and organizations, for present purposes they are useful largelybecause they allow a causal connection to be made between the economics of new entry (expected marketshare, rates of return etc) and the political processes that accompany new entry and the possibility of newentry. These political processes in turn structure the institutions, in Norths sense, which have played animportant role in shaping the evolution of the industry. Key issues in the industry, such as how the industryshould be regulated, how regulation should change over time, what specific regulations are needed, howregulation itself should be organized, who should be given licenses to operate and according to whatcriteria, etc are examples of institutional change in the Northian sense, all of which are subject to

    determining political processes.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    10/41

    10

    Based on the triad of technologies contained in packet-switching, IP (internet protocol),

    and the World Wide Web, the Internet, as is discussed later, provided an alternative

    infrastructure for most telecoms services, including services such as voice and video-conferencing.6 The rapid growth in markets, the improvement of existing technologies

    and the emergence of new substitute ones helped to fuel new entry and intensified

    competition in the industry.

    Further Liberalisation And Globalisation

    The latter 1990s saw a further round of liberalisation, this time on a global scale. In the

    U.S. the Telecommunications Act was passed in 1996 with the intention of introducing

    competition at the regional and local levels (although this legislation soon became

    bogged down in litigation as the Baby Bells successfully challenged the attempt to prise

    open their markets). From January 1st 1998 the European Union officially opened all its

    telecoms markets to competition (some markets having been opened earlier) although in

    practice liberalisation is not yet complete in a few of the major European countries while

    other countries were given extra time to liberalise. In 1997 the World Trade Organisation

    (WTO) concluded an international agreement committing most countries in the world to

    telecoms liberalisation.

    Equally importantly, for the first time incumbents such as AT&T, NTT 7, BT, Deutsche

    Telecom, and France Telecom began to globalise their activities and become new new

    entrants in each others markets. Furthermore, with the notable exception of NTT, a

    latecomer to the global race, these incumbents also established global alliances aimed at

    providing multinational corporations with end-to-end services.

    The late 1980s and early 1990s also saw the emergence of new breeds of new new

    entrants. Two groups are particularly important. The first consists of industrial

    companies and utilities that saw the growth and liberalisation of the telecoms industry as

    6 For further details see Fransman (1998b).7 The complicated situation in Japan which in December 1996 resulted in the decision to allow Japans

    largest carrier, NTT, to globalize is examined in Fransman (1997a and b).

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    11/41

    11

    an opportunity for profitable diversification. The second group is made up of

    entrepreneurs, usually without any background whatever in telecommunications, financed

    by venture capital financial institutions8

    . The modus operandi of the entry of both thesegroups, facilitated by one of the most important dynamic characteristics of the telecoms

    industry, is analysed in the following section.

    By 1995, as is shown in Figure 1, the size of the global telecommunications market was

    estimated to be $519 billion (the table also showing the most important sub-markets).

    PART TWO: THE DYNAMICS OF THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS INDUSTRY

    The main argument of the present paper is that there are five determinants that together

    constitute the driving forces behind the evolution of the telecoms industry and therefore

    determine its dynamics. These five factors also determine the structure of the telecoms

    industry. In this paper the definition of industrial structure suggested in Afuah and

    Utterback (1997) is followed, namely to refer to barriers to entry, the nature and sources

    of substitutes, the number and kinds of rivals, suppliers and customers (p.184). (The

    important problem of the meaning and definition of industry, industrial structure and

    industry boundary is considered further in the conclusion to this paper. 9)

    DYNAMIC 1: QUASI-VERTICAL SPECIALISATION

    THE SIGNIFICANCE OF SPECIALIST SUPPLIERS

    The present organisation of the telecoms industry may be described as one of quasi-

    vertical specialisation. One of the most important characteristics of the industrialorganisation of the telecoms industry is the role played by specialised equipment and

    software suppliers. As noted in the last section, the equipment suppliers evolved in

    8 To return to Norths definition of institutions, reference here, strictly speaking, should be to financialorganizations. However, as is shown later, the role played by capital markets in the evolution of thetelecoms industry constitutes one of the crucial rules of the game (in a general, rather than game-theoreticsense) under which the industry is evolving. Therefore, capital markets may also be thought of asinstitutions in the Northian sense.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    12/41

    12

    different ways in different countries. In Japan and Europe, although the monopoly

    telecoms carrier did a significant amount of equipment-related R&D, the activities of

    equipment research, design and development were, from the outset, left largely tospecialist equipment companies. It was in this way that companies like NEC, Fujitsu,

    Ericsson, Alcatel and Siemens emerged as telecoms equipment suppliers (although all of

    these companies are diversified beyond the telecoms equipment market). In different

    countries, however, the pattern of co-operation between telecoms carrier and equipment

    supplier/s differed. In Japan, for example, right from the outset in the late 1800s the

    Ministry of Communications insisted on a degree of competition between its suppliers, a

    form of industrial organisation that has been referred to as controlled competition10. In

    Germany, on the other hand, Siemens was in effect the only supplier to the Deutsche

    Bundespost and did the lions share of telecoms R&D.

    In the U.S., however, "from the time that Alexander Graham Bell co-operated with

    instrument-maker Thomas Watson in producing the first telephone sets, it was the same

    organisation that both developed the telecommunications network and developed and

    manufactured the equipment that it required. This pattern was firmly established in 1880,

    when the American Bell Telephone Company purchased Western Unions telephone

    supplying subsidiary, the Western Electric Company of Chicago. According to an 1882

    agreement, American Bell restricted itself to purchasing all its telephone equipment from

    Western Electric, while the latter agreed to limit its activities to supplying American Bell

    and its licensees.11 This vertical integration of network operation and equipment

    production in AT&T continued until the companys voluntary trivestiture in September

    1995 into one company providing telecoms services, the new AT&T, one providing

    equipment, Lucent, and one providing computers and computer services, essentially the

    former NCR that had been acquired in a hostile take-over by AT&T in 1993.

    9 In the conclusion it is suggested that there is no consensus in the literature regarding the meaning anddefinition of these terms and that this may be a drawback for the analysis of industry evolution. Somesuggestions are made using the present example of the telecoms industry.10 See Fransman (1995).11

    See Fransman (1995), p.24.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    13/41

    13

    Why these different forms of industrial organisation in the different countries? The basic

    problem that needed to be solved, as G. B. Richardson (1972) has analysed, was one of

    organising complementary but dissimilar activities (dissimilar in the sense that networkoperation, on the one hand, and equipment design and manufacture on the other, required

    different sets ofcapabilities12). That in AT&T these activities were organised inside the

    same company, while in Japan and Europe they were separated in different companies, is

    a reflection of Richardsons observation that It will be clear, in some situations, that co-

    ordination has to be accompanied by direction [i.e. within a firm], by co-operation or

    through market transactions, but there will be many others in which the choice will be

    difficult13. It is worth adding, however, that apart from AT&T in the U.S., in all the

    other countries the form of organisation adopted for co-ordinating the activities of

    network operators and equipment providers was one of co-operation (in Richardsons

    sense14) rather than a market-based relationship.15

    Distribution Of R&D Between Carriers And Specialist Equipment Suppliers

    With the increasing intensity of competition in the 1990s has come a tendency for a

    greater proportion of telecoms industry R&D to be undertaken in equipment companies,

    rather than carriers. In 1995, for example, while the global top eight carriers (including

    NTT, AT&T, Deutsche Telecom, France Telecom and BT) spent a total of $7.5 billion on

    12 I follow Afuah and Utterback (1997) here in making competencies + firm-specific assets = capabilitiesor resources [in the Penrosian sense], p.183.13 Richardson (1972), p.896.14 According to Richardson (1972), The essence of co-operative arrangementswould seem to be the fact

    that the parties to them accept some degree of obligation and therefore give some degree of assurance with respect to their future conduct. But there is certainly room for infinite variation in the scope of suchassurances and in the degree of formality with which they are expressed. (p.886). In Fransman (1995) Ihave analyzed in detail the form of co-operative organization that evolved in the Japanese telecomsindustry, which I called controlled competition.15 This raises the question of the causes behind AT&Ts voluntary trivestiture in September 1995, whichresulted in the U.S. falling in line with Japan and Europe in this aspect of its industrial organization of itstelecoms industry. While this matter is too complex to analyze fully here, it is worth noting that one of thereasons officially given by AT&T for the trivestiture was the difficulty that its equipment divisions werehaving in trying to sell equipment to AT&Ts competitors who in some cases suspected that these divisionswould give competitive preference to their mother company. It is likely, however, that a related reason wasthe realization that as an independent company the equipment divisions (that later became Lucent) wouldbe able to take greater advantage of economies of specialization. In addition, the trivestiture allowed the

    management of AT&T to give greater focus to the companys core telecoms services businesses.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    14/41

    14

    R&D, the top eight equipment companies (including Lucent, Ericsson, Northern

    Telecom, Siemens, Motorola, and NEC) spent $23.4 billion.

    The Emergence Of Specialist Data Networking Equipment Suppliers

    A significant new trend that emerged from the late 1980s, on the back of the explosion of

    Internet-related demand, was the rapid growth of a new breed of companies producing

    data networking equipment for the Internet and IP (internet protocol) networks more

    generally. Many of these new companies emerged through the activities of individuals

    involved in designing and building the early computer networks, like the ARPANET, that

    led to the development of the Internet. These companies include Cisco, 3Com, Bay

    Networks, and Cabletron. It is highly significant that in 1996 these four companies

    together spent $9.6 billion on R&D, compared to the $7.5 billion spent the previous year

    by the top eightcarriers (NTT, AT&T etc). Cisco, the largest of them, only started in late

    1984 as a venture by a group of Stanford University computer scientists. By March

    1998, Cisco had grown into the third-largest company on Wall Street; with a market

    value of $71 billion it was worth more than General Motors, making it the fastest-

    growing technology firm in history16. Significantly, although some of the major

    telecoms-related companies claimed that they had successfully integrated computer

    competencies into their portfolio of competencies this was the official reason AT&T

    acquired NCR, and the Japanese companies NEC and Fujitsu were both computer and

    telecoms equipment producers none of them has made much headway in the rapidly

    growing markets for data networking equipment.17

    16 The Economist, March 28th, 1998, p.98.17 The difficulties that established firms often have in reconfiguring their competencies and routines inorder to produce new products competitively is now a well-established finding in the evolutionary literatureon firms (see, for example, Henderson and Clark, 1990). In this case the firms concerned (e.g.AT&T/NCR, NEC, Fujitsu) were significant players in computer markets, in addition to having importantcompetencies in communications networking, and a rigorous story still needs to be told to explain why theyfailed to enter successfully the markets for data networking equipment. It is likely that an important part ofthis story will be the significance of the circuit-switching paradigm in traditional telecoms products asopposed to the packet-switching on which the new data networks were based and, in the case of theJapanese companies, the relatively slow adoption of distributed client-server systems and the greater use of

    proprietary mainframe platforms.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    15/41

    15

    The Emergence Of Specialist Software Suppliers

    Also important to the dynamic of competition in the telecoms industry has been theemergence of specialist software suppliers. For instance, it has become apparent that

    billing systems can play an important role in the competitive struggle. One famous

    example is the Friends and Family option offered by MCI in a bid to attract customers

    away from the dominant incumbent, AT&T (which involved offering cheaper rates on a

    few frequently-called numbers). Billing systems can offer customers more information

    about the services they are using and how they are charged, which may allow a carrier to

    differentiate its product. More generally, billing systems can be integrated with the

    carriers other information systems, such as network operation and management, giving

    the carrier far more details about customer behaviour and therefore allowing for a more

    sophisticated marketing of customised service packages. These packages, in addition to

    the conventional fixed-wire voice service could also include mobile service, Internet

    access, video-phone, as well as home banking and shopping.

    The Consequences For Industrial Structure Of The Availability Of Specialist Suppliers

    The availability of specialist suppliers is a particularly important determinant of industrial

    structure (as defined above) and it is for this reason that it has been singled out as one of

    the main driving forces in the telecoms industry. What impact does the availability of

    specialist suppliers have on the structure of the industry?

    The first effect is on entry barriers. More specifically, while barriers such as the amount

    and cost of capital needed for entry, management and marketing competencies,

    regulations, and brand name and reputation of the incumbent remain, the availability of

    specialist suppliers has significantly lowered technology barriers. Original new

    entrants, such as MCI in the U.S., DDI in Japan, and Mercury in Britain, as well as new

    new entrants like WorldCom and Quest in the U.S. and Energis, Colt, Ionica and Esprit

    in Britain, have been able to enter to begin with without any R&D capability to speak of.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    16/41

    16

    Two processes, both emerging from the specialist suppliers, have facilitated this

    technological ease of entry. The first process has involved both the sale of telecoms

    equipment and software to the new entrants as well as significant development work doneon their behalf to customise equipment and software systems to meet the entrants

    specific requirements.18 The second process works through labour markets and involves

    the entrant hiring staff who have accumulated knowledge, skill and experience in a

    specialist supplying company and who accordingly are able to operate, manage, and

    develop the new entrants network. These two processes, working together, have

    considerably eased the entry process. The contrast with other industries, such as motor

    cars, where technological and organisational barriers are far higher, is great.

    The second component of industrial structure defined earlier is the nature and sources

    of substitutes. Here too the specialist suppliers have played a key role. Several

    examples will highlight this point. One example is Voice-on-the-Internet (VOI), a

    substitute for conventional telephony over circuit-switched lines, which with its far lower

    costs (the result of Internet tariffing) is already beginning to reduce standard telephone

    charges by the established carriers. Some estimates suggest that by 2002 as much as 13

    percent of voice calls may be made over the Internet19. VOI was pioneered in 1995 by a

    small Israeli-owned start-up called Vocaltec. Vocaltec is now working with Deutsche

    Telecom in Germany to introduce VOI.

    A second example is a possibly radical breakthrough called Power Line. Essentially,

    Power Line involves the provision of data communications, including VOI and Internet

    access, through the electric power cables that are already connected to firms and homes,

    thus avoiding the need to dig up streets (as with optical fibre cables) or establish radio

    base stations (as with mobile or fixed radio access connections). Power Line works

    through radio frequencies being transmitted through electric power cables. Relatively

    18 In a personal interview, a senior executive from WorldCom explained to me how the company, which in1997 achieved global prominence when it snatched MCI away from BT in a takeover bit, while doingvirtually no R&D, works extremely closely with traditional suppliers like Northern Telecom and Alcateland new suppliers like Cienna. The size of WorldComs network and its buying power guarantees it theclosest attention from its suppliers with the result that the company does not feel it necessary to make in-house R&D a priority.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    17/41

    17

    cheap enabling technology is required at the electricity substation (serving 250 homes)

    and at the customers electricity meter. The original innovation was made by an engineer

    working with Norweb, the electricity company that supplies the Manchester andYorkshire areas of Britain. (Apparently, the engineer persisted with his research after

    being told my his managers that the project was not feasible and should be ended.) In the

    event, Norweb obtained the commanding patents for Power Line. However, Norweb,

    lacking the technological competencies, also entered into a strategic alliance with

    Northern Telecom (Nortel), the established Canadian telecoms equipment company

    which went on to develop the necessary technology to make Power Line both

    technologically and economically feasible. Although it is too soon to tell whether this

    new technology will be a serious substitute for other alternative telecoms transmission

    and local access technologies (Norweb and Nortel claim that it is significantly cheaper

    than the other alternatives), the example is a good illustration of the importance of

    specialist suppliers as a force driving the dynamics of the telecoms industry.

    The third component of industrial structure is the number and kinds of rivals [and]

    suppliers. From what has already been said it is clear that the specialist suppliers have

    had, and are continuing to have, a significant impact on this component too. The fourth

    and final component, customers, are dealt with below.

    The Question Of Shakeout

    Specialist equipment suppliers also have important implications for another aspect of

    industrial structure, not included in the definition we have used here by Afuah and

    Utterback (1997) but emphasised by Klepper (1997) and Klepper and Simons (1997),

    namely the process of shakeoutwhich was briefly discussed in the introduction to this

    paper. More specifically, by making most of the network technologies available to all

    entrants able to pay the market price, specialist suppliers may have circumvented a major

    19

    Business Week, April 6, 1998, p.49.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    18/41

    18

    source of shakeout20 that has occurred in industries such as motor cars, tires, televisions,

    and penicillin, namely increasing returns to innovation, which may accrue to the early-

    entering incumbents. Correspondingly, the availability of specialist suppliers and theaccess to technologies that they supply has also had the effect of shifting the thrust of

    competitive strategies away from equipment-oriented R&D towards the achievement of

    other objectives such as service differentiation (that may depend on software

    development), speed of response to market opportunities, reliability of services, security,

    etc.

    The issue of shakeout, however, raises an intriguing question regarding the future

    evolution of the telecoms industry, namely, will this industry experience shakeout as

    defined here? With the liberalisation and globalisation of telecoms markets there has

    been a significant increase in net entry (i.e. entry minus exit) of firms. In Britain, for

    example, by 1998 the national regulator, Oftel, had granted 20 licenses to fixed link

    public telecommunications operators (which included companies like WorldCom, AT&T,

    Deutsche Telecom, France Telecom, and NTT), 56 licenses to international facilities-

    based services operators, and 78 licenses to international simple resale operators (who

    provide services based on capacity leased from other carriers).21 (These figures exclude

    entrants into the mobile, cable, and satellite markets.) How will net entry change over the

    next five years? How many of the players will be left in the market in five years time?

    These are key questions requiring an understanding of the dynamics of the industry.

    Klepper and Simons (1997) conclude that

    Our findings suggest that shakeouts are not triggered by particular

    technological developments but are part of an evolutionary process that is

    driven by continual technological change. Technological innovation

    20 According to Klepper (1997) a product [i.e. industry] is deemed notto have experienced a shakeout ifthe number of firms never declined below 70% of the peak number, or if it did but subsequently recoveredto over 90% of the peak. (p.165)21 Authors calculation based on data from Oftel. As far as the author is aware, there are no reliablestatistics regarding net entry rates for the major industrialized countries. One of the problems regarding

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    19/41

    19

    apparently contributes to a mounting dominance by some of an industrys

    early-entering firms which eventually makes entry untenable and steadily

    drives out smaller firms with relatively high costs and low quality.(p.381, emphasis added)

    While the process of full competition has not been going long enough in the telecoms

    industry for this industry to provide further evidence against which to test this

    Klepper/Simons hypothesis, from the ex ante viewpoint of the present it seems at least

    possible that, whether or not a shakeout as technically defined here emerges in the future,

    the presence of specialist equipment and software suppliers will limit mounting

    dominance by some of the industrys early-entering firms and will provide increased

    viable options for smaller firms by providing them with both cost and quality competitive

    advantages. In short, it may well turn out that the telecoms industry is more in line with

    the second group of industries referred to in Klepper (1997, p. 168-174) which do not

    conform to the conventional product life cycle pattern of entry and exit and which do not

    experience shakeouts as defined, industries that include petrochemicals. Significantly, as

    Klepper notes, these latter industries are also characterised by the presence of specialised

    suppliers of one sort or another, though not necessarily confined to equipment suppliers.

    DYNAMIC 2: FOUR KINDS OF COMPETITION

    Many of the applications of the product life cycle model to the evolution of particular

    industries have emphasised the importance of technical change as a driving force (see,

    e.g. Klepper (1997), Klepper and Simons (1997), Utterback and Abernathy (1975),

    Utterback and Suarez (1993), and Afuah and Utterback (1997). Particular attention has

    been paid to the process of convergence around a dominant design in product technical

    change and, once this has occurred, to the priority assigned to process technical change.

    Although competition between technologies is undoubtedly an important part of both

    these statistics is that they should measure effective entry i.e. refer to firms that have not only been

    granted licenses but have made credible entry into telecoms markets.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    20/41

    20

    product and process technical change, this competition per se has not received

    prominence in most of the explanations.

    In the present analysis of the telecoms industry, however, it will be argued that

    competition between technologies is so important as to constitute the second dynamic

    driving the evolution of the industry. But competition between technologies, as will be

    shown, is also intricately tied up with competition between networks and competition

    between services, as well as the more conventionally recognised competition between

    firms.

    Complementarity Between Technologies And Network Assets

    Although there are always specific technologies embodied in network assets, it is

    necessary to separate conceptually network assets from the ongoing process of technical

    change because they (i.e. the assets) are often the object of further technical change. The

    example of asynchronous digital subscriber line (ADSL) technology illustrates this point

    as well as highlighting some of the processes driving the co-evolution of technologies,

    firm strategies and competition.

    One of the main advantages enjoyed by the incumbent telecoms operators is their existing

    extensive networks with greater geographical coverage than any of the entrants, whether

    original new entrants or new new entrants. These networks, however, embody different

    generations of technologies that are, nevertheless, designed to be compatible and

    interoperable with one another. Accordingly, while part of the incumbents networks are

    state of the art (for example, using digital or ATM asynchronous transfer mode -

    switching and SDH/SONET transmissions), other parts consist of old technology, such as

    the copper cables that still connect the metaphorical last mile to most homes. Although

    the upside to the use of these old technologies and the assets in which they are embodied

    is the low fixed cost of using fully-depreciated assets (albeit counterbalanced by possibly

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    21/41

    21

    high running costs), the downside is the limited capacity (bandwidth) provided by these

    assets.

    It was in order to address this bottleneck22 that a wave of research was undertaken

    globally, particularly by incumbents, to develop ASDL technology, a technology that at

    first was thought to be of limited relevance. A good deal of this research in the early

    stages, such as that undertaken by BT in conjunction with trials in the vicinity of its

    Martlesham Laboratories, was done in order to establish the viability of ADSL for use in

    a hoped for killer application, namely video-on-demand (VOD) over copper telephone

    lines. As things have turned out, however, much of the demand for VOD appears to be

    still-born but ADSL (now called XDSL, to include later generations of the technology)

    has been significantly improved through a process of rapid incremental change and is

    now seen as a competitive technology for the transmission of data at sufficiently high

    bandwidths to allow, for example, voice and video over the Internet to be received in

    homes where the last mile is connected by copper cables.23

    Competition Between Technologies

    XDSL also provides an example of competition between technologies that, as will shortly

    be shown, is an important driver of other aspects of telecoms industry evolution. The

    main site for the battle between XDSL and its rival technologies is the local access

    market. The crux of the matter is portrayed in the following extract from a partisan paper

    by BT in response to a document by the industrys regulator, Oftel, the paper carrying the

    22 As scholars of innovation and technological systems have noted, techno-economic systems produce aninternal dynamic that influences the innovation process and through it the future evolutionary path of thesystem. This dynamic is created by the incentives and focussing mechanisms that arise in addressingsystemic bottlenecks that impede the systems performance. Tom Hughes uses the military terminology reverse salient to describe this process (see Hughes (1984). A similar analysis is contained in Rosenberg(1976). XDSL provides a telecoms example.23 Interestingly, at the Competitive Carrier Forces conference held in Versailles in March 1998 attended bythe author, one of the main meeting points for members of the industry, XDSL was branded by one of thespeakers as the incumbents technology, and was portrayed as a negative force with the potential toincrease the staying-power of incumbents who were otherwise seen as uncompetitive, bureaucratic,anticompetitive, and reactionary forces in the industry! For present purposes, however, the XDSL exampleprovides an instance of the co-evolution of technologies, firm strategies, competitive process, and industrial

    structure (in terms of the effect on entry, exit, shakeout, the positioning of rivals etc).

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    22/41

    22

    underlying message that BT faces effective competition even in the UK local access

    market which in terms of market share it appears to monopolise with a share of 90

    percent. (This extract also raises the important related issue of the impact of technologieson the definition and boundaries of markets through the effect of the technologies on the

    substitutability of telecoms services.):

    When analysing the market for access from the point of view of the

    customer wishing to obtain access to the telecommunications networks in

    the UK, there are a number of products that can reasonably be regarded as

    substitutable. Analogue lines [based on copper cables], ISDN lines

    [integrated services digital network capable of carrying voice, data, text,

    and video], telephone lines offered by cable TV companies, fixed and

    mobile radio access and PCN [another mobile service] are all currently

    available alternatives. The cost of access to the customer may vary

    depending upon the technology used, and the different means of access

    may be regarded as more or less substitutable, taking into account

    functionality, price and the speed of delivery.the different technologies

    are likely to become more and more substitutable and the degree of

    substitutability over time needs to be taken into account when determining

    whether a number of different alternatives are in the same market, and

    whether that market can be described as competitive. (BT, 1996, p.19)

    While this observation is standard fare for those in the telecoms industry, from the point

    of view of evolutionary analysis the significance lies in the co-evolutionary processes

    that are at work. These processes are worth spelling out at a general level. There are at

    least seven distinct technologies that can be identified which are involved in the process

    of local access. These are: optical fibre, copper/XDSL, co-axial cable TV, fixed radio

    access (which uses radio to provide access on fixed lines), mobile cellular and PCN,

    satellite, and power line (involving the use of electricity cables, as discussed above). The

    first point to make about the co-evolutionary process is that the evolution of each of these

    seven technologies is co-determined by each of the other technologies in that the

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    23/41

    23

    performance parameters that the technology must meet in order to remain viable is

    determined by the performance of the competing technologies. For example, within

    certain cost and price limits, XDSL using copper cables must be able to carry comparablebandwidth to that available over optical fibre or co-axial cables.

    But competition between these technologies is also influenced by the firms (their

    strategies and their competitive fortunes) with a vested interest in the technologys

    development and performance. For instance, as noted in the last footnote, it is the

    incumbents who have a particular interest in increasing the performance of copper cables

    through XDSL since these cables still form an important part of their network. For this

    reason XDSL has been referred to as the incumbents technology. On the other hand,

    new entrants have usually entered on the basis of later generations of technology and

    therefore have different technological vested interests. For example, MCI in the U.S. was

    an early adopter of optical fibre as it rolled out its network to compete with AT&T. In

    Britain, Ionica, a new new entrant based in Cambridge, created its network on the basis

    of fixed radio access, with a radio connection covering the last mile and linking the

    customer to the fixed network. In this case the technology was developed for Ionica by

    Nortel, the Canadian equipment-maker, but clearly Ionica has a vested interest in the

    future progress of fixed radio access technology. (Ionica has recently run into difficulties

    leading to speculation that it may become one of the first major examples of exit in the

    U.K., though these problems have not been specifically technological in nature.) In

    Japan, DDI, the main original new entrant competing with NTT, based its network on

    microwave radio (partly to overcome rights-of-way problems) although the bandwidth

    constraints of this technology subsequently created problems for the company with the

    explosion of Internet and IP (internet protocol) demand for bandwidth.

    From these examples it is clear that the causal influences shaping the evolution of each of

    the technologies are closely bound up with the factors influencing the firms which

    support these technologies. In turn, the evolution of these firms is determined by their

    success in the various selection processes that define winners and losers, an outcome that

    is partly dependent on the capabilities of the firms (i.e. their competencies and

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    24/41

    24

    complementary assets) and the strategies they have formulated. However, while this

    brief and partial account of the co-evolutionary process is very much at the general level,

    far more detailed research is necessary to show precisely how specific technologicalchanges have come about under the influence of the co-evolutionary process.

    Evolutionary studies of industries have thus far, for understandable reasons, generally not

    delved too deeply into this detailed complexity.

    Competition Between Networks

    Telecoms networks are complex systems made up of aggregations of different

    generations of technologies. While in the last section competition between different

    micro-technologies was discussed, it is also necessary, in order to understand the

    dynamic of the telecoms industry, to analyse competition at a higher level of aggregation,

    namely between networks and the services they provide (and are constrained from

    providing). The reason is that in many instances these networks provide alternative ways

    of providing similar services. The networks also complement one another in various

    ways. For this reason it may be suggested that the telecoms industry as a whole may be

    understood as being based on a network of networks, an overarching network consisting

    simultaneously of complementary and competing sub-networks that are interconnected

    and interoperable.

    The Evolution Of Packet-Switched Networks

    An important example illustrating this point is the evolution of packet-switched networks

    that eventually, together with other complementary innovations, facilitated the emergence

    of the Internet, an outcome totally unforeseen by the original creators of these networks.

    Packet-switching is essentially a technology used for the transmission of data. It involves

    the breaking up of data (in the form of bits) into packets which are then given an

    address header enabling the packet to be routed in the way that is most efficient at the

    time, different packets from the same data set possibly taking different routes to the final

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    25/41

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    26/41

    26

    they had already decided to develop a packet-switched network, TRANSPAC, which

    improved rapidly and is the centre-piece today of the companys data network.

    The subsequent evolution of packet-switched networks was influenced by many other

    factors including the PC revolution beginning in the late 1970s and the consequent

    emergence of client-based distributed computing, the related proliferation of local area

    networks connecting computers (LANs), the facilitating evolution of the TCP/IP and

    other protocols, and an explosion in user demand for services such as electronic-mail and

    later World Wide Web applications (which depended on another key complementary

    innovation, namely the technology on which the World Wide Web was built (facilitating

    the subsequent production of Web browsers) originally developed by Tim Berners-Lee at

    the CERN physics laboratory in Switzerland).

    By the mid-1990s, packet-switched networks were able to offer substitutes (with varying

    elasticities of substitution) for most of the services offered by telecoms companies using

    conventional circuit-switched networks. Accordingly, there is currently increasing

    competition between these two kinds of networks. Nevertheless, some important

    distinctions remain as a result of the original purposes served by these networks. More

    specifically, having originally been developed for the purposes of voice communication,

    circuit-switched networks are real-time based and therefore currently offer the best

    quality of voice reception. On the other hand, packet-switched networks, though near-

    real-time, still exhibit a slight delay, the result of packets arriving at different times and

    orders. Whether packet switching and transmission technologies will ever improve so as

    to offer a more perfect substitute for circuit-switched voice remains an open question

    currently.

    For present purposes, this example highlights the role played by competition between

    networks and the services they provide as a driver of the evolutionary process in the

    telecoms industry.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    27/41

    27

    Competition Between Services

    As we have just seen, different networks may support different, competing, services. Afurther example is fixed versus mobile telephony, the latter offered over land or satellite

    based networks. However, there is not necessarily a one-to-one correspondence between

    network competition and services competition. Competing services may also be offered

    on the same network. For example, both packet-switched and circuit-switched networks

    can offer voice, fax, and e-mail services that to some extent, for some purposes, are

    substitutable services. It is for this reason that a conceptual distinction between

    competition between networks and competition between services is necessary. From the

    co-evolutionary point of view, it is clear that the outcome of competition between

    services will have knock-on implications for the relationship between networks and

    technologies.

    Layers Of Competition

    To facilitate the conceptual distinctions required, it is helpful to think of layers of

    competition (the generic layer model, incidentally, playing an important conceptual role

    in telecommunications design thinking more generally). While the lowest layer consists

    of competition between micro-technologies (i.e. the alternative building-blocks of

    telecoms systems), the following layers, in ascending order, consist of competition

    between networks, competition between services, and finally, competition between firms.

    Competition Between Firms

    Competition between firms more specifically, between incumbents, original new

    entrants, and new new entrants may therefore be thought of as overlying the other

    layers of competition. As already stressed, the relationship between the layers is not

    necessarily one-to-one. For example, incumbents may have circuit-switched, packet-

    switched, mobile, and even cable and satellite networks as part of their overall network,

    although new entrants typically have a far narrower range of networks. Similarly,

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    28/41

    28

    different firms will offer different combinations of services and will depend on different

    combinations of technologies. Furthermore, to make matters even more complex, the

    competition between technologies that according to the present layer model takes place inthe technology layer, may also simultaneously take place within the firm layer. This

    happens with inter-technology competition within firms. Examples studied in detail by

    the present writer include the battles between supporters of space-division switching and

    digital time-division switching within firms like AT&T and NTT, which were in

    principle similar to the rivalry that took place between proponents of silicon-based

    semiconductors and III-V compound semiconductors such as gallium arsenide in

    semiconductor firms like NEC, Fujitsu and Toshiba.24 Once again, there are important

    implications of these kinds of competition for the co-evolution of firms, services,

    networks, and technologies.

    DYNAMIC 3: THE ROLE OF FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS

    Financial institutions also play a key role in the dynamics of the telecoms industry,

    particularly in the current phase of rapid expansion, liberalisation and globalisation. In

    the sense of Douglas North (quoted earlier), financial firms play a dual role in the

    evolution of the telecoms industry. On the one hand, they are Northian organisations,

    action groups with their own vested interests, seeking to make profit from financial inter-

    mediation. As action groups, however, they also collectively play a crucial role in

    assigning market values to the competencies and complementary assets of both telecoms

    operators and their specialist suppliers. These market values, based essentially on the

    present value ofexpected25 future net earnings, play a crucial role in the evolution of the

    industry as will shortly be demonstrated. On the other hand, financial firms are also

    24 See Fransman (1995) for details.25 A perennial debate in the telecoms industry, as in all other industries, relates to the rationality of theprocedures financial analysts use in order to arrive at their strong buy/buy/hold/sell recommendations,conclusions which are not necessarily free of self-interest (even if these are explicitly declared) and whichthemselves often come to constitute a key part of the set of information which investors use to make theirbuy and sell decisions, which in turn drive the process of company valuation. The interpretive ambiguity(see Fransman, 1998a) involved in the financial analysts calculations is often manifestly apparent, raisingimportant questions regarding the whole role of financial valuation and its role in industry evolutionary

    processes.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    29/41

    29

    Northian institutions insofar as they influence the rules of the game and the humanly-

    devised constraints that structure human interaction in the telecoms industry.

    The role played by financial institutions in the evolution of the telecoms industry is

    illustrated most dramatically by the case of WorldCom, the new new entrant in the U.S.

    market that rose to global prominence in 1997 when it frustrated BTs attempt to merge

    with MCI, the U.S.s second largest long distance carrier, with a takeover bid for MCI of

    $30 billion. Originally set up in a coffee shop in Hattiesburg, Mississippi in 1983 as

    Long Distance Discount Service (LDDS) WorldCom on its web-site proudly recording

    that this was a name suggested by a waitress [in the coffee shop] the company from

    an early stage, having captured the imagination of financial analysts, was able to grow

    primarily through stock-financed merger and acquisition. By the time it made its bid for

    MCI, WorldCom had already acquired UUNet, the U.S.s largest Internet access

    provider, and MFS a telecoms company providing local access and services largely in

    major financial and business centres around the world. By 1998 it was clear that

    WorldCom - with its strength in the U.S. in local, long distance and international markets,

    as well as Internet traffic, and its rapidly growing global network - arguably posed the

    greatest competitive threat to incumbents like AT&T, NTT, and BT.

    Figure 2 provides data on the ratio of firms market capitalisation to their sales for 1997.

    WorldCom clearly stands out. While the other established players mainly incumbents

    but for the U.S. also including original new entrants MCI and Sprint have a multiple of

    around 2 to 3, World Com enjoys about 5. More recently, in fact, even newer entrants

    such as Quest and Teleport in the U.S. have been given multiples of around 1026

    facilitating similar rapid growth in part through merger and acquisition. In Europe, new

    new entrants like Energis, Colt, and Esprit have been able to play a similar role, though

    on the basis of a market capitalisation that has not been as high as that obtained by the

    U.S. entrants.

    26

    Business Week, April 6, 1998.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    30/41

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    31/41

    31

    The example of voice telephony will be examined briefly to make clearer the

    evolutionary implications of heterogeneous and rapidly changing consumer demand.

    From the beginning, and until relatively recently, voice telephony was confined to arather homogeneous service that is now rather nostalgically referred to in the industry as

    POTS, plain old telephone service. In the days of POTS the main differentiator was

    distance, with different tariffs being charged for local, long-distance, and international

    services. More recently, things have changed radically since one of the main

    implications of the technological advances introduced primarily by optical fibre (with its

    almost unlimited bandwidth) and packet-switching is the so-called death of distance

    where the cost of sending bits of information is no longer a function of distance.

    At first sight one might suppose that this would result in a greater homogenisation of

    voice services. However, this has not been the case since voice services themselves have

    become differentiated in a number of different directions. One example is the advent of

    cellular mobile voice telephony, an invention that was first made in Bell Laboratories

    between 1947 and 196027 but which at first diffused most rapidly in Sweden and the other

    Nordic countries.28 At first there was a great degree of interpretive ambiguity in the

    industry regarding the extent to which consumer preferences for the characteristic of

    mobility would be sufficient to compensate for the additional cost of mobile voice

    services, the frequently lower quality of these services (due to radio interference), the

    limited geographical availability of the services, and other disadvantages such as the

    initial heavy handsets. With time, however, an explosion of demand (largely unforeseen)

    for mobile voice telephony occurred, spurred by the dynamics of increasing returns

    which, via Marshallian interactions between improving organisation and knowledge,

    resulted in improving and cheaper mobile services. Furthermore, the adoption of

    regional, if not global, standards, such as the highly successful European GSM (Global

    27 See Mellman (1984), p.235-7.28 It was early diffusion in Sweden and the other Nordic countries that, through processes of path-dependency and dynamic increasing returns, presented distinctive opportunities to companies in this region,advantages that were strategically seized by Ericsson and Nokia which still enjoy dominant positions in

    global mobile markets.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    32/41

    32

    System for Mobile Phones) for digital mobile voice telephony, has further increased the

    utility of the service.29

    Mobile voice telephony, however, is in the throes of further evolutionary differentiation.

    One important trend is captured by the decision in early 1998 by ETSI (the European

    Telecommunications Standards Institute) to adopt a new standard for so-called third

    generation mobile services, referred to as UMTS (universal mobile telephone system).

    This set of standards will facilitate the provision of multimedia services including, in

    addition to voice, Internet access and the receipt of live video on mobile handsets.30

    Voice is also becoming integrated with other services in other areas too. One example is

    so-called computer-telephony integration (CTI), where voice telephony is integrated with

    computer functionalities with applications in areas such as call centres where an operator

    can answer a query from a customer while simultaneously getting information from a

    database regarding that customers past purchasing history, payments record, other

    purchases etc, therefore at the same time facilitating attempts to market other products to

    the customer. More recent is the integration of Internet telephony with Web sites so that

    at a click it is possible to speak to a sales person to get immediate answers to queries that

    arise from the information presented at the site.

    For present purposes, these examples point to heterogeneous and rapidly changing

    customer demands and products as important dynamic influences on the evolving

    structure of the telecoms industry, as defined earlier in terms of barriers to entry, the

    nature and sources of substitutes, the number and kinds of rivals, suppliers and

    customers. For instance, it may be hypothesised that both the heterogeneous as well as

    the rapid change in customer demand will have a positive effect on net entry and

    29 GSM was also widely adopted in Asia and Latin America, although the U.S. went its own way withanother set of standards.30 The adoption of UMTS was preceded by a standards battle around two competing standards. The one,TD-CDMA, was supported by suppliers like Alcatel, Siemens, Lucent and Motorola, while the opposingstandard, WB-CDMA, was proposed by Ericsson and Nokia, two of the strongest suppliers in the mobilearea, as well as most of the European telecoms operators. Furthermore, WB-CDMA also had the advantageof drawing significantly on similar standards that had been developed by an NTT mobile subsidiary, NTTDocomo, opening up the future possibility of this also becoming the dominant standard in Japan and therest of Asia. In the event, although a compromise was announced, it was the WB-CDMA standard that

    dominated. The U.S., meanwhile, has decided to go its own way with a somewhat different standard.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    33/41

    33

    significantly reduce the probability of shakeout as defined earlier. As these examples

    testify, it is clearly necessary to model demand as an integral part of the dynamic

    processes that drive the evolution of the telecoms industry, even if this is donequalitatively rather than quantitatively in order to capture the essential complexities and

    causalities of heterogeneous and changing demand.

    DYNAMIC 5: PERMEABLE INDUSTRY BOUNDARIES

    The fifth and final dynamic driving the evolution of the telecoms industry that will be

    considered in this paper is the permeability of industry boundaries, more particularly,

    ease of entry from neighbouring industries. The specific case that will be examined is

    entry from the computer and software industries.

    From the authors interviews with senior executives from companies like AT&T and BT

    it is clear that computer and software companies are viewed as increasingly threatening

    new entrants into some of the markets being contested by these incumbent telecoms

    companies. (Although this issue should simultaneously be analysed from the perspective

    of computer and software companies diversifying into new areas, it is the perspective of

    the telecoms industry that will be followed here.) Where precisely is the threat perceived

    as coming from? Two areas will be identified in this section.

    The first area is a new emerging market that may be referred to as the solutions market.

    What is the solutions market? It is the market where telecoms companies not only act as

    bit transporters for their customers, but go further up the latters value chain to offer

    solutions to their communications problems. This requires, metaphorically, that the

    telecoms company does not simply take its pipes up to the door of the customer, but

    also enters the customers establishment whether firm or residence and helps

    customers with solutions to their communications problems. A telecoms company that

    has begun to articulate a solutions strategy, as part of its strategic portfolio, is AT&T

    which explicitly has begun to define itself as an information and communications

    company. In Europe, for instance, AT&T and its partners in Unisource are attempting to

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    34/41

    34

    differentiate themselves from other competitors by offering what they term solutions

    and applications.31

    What are the attractions of the solutions market for telecoms companies? The first

    attraction is that the solutions market is seen as a potentially high profit margin area, in

    contrast to the bit transportation market which some argue has become commoditized,

    with correspondingly low margins, as substantial economies of scale are realised by

    companies like WorldCom which have invested in huge pipes, that is high speed, high

    capacity networks which, with sufficient traffic, yield relatively low unit costs. A further

    factor making for the commoditization and low margins of bit transportation is the

    competition between different kinds of networks such as cable TV coaxial, mobile, and

    satellite networks in addition to the fixed public switched network which are

    increasingly interconnected and interoperable thus providing alternative ways of

    transporting bits. Secondly, it is argued that there is a complementarity between

    solutions and bit transportation insofar as a telecoms company that sells solutions to a

    customer is also more likely to get that customers bit transportation business. For

    intensive potential users of these kinds of services, such as leading financial institutions,

    complementarity is an important issue. It is for this reason that AT&T has begun to sell

    itself in Europe as a company which specialises in all aspects of data, including the

    storage, processing, and communication of data. This has taken the company into the

    areas of Intranets (using the TCP/IP protocol for intrafirm communications) as well as

    Extranets (using the same protocols for network-based communications with suppliers

    and customers, including electronic commerce).

    The problem, however, is that while this seems like a natural competence-based

    diversification for telecoms companies like AT&T,32 entering a domain that is also

    contested by computer and software companies raises important strategic questions of the

    31 Authors interview.32 Interestingly, AT&Ts solutions strategy is, if anything, being more strongly articulated since thecompanys voluntary trivestiture in September 1995 when NCR was spun off. However, the rationale forthe acquisition of NCR in 1993 was that AT&T needed in-house computer competencies in order toprovide information and communication solutions. Evidently, the new AT&T has come to the conclusion

    that the earlier assumption was a mistake.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    35/41

    35

    distinctive competencies and complementary assets of the two sets of firms. While it

    might be supposed that telecoms companies have distinctive competencies in designing,

    managing, and maintaining networks, the advent of data networks based on packet-switching which, as shown earlier, emerged from the computer rather than the telecoms

    industry, and IBMs capabilities in running its own extensive global corporate network,

    provide reasons for doubting the exclusivity of the telecoms companies competencies in

    this area.

    The second area where telecoms companies are being challenged by computer and

    software companies is in more conventional telecoms services such as voice and fax. In

    part the threat comes from packet-switched data networks that have already been

    discussed in this paper. But threat also comes from the domination of what may be

    thought of as strategic heights (to again use a military analogy) by computer and

    software firms. To take a key example, Microsofts dominance of the de facto standard

    for desktop computers, which it is currently attempting to extend into Internet servers

    through its Windows NT format, as well as into browsers with its Internet Explorer, and

    into networked consumer electronic products with Windows CE, raises the possibility of

    Microsoft having the power to guide consumers to the use of particular telecoms

    services over particular networks. For example, Microsoft networked meeting software,

    used for remote users to communicate with each other and share data, already has

    Internet telephony incorporated. Although at various points Internet traffic is carried

    over the networks of telecoms companies such as the Internet backbones and although

    this means that some of these companies benefit from the growth in demand for Internet

    usage, the worry for telecoms companies is clearly that they will be excluded from

    profitable business areas as a result of the dominance of commanding heights by

    computer and software companies.

    Again from the point of view of the evolutionary analysis of the telecoms industry, these

    examples make clear that an important dynamic driving force emerges from the

    permeability of the boundaries of this industry. This permeability clearly influences all

    the elements of industrial structure considered in this paper.

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    36/41

    36

    CONCLUSION

    What are the implications of the evolution of the telecoms industry for the general

    evolutionary/institutional analysis of industry? The first implication relates to a set of

    issues revolving around what may be called the Product Life Cycle Paradigm.

    How well does the telecoms industry fit into the Product Life Cycle Paradigm? The

    general answer is not very well. There are several reasons for this answer. To begin

    with, in the industries that supposedly conform to this paradigm industries such as

    motor cars, televisions, tires, and penicillin there is a tight coupling or correspondence

    between three sets of factors: consumer tastes and characteristic preferences, design

    configurations that provide these tastes and characteristics, and manufacturing or process

    technologies which are used to produce the products embodying these design

    configurations. The telecoms industry, conversely, is characterised, firstly, by a far

    greater degree of heterogeneity in each of these three areas, and secondly, by a much

    looser correspondence between each of them.

    The example of voice telephony, analysed in this paper, illustrates this point. The

    relevant consumer characteristic preferences in the case of voice telephony relate to

    factors such as mobility, quality of reception, ease of use, portability, geographical range,

    combinability with other complementary services, in addition to price. Furthermore,

    there is a wide variety of configurations capable of providing all or some of these

    consumer characteristics (configurations of product/service packages, the networks over

    which these characteristics are provided, and the technologies provided in these

    networks, as has been shown in detail in this paper). If the notion of dominant design

    does have a relevant meaning in the telecoms industry, and in the authors view it does, it

    is in a far more restricted area such as the design of individual products (e.g. mobile

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    37/41

    37

    handsets or digital switches) or even the design of particular kinds of networks (e.g. local

    area networks (LANs). But these designs do not provide a central organising principle

    for the industry as a whole as the dominant design does in the Product Life CycleParadigm.

    The second reason the telecoms industry does not fit the Product Life Cycle Paradigm

    very well has to do with the important role played in this industry by specialist equipment

    and software suppliers, a major theme in the present paper. While Klepper (1997) has

    suggested that a key behavioural characteristic of product life cycle industries is the

    appearance of a shakeout once a dominant design has been established and once some of

    the industries firms, often early entrants, have managed to reap the rewards of dynamic

    increasing returns to innovation, in the telecoms industry it would seem that the presence

    of specialist suppliers constrains the shakeout process by making key technologies and

    other inputs available to all able to pay the price. A further consequence of the presence

    of specialist suppliers is that the dynamic of competition, and the thrust of corporate

    strategy, at least as far as the suppliers of telecoms services to final consumers are

    concerned, has tended to move away from technology based determinants towards other

    attempts to segment customer markets and differentiate services.

    The importance of specialist suppliers also noted by Klepper (1997) in the case of

    industries that do not exhibit shakeouts also raises questions regarding the appropriate

    conceptualisation of industry boundaries. A notable feature of the industry studies based

    on the Product Life Cycle Paradigm has been the close identity in these studies of

    product and industry. The importance of specialist suppliers, however, suggests that

    where they exist this narrow identity is not justified and a broader definition of industry

    boundary is necessary. Apart from the telecoms industry analysed in this paper, other

    examples may include the importance of specialist equipment suppliers (such as the

    makers of optical lithography equipment) in the semiconductor industry and the

    importance of specialist chip suppliers in the case of industries like PCs. In the latter

    case the availability of specialist chip suppliers like Intel has allowed firms like Dell to

    become significant players in the PC market largely on the basis of marketing, sales, and

  • 8/6/2019 Analysing the Evolution of Industry- The

    38/41

    38

    distribution capabilities, rather than technology-based capabilities. Clearly, this pattern

    of specialisation has directly influenced all asp