Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

download Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

of 16

Transcript of Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    1/16

    Production Technologies in StochasticContinuous Time Models

    Klaus Wlde

    CESIFO WORKING PAPERNO.2831CATEGORY 6:FISCAL POLICY,MACROECONOMICS AND GROWTH

    OCTOBER2009

    An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded

    from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com

    from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org

    from the CESifo website: Twww.CESifo-group.org/wpT

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    2/16

    CESifo Working Paper No. 2831

    Production Technologies in StochasticContinuous Time Models

    Abstract

    Properties of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models can be revealed by either usingnumerical solutions or qualitative analysis. Very precise and intuition-building results areobtained by working with models which provide closed-form solutions. Closed-formsolutions are known for a large class of models some of which, however, have someundesirable features. This paper offers closed-form solutions for models which are just astractable but do not suffer from these shortcomings.

    JEL Code: E20, O40.

    Keywords: dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, closed-form solution, continuoustime, jump diffusion.

    Klaus Wlde

    Mainz School of Management and Economics

    University of Mainz

    Jakob-Welder-Weg 4

    55131 Mainz

    Germany

    [email protected]

    October 2009I am grateful to Florian Nolte for very valuable research assistance.

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    3/16

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    4/16

    constraint with differential formulations of the technology such that the formulation of thetechnology is standard. In this reading, our contribution is this reinterpretation and thegeneralization of results to a setup with a Wiener process and many Poisson processes.

    2 The model

    2.1 The planner

    We study a classic saving-investment problem. A social planner chooses the amount ofconsumption () so as to maximize a social welfare function representing expected utilityof infinitely-lived households,

    =

    Z

    [] (()) , (1)

    where denotes the time preference rate. The instantaneous utility function is of the CRRAclass,

    (()) =

    (()11

    1for 6= 1

    log () for = 1 (2)

    We see this central planner view as a short-cut to a decentralized economy without anydistortions. All of the results which will follow below will therefore also hold in an economywith many households.

    2.2 Differential representation of the technology

    This section presents the approach which specifies technologies by a differential. In orderto be comparable as much as possible to the approach appearing in section 2.3.2 below, wemodify the differential setup, as it can be found in the literature, in two ways. First, we makethe depreciation rate explicit. The depreciation rate is is usually implicitly contained inthe constant production technology factor We replace by which is of course just anotational matter and does not alter any of the implications of the differential model. Second,instead of adding a stochastic component in the equation for the production technology wesubtract this term. Again, this is just a notational matter and only changes the signs ofthe corresponding parameters of the stochastic processes considered. It will, however, beadvantageous later when comparing the approach we suggest with this differential approach.

    The production process of an economy can now be specified - following a large part ofthe literature as cited in the introduction - by

    () = ( ) () () () , (3)

    where () is aggregate output in , ( ) is a constant measure of the TFP less thedeterministic depreciation rate , () is the capital stock, and the increment () will bespecified below. The flow of output is used for capital accumulation and for consumption,modeled as

    () = () + () . (4)

    3

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    5/16

    Combining equations (3) and (4) gives the expression for the capital accumulation which isequal to investment2

    () = (( ) ()()) () () (5)

    This and similar processes are used for example by Evans and Kenc (2003), Gertler andGrinols (1982), Gokan (2002), Gong and Zou (2002, 2003), Grinols and Turnovsky (1998a,1998b), Steger (2005), or Turnovsky (1993). In most of these papers the stochastic incrementin eq. (3) is defined to be () = () where () is a Brownian motion and the issome variance measure of output.

    While some authors acknowledge (see e.g. footnote 4 in Grinols and Turnovsky (1998a))the fact that this implies the possibility of a negative , we briefly recapitulate this propertyhere by simply solving the differential equation (3) starting in = 0 with (0) 0 and(0) 0,

    () = 0 + ( )Z

    0

    () Z

    0

    () ()

    To see that this is in fact a solution of the above flow-representation just apply Itos Lemmaand recover (3).3 This says that with a constant factor input , i.e. () = 0+( ) (), output in is determined by a deterministic and a stochastic part. The latter one isoften interpreted to reflect various random elements affecting output production (e.g. Gongand Zou, 2003). Ignoring 0 the deterministic part ( ) implies linear growth (i.e. notexponential growth as is usually the case and empirically more relevant) and the stochasticpart () implies deviations from the trend. As () is Brownian motion, the sum of thedeterministic and the stochastic part can become negative.

    The unusual formulation in (3) and the property that () can become negative might be

    two reasons why this approach is not as popular as it could be. We will now present standardformulations of technologies which make models just as tractable as with this formulation.

    2.3 Standard representation of the technology

    We now present technologies in the standard way. We use a typical structure and intro-duce uncertainty either through uncertainty in TFP - standard I - or through uncertaintyin the capital accumulation process - standard II.

    2.3.1 Standard I: stochastic TFP

    This section will now preserve the spirit of the technology used above - the AK-structure -but expresses the technology in a way such that it has standard properties. The economy

    2 This equation (5) can be obtained under the additional assumption that that () = () where...consumption over the instant occurs at the non-stochastic rate () . (cf. Turnovsky and Smith(2006) on page 251). The expression () = () can be found expicitly e.g. in Grinols and Turnovsky(1998a) on page 503 or in Turnovsky (2000) on page 400 and is at odds with the prediction of this model (seefurther below) that optimal consumption is a constant fraction of the capital stock, i.e. () = () making consumption stochastic and not just a function () times the deterministic time differential .

    3 For an introduction to the methods behind this and for more background, see Wlde (2009, part IV).

    4

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    6/16

    produces the final good according to

    () = () () . (6)

    Capital is the only factor of production and TFP is given by (). It follows the stochasticprocess

    () = () + () () , (7)

    where the increment () in its most general formulation will be specified below as acombination of one Wiener and many Poisson processes.

    Capital accumulation is equal to investments () = ()() net of depreciation,

    () = ( () ()()) . (8)

    2.3.2 Standard II: stochastic depreciation

    There is an alternative where output is left in the standard formulation (6), TFP remainsconstant at , i.e. () = 0, and hence (7) is not valid. In contrast, following Rebeloand Xie (1999), we assume that capital accumulation is stochastic. Let there be a standardgoods market clearing condition () = () + () but let capital accumulation be risky,e.g. by a stochastic depreciation process:

    () = () () ( + ()) .

    Again, () is a combination of a Wiener and Poisson processes. This capital accumula-tion equation gives, together with the goods market clearing condition and the productiontechnology, an expression of

    () = (() ()()) () () . (9)

    Notice that this equation is identical to the capital accumulation process of the differentialsetup in (5). Hence, if () is a simple Brownian motion we have a similar formulation ofthe resource constraint as Eaton (1981) and others, only that we have obtained it with amore standard setup with standard output and a stochastic capital accumulation process.

    The interpretation that the stochastic part of the capital accumulation process is theresult of stochastic depreciation was already suggested by Eaton (1981, footnote 2). Inthe differential approach, stochastic capital accumulation is the result of combining theassumptions about the stochastic evolution of output in (3) and the goods market clearingcondition in (4). By contrast, in the standard II approach proposed here, the fact that capitalaccumulation is risky is an assumption which results in a stochastic evolution of output.

    This has the advantage of explicitly specifying where uncertainty comes from and avoidsspecifications of output which can easily be criticized. With more conventional technologiesas proposed here, the continuous time approach to uncertainty could become more popular.

    3 Closed form solutions

    It is well-known that closed form solutions exist for a variety of models. Table 1 summarizesthe structure of the models presented above and provides a preview of the optimal consump-tion levels. This section generalizes existing closed-form solutions and compares them to the

    5

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    7/16

    new ones - which are based on models with standard production functions.

    Table 1: Model overview and preview of results

    differential standard I standard II

    (stoch. output) (stoch. TFP) (stoch. depreciation)output = ( ) = =

    TFP constant

    = + constantcapital = = =

    investment = = = stoch. process = +=1 identical identical

    log-utility = = = CES-utility = n.a. =

    The differential approach widely used in the literature and its features are presented in thesecond column. Approaches with standard production functions appear in columns threeand four. The notation used in this table is as in the text. The only new parameter is

    1

    ( ) + (1 )

    1

    22

    1

    =1

    (1 )

    1 1

    (10)

    Following the idea of Merton (1976), we allow the stochastic component () in thetechnology (column 2), in TFP (column 3) or in depreciation (column 4) to be a mixture ofboth a continuous and countably many jump processes, () = ()+=1 (), implyingthat

    () = () +

    =1 () . (11)The differential () stands for the increment of standard Brownian motion, i.e. () (0 ), whereas the () for = 1 describe increments of independent Poisson pro-cesses with arrival rates . By setting = 0 the formulation used by Eaton (1981) and inthe bulk of the literature thereafter is obtained. With = 0 a pure jump setup results.

    3.1 Differential approach

    The definition for uncertainty in (11) applied to the capital accumulation process in (5)yields

    () = (( ) ()()) () ()=1() () (12)

    In order to obtain a closed-form solution, one needs to solve the following nonlinear ordinarydifferential equation called the maximized Bellman equation (for the derivation, see app.6.1.1),

    () = log

    1

    +

    ( )

    1

    +

    1

    222+ (13)

    =1 ( ( ) ())

    6

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    8/16

    Solving requires an educated guess about the value function whose structure can be shownto be identical (cf. app. 6.1.2) to that one of the well-known case where = 0 (cf. e.g.Merton, 1969), i.e.

    () log()

    + (14)

    with

    = , = 1

    22 +=1 log (1 )

    2.

    This explicit form of the value function leads to the conclusion that optimal consumption isjust the constant fraction of the capital stock,

    () = () (15)

    The result that is a constant fraction of is robust to allowing a more general in-stantaneous utility function as in (2). This implies optimal consumption to be given by (cf.

    app. 6.1.3) () = () (16)

    where the constant is the one from (10).

    3.2 Standard approaches

    3.2.1 Standard I

    In contrast to the differential approach, we now let TFP () to be a function of time andstochastic disturbances. Allowing 6= 0 in the formulation for the TFP process (cf. eq.(7) with (11)), we specify the parameters , , , and the arrival rates of the Poisson

    processes such that () is a martingale, i.e. the expectation about the TFP level atsome future point in time is given by the current level, [ ()] = () for implyingthat () has no trend. Given the technology in (6), this assumption is made in orderto preserve a stationary expected growth rate of the economy which is governed by the

    marginal product of capital () (cf. app. 6.2.1). As [ ()] = () (+=1)() (cf.

    app. 6.2.2) the restriction of no trend in the TFP-process requires that

    +=1 = 0. (17)

    Economically speaking, given that the arrival rates are positive by construction, technolo-gical progress is either technological regress ( 0) or there are occasional negative shocks,

    i.e. 0 We find the second interpretation more plausible where oil price shocks, naturalor other disasters disrupt the smooth evolution of an economy. But it should be kept inmind that without an specification, one could allow for both positive and .

    With this setup and a logarithmic utility, the maximized Bellman equation is a secondorder nonlinear partial differential equation (cf. app. 6.2.3),

    ( ) = log

    1

    +

    1

    + +

    1

    2

    22+ (18)

    =1 ( ( + ) ( ))

    7

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    9/16

    It is standard in the literature to provide an educated guess and prove a verificationtheorem. Finding such a guess can sometimes be very time-consuming. For our case here in(18), we can be more systematic and derive a solution.

    Use the definition of the value function as the expected utility out of current and allfuture optimal consumption, ( ) max{()} subject to constraints where is theobjective function from (1). Looking at the results from the literature as well as from theprevious section, a plausible guess concerning optimal consumption is

    () () , (19)

    where the is an arbitrary constant. Inserting this conjecture into the objective functionwe can analyze whether the resulting integral can be solved. In fact, doing so by derivingexpressions for () from (8) and for () from (7) with (11), respectively, together withthe guess (19) gives (cf. app. 6.2.4)

    ( ) =

    Z

    () log() (())

    , (20)where

    = ( )1

    22 ( ) + () + log

    =1

    1 +

    =1

    ()

    Simplifying and solving this integral and dropping the time subscript (as this expressionholds for each point in time) yields the value function,

    =log

    +

    2

    +

    2. (21)

    It is easy to verify that, for = , this is indeed a solution to the maximized Bellman

    equation. Therefore it is confirmed that optimal consumption is a constant fraction of thecapital stock,

    () = () . (22)

    Unfortunately unlike in the case with the differential technology this result holds only forthe logarithmic utility (2) and not for the CRRA case of 6= 1

    3.2.2 Standard II with Brownian motion and many Poisson processes

    Fortunately, however, closed from solution can be found for CRRA utility functions with 6=1 and standard technologies. The alternative to stochastic TFP we propose is a stochastic

    capital accumulation technology via e.g. stochastic depreciation. Let the () in (9) againstand for a combination of a Wiener process and many Poisson processes as in (11):

    () = (()()) () ( + () + =1 ()) (23)

    Of course this equation is identical to the corresponding expression in the differential setup in(12). Therefore, computing the solution for the maximization problem of the social plannerboth in the case with log-utility (2) and in the case with the more general instantaneousutility function (2) leads to the same rule concerning optimal consumption, i.e. consumptionis just the constant fraction (cf. eq. (15)) and (cf. eq. (16)), respectively, of the capitalstock.

    8

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    10/16

    4 Conclusion

    The differential approach to specifying technologies is widely used. Specifications of tech-nologies of this type in continuous time models with uncertainty have undesirable features.These features might be one reason why modeling uncertainty in continuous time is not as

    popular in macroeconomics as it could be. One major advantage of these specifications istheir analytical tractability.

    This paper generalizes existing closed-form solutions for differential technologies. Moreimportantly, it proposes two alternative setups where technologies are modeled by standardproduction functions. In both cases, the undesirable features of the differential approach arenot present and the analytical tractability is preserved. Closed form solutions are providedfor both alternatives.

    One alternative implies solutions which are identical to solutions of models followingthe differential approach. This shows that all results obtained so far in the literature can bepreserved even without the undesirable features. For all future papers, analytical tractability

    can be obtained just as easily as before.

    5 Appendix

    The appendix is available upon request

    References

    Asea, P. K., and S. J. Turnovsky (1998): Capital income taxation and risk-taking in a small

    open economy, Journal of Public Economics, 68(1), 5590.

    Bianconi, M., and S. J. Turnovsky (2005): Welfare gains from stabilization in a stochastic-ally growing economy with idiosyncratic shocks and flexible labor supply, MacroeconomicDynamics, 9(3), 321357.

    Chattopadhyay, P., and S. J. Turnovsky (2004): Volatility and growth in developing econom-ies: some numerical results and empirical evidence, Journal of International Economics,59(2), 267295.

    Clemens, C., and S. Soretz (2004): Optimal fiscal policy, uncertainty, and growth, Journalof Macroeconomics, 26(4), 679697.

    Corsetti, G. (1997): A portfolio approach to endogenous growth: equilibrium and optimalpolicy, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21(10), 16271644.

    Eaton, J. (1981): Fiscal Policy, Inflation and the Accumulation of Risky Capital, Reviewof Economic Studies, 48(153), 435445.

    Epaulard, A., and A. Pommeret (2003): Recursive utility, endogenous growth, and thewelfare cost of volatility, Review of Economic Dynamics, 6(3), 672684.

    9

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    11/16

    Evans, L., and T. Kenc (2003): Welfare cost of monetary and fiscal policy shocks, Mac-roeconomic Dynamics, 7(2), 212238.

    Garca-Pealosa, C., and S. J. Turnovsky (2005): Production risk and the functional dis-tribution of income in a developing economy: tradeoffs and policy responses, Journal of

    Development Economics, 76(1), 175208.

    Gertler, M., and E. Grinols (1982): Monetary randomness and investment, Journal ofMonetary Economics, 10(2), 239258.

    Gokan, Y. (2002): Alternative government financing and stochastic endogenous growth,Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26(4), 681706.

    Gong, L., and H. fu Zou (2002): Direct preferences for wealth, the risk premium puzzle,growth, and policy effectiveness, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 26(2),247270.

    (2003): Military spending and stochastic growth, Journal of Economic Dynamicsand Control, 28(1), 153170.

    Grinols, E. L., and S. J. Turnovsky (1993): Risk, the financial market, and macroeconomicequilibrium, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17(1/2), 136.

    (1994): Exchange rate determination and asset prices in a stochastic small openeconomy, Journal of International Economics, 36(1/2), 7597.

    (1998a): Consequences of debt policy in a stochastically growing monetary eco-nomy, International Economic Review, 39(2), 495521.

    (1998b): Risk, Optimal Government Finance and Monetary Policies in a GrowingEconomy, Economica, 65(259), 401427.

    Kenc, T. (2004): Taxation, risk-taking and growth: a continuous-time stochastic generalequilibrium analysis with labor-leisure choice, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Con-trol, 28(8), 15111539.

    Koethenbuerger, M., and B. Lockwood (2009): Does Tax Competition Really PromoteGrowth?, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, forthcoming.

    Merton, R. C. (1969): Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 51(3), 247257.

    (1971a): Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model,Journal of Economic Theory, 3(4), 373414.

    (1971b): Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous, Journalof Financial Economics, 3(1-2), 125144.

    (1975): An Asymptotic Theory of Growth under Uncertainty, The Review ofEconomic Studies, 42(3), 375393.

    10

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    12/16

    Oksendal, B., and A. Sulem (2005): Applied Stochastic Control of Jump Diffusions,Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg.

    Pommeret, A., and W. T. Smith (2005): Fertility, volatility, and growth, Economics Let-ters, 87(3), 347353.

    Rebelo, S., and D. Xie (1999): On the optimality of interest rate smoothing, Journal ofMonetary Economics, 43(2), 263282.

    Santanu Chatterjee, P. G., and S. J. Turnovsky (2004): Capital Income Taxes and Growthin a Stochastic Economy: A Numerical Analysis of the Role of Risk Aversion and Inter-temporal Substitution, Journal of Public Economic Theory, 6(2), 277310.

    Smith, W. T. (1996): Taxes, uncertainty, and long-term growth, European EconomicReview, 40(8), 16471664.

    Steger, T. M. (2005): Stochastic growth under Wiener and Poisson uncertainty, EconomicsLetters, 86(3), 311316.

    Turnovsky, S. J. (1993): Macroeconomic policies, growth, and welfare in a stochastic eco-nomy, International Economic Review, 34(4), 953981.

    (1999a): Productive government expenditure in a stochastically growing economy,Macroeconomic Dynamics, 3, 544570.

    (1999b): On the role of government in a stochastically growing open economy,Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 23(5/6), 873908.

    (2000): Government Policy in a Stochastic Growth Model with Elastic LaborSupply, Journal of Public Economic Theory, 2(4), 389433.

    Turnovsky, S. J., and W. T. Smith (2006): Equilibrium consumption and precautionarysavings in a stochastically growing economy, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control,30(2), 243278.

    Wlde, K. (2009): Applied Intertemporal Optimization. Lecture notes, University of Mainz,Available at www.waelde.com/aio.

    11

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    13/16

    CESifo Working Paper Seriesfor full list see Twww.cesifo-group.org/wpT(address: Poschingerstr. 5, 81679 Munich, Germany, [email protected])

    ___________________________________________________________________________

    2769Alessandro Balestrino, Kind of Black: The Musicians Labour Market in Italy, August2009

    2770Yosr Abid Fourati and Cathal ODonoghue, Eliciting Individual Preferences for PensionReform, August 2009

    2771Christian Breuer and Chang Woon Nam, VAT on Intra-Community Trade and BilateralMicro Revenue Clearing in the EU, August 2009

    2772Choudhry Tanveer Shehzad, Jakob De Haan and Bert Scholtens, Growth and EarningsPersistence in Banking Firms: A Dynamic Panel Investigation, August 2009

    2773Erdal Yalcin, Uncertain Productivity Growth and the Choice between FDI and Export,August 2009

    2774Klaus Abberger, Wolfgang Nierhaus and Shynar Shaikh, Findings of the SignalApproach for Financial Monitoring in Kazakhstan, September 2009

    2775Sascha O. Becker, Francesco Cinnirella and Ludger Woessmann, The Trade-off between Fertility and Education: Evidence from before the Demographic Transition,September 2009

    2776Thomas Aronsson and Erkki Koskela, Optimal Income Taxation, Outsourcing andPolicy Cooperation in a Dynamic Economy, September 2009

    2777Joel Slemrod, Old George Orwell Got it Backward: Some Thoughts on Behavioral TaxEconomics, September 2009

    2778Cagri Seda Kumru and Athanasios C. Thanopoulos, Social Security Reform andTemptation, September 2009

    2779Alessandro Bucciol and Roel M. W. J. Beetsma, Inter- and Intra-generationalConsequences of Pension Buffer Policy under Demographic, Financial and EconomicShocks, September 2009

    2780Eduardo Strube and Marcelo Resende, Complementarity of Innovation Policies in theBrazilian Industry: An Econometric Study, September 2009

    2781Henry Tulkens and Vincent van Steenberghe, Mitigation, Adaptation, Suffering: InSearch of the Right Mix in the Face of Climate Change, September 2009

    2782Maria L. Loureiro, Anna Sanz-de-Galdeano and Daniela Vuri, Smoking Habits: LikeFather, Like Son, Like Mother, Like Daughter, September 2009

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    14/16

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    15/16

    2800Peter Friedrich, Chang Woon Nam and Janno Reiljan, Local Fiscal Equalization in

    Estonia: Is a Reform Necessary?, September 2009

    2801Even Koenda and Jan Hanousek, State Ownership and Control in the Czech Republic,September 2009

    2802Michael Stimmelmayr, Wage Inequality in Germany: Disentangling Demand andSupply Effects, September 2009

    2803Biswa N. Bhattacharyay, Towards a Macroprudential Surveillance and Remedial PolicyFormulation System for Monitoring Financial Crisis, September 2009

    2804Margarita Katsimi, Sarantis Kalyvitis and Thomas Moutos, Unwarranted WageChanges and the Return on Capital, September 2009

    2805Christian Lessmann and Gunther Markwardt, Aid, Growth and Devolution, September2009

    2806Bas Jacobs and Dirk Schindler, On the Desirability of Taxing Capital Income to ReduceMoral Hazard in Social Insurance, September 2009

    2807Hans Gersbach and Noemi Hummel, Climate Policy and Development, September 20092808David E. Wildasin, Fiscal Competition for Imperfectly-Mobile Labor and Capital: A

    Comparative Dynamic Analysis, September 2009

    2809Johan Eyckmans and Cathrine Hagem, The European Unions Potential for StrategicEmissions Trading through Minimal Permit Sale Contracts, September 2009

    2810Ruediger Bachmann and Christian Bayer, The Cross-section of Firms over the BusinessCycle: New Facts and a DSGE Exploration, October 2009

    2811Slobodan Djaji and Michael S. Michael, Temporary Migration Policies and Welfare ofthe Host and Source Countries: A Game-Theoretic Approach, October 2009

    2812Devis Geron, Social Security Incidence under Uncertainty Assessing Italian Reforms,October 2009

    2813Max-Stephan Schulze and Nikolaus Wolf, Economic Nationalism and EconomicIntegration: The Austro-Hungarian Empire in the Late Nineteenth Century, October2009

    2814Emilia Simeonova, Out of Sight, Out of Mind? The Impact of Natural Disasters onPregnancy Outcomes, October 2009

    2815Dan Kovenock and Brian Roberson, Non-Partisan Get-Out-the-Vote Efforts andPolicy Outcomes, October 2009

    2816Sascha O. Becker, Erik Hornung and Ludger Woessmann, Catch Me If You Can:Education and Catch-up in the Industrial Revolution, October 2009

  • 8/2/2019 Waelde2009wp_ProdTechnologiesInStochContTimeModels

    16/16

    2817Horst Raff and Nicolas Schmitt, Imports, Pass-Through, and the Structure of Retail

    Markets, October 2009

    2818Paul De Grauwe and Daniel Gros, A New Two-Pillar Strategy for the ECB, October2009

    2819Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Thouraya Hadj Amor and Christophe Rault, InternationalFinancial Integration and Real Exchange Rate Long-Run Dynamics in EmergingCountries: Some Panel Evidence, October 2009

    2820Saa ikovi and Randall K. Filer, Hybrid Historical Simulation VaR and ES:Performance in Developed and Emerging Markets, October 2009

    2821Panu Poutvaara and Andreas Wagener, The Political Economy of Conscription, October2009

    2822Steinar Holden and sa Rosn, Discrimination and Employment Protection, October2009

    2823David G. Mayes, Banking Crisis Resolution Policy Lessons from Recent Experience Which elements are needed for robust and efficient crisis resolution?, October 2009

    2824Christoph A. Schaltegger, Frank Somogyi and Jan-Egbert Sturm, Tax Competition andIncome Sorting: Evidence from the Zurich Metropolitan Area, October 2009

    2825 Natasa Bilkic, Thomas Gries and Margarethe Pilichowski, Stay in School or StartWorking? The Human Capital Investment Decision under Uncertainty andIrreversibility, October 2009

    2826Hartmut Egger and Udo Kreickemeier, Worker-Specific Effects of Globalisation,October 2009

    2827Alexander Fink and Thomas Stratmann, Institutionalized Bailouts and Fiscal Policy:The Consequences of Soft Budget Constraints, October 2009

    2828Wolfgang Ochel and Anja Rohwer, Reduction of Employment Protection in Europe: AComparative Fuzzy-Set Analysis, October 2009

    2829Rainald Borck and Martin Wimbersky, Political Economics of Higher EducationFinance, October 2009

    2830Torfinn Harding and Frederick van der Ploeg, Is Norways Bird-in-Hand StabilizationFund Prudent Enough? Fiscal Reactions to Hydrocarbon Windfalls and GrayingPopulations, October 2009

    2831Klaus Wlde, Production Technologies in Stochastic Continuous Time Models, October2009