World Bank Document · 2016. 7. 13. · Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance 9 In...

60
9 Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance . Jcf Rzlster 13 A Pre-export Guarantee Facility in Moldova-Mitigating Political Risk in Transition Onrzo Riihl and AIfred Watkins 17 Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High? Fernando Montes-Negr-et and Luca Papi 21 Emerging Markets and Financial Volatility-Beyond Mexico Gary Perlin 25 Pension Funds and Capital Markets-Investment Regulation, Financial Innovation, and Governance Dimitri Vittas 29 Designing Mandatory Pension Schemes-Some Lessons from Argentina, Chile, Malaysia, and Singapore I Dimitri Vittas .. I * a 33 The Privatization Dividend-A Worldwide Analysis of the Financial and Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms William L. Meginson, Robert C. NaSh, and Matthins van Randenborgh 37 The Macedonian Gambit-Enterprise cum Bank Restructuring .JosephPernia and S. Ramacharzdran 41 Finding Real Owners-Lessons from Estonia's Privatization Program .John Nellis 45 End of the Line for the Local Loop Monopoly? Technology, Competition, and Investment in Telecom Networks PetePSnz ith 49 Regulating Telecommunications-Lessons from U.S. Price Cap Experience . Jeflrell (i. Rohlfs 53 Ffanchising Telecom Service Shops-Meeting Demand from Nonsubscribers in Indonesia Rajesh Pradhan and Peter Smith The World Bank Group Vice Presidency for Finance and Private Sector Development Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Transcript of World Bank Document · 2016. 7. 13. · Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance 9 In...

  • 9 Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance . Jcf Rzlster

    13 A Pre-export Guarantee Facility in Moldova-Mitigating Political Risk in Transition Onrzo Riihl and AIfred Watkins

    17 Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High? Fernando Montes-Negr-et and Luca Papi

    21 Emerging Markets and Financial Volatility-Beyond Mexico Gary Perlin

    25 Pension Funds and Capital Markets-Investment Regulation, Financial Innovation, and Governance Dimitri Vittas

    29 Designing Mandatory Pension Schemes-Some Lessons from Argentina, Chile, Malaysia, and Singapore

    I Dimitri Vittas .. I * a

    33 The Privatization Dividend-A Worldwide Analysis of the Financial and Operating Performance of Newly Privatized Firms William L. Meginson, Robert C. NaSh, and Matthins van Randenborgh

    37 The Macedonian Gambit-Enterprise cum Bank Restructuring .Joseph Pernia and S. Ramacharzdran

    41 Finding Real Owners-Lessons from Estonia's Privatization Program .John Nellis

    45 End of the Line for the Local Loop Monopoly? Technology, Competition, and Investment in Telecom Networks PetePSnz ith

    49 Regulating Telecommunications-Lessons from U.S. Price Cap Experience . Jeflrell (i. Rohlfs

    53 Ffanchising Telecom Service Shops-Meeting Demand from Nonsubscribers in Indonesia Rajesh Pradhan and Peter Smith

    The World Bank Group Vice Presidency for Finance and Private Sector Development

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

  • Private Sector is an open forum intended t o encourage dissemina'tion of and debate on ideas, innovat ions, and bes t pract ices fo r expanding t h e p r i va te sector. The v i ews published are those of the authors and should not be attr ibuted t o the World Bank or any of i ts affiliated organizations. Nor do any of the conclusions represent off icial pol icy of t h e World Bank or of i ts Executive Directors or the countries they represent.

  • Quarterly No. 5 , December 1995

    Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance 9

    In developing countries, project finance is commonly used as a \:chicle for private participation in such i n f ~ t -

    stnlcture projects as power plants and toll roacls. The investor's recourse is limited to claims on the project's cash

    Flow and related assets. Ancl risks are distributed across project participants-sponsors. lenders, third-party con-

    tractors, state-owned enterprises, and the government as end user-n the basis of who is best positioned to

    nlnnage them efficiently, though commitments are usually limited in scope, amount, and time. From a lender's

    perspective, Jeff Ruster lists common instruments for mitigating commercial risks.

    A Pre-export Guarantee Facility in Moldova-Mitigating Political Risk in Transition 13

    About 70 percent of Moldov:ln inclustrial firms have heen privatized. But any of these firms wanting to export

    f:lce severe financing const~.aints. Local banks are i~nahle to provide working capital, and any export credit

    agencies willing to provide cover require 3 full government guarantee for all risks--commercial and political.

    Foreign input suppliers and trading companies, however, have indicated a willingness to bear the commercial

    (but not political) risks OF supplying inputs on credit to exporters. So the Moldovan government and the World

    Bank have set lip a pre-export guarantee facility in which the government guarantees the financier against

    political risk and the Worlcl Bank provides :I backstop guarantee of the government's claim payment obligations.

    Onno Riihl and Alfred Watkins explain how the facility works.

    Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High? 17

    During the first half of 1095, average bank spreads in Ukraine ranged from 46 percentage points to 8t percent- age points. At first sight? these wide spreltds might suggest that banks were enjoying a tidy profit margin. But in

    a transition economy with high inflation and large stocks of nonperforming loans, that may not be thy ccrse.

    Fernando Montes-Negret and 1.uca Papi construct a simplified lnodel to help estimate breakeven spreads

    with :I positive real return on hanks' equity. It shows that spreads in Ukraine are in fact helow the breakeven

    point. The model can ensily be appliecl in other countries.

    Emerging Markets and Financial Volatility-Beyond Mexico 2 1

    Gary Perlin expl~rins that understanding the financial crisis in Mexico and its effect in other countries' financial

    m ~ r k e t s requires understanding what has changed in glolxtl capital markets. One important new feature is the

    behavior of investors in emerging markets. a ~ h o seek out high-risk. high-return investments.

    Pension Funds and Capital Markets 25

    The Mexican crisis highlighted once agLtin the importance of local sources of savings to develop domestic

    capital markets. The main source of long-tern~ savings is pension funds. ivhich interact with capital rnarkets in

    import:uit ways. Dimitri Vittas re\.iews this clynamic interaction. giving special attention to lessons from Chile.

    Designing Mandatory Pension Schemes 29

    Dimitri Vittas explains that governments should make retirement saving compirlsory to protect society against

    those who make inadequate provision for their old age. Compi~lsion should be accompanied by tax induc-ements

    to encourage compliance. And it ohliges governments to make sure that the ccxnpulsory schemes work well. are

    siirlple and easy to understand, and dcliver the targeted benefits. Ilimitri Vittas explains hoar to d o this.

  • The Privatization Dividend-A Worldwide Analysis of the Financial and Operating Performance

    of Newly Privatized Firms 33

    In a sample of sixty-one privatized compnies in eighteen countries-including Chile. France, Germany. Italy.

    M;~laysia, Singapore. and the United Kingdom-William Megginson, Rober t Nash, and Matthias v a n

    Randenborgh iclentify significant improvements in postprivatization performance. On average. profitability,

    efficiency, in\:estnlent. and employ~nent all rise in the years following priv;ltiz:ltion. And financir~l policies start to

    resemble those of privatt. entrepreneurial companies-lower debt-equity ratios and higher diviclend payout.

    The Macedonian Gambit-Enterprise cum Bank Restructuring 37

    The usual practice in transition economies is for the government to sell state-owned enterprises a,ithout first

    restmct~iring the~n . That is left to the new owners, who, it is arguetl, are better able to manage the risks and

    opportunities. In the period before sale, the government irnposes a hard t,udget constraint by "isolating" enter-

    prises from hanks. But this isolation rarely succeeds. Seeking more credit, enterprise managers lean on politi-

    cians, who lean on 1,anks. J o s e p h Pernia and S. Ramachandran describe Maceck~nia's strategy to circum\-ent

    these lold>ying tactics-isolating politically powerful enterprises from banks but giving them transparent sul7si-

    clies in return for reforms that will ultimately Icld to privatization or liquidation.

    Finding Real Owners-Lessons from Estonia's Privatization Program 41

    Tile Estonian government has privatized Inore than 00 percent of its industrial and manufacturing enterprises.

    John Nellis explains that. unlike most countries in Eastern Europe and the forlner Soviet Union. Estonia has

    avoided selling its state-owned enterprises into the control of insiders-arorkers and rnanagers in the firm or

    financial institutions tied to the state. Instead, the Estonians have c~sed a modified version of the German

    Treuhandanstalt's group tender method, \\:hick1 helps to ensure that pr~wtizeci firms have real owners serious

    :~hout creating a prod~~cti\ .e and enduring business and willing to pay a ~lleaningful price.

    End of the Line for the Local Loop Monopoly? 45

    Peter Smi th argues that local network competition is increasingly feasible both technically and in terms o f cost.

    is incre:~singly accepted by investors, anti offers important p ~ ~ b l i c policy benefits-especially its potential to

    stimulate investment. He describes how local network competition is cielivering in such countries as Ghana, the

    I'hilippines, and Sri Lanka.

    Regulating Telecommunications-Lessons from U.S. Price Cap Experience 49

    The ITnitrd Sti~tea has recently switclled from rate-of-return regulation to price cap regulation of monopoly

    sesvices. Re\.iem.ing the U.S. experience. Jeffrey Rohlfs argues thxt since price caps promote productivity.

    reduce incentives to cross-st~l~sidize. and are simpler to adininister and therefore more tcmsparent and less

    subjcct to al,use, developing countries should bypass rate-of-return rcg~~larion and opt for price caps.

    Franchising Telecom Service Shops-Meeting Demand from Nonsubscribers in Indonesia 53 Indonesia has colne up with an inno\.ati\.e way to meet nonsul>scriber clenrand for telephone senrice. Rajesh

    P r a d h a n and Peter Smi th descrilx the franchise system that the nlostly state-owned telephone operator PT.

    Telkom has cleveloped to aHo\v small private investors to operate co~nn~rrcially viable telecom service shops.

  • Letters and emails Suzanne Smith, Editor, The Wor ld Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Room G8105, Washington, D.C. 20433, USA, fax: 202 676 9245, email: [email protected]

    Subscribing to Monopoly Industrial countries had dozens of years of monopoly that allowed uneconomic service

    In the September issue. Peter Smith attacked to b e subsidized and hence resulted in uni- t he lexicon of catchphrases often used by versal service. -4 quick rush to competition telecom executives, civil servants, and invest- in developing countries may result in tele- ment twnkers to justify monopoly provision of phone service's becoming a luxury. telecommunications sewices. He claimeci that I don't think the example of -4ustralia is a good those phrases-zuastclfiil clrrplication qf.,f:facili- tic~s, l t~~econonz ic entry: z/nivc~rsaE serb1ice and creanz s k i n z ~ n i n e h a v e a simplistic and falla- cious ration:ile and that the monopoly approach they defend has resulted in chronically poor te1ecommunic:~tions services in many develop- ing countries. These views provoked many comments. Several ;ire puhlishecl Ix low:

    T o t h e Editor-Peter Smith's piece is stimu- lating to read, and I wish to congratulate him. I enjoyed following his arguments directly at- tacking the assumptions that have been widely accepted as justification for monopoly regimes in the telecommunications sector. Kepresenta- tives from countries (both developing and in- dustrial) with restrictive telecon~munications regimes often say that, although they support liberalization in general, it must b e achieved graclually a n d wi th s o m e l imitat ions. T h e phrases duplicatio~z of faci1itit.s. trniuel-sal ser- uice, :~nci s o o n , are indeed often used t o jus- tify such arguments. Whilc I appreciate the economic, social, and historical realities unique to each country. I question how much value they hold in arguments for protecting monopoly regimes. The terms examined are often used to protect interests other than the provision of telecommunications to the broad put)lic. Airline Tclecurt~~nt~~zicatiorls I.i)shiku Kurisaki a ~ i d Ififurrnution SL '~Z '~C(JS .

    Gefic~ia

    T o t h e Editor-This is a n excellent and most helpfill contribution to the dehate. TeiConz. L O H L ~ J H Trc?Jor Kelsall

    T o t h e Editor-I do not find fa i~l t with the pure economic theory that monopoly is ineffi- cient. However, the real world is different. klj- feelings are the following:

    one for arguing that the cost of universal ser- vice is lower than assumeci. Most people in Australia live in clustered urban areas, and only a few live in remote areas. In the dozens of conversations I have had with putdic tele- communications operators and equipment vendors, the universal view is that rural and remote coinmunications are expensive and the revenues will not cover the costs. As wireless technology drops in price, this service may l x c o m e more affordable. In my experience, most developing (if not all) countries lack the regulatory espertise to handle competition. If advanced econo- mies such as Australia, Hong Kong, Near Zealand, a n d the United Kingdom have not solved interconnection problems, I don ' t think developing ones ~vil l . Industrial coun- tries' complicated, legalistic solutions to in- terconnection and universal service will only lead to fraud a n d corruption in developing countries. Far t~et ter are simple approaches such as that in the Philippines: if a public telecommunications operator wants lucrative services, such as international or cellular, it must deal with the sut>sidy issue by also re- quiring lines in remote a n d rural areas. There is anecdotal evidence that countries that have sold off their international services ifor example, to France Telecom in West Africa or Cable S; Wireless in former British colonies) have done far worse in the provision of local service because the revenues from lucrative international services are not reinvested in the network. C:~pit:~l is scarce a n d there will not t,e tak- ers for all regions of 3 country. Look at In- dia. where there w e r e n o bids for a number of unattractive regions. Moreover, w h e n countries are desperate for funds for ad- equate health : ~ n d ed i~ca t ion services, it is

  • ludicrous to promote duplicate investment in telecoms.

    Zntermitiotlrll ,Michael Minges Teleconlt?~llrlicatiotz.s l / ~ z i o ~ z .

    Geneva

    P e t e r Smith responds t o Mr. Minges :

    Back in the real world, the overwhelming evi- dence from most developing countries is that the performance of the monopoly operator has been very unsatisfactoq-most clearly seen by waiting times for service that have frequently exceeded five or ten years, high costs, low staff productivity. and a dearth of service outside of major cities. Thus, what w e have observed in no st developing countries over the past twenty or s o years i,s chronic underinvestment in the telecommunications sector and low efficiency. These are supply problems-that is, the cru- cial problem is not inadequate demand (that needs to be cross-subsidized) but inadequate or inefficient supply or both-a situation that is most likely to b e sustained where new entry is prohibited.

    In my view, competition is likely to stimulate investment in the sector because it opens n e w channels for investment and changes incen- tives-companies that d o not invest to meet demand risk losing inarket share (see "End of the Line for the Local Loop Monopoly?" o n pafie 45). O n this point, the example of the Philippines is instructive. Only after the main operator in the country came to helieve in 199.1 that the governnlent was serious about autho- rizing new entrants did it announce a "zero backlog" program to try to clear the waiting list for telephone service.

    The assumption th21t monopoly is necessary for cross-suhsidy to occur is wrong. Competition and cross-subsidy can and d o coexist. But it would be wrong to put too much frlith in cross- subsidies. Many monopoly operators have very high costs, suggesting that inefficiency is be- ing cross-subsidized rather than customers. Mr. Minges notes that rural telephone sewice is usu- ally seen t o be uneconomic. But this is n o jus-

    tification for giving the typically high-cost in- cumbent operator a monopoly on a service that it does not provide or does not provide to an adequate standard. Mr. Minges says that devel- oping countries d o not have the regulatory ex- pertise to handle competition. But these are the same countries that have not hacl the regu- latory expertise to make monopoly work.

    I d o not want to suggest that there is only a single route to high performance in the tele- communications sector. Many different ap - proaches can be made to work. But it is clear that in very m:my developing countries, the state-owned monopoly model of sector devel- opment has failed to deliver-in the worst cases, the population is growing faster than the telephone network, resulting in declining telephone penetration rates.

  • Fill out and mail or fax this form

    To Suzanne Smith, Editor, The World Bank, G8105, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, D.C. 20433, USA, fax: 202 676 9245

    FIRST NAME

    --

    JOB TITLE

    COMPANY OR 0RI;ANIZATON

    -

    STREET

    ---

    CITY

    COUNTRY

    -- - --

    LAST NAME

    STATE POSTAL CODE

    WORK PHONE FAX NUMBER

    Topics of interest:

    Finance Privatization Law & regulation Telecommunications & informatics Energy All

    Call 202 458 11 11 to record this information

    Email this information to [email protected]

  • Editor: Suzanne Srnith Roo111 G8105 The World Rank 1818 H Street. NW Washington, D.C. 20433

    Telephone: 202 458 7281 Fac5irnile: 202 6'6 9245 Email: [email protected]

    Illustrations by Ruth Sofair Ketler Photo on page 1 provided by FPG International and o n page 5 by Hargrove, Inc.

    The entire contents of Private Sector 01995 World Rank. \ b u are authorized to repro- duce, duplicate, and clisserninate a11 or part of this publication so long as you include the name of the publication and the narne of the respective author. You may not, however. modify, alter, or otherwise change any part of this pub1ic:ition or sell, transfer. or other- wise disseminate any part of the pul3lication for profit.

    @ Printed on recycled pxper.

  • Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance

    In project fin:~nce. risks are allocatecl to the par- ties Ixst a l~ le to mxnage them. However, the risk mitigation instruments incorporated in the project's contractual anel financial arrangements need not l,e all-encompassing to provide the se- curity investors require. Commitments may he liinited in scope (restricted to geological risk. la- bor and equipment producti\zity, operation and maintenance, market demancl, or force majeure). amount (liniitetl to a percentage of project debt or capital costs. contract price, or operating bud- get), ancl duration (applicalde only cluring con- stn~ction, perforn~~nce testing, st;llt-i~p, operation. or on f;~ilurc to ac,hieve certain inilestone elates or opc';~tional or financial indicators). This Note pro\ ides :I checklist of commercial risk mitiga- tion instruments commonly used in project fi- nance 11)- private lenders and sometimes by equity inve.stors. The checklist is stnictured around a ~ x o j e c t ' ~ d e v e l o p m e n t cycle, which, for sim- plicity's s:lkc, is tliviclecl into the constn~ction (in- c l ~ ~ d i n g st:~rt-up and testing) and operating phases. (See t:ll)lcs 1 and 2 for s~uninaries of possil~le risks :~ncl coverage.)

    Construction period

    Three main groups of instn~ments are used to mitigate risk during the construction period: con- tr:lctu:ll arrangements ancl associated guarantees. contingency funds :~nd lines of credit, and pri- vate insu~ince.

    Contractual arrangements

    Contractual :Irr:lngements offer a broad range of possibilities for ;lllocating risks among project par- ticipants. The constr~lction contract, for example. :issigns sesponsi1)ilities to the project sponsor and the construcTion companies for engineering, pro-

    curement, pvrformance testing, obtaining permits and insurance. provision of required services (wa- ter, electricity, fuel), and relief under force ma- jeure events. The contractor inay be responsible only for bringing 21 project to mechanical comple- tion according to the owner's design and specifi- cations, transferring to the sponsors responsibility for start-up and testing. Under an engineering, procurement, ancl constnlction c o n t ~ ~ c t , however, the contractor accepts full responsil~ility for delivering a fully operational facility on n elate- certain, fixed-price basis.

    If the contractor fails to meet its obligations, it may be required to pay compensation to the project sponsors, often in the form of lirll~irduted rlrit)lrigc.s (LDs. typically assigned to lenclers as 1~1i-t of their security package). L3elay LDs; pay- able when the contractor fails to meet certain milestone dates, normally cover additional inter- est costs arising from the delay and may com- pens:lte equity investors for lost income and fixed costs inc.i~rred. Buydown LDs compensate a project's owners for the contractor's failure to meet project operating criteria (output, input efficiency. and emissions). Buydown LDs, used to pay down project debt to offset the expected decline in net operating cash flow, arc sct at a value that will allow the d e l ~ t service coverage ntios (DSCK) to ren~ain unchanged. But contractor li:il%lity under the LDs is almost always capped at some per- centage of the construction contract price. LDs are often 10 to 15 percent of the contract price for many gas pipelines, for es:~mple. while for longer-gestation and more techrlically compli- cated coal-fired ponrer generation projccts they may be as high as 35 to 40 percent.

    h,laterial, workmanship, and equipment iorir- rarities cover defects discovered following a

  • Mi t iga t ing Commerc ia l Risks i n Project Finance

    TABLE 1 POSSIBLE RISKS AND COVERAGE DURING THE CONSTRUCTION PERIOD

    Start-up Contractor

    Cost and testing payment Hidden Force

    Instrument overruns Delays problems defaults defects majeure

    Liquidated damages X X X

    Performance bonds

    Retainage accounts

    Warranties

    Contingency funds X X X

    Insurance X

    Note:Table shows principal applications of instruments.

    project's final completion. Warranties may be issued on an evergreen basis, guaranteeing the reliability of a stipulated item for a period fol- lowing final completion. typically one to two years. If any repair is required, the clock starts again and the item must perform without prob- lems for the full warranty period.

    Lenders often require a performance bond or other type of surety instrument from third-party financial institutions to backstop the contractor's payment obligations. In addition. hecause of fre- quent delays in collecting under LDs and per- formance bonds; 5 to 10 percent of monthly payments owed by project sponsors to the con- tractor may be escrowed in a retainage account. This cash reserve further backstops the con- tractor's payment obligations.

    Cont ingency funds a n d l ines o f credit

    Construction budgets often include a 5 to 15 percent line item to cover unexpected cost in- creases. This financing may be provided pro rata between debt and equity or under some other sharing arrangement (for example, 100 percent equity for the first 5 percent of cost overruns and pro rata thereafter). Contingency funds can be used to cover all types of cost overruns or earmarked for specific contingen- cies such as environmental cleanup.

    In addition to, or in the absence of, such in- struments, contingent lines of subordinate debt

    may be provided by third-party contractors, standby letters of credit, or sponsor guaran- tees. These instruments may be limited in amount (available only for the first 10 percent of overruns), scope (not callable upon a force majeure event), and time (applicable only af- ter a project achieves mechanical completion).

    Insurance

    A project is generally covered by several types of insurance. Construction All Risk insurance protects against property damage and is effec- tive from the commencement of procurement to transportation to the project site through completion of construction and performance testing. Risks covered include acts of God ancl standard perils (fire, lightning). Adjunct liability coverage insures against bodily injury or prop- erty damage to third parties resulting from project work. Advance Loss of Profits insurance covers income losses due to delays resulting from the same risks covered under Construc- tion All Risk insurance. Miscellaneous coverage may include employer's liability. architect er- rors and omissions, :~nd force majeure insur- ance, which can cover losses due to strikes, contractor insolvency, and delays in obtaining permits.

    Operating period

    The instruments most commonly used to mitigate risk during the operating period are

  • T h e W o r l d Bank Group -- - .

    TABLE 2 POSSIBLE RISKS AND COVERAGE DURING THE OPERATING PERIOD

    Instrument

    Operating Increase Increase Market

    efficiency in routine in major demand Input Force

    problems O&M O&M and pricing availability majeure

    Take-or-pay

    Put-or-pay

    Pass-through

    Debt service reserve funds X

    Maintenance reserves

    Cash traps X Insurance

    Tracking accounts

    Equity kickers

    Note:Table shows principal applications of instruments.

    contractual arrangements, contingency re- serves, cash traps, insurance, and risk com- pensation devices.

    Contractual arrangements

    Of the many contractual structures that can allocate risks during the operating period, take-or-pa),, put-or-pay, and pass-through structures are perhaps the most commonly applied. Take-ot*-pa~' arrangements require the offtaker to pay for the good or service regard- less of n;hether it is needed. This obligation is normally conditioned on, among other things, the project's compliance with the terms of the offtake or concession agreement (for example. minimum availability factor. environmental permitting). I'ayments ~ lnde r take-or-pay con- tracts may be set to cover all fixed costs of the project (fixed operation and maintenance costs, debt service. after-tax equity return) or may cover only part of the project's available capacity. In the latter case, project sponsors inc~st sell the uncommitted portion to the spot market or seek long-term offtake arrangements with third parties to achieve their r eq~~ i sed cq- uity return.

    Pzlt-or-pa-)] contracts provide for a secure SLIP- pIy of project feedstocks or raw materials. If the supplier is unable to provide the inputs.

    it agrees to indemnify the project company for excess costs incurred in securing the in- puts from third parties or. if third-party sup- ply is unavailable, for revenue losses due to the project's resulting inability to comply with its offtake arrangements.

    Pass-through structures often link the offtake and input agreements to shield investors from adverse changes in the prices of project inputs or outputs.' For a power project. fuel price es- calation fo rm~~las might be tied to a basket of international reference prices. The offtake agreement, referred to as the power purchase agreement (PI'A), would include an energy pay- ment to cover the project's variable operating expenses, including fuel costs. The price esca- lation formula for the energy payment typically matches that of the fuel supply agreement. However, although I'I'A escalation formulas may include pass-throughs for fuel price changes, they typically do not include cost pass- throughs related to lower than expected fuel consumption efficiency. Thus, if the project re- quires more fuel than expected to produce a given amount of electricity, its net operating income would decline. This risk can be miti- gated through penalty provisions in the project's operat ion and maintenance agreements . through sponsor guarantees, or through other mechanisms described below.

  • Mitigating Commercial Risks in Project Finance -- -- . .-

    Contingency reserves

    To cover cash flow shortages, a debt service reserve fund can be established through spon- sor equity contributions, excess cash flow (avail- able cash flow after debt service payments but before dividend distributions), standby letters of credit, or sponsor guarantees. .4 separate fund to cover extraordinary maintenance can also be created to ensure proper operation and maintenance in the future.

    Cash traps

    Sometimes a project can meet its debt service obligations, but not with the cash flow margins that lenders had expected. Cash traps can be used to ensure that lenders continue to receive timely payments. For example, if a project is un- able to maintain a required DSCK (typically de- fined on a pretax basis as gross revenues minus operating expenses divided by interest and prin- cipal payments), no dividend distributions would be permitted. Until the project achieves the re- quired DSCR, "trapped" cash flow could be es- crowed or applied in inverse order of maturity to prepay debt (often referred to as a .'clawback"). If noncompliance persists beyond a certain date, the project may be considered in default, and all excess cash flow would be permanently ap- plied to prepay project debt. One possible ap- plication is as follows: If the expected DSCR is 2:1, but the actual is between 1.75 and 1.90, excess cash flow would he escrowed until the project achieves the required DSCR for two con- secutive quarters, at which time dividends would once again be permitted; 50 percent of excess cash flow would be "clawed back" if the actual DSCR falls between 1.35 and 1.74, and 100 per- cent if it falls to between 1.20 and 1.34. An event of default may be called if the DSCR falls below 1.20 for more than two consecutive quarters.'

    Insurance

    Coverage for the operating period typically includes property insurance with extensions available for loss of revenue from machinery breakdown and for business interruption from

    property damage. Third-party general liabil- ity insurance might include coverage for work- ers' compensation, autoinobiles, and pollution cleanup.

    Risk compensation devices

    Sonletimes investors and contractual participants assume certain risks in return for an opportu- nity to share in the project's upside potential. T~~acking accozlizts are often used to compen- sate input suppliers or offtakers for offering fixed price agreements, which shield project spon- sors from market risk. Under an offtake agree- ment that provides for tracking, if the contract price exceeds spot market prices, the difference between the two would be tracked. Amounts tracked may be 100 percent of the price differ- ence or a lower proportion, with payments owed only if the difference exceeds a certain thresh- old. Equity kickers, such as convertible deben- tures, stock warrants, and contingent interest payments, allow investors to share in the up- side potential of the project while still provid- ing them priority over common equity investors with regard to claims on project assets and cash flow if the project is unable to generate suffi- cient cash flow to meet its financial obligations.

    ' Othrr r y p c ot pass-through structures relate to nunprlce con- rraclu:~l terrn \uch as force maleure and cure pel.lod prov~\ii~ns. For example, ~f .I rhird-parry contractor 1s rel~eved from ~ t s oh11- g:ltlon\ upon the occurrence of a specltied torte maleure event, the project nrlll seek slmllar rellef In 1 t l n p ~ ~ t or offtake agree- ments for f,illure to meet 1t5 contractual ot>l~g.lt~ons as a result 11f rhc same force tn,lleilre event

    - 1)eht senlce resene fund\ :lnJ cash t~:lps are designed to cover v e ~ different scm'inos. Drlx m l c e re\m.es prc)tect ;tgamst cata- strophic events (for ex.lmple. a tur1,lne Ihl~de t>rmklng) thar noulcl prevent the project from genrlating rermue f o ~ an extended pe- rlod Cash traps cover a scen.~rio in n-hich the project ma); Ihe linrp- ing along. still rneetlng ~ t s detx senJlce obllgatlons hut not a ~tli the cash tlon, ma~gins tliat lender\ had anticipated T h ~ s sltuatlon crlulcl rise, fc,r exnrnple. I E \pol price\ ale helow ba\e case pn>lectli~nc, I , ~ C G I ~ I C I ~ and In:llntell.IIlce cobtb are highel than projected (per- hap,\ :I\ :I result 11t cluic.l\e~ than expected \);stem clcgraddtlon). r x produ~tion is helow expectecl levels becaue of lower th.ln ex- pectrd pl:lnt di\pareli rc.;ulrlng from the mtq- of new low-co\r producer\ 01 .In in;il,il~ty to meet recl~l~red mrission\ standards at Ix1sr loll~lctlr~ll level\

    Jef Ruster, Financial Specialist, Private Sector Dt.~)elopment DepaWnent (enlad jnlster@ zclorldbank.org)

  • A Pre-export Guarantee Facility in Moldova Mitigating political risk in transition

    Atlout 70 percent of industrial and agro-industrial firms in Molclova are now in private hands. But any of thest. firins a:lnting to export face se- vere financing constraints. The local banking sys- tem has neither the capital hase nor the technical capacity to finance their working capital require- ments. And export credit agencies either are not willing to provide cover or. if the); ;ire, require :I full government counterguarantee covering 130th commercial and political risks. Thus, to en:lhle \,ial>le 1oc:il firms to attract private work- ing capital. the government of Moldova asked the World Bank to help design a pre-export guar- antee facility. but with the proviso that the facil- ity should not require the go\,ernment to assume comnlercial risks. Under this facility, which be- came operational on October 30, 1995, the Moldovan government guardntees financiers against political risk, and the World Bank pro- vides a Ixckstop guarantee of the government's claim payriient obligations. A similar approach could be used in other transition economies. where firms face n n ~ c h the same constraints.

    This Note l~riefly clescrik~es the development of the facility and offers suggestions for cle- signing a "line of guarantee" modeled o n it a s a \v:ly to help attract private finance for a rela- til-ely large n u m l x r of sm:i11 projects.

    Catering t o risks and opportunities

    Although local and international banks are un- willing to provide pre-export finance to Moldo- van enterprises. foreign trading companies and input suppliers have indic~ited that they would I)e willing to Ixa r the commercial risk of supply- ing inputs on credit. But these non l~ank finan- c i e r s n e e d a s s u r a n c e tha t t h e Moldovan govcrnii ient w o u l d no t impose retroactive

    changes in rules and regulations that would pre- vent their being paid. Discussions with a wide range of input suppliers, trading companies, and commercial lenders suggested that an effective program to mitigate political risk could d o much to t~oos t private fin;ince for commercially viable pre-export transactions. Politicxl risk coverage would also encoul-age many trading companies and input suppliers not now active in Moldova to look into the possibility of doing business there.

    These risks and opportunities defined the ba- sic design. First, the noncommercial risks in-

    THE POLI'I'ICAL RISKS OF PRE-EXPORT FINANCE

    A Western European trading company that has been selling canned

    fruits and vegetables to buyers in Russia and Kazakstan would like to

    start selling them Moldovan canned fruits and vegetables to increase

    its profits. There is no apparent quality difference between Western

    European and Moldovan produce, and the Moldovan canning factory

    has sufficient excess capacity to meet the anticipated demand. But it

    needs to improve its labeling and canning equipment to match

    Western European quality standards.

    The trading company is willing to provide the equipment the factory

    needs to upgrade. And since the company has already established

    commercial relationships with Russian and Kazak buyers, i t is

    willing to accept the political and commercial risk associated with

    selling in the former Soviet states. But the perceived government

    performance risk of producing and exporting in Moldova has

    deterred the company from providing the upgrade equipment,

    foreclosing a potential new export opportunity for the country.

  • A Pre-export Guarantee Facility in Moldova - -- -

    hibiting the private sector from financing vi- able pre-export transactions in Moldova had to b e identified and mitigated. Second, the risk coverage, risk definitions, and claim adjudica- tion procedures hacl to have sufficient cred- ibility in the private financial community. Finally, the design had to be flexible enough to accommodate the diverse pre-export financ- ing structures expected to emerge in Moldova in the short to mecli~im term.

    FIGURE 1 STRUCTURE OF THE MOLDOVAN PRE-EXPORT GUARANTEE FACII-ITY

    Counter- guarantee

    *

    Access to loan facility,

    umbrella guarantee

    Confirmation of approval

    Right to sell guarantees

    Letter of credit

    Confirmation of availability

    of funds

    Guarantee

    The facility is designed to be an instrument of tr;insition. Its potential catalytic effect would h e especially strong during the early stages of the economic transition, when politic:d and eco- nomic uncertainty is greatest and the govern- ment's commitment to trade liberalization and private initiative relatively untested. I t is dur- ing this period that a Favorable enabling envi- ronment-in the form of a 1iber:llized tr:lde :~nd foreign exchange regime-may not suffice to assuage the concerns of private lenders. The reason is not that the proposed policy envi- ronment is "wrong." but that potential lenders are not confident that the new, more liberal rules and regulations will survive the underly- ing input supply transaction. Once these rules iind regulations have gained some traction, in- vestor perceptions of politic:ll risk n-ill dimin- ish, and the guarantee facility c:in give way to more mainstream financing techniques.

    The architecture

    The pre-export guarantee facility was designed to work in the following way:

    A foreign trading company, input supply com- pany. or commercial bank would agree to fi- nance nrorking capital inputs for a Moldovan enterprise. The local firm would repay the working capital advkince with a portion of the revenues from exporting the resulting outputs. To ensure repayment, the input supplier would act as a marketing ;igent for the Moldovan en- terprise, arranging for the sale of the output to a creditworthy buyer outside Moldova. In this way, input suppliers nrould also help Moldovan enterprises develop new ~narkets and restore old markets ruptured by the breakup of the Soviet Union. A government-owned guarantee administration unit woc~ld sell political risk coverage on ;I first- come, first-served basis to any foreign creditor willing to bear the commercial risk of financ- ing a pre-export transaction in Moldova. A framework guarantee contract outlining the terills and conditions of the political risk guar- antees would protect the holders against losses arising from retroactive government interference with a guaranteed pre-export

  • The World Bank Group 15

    transaction. The contract n7ould cover such risks as currency inconvertibility o r inability to transfer foreign eschange out of Moldova, government seizure of inputs or outputs, gov- ernment expropriation of the local enterprise, the retroactive revocation of import or ex- port permits. the retroactive imposition of other import or export restrictions: a n d po- litical force majeure related to war and civil disturlxlnce o n the territory of Moldova. All 17ut tlle last risk are entirely within the con- trol of the government, which simply has to refrain from retroactive interference with a transaction to avoid liability. Thus, the gov- ernment xccepts responsibility only for risks at le:~st partly within its control. It bears n o financial responsibility for any of the com- mercial risks typically associated with pre- export transactions, such as a n unexpected decline in world market price, the Failure of t h e local enterprise to deliver goocis of acceptable quantity or quality, or the failure of the foreign 1,uycr to fulfill the purchase contract. Under the terms of the framework guarantee contract, the government would pay only for damages caused by government actions o r inactions specified in the contract. The guar- antee holcler would b e required to notify the guarantee :~dininistration unit thirty days be- fore filing a claim. During this thirty-day "cure" period, the government would have an o p p o r t ~ ~ n i t y to correct the actions that trig- gereci the notification. If the problem is cor- secteci, n o claim would b e filed a n d n o payment ~ n r ~ d e to the guarantee holder.

    The World Bank's role

    Because political risk guarantees issued by the government of Moldova d o not yet have suffi- cient credibility in international markets, a World Bank contingent loan facility was de- signed to hackstop the government 's claim payment ohligations o n u p to VS$30 million of outstanding guarantees. Thy facility works ns follows: An agent bank employed by the guar- antee administration unit issucs standby letters of credit t o accomp:in)- each gilarantee con-

    tract sold by the unit. If a claim must b e p:~id and the government does not remit funds to the agent bank by the payment deadline. the agent bank can draw funds from the World Bank loan facility, to which it has irrevocable access. Under the terms of the World Bank fa- cility, funds used to pay claims o n guarantees would be permanently deducted from the fa- cility, reducing the amount of future govern- ment guarantees th:~t could b e issued with W r l d Bank support .

    The World Bank facility is available for back- s topping new gu:Irantees for five years. Thus, t he guarantee administration unit could po- tentially support US$lSCI million of pre-export transactions, assuming th:~t the average length of the transactions is o n e year and that the unit 's guarantee issuance capacity is fully uti- lized. Guarantees issued during the five-year period would remain valid for the remaining life of the private transaction, m-hich could b e u p to three years.

    Using the design in similar Bank operations

    Other transition economies also face problems in financing private firms' pre-export transac- tions. For these countries, it would b e rela- tively straightforward to develop a pse-export gurlrrintee facility similar to Molciova's, adapt- ing it as needed. Preparation would b e rela- t ively q u i c k , s i n c e a g e n e r i c f r a m e w o r k guarrlntee contract and :In operating manual for a gurirantee administration unit already exist and would require only minor modifica- tion. Efforts t o develop such facilities are un- d e r n-ay in Ukraine, Russia, a n d possibly Armenia.

    To b e feasible, such a facility requires a rela- tively open trade and foreign exchange regime, to give the private sector confidence that there is s cope for viable pre-export transactions. World Bank support would help assure the pri- vate participants in pre-export transactions that the relatively o p e n regime will remain in place for at least the life of a transaction.

  • A Pre-export Guarantee Facility in Mo ldova -- - . ..

    WORLD BANK SUPPORT

    No existing World Bank Group guarantee

    instruments were appropriate for supporting the

    Moldovan project. The Multilateral Investment

    Guarantee Agency is not permitted to guarantee

    loans with a maturity of less than three years.

    And the International Finance Corporation is

    prohibited from obtaining a government

    guarantee--a prohibition that applies in this

    case even though the guarantee facility's

    credibility derives from the government's

    commitment to pay for losses directly resulting

    from retroactive changes in government rules

    and regulations.

    Furthermore, the World Bank's then-new policy

    of mainstreaming guarantees did not envisage

    the use of guarantees for this type of project. The

    Bank therefore provided support to the Moldovan

    project in the form of a contingent loan with a

    Using the "delivery mechanism" for capital investment or infrastructure projects

    While Moldova's guarantee facility is designed to support pre-export transactions, the gen- eral appro:ich could also he ~ ~ s e d to deliver a government "line of guarantee" ~ v i t h World Bank hackstop for a large number of rel:itively small projects. For example, a framework gu:ir- antee contract c o ~ ~ l c l he developed to promote fixed capital investinents in sinall or inccl i~~m- scale enterprises, or to support a large n u n - her o f relatively snlall pri\:ite municipal infr:lstructure investments or small hyclro- power investments. In either case, ;i govern- ment unit would sell a W)rlcl Bank-backed guarantee contr:ict covering the discrete gov- ernment compliance risks-but none of the

    ten-year bullet maturity, meaning that any

    repayment is due ten years after the loan

    becomes effective, no matter when disburse-

    ment took place. Yet discussions during

    preparation of the project and the discussion of

    the project by the Bank's Executive Board

    acknowledged that it was very much in the spirit

    of the mainstreaming policy: the government and

    the Bank bear only those risks the government

    can control, and the project enables the country

    to attract private foreign capital for productive

    purposes.

    'Thus, future projects of this type are likely to be

    supported by a World Bank guarantee. But

    the contingent loan design could still be used

    in countries that borrow from the International

    Development Association and for which the

    guarantee option i s not available.

    commercial risks-associated with pri\.:ite in- vestment in the sector.

    Onno Riihl, Cout~tly Department 15: Europe and Central Asia Rc~giolz (email: orz~hlO ~i:ol-ldba~ k. ow, and Avred Watkilzs. Technical Departn~e~zt, E~trope and Centlzrl Asia and Middle E ~ L Y ~ a n,d North A fr'ca Keg io, 1s feiiz oil: c/u~otki1~~O~1~orldbank.org)

  • Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High? A simple model for decomposing spreads

    In the first seven months of 1995, average bank spreads in Ukraine ranged f rom 46 percentage

    points t o 84 percentage points (table 1). The size of these spreads might suggest that banks

    enjoyed a wide profit margin. But inflation was high in Ukraine, and its banking system had large

    stocks of nonperforming loans. Using a simplified model t o make a "quick and dirty" estimate of

    the spreads banks need t o achieve a positive real return on equity, this Note shows that nominal

    spreads in Ukraine were in fact wel l below breakeven. The model can be adapted for use for any

    country or for any bank or group of banks.

    Specifying the model

    An important task for hank analysts is to as- sess the efficiency of bank intermediation. A good place to start is the size of interest rate spreads-the difference between lending and deposit rates (ex ante spreads). In theory, this difference should comprise a liquidity risk pre- iniuin "reararcling" banks for t~~~nsforming more liquid :issets (deposits) into less liquid assets (loans), an information premium for banks' comparativc acivantage in selecting and moni- toring projects and borrowers, and a premium for controlling and ~nanaging risk. In reality, it is a complicated business to assess whether these premiums-and therefore the spreads- :ire too high o r too low- for efficient interme- diation. T h ~ s Note approaches the question froin a inethociological perspective, using :t

    = The prevailing policy parameters (reserve re- quirements and their remuneration, if any; taxes; and the capital-asset ratio)

    = Thy operating condition of the banks (oper- ating costs, targeted real return o n equity, and share of nonperforming loans) The rate of inflation (and the related deposit interest rates).

    TABLE 1 COMMERCIAL BANK INTEREST RATES AND SPREADS IN

    UKRAINE, 1995 (percent)

    Average Average Spread

    Month lending rate deposit rate (simple difference)

    January 220.7 144.9 75.8

    February 212.9 128.9 84.0 highly simplified mociel and applying interna- March 189.6 112.6 77.0 tional parameters for hank performance as a

    April lxnchmark. The model is a st:itic one based

    152.8 88.2

    on quite restrictive ;~ssumptions, and it manipu- May 122.2 61 .O

    Iates siinple :iccounting identities without any June 91.9 41.8 50.1 consideration of the strategic behavior of in:lr- July 81.6 35.4 46.2 ker particip~lnts. The moclel contains three groups of c.ritica1 variables (see hox for the deri- Source:National Bank of Ukraine, Bulletin No. 7.1995. vation of the formula):

  • Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High? -. -

    A STYLIZED MODEL

    The balance sheet of the representative bank has three assets, loans (1). nonperforming loans (NPL), and reserves (R), and two sources of funding, deposits (D) and capital (K):

    Bank profits (P) are defined as:

    where i, r. and dare the interest rate on loans, on reserves, and on deposits, c i s the operating cost per loan, and t i s the tax rate on profits. The interest rate on loans i s obtained by adding a spread (s) to the deposit rate (markup pricing):

    The real return on equity (RROE) can be defined as:

    where x is the inflation rate. Substituting equations 2 and 3 into equation 4 and solving for s gives the following expression:

    [RROE(I + n ) + x ] K K NPL (5) s =

    D - - d - + - ( d + ~ ) + - p ( d - r ) + c

    1 - t L L L L

    where R is the coefficient of mandatory reserves (R = RID). Alternatively, and in a more manageable way, equation 5 can be expressed as:

    K K NPL [ R R O E ( ~ + ~ ) + ~ - d l - + ~ ( l - - ) ( d - r ) + d + c

    s = A A A (6) NPL K

    1----P(I--) A A

    where Astands for total assets (L+NPL+R) and, to simplify, t i s assumed to be zero.

    Equation 5 shows that the spread w i l l be higher the higher the rate of inflation, the profit tax rate, the share of nonperforming loans, the bank's operating costs, the targeted return on equity, and the required minimum legal reserve ratio and the greater the difference between the deposit rate and the return (if any) on reserves. Under some assumptions. equation 5 can provide an indication of the sensitivity of the spread to changes in key variables. For example, given the interest rate on deposits, the rate of inflation, and operating costs, i t i s possible to calculate the effect on the spread of changes in reserve requirements or in the share of nonperforming loans for a desired return on equity.

    The inodel assumes a simplified balance sheet in which loans and reserves are the only assets and there are n o liquidity reserves or other invest- ments by banks. It assumes that banks target a clesired real return o n equity, that banks are free of controls and competitive pressures, and that the market is not competitive (that is, that banks are price setters in the loan market). It assumes n o dynamic interaction between the lending rate and market participants. Thus, banks d o not ra- tion credit, and the likelihood of adverse selec- tion and moral hazard and the elasticity of credit demancl are not taken into account. Similarly. the model assumes that there is no interaction between hanks' financial situation and authori- ties' actions. Thus, for example, banks d o not receive automatic central bank or government support, s o nonperforming loans widen spreads.

    Calculating breakeven

    For the illustrative calculations in this Note, a number of assumptions are made about the criti- cal varial>les. The capital-asset ratio is set at 8 percent (in line with Rasle Accord requirements). and the central bank pays n o interest o n required rcsenres (as is the case in many developing ancl transition economies). Banks' operating costs are 2 percent of assets, banks aim to pay their share- holders a real return o n equity of 5 percent a year (a consel~at ive assumption considering the risk banks in developing countries face), and spreads are not taxed directly. Finally, the de- posit rate is equal to the inflation rate, and de- positors therefore d o not receive a positive return in real terms, nor d o they pay an inflation tax. (Most of these assumptions can be relaxed to fit the model to any bank, group of banks. or bank- ing system. For example, the equations in the box can be solvecl for positive real interest rates o n deposits, interest paid on required reserves, different operating costs, different rates of return o n equity, capital-asset ratios, and taxes.)

    With a spreaclsheet format, this model can be run using a range of values for the rate of infla- tion, reserve requirements, and share of nonper- forming loans. In the simulation table (table 3), the share of nonperforming loans is allowed to

  • T h e W o r l d Bank G r o u p 19

    fluctuate betnreen 1 percent and 30 percent, and minimum reserve requirements fall in the range of 10 percent to 30 percent. '['his table c:ln be a handy guidt. to assess Ixmk spreads for a given bank or banking system-for example, the bank- ing system of Ukraine from January tc) July 1995. During that periocl, reserve requirements were 15 percent of deposits, and annualized rates o f inflation ranged from about 170 percent to Inore than 1,000 percent in Janu;il-)- (table 2). It is as- sumecl that loan portfolios were in bad shape- that, say. 20 percent of bank assets were nonperfc)rming (perhaps a consewative assump- tion given rhe experience in other transition economies).

    The sirnulation talde shows that in the hyper- inflationary conditions of J~inuary, the systein's I~reake\~en spreacl for a return on equity of 5 per- cent shoulcl have been about 520 percentage points. or 31inost seven times the actual average spread in IJkraine's 1,anking system for that month (tahle 1). In July, after a dramatic Fall in the an- nualized rate of inflation. the Ixeakeven spre:ld should 1i:ive been 98.5 percer1t:lge points, yet the actual avel-aye spread was about 46 percentage points. Only if the share of nonperforniing loans dicl not exceed 5 percent-a very unlikely possi- 11ility-would banks have 11een able to achieve a 5 ~ x r w n t real return on assets in July.

    These results must 11e interpreted with caution. With the dramatic and unpredictable changes in inf1;ition cluring the first half of 1995, it would be hard for :in); bank to get its prices exactly right. Furthermore. the model has many cxveats, includ- ing the fact rhat it ignores other sources of bank revenue, such as fee income. Moreover, the model looks at LJkraine's banking system as :I whole. Some large, formerly stire-owned banks with di- sastrous portfolios could he skewing the outcome, obscuring the profital~ility of banks with healthier ~~ortfolios. Nc:vertheless. the simulation shows that. :ilthough apparently \.cry wide, the nomin:ll spreads ol~served in Ukraine were not high enough for the banking system to break even at a j per- cent real rctllrn on equity. This suggests that the representative Lykl~inian bank cloes not recog- nize the extent of its portfolio prol>lems and is

    grossly underprovisioning for the assets in its port- folio that are at risk.

    The results for Ukraine should not be inter- preted to mean that bank spl-eads should sim- ply rise to yielcl a reasonal3le rate of return. In all likelihoc)cl, more funclamental portfolio prob- lems, ~~nclercapitalization, and oppressive regu- latory constr:~ints (for example. heavy taxation. excessively tight restrictions on loan loss pro- visioning) need to I,e addressed. But what the model can do is alert policymakers to possil3ly

    TABLE 2 MONTHLY AND ANNUALIZED RATES OF INFIATION I N

    UKRAINE, 1995 (percent)

    Month Monthly ratea Annualized rate

    January

    February

    March

    April

    May June

    July

    a. Based on consumer price index.

    Source: Ministry of Statistics of Ukraine and World Bank staff estimates.

    ~1nsustain:lble situations and provide estimates of the effects of changes in the policy param- eters or the size of the spreads.

    References

    I)irrus, I'etrr, n.d. -"Corpor:lre Govrrnance In Cenrrvl F.urope: The Ride 1)f Hanks " I3ank for International Srtrlemcn~\, 13.1cle.

    H~.Naughton. 1)ian.l 1W" Ra~zkin,q Instit~rtio?~.~ iiz Ilc.l.elrgit~g .Mur- k l s . WII. I . UuiWirr# Slrong,i

  • Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High?

    TABLE 3 BREAKEVEN SPREADS FOR A 5 PERCENT TARGETED RETLIRN ON EQUITY

    Ratio of nonperforming loans to assets Inflation Resenre (percent) ratio 0.01 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.30

    10 0.05 0.032 0.038 0.046 0.055 0.065 0.090 10 0.10 0.039 0.045 0.054 0.064 0.076 0.105 10 0.15 0.046 0.053 0.063 0.075 0.088 0.121 10 0.20 0.054 0.062 0.074 0.087 0.102 0.141 10 0.25 0.064 0.073 0.086 0.101 0.118 0.165 10 0.30 0.074 0.085 15 o.m 0,026 o.on 15 0 . 1 0435 0.01 15 0.1Q 0.W 0.159 15 0.15 o,m o . 0 ~ 15 0 2 0 0 a 7 0.078 15 0.25 tM189 0.093 I S D.30 0.095 @,to9 20 0.00 0.027 0.037 20 0.05 0.038 0.049 20 0.10 0.050 0.062 20 0.15 0.064 0.077 0.095 0.116 0.140 0.200 20 0.20 0.079 0.093 0.114 0.138 0.165 0.236 20 0.25 20 0.30 PO 0.00 OD 0.B 30, aro 30 0.1 5 33 0.20 30 0.25 30 030 50 0.00 50 0.05 50 0.10 0.086 0.113 0.151 0.194 0.243 0.365 50 0.1 5 0.117 0.148 0.190 0.239 0.295 0.436 50 0.20 0.153 0.187 0.235 0.290 0.354 0.519 50 0.25 0.192 50 0.30 0.237

    0.00 lW 0.05

    0.038 169 0.089 100 0.10 0.145 169 0.15 0207 100 0 2 0 OZ?5 1OD 0.25 0153 TOO 030 0.440 150 0.15 0.296 175 0.15 0.340 0.443 0.587 0.751 0.940 1.419

    1 184 0.15 0.356 0.464 0.615 0.787 0.985 1.487 1 200 0.15 0.385 0.502 0.667 0.854 1.069 1.616 500 0.1 5 0.920 1.212 1.619 2.084 2.619 3.975

    Note:Assumas that tax rate = 0, interest rate on resetves = 0, deposit rate = inflation rate, real return on equity = O.llS, capital-asset ratio = 0.08, and ratio of operating costs to assets = 0.02.

  • Emerging Markets Beyond Mexico

    and Financial

    In the wake of the blesican financial crisis. too much attention has heen given to what was hap- pening in emerging economies and too little to what was changing in financial markets. Easily forgotten now is that within weeks of the Mexi- can devaluation in December 1994, the unprec- cdentecl power of financial m:lrkets nr:ls twice demonstr:lted. and with equal clrama. in the clo\vnk~ll of O ~ l n g e County. California, :lnd of the venerable narings Bank. Such events sug- gest that enlerging m:~rket investors and bor- rowers must derive lessons not only from their olvn experience but also froni the broader changes in market structilre and hehavior.

    What are these changes? First, much of the capital flowing to emerging markets is now- in the form of honcls ;tnd portfolio equity investn~ent. Sec- ond. in\.estors managing these flows are :~ttracted to high-risk, high-return opportunities :~ncl are less patient than the foreign direct investors or hanks that emerging market governments may have heen inore used to dealing with. Third. these in~,estors ha\-e no n a y of communicating their patience le\,el to polic)7makers other than by exit. And foilrth, high information costs tend to concentrate these flows in "hot" countries ancl 1e;lcl investors to rely on a few knowleclge:tble o lxeners tu signal ~ v h e n their returns are at risk. :iclcling to the potential vol:~tility. These changes require a new perspective and new fi- nancial management capacity in both the pub- lic and the private sector.

    Origins of volatility

    "Putting the financial genie back in the hottle" I>y silnply restricting the flow of capital, as some suggest. is not an option. Why? Because \.ola- tilit): predated the flows. It m-as, ironically, m:lr-

    ket volatility that in large p:lrt caused the globalization of financial markets in the first place. Until the 1970s, most international capi- tal flows were fairly steady, passing through banks as a means of settling underlying tracle in goods ancl senices . Then oil price inflation. budget and tracle deficits, and a variety of speculative bubbles appeared. The U.S. Fed- eral Reserve abandoned its policy of targeting stable interest rates and announced that the best remedy for these ills was to ste:tdy growth in the supply of money. This policy shift set off unprecedented worldwide interest rate swings to accompany already volatile exchange rates. As interest rate targets dropped, economic volatility was transformed into financial asset volatility, :1nd the markets responded.

    Kather than following tr:lde, growing pools of sav- ings, increasingly managed by sophisticated, com- petitive institutions, began to flow across borders in search of much higher returns or, for the fainter of hear-t, portfolio diversification. These flows in- creasecl as nominal interest rates in the lJnited States fell through the mid-1980s. Financial de- regulation was embracecl as a way to free institu- tions to deal with the volatility that threatened their access to funds or their ability to diversify into new businesses and nl:~rkets. And new technolo- gies allowed investors and intermediaries to complete transactions quickly and securely. Com- munications and information engineers rnade it possible to talk, trade. and settle across borders and time zones. Meanwhile, a new class of finan- cid engineers developed security stnictures :~nd derivatives that enahled investors to build inrer- national exposure-and to affect international market levels-without e\.er leaving their home market. Then it v a s only a matter of rime before global capital discovered-and in some senses

  • 22 Emerging Markets and Financial Volatility-Beyond Mexico -

    created-the "emerging markets." And in the early 1990s, investors who had mastered the art of seek- ing out returns and diversification wherever they could were quick to recognize the opportunities in the newly liberalized economies in Latin America, East and Southeast Asia, the hsliddle East, and even Central Europe.

    An unstoppable virtuous cycle had begun, or s o the thinking went. Growing pools of savings in aging industrial countries would continue to find superior investment returns by building expo- sure to faster-growing developing countries. In turn, the integration of these countries with world

    . . . highly quantitative managen intentionally create eqoszr r+t#ically representing a small share of assets -to h@-risk, h&h-return classes of investments. Taken together; such investme~zts can make ztp a large share of l@tly capitalized markets, reinforcing the markets' volatility.

    financial markets would assure a level of con- nectivity and discipline that would prevent the kind of economic backsliding that had earlier soured such investments. It was presumed that newly powerful capital market forces would de- mand great discipline on the part of borrowers, with investors able to sell their holdings and refuse to invest again. After the loan failures of the 1970s and 1980s, when many commercial banks, try- ing to bail themselves out. threw good money after bad in lending to long-time customers, capi- tal markets were expected to reduce volatility and its underlying conditions. But as things have turned out, the information content of the capi- tal flows and the discipline they could instill in borrowers were both overestimated. And, as the Mexican experience shows, volatility was too often-and at great risk-simply assumed away.

    What has changed?

    Capital need not :~lnrays be crossing borders in record flows for it to he "global," nor can w e expect investment flows to expand in an unin- terrupted fashion. Still. capital flows now result from deliberate locational decisions by inves- tors and borrowers who have considered glo- bal alternatives. Flows will slow from time to time. Incieed, after tripling from an average US$50 billion a year in 1989-91 to US$159 bil- lion in 1993, investment flows to developing countries rose by only 5 percent to USS167 bil- lion in 1994 and hy some estimates fell by up to 20 percent in 1995.

    The question now is, how does volatility affect emerging market investors, borrowers, and the market itself? To answer this, it is important to note the dramatic shifts in the composition of investment in developing countries since it ex- plodecl during the early 1990s. These flows are not "stodgy" olci hank loans. Commercial bank 1o:lns have fallen sharply-from more than 20 percent of total capital flows to developing coun- tries in the late 1980s to less than 4 percent in the past four years. Limited hy balance sheet capac- ity and banks' new focus on fee-generating busi- ness, bank loans and syndications have given way to securities issues. Bonds reach a much broader range of investors, many of whose po- tentially longer-term and less-leveraged liabilities are well suited to bond assets. These investors are also willing to bear risks because of their ahility to diversify portfolios and their perceived ability to trade assets actively when conditions appear to shift.

    Capital flows to developing countries in the form of debt securities reached 25 percent (or US$42 hillion) in 1993. But bonds are not the only fi- nancial market instnlment being traded. Dynamic equity portfolio investments have grown froill low levels to nearly another quarter of capital flows. These portfolios interact with increasingly well-developed stock markets. Or investors can trade them without ever leaving the comfort of their home market I,y using American or global depository receipts, which represent interests in emerging market companies.

  • The World Bank Group 23 - - - --

    Not all equity investments are held in trading portfolios. of course. In f x t , nearly half the capi- tal flows t o developing countries represent di- rect foreign investment (like that in plant and equipment) hy strategically minded glotjal cor- porations. Still. some tJS$6i t>illion of capital- ahout 30 percent more than the total ~ lnnual investment flows just five years a g ~ h a s flowed in each of the p:lst few years to developing coun- tries in the form of bonds and portfolio equity investments.

    The profile of these investments is decidedly less patient than that of the direct foreign in- vestment whose presence in part attracts them. The n e w investors appreciate vo1:ltility. Their often llighll- quantitative inanagers intention- ~rlly create exposure-typically representing a small sh;~se of assets-to high-risk, high-return classes of investments. Taken together, such investments can make u p a large share of lightly capitalized markets. reinforcing the markets' volatility. And einerging markets :Ire well suited to the nen7 investors. Nen:ly opened econo- mies present opportunities for n:indfall gains : ~ t the same time that thev are steering through the uncharted waters of adjustment (which occasionally turn windfalls into waterfalls). Moreover. the performance of many firms in the eincrging economies is tied to the fate of their 1narkc.t. This phenomenon, along with the high inform~ition and transaction costs of deal- ing in a wide variety of equity a n d debt instru- ments, can lead to holdings concentrated in a few countries o r companies. again adding to volatility. For example. during the 1990s. 84 percent of private capital flows to developing countries have gone to just twelve countries. with ne:lrly 30 percent going to China and ahout 13 percent to Mexico. Trouble in o n e of these countries cannot but have a major impact o n the market ;IS a whole.

    Financial market in\ estors compensate for their lack of intimate knowledge of-and long-tern~ relationships with-the countries and compa- nies in which they invest with hair triggers o n their investments. They count on other. Inore knowlectgea1)le ohsen~ers to signal when returns Itre in jeopardy. They expect such sign:lls t o be

    reflected quickly in market prices, which are in turn affected by the relatively large number of investors whose decisions are linked to price performance. Prices are therefore more likely to rise o r fall precipitously. The trouble is that the markets have n o easy way to transmit their time-bound expectations and their ongoing judg- ments to borrowers. As long as prices are high. both investors and borrowers tend to presume that all is o n track. Neither pays enough atten- tion to fundamentals. Investors believe that oth- ers will want to buy their stakes when it is time to take profits. And borrowers draw from the price charts and their success stories a sense

    . . . the messagefrom investors was not that all was well. It was simp@ that they would give Mexico another chancc-as long as it absorbed more ofthe market rtsk.

    that their job is done. By the time it becomes clear that not enough has been done to support long-term investments, there is little or n o mar- gin left for completing the task.

    Economic management implications

    In view of the benefits of financial integration- increased trade, more uniform market rates (ad- justed for risk a n d inflation), a n d a higher potential for gron-th-investors and developing country capital i~nporters both must understand h o w the other responds to financial volatility.

    So how should investors adapt? Recent esperi- ence suggests that investors might be well served to ignore traditional counsel against "fighting the tape" and hegin to rely less o n market trends as a guide to investment strategy. Developed mar- kets in which trend analysis is used enjoy rela- tively complete information flon:s a n d a re populatecl by a wide variety of investors with different objectives and time horizons. In thinner and more crisis-prone enlerging markets, inves-

  • 24 Emerging Markets and Financial Volatility-Beyond Mexico

    tors should consider the underlying fundamen- tals for the countries and companies-not only policies and the commitment and ability to imple- ment them, but also the ability to nunage in the wake of financial volatility.

    There is already l~road agreement on the impor- tance of hetter-quality information on the fund;i- mental condition of economies into which glohal funds are flowing. But this is not a panacea, nor will it improve the situation i1nmedi:itely. It might even slow capital flows don-n for a while. Soine investors will be deterred by the information they receive or by the dil'ficulty of determining how others in the market will respond to such data. And it might take time for existing or prospec- tive investors to reclassifj. their emerging n~arket assets away from the most high-risk. high-return categories, while in the short run they coulcl choose to reduce their portfolio esposure to all developing country securities.

    The countries on the recei\.ing encl of glohal capital flows. meanwhile, face substantial risk along with high opportunity. The cost of avoid- ing financial integration is unacceptably high. But integration is not costless; in the early stages of economic nncl financial reform, it can intro- duce a potential for higher financial volatility. That is why some countries have deliberately curbed investment inflows during long periocls of adjustment. But not ;111 have found this tradeoff attractive. Some attempt to integrate quickly into global financial markets even if their local markets are not yet cle\.elopecl to global standards. This leads to a pattern of events that by now has been repeated in several countries, notably in Latin America but also in such coun- tries as Turkey. In the typical scenario, econonlic adjustment is led by tight-money policies aimcd at reducing clironic inflation. This generates sub- stantial inflows of foreign funds and heavy re- patriation of overse;ls holdings. Success in this phase, however, does not necessarily signal :I capacity in the economy to absorb investment flows. Countries that have .'sufferedu such a sur- feit of capital inflo\vs relative to their ability to deploy then1 in a fi~lly procluctive way find that international markets continue investing even

    when trade deficits balloon, growth remains anemic. banking weakness reflects poor invest- ment perforrn:ince, and the po1itic:ll will to com- plete the reform is lacking.

    Investors' reaction to conditions in Mesico throughout 1994 and 1995 was. of course. the extreme case. ,4s the markets there began to pla- teau, competitive investment yields rose ancl in- vestors became war).. Outflows were stemmeel by offering higher returns and through financial engineering that lowered investors' risks. But the message from investors was not that all was well. It was simply that they would give Mexico an- other chance-as long as it absorbed more of the market risk. Even if this was recognized in Mexico as well as outside, it was not clear that the Mexicans were granted enough time or room to f i s the economy to meet inarket expectations, nor coulcl they easily change those espectations. Clearly, officials must learn to manage the eco- nomic f~~ndamentals that it is in their power to affect. to inform investors of their progress, and to listen carefillly to the feedback that the mar- ket offers. Market jitters d o not necessarily re- quire filnclament:ll rethinking, nor does market euphoria suggest that necessary reforms can be postponed. But the stakes are rising, and the win- dow of opportunity for action is shrinking.

    Like other international financial institutions, the World Bank too must reconsicler its role in the wake of volatile global capital flows. Strategic advice ;lnd financial support can no longer be offered in ;I m;irket vacuum. The message of market flows must feed into Bank operations, and the Bank must try to improve the inform;l- tion content of its advice to client countries. Fi- nally. while the Bank's need to address long-run fundamentals is increasingly important, so too is the need to help client countries irnpro1.e their capacity to anticipate, avoid, and manage the crises of volatility that can accompany economic liberalization and financial integration.

    Gag' Perlir~, Directo~. Financial Sector Derjelop- n1c2nt Dcp~tment (appointed Lace President and Treasr/,er qf the World Bank, efl~ctive &larch 19961

  • Pension Funds and Capital Markets Investment regulation, financial innovation, and governance

    The volatility in emerging markets during 1995 has reinforced the importance of local capital market de\relopment. Chile's resilient financial illarkets provicle some useful lessons on the role pension funcls can play in generating long- term financial resources and facilitating the growth of c~lpital markets. The experience of Chile and incleed of several OECD, East Asian. and other Latin American countries shows that both pension funds and capital markets can thrive under the right macroeconomic poli- cies-lo\v infl:ition, small budget deficits, and positive long-tel-m real rates of interest.

    This Note briefly examines the dynamic inter- action that can develop between pension funcls and capital markets. Pension funds are not only a source of long-term savings to support the development of bond ancl equity markets. They can also be a positive force for innovation, for corporate governance, and for privatization. In turn, capital markets offer pension funds the opportunity for better portfolio returns and risk management. This interaction is a long, self- reinforcing process that builds on sound macroeconomic policies, effective regulatory reforms, ancl robust accounting, legal, and in- formation infrastructure.

    The key message for policymakers is that pen- sion reform should be part of a broad reform program. It need not be delayecl until capital markets :Ire well established. But, equally important. large quantities of state assets sho~lld not be transferred to newly formecl private pension funds-or, even worse, to state petision funds-without first taking steps to develop ro11~1st and -.ell-regulated capital markets. Chile's graclual approach to invest- ment deregulation is a good moclel for devel-

    oping countries introducing mandatory but de- centralized pension systems (see box).

    Pool of long-term financial savings

    Although the quantitative effect of pension sav- ing on total savings is unclear and hotly de- bated, there can be little doubt that funded pension schemes lead to a big increase in long- term financial savings that can underpin capi- tal market development.

    The size of accumulated long-term f~~ncls depends on the maturity of the schemes, their coverage, the contribution rate, and the investment rate of return. The experience of Malaysia, Singapore, and, more recently, Chile shows that, once in place, a credible and well-run pension system can accumulate long-tern~ resources rapidly. In Singapore, the resources of the Central Provident Fund rose from 28 percent of GDP in 1976 to 73 percent in 1986 and 76 percent in 1990, and in Malaysia, provident fund assets grew from 18 percent of GDP in 1980 to 41 percent in 1990 (table 1). Chile's pension system expanded from a mere 1 percent of GDP in 1981 to 9 percent in 1985, 26 percent in 1990, and 43 percent in 1994. Aclding the assets of insurance companies brings contractual savings in Chile to nearly j j percent of GDP. Large increases were also experienced in OECD countries with funded pension schemes.

    Although the large accumulations of financial resources in these countries are sometimes smaller than the total assets of hanks, their eco- nornic significance is often greater, because con- tractual savings are not inflated by interbank borrowing and lending. Pension and insurance reserves are the largest component of house- l~old financial wealth in all these countries.

  • 26 Pension Funds a n d Capital Marke ts -

    INVESTMENT LIMITS: CHILE'S GRADUAL APPROACH

    Chile applied very tight investment limits when i t created its new,

    government-mandated but privately managed pension system.

    Initially, the investment limits were 100 percent for state securities,

    80 percent for mortgage bonds, 70 percent for bank liabilities, 60

    percent for corporate bonds, and 20 percent for quotas of pension

    funds. The limit on bank liabilities was reduced to 40 percent in

    1932. In 1985, the limit on state securities was lowered to 50 percent

    and that on corporate bonds to 40 percent. Pension funds were

    permitted to invest up to 30 percent of their value in equities of

    privatized state enterprises, but no more than 5 percent for any one

    enterprise. In 1986, pension funds were also allowed to invest in

    corporations with dispersed ownership. Investments in real estate

    companies were permitted in 1989, subject to a global limit and a

    limit for individual companies. Pension funds were authorized to

    invest in foreign securities in 1990, subject to a very low and slowly

    increasing limit. At the same time, the limit on state securities was

    lowered further to 45 percent, while the limits on bank liabilities and

    corporate bonds were raised to 50 percent Investments in venture

    capital and infrastructure funds were permitted in 1993, and in 1995

    the limit on equity holdings was raised to 37 percent and that on

    foreign securities to 9 percent. Chile has also imposed limits on

    holdings of the securities of individual companies in order to prevent

    the concentration of risk. See the table below for the investment

    profile of Chilean pension funds.

    INVESTMENT PROFILE OF CHILEAN PENSION FUNDS

    (percentage of total assets)

    Type of asset 1981 1985 1990 1 994

    State securities 28 43 44 40

    Bank deposits 62 21 17 5

    Mortgage bonds 9 35 16 14

    Corporate bonds 1 1 11 6

    Corporate equities 0 0 11 32

    Other 0 0 1 3

    Total 100 100 100 100

    Source: Administradoras de Fondos de Pensionas.

    To b o n d o r equ i ty markets?

    Historically, whether pension fund assets flow into bond or equity markets has usually been a matter

    of regulation (investment limits) and attitude toward risk. U.K. pension funds' emphasis o n equities is attributed to their freedom fro111 de- tailed regulations and to the adverse effect o n bond returns of the high inflation of the 1960s and 1970s (table 2) . U.S. pension funds invest 46 percent of their resources in real assets and 54 percent in debt instruments. Although both countries apply the "prudent man" rule to pen- sion fund investments and do not specify lim- its on different tI7pes and classes of assets, U.S. pension fund investment policies are more conservative as a result of the minimum fund- ing requirements imposed by pension law. Continental European countries show a stron- ger predilection for bonds. The low level of equity holdings by European pension funds is often attributed to tight investment limits. But in rnost cases the limits are not binding, and the investment policies are due to a more con- servative approach.

    In Singapore and Malaysia, most pension funds are placed in government bonds and other debt instruments, with only a very small proportion going into equities. But Singapore and to a lesser extent Malaysia allow workers to invest their provident fund balances in housing and other approved securities. Singapore has recently per- mitted investments in foreign securities, and Ma- laysia is likely to follow suit. Chile did not initially allow pension funds to invest in equities and still subjects them to strict rules with maximum limits on investments in different instruments and issu- ers. These limits, designed to ensure adequate risk diversification, have been re1:lsed over time. Chile allowed equity investments in the mid- 1980s, first in privatizecl utilities and then in other companies, and recently raised the equity limit to 37 percent of a pension fund's assets.

    To local o r fo re ign marke ts?

    Pension fund investment in foreign assets is a controversial but important issue for :111 coun- tries. International diversific:~tion may increase portfolio returns. especially if pension funds :Ire too big for the size of the local capital markets. Most important, it helps reduce investment risk I~ecause of the less than perfect cov:~riance in

  • investment returns :rc'ross countries. But unre- stricted foreign investment may institutionalize capital flight and prevent clomestic markets from reaping the benefits of creating pension funds with long-term financial resources. For these rea- sons, most developing countries limit foreign in- vestments. Chile, for example, did not allow overseas in17estments until 1990. It recently rnisecl the limit for investments in overseas securities to 9 percent of assets (4.5 percent for foreign equi- ties). even though actu~ll holdings of foreign se- curities were less than 1 percent of assets, well t x low the 1,revious limit of 6 percent. Chile also recently allowed pension funds to engage in cur- rency t~eclging operations.

    In inclustri;~l countries, pension funds h21r.e built u p substantial holdings of foreign equities a n d honds since the removal of exchange controls from the earl)- 1980s onward and the relax- ation of in\,estment rilles. These holdings range from well over 50 percent for the typical pen- sion fund in Hong Kong to over 20 percenl in Australia, New Zealand, and the United King- dom. In the L7nited States, foreign investments account for only about 10 percent of total as- sets. reflecting the co~lntry 's large size ancl per- haps the ~lhility to diversify risks I>y investing in U.S. multinationals.

    Lessons o n l imits

    Investment lirnits are unnecessary for industrial countries. with their well-established financial markets and sophisticated supenrisory agencies. The "pn~clent man" rule and fiduciary diligence s l ~ o ~ ~ l d sc~l'fice to ensure adequate diversifica- tion ancl cilstoclial protection of p ~ n s i o n f ~ l n d assets. But in cleveloping countries, initially tight and detailed investment nlles are justified by the absence of strong and tzmsparent capital markets, the co~npulsory n~ltilre of the pension system, and the pension filnd members' lack of k~~niliarity wit11 capital market investments. These rules should Ile systematically relaxed as do- mestic capital markets grow and mature.

    As a gener:~l rille. prudent policy would initizllly favor in\ estments in indexed government bonds on rnrlrket-determined terms. Relaxation of invest-

    T h e Wor ld Bank Group

    TABLE 1 PENSION FUND AND LIFE INSURANCE ASSETS

    (percentage of GDP)

    Country 1970 1980 1990

    Switzerland

    Netherlands

    United Kingdom

    United States

    Singaporea

    Malaysia8

    Chilea

    South Africa

    ..Not available. a. Refers to pension fund assets only. b. 1976. c. 1981. Source:National central banks.

    TABLE 2 ALLOCATION OF PENSION FUND ASSETS. 1990

    (percent)

    Country Real assets Debt instruments

    Switzerland 33 67

    Netherlands 31 69

    United Kingdom 72 28

    United States 46 54

    Singaporea 2 98

    Malaysiaa 2 98

    Chile 20 80

    South Africa 60 40

    a. Does not include workers'direct invesbnents in housing and approved securities. Source:National central banks.

    ment rules, such as lowering the ceiling o n gov- ernment bonds and permitting investment in eq- uities, could come when pension f lnd assets reach, say. 5 percent of GDP, and permission to invest in overseas assets when they reach, say. 20 percent of CDP. Small countries could give permission to invest overseas earlier and allow a higher limit for foreign assets than larger countries with more di- versified capital markets.

    Force for innovation

    Pension filnds can play a big part in encourag- ing financial innovation a n d stimillating the

  • 28 Pension Funds and Capital Markets

    modernization of capital markets. As pension funds grow in size and relative importance, new instruments are developed to meet their needs and to f i l l perceived gaps in the markets. In the United States, for example, the develop- ment of securitization and financial derivatives has been attributed at least in part to the in- vestment and risk management needs of pen- sion funds and other institutional investors. The emergence of block trading and the reform of stock exchanges around the world, including the abolition of fixed con~nlissions, can also be attributed to the growth of pension funds and other institutional investors.

    Pension funds can act as catalysts for the devel- opment of efficient trading and settlement sys- tems, the adoption of modern accounting and auditing standards, and the promotion of mean- ingful information disclosure. But their impact on trading efficiency and on market liquidity also depends on their investment policies. In countries where pension funds acquire strate- gic holdings and follon- a policy of "buy and hold:" their effect on market liquidity is small. But heavy trading is often criticized as exces- sive and m