VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

66
VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation

Transcript of VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Page 1: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation

Page 2: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Induced Bias

• Traditionally, one assumes that TP enters the production function in some exogenous way

• What if innovators can ex-ante seek to obtain a given type of technical progress?

• That is what the old “induced bias” literature tries to model

Page 3: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The traditional view

• Innovation augmenting one factor increases the return to the other factor

• Because of such “bottlenecks”, further innovation will be biased in favor of the other factor

• We eventually expect innovation to be “balanced”

• These bottlenecks imply that if one factor is more abundant, innovation will favor the other factor, to compensate

Page 4: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The modern view (Acemoglu)

• There exists market size effects: profits from an innovation depend positively on its market size

• Market size is larger if factor affected by innovation is more abundant

• This effect tends to reinforce existing biases rather than compensate them

Page 5: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Consequences for the distribution of wages

• If market size effects dominate bottleneck effects, then an increase in H/L triggers skilled-biased innovations

• These innovations themselves increase the skill premium,

• Which in turn induces people to accumulate more human capital…

Page 6: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

A simple heuristic argument

• Suppose firms could “pay” for technical progress in one dimension or another

• How much are they willing to pay?

• That gives us an idea of where TP is going to take place

• Firms willing to pay more more profits for innovators

Page 7: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The logic

• Production function

• Marginal product conditions

• Cost function

• Willingness to pay per unit of output

Page 8: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The equilibrium MWP for technical progress

• Diferentiating cost functions and substituting MP conditions, we get

Page 9: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Interpretation

• Because of optimality, how I reduce costs is irrelevant at the margin

• Suppose, upon an increase in A, that I reduce L proportionally

• I produce the same, and costs are reduced by wLdA/A = F’1LdA

Page 10: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

What happens to MWP when factor endowments change?

• Assume H goes up

• The wage of human capital falls, thus reducing my savings from human capital augmenting technical progress (bottleneck effect)

• But a proportional reduction in H would affect more people, and thus be more profitable (market size effect)

Page 11: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Implications for the induced bias

• Assume the bias in TP adjusts so as to equate MWP across types of TP

• Then the endogenous bias is determined by

• That formula determines the endogenous skilled bias b = B/A as a function of the factor endowment h = H/L

Page 12: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.
Page 13: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Which effect dominates?

• db/dh > 0 if curvature of f not too large

• Bottlenecks are small if H and L are substitute, market size effects then dominate

• Botlleneck effects are large if complementarities between H and L strong enough

Page 14: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The CES example

Page 15: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Net effect on the skill premium

• While an increase in H/L induces SBTC, skill premium need not go up on net

• For skill premium to go up, the positive effect of induced technical change must be higher than the direct negative effect of a greater H/L

Page 16: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The net effect on the skill premium

• To get an increase in the skill premium, we need a more than proportional response of b to h

• That implies even less complementarity

Page 17: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Computing the skill premium in the CES case

Page 18: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

An endogenous innovation model

• Can the preceding analysis be made more rigorous by explicitly taking innovation into account?

• The answer is: yes

• And the analysis and intuition are basically similar

Page 19: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The model’s ingredients

• We need a simple model of endogenous innovation

• Building on Romer, we assume innovation introduces new varieties

• These varieties enter as inputs into the production of aggregate intermediate goods

• Two categories of varieties depending on whether H or L is used

• Two different aggregate intermediate goods

Page 20: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

From product diversity to factor productivity:

• As in Romer, the CES aggregate for the intermediate input entails « taste for diversity »

• Hence, an increase in the number of varieties is equivalent to technical progress which increases the efficiency of the relevant factor

Page 21: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The production structure

• Aggregate production function:

• l-aggregate uses l-inputs:

• Similarly for h:

• l-inputs use labor

• Similarly for h

Page 22: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Computing aggregate factor productivity

• By symmetry, all goods of the same kind are produced in the same quantity

• Therefore, yl = L/Nl and yh = H/Nh

• Hence, Yl = AL, Yh = BH, Y = F(AL,BH)

Page 23: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Pricing

• Individual price-setters face constant elasticity

• Using price index for intermediate aggregates, we get

• Profit maximization for the final good allows to recover wages

Page 24: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Profits

• In equilibrium, labor uniformly allocated

• This allows to compute quantities, and thus profits

Page 25: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Patents and innovation

• The value of a patent is given by

• In an interior BGP, Vh = Vl throughout, implying

Page 26: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Profit equalization allows to compute equilibrium bias in

technology

• We get a formula quite similar to the heuristic model:

Page 27: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The effects

• When a factor is in larger supply, any intermediate good which uses that factor will have a larger market (Market size effect) term in H/L

• If a factor is more abundant in efficiency units, its marginal product falls, which reduces the demand for the corresponding intermediate inputs (Bottleneck effect) term in F’1/ F’2

• If a factor is more productive, it means more intermediate goods for that factor, and lower market size term in (B/A)1-η

• If a factor is more productive, its price is higher, which boosts prices and profits for intermediate goods term in (B/A)

Page 28: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The CES case

• Relative profits are equal to

• That determines a stable interior value of b provided

• That value is then given by

Page 29: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

When does the supply effect increase the bias?

• Clearly, db/dh > 0 iff γ > 0

• Substitutability market size effects dominate

• Complementarity bottleneck effects dominate

Page 30: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

When does the skill premium go up on net?

• The skill premium is given by

• It is increasing in h provided

Page 31: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Discussion

• Again, more substitutability is needed for the SP• The bias must react enough to h• Furthermore, condition more likely when η is

smaller• η is smaller b more reactive to h

– The lower η, the lower the increase in N associated with a given increase in A, the smaller the profit dissipation effect associated with an increase in A

Page 32: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Dynamics

• Assume a fixed supply of researchers• They can pick any kind of innovation at

any point in time• Assume a productivity spillover à la

Grossman-Helpman• At each date, all researchers work in the

most profitable kind of R & D• Unless patent values are equalized, they

are then indifferent

Page 33: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Aggregate research dynamics

Page 34: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The allocation of R & D

Page 35: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.
Page 36: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

db/dt = 0

dΔ/dt = 0

C

b

Δ

Figure 5.7: the dynamics of the technology bias

E

E

D

D

Page 37: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

b =B/AFigure 5.8: convergence path of the technology bias

b*

Page 38: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

db/dt = 0

dΔ/dt = 0

C’

b

Δ

Figure 5.9: response of the technology bias to an increase in H/L

C

Page 39: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

A

B

time

time

Figure 5.10: response of the skill premium to an increase in H/L

b

b

Page 40: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

IX. The bundling model

Page 41: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The limitations of neo-classical models

• In neo-classical models, individuals are irrelevant

• They earn the sum of the income of the characteristics they bring to the market

• Where they work and whom they work with does not matter

• We now turn to models where individuals matter

Page 42: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The role of unbundling

• A first mechanism by which individuals may matter is unbundling

• Unbundling means that all the characteristics of the individual must be supplied to the same employer

• We will show that the price of each characteristic then need not be equal across sectors

• One implication is that people will sort themselves into different sectors by different skills

Page 43: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Back to the basic model

• Each worker has a skill s

• Skill determines h(s) and l(s)

• We order skills by comparative advantage so that h(s)/l(s) grows with s

• Workers can’t elect which characteristic they supply

Page 44: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

A pseudo-obvious result

• If there is a single homogeneous final good, then each worker earns an income

• Where ω and w are the economy-wide price of H and L

• In the unbundling model, that result is obvious• But is is not in the bundling model• We have to prove that each firm offers the

same return to each characteristic

Page 45: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The firm’s optimization problem

• To complete the proof we need to show that these MPs are equalized across firms• Workers are paid the marginal roduct of their characteristics in the firm where they work

Page 46: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Completing the proof

• In equilibrium, all firms have the same H/L ratio

• Therefore, each marginal product is equalized across firms

• Otherwise, firms with a higher H/L pay more for L and less for H

• But then they attract lower-skilled workers and cannot have a higher H/L ratio

Page 47: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.
Page 48: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The 2-sector model

• Firms in different sectors sell their output at different prices

• A non unique price may be supported

• Example: sector 1 pays more for H and attracts the higher skilled workers

• It does so not because it has a lower H/L ratio, but because its production is more intensive in H

Page 49: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The model

• Under unbundling, the allocation is determined by standard considerations

• The two FPF interact if both goods are produced

• Each factor price is unique

Page 50: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

wFigure 6.1: factor-price equalization in the two-sector model

PFPFA

ω

PFPFB

E

-L/H

Page 51: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

wFigure 6.2: full specialization under unbundling

PFPFA

ω

PFPFB

E

-L/H

Page 52: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Can the bundling allocation be an unbundling equilibrium?

• A necessary condition is that there exist an allocation of people which matches H and L in both sectors

• Because people come to a sector with their own endowment of both h and l, an arbitrary allocation is not necessarily feasible

• A feasible allocation must be between the minimal and maximal human capital intensity curves

Page 53: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

L

H

Figure 6.3: the allocation of labor and human capital

LBLA

HA

HB

MM

MM’

E

Page 54: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The “lens”

• It defines the set of macro allocations of H and L such that their exists a micro allocation of individuals which yields that macro allocation

• The lowest possible H/L ratio in sector A is obtained by allocating the lowest skilled people there first

• If I want to allocate more labor to A, I must move more skilled people there, and the minimum H/L ratio goes up

Page 55: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The determination of MM and MM’

Page 56: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Equilibrium and the lens

• Any equibrium must lie in the lens, otherwise it cannot be supported by an allocation of people

• Any point in the lens can be supported by an allocation of people

• If the unbundling equilibrium is in the lens, it is also an equilibrium with bundling– Neither firms nor workers have an incentive to

deviate

Page 57: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

If bundling is outside the lens:

• Factor prices can’t be equalized across sectors, otherwise one would be outside the lens

• Assume B is more H-intensive• Sector B pays more for H and less for L

than sector A• Workers below a critical skill level work in

A, workers above it work in B sorting• Equilibrium thus lies on MM

Page 58: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

L

H

Figure 6.4: Equilibrium when E is outside the lens

LBLA

HA

HB

MMMM’

E

E’

O

O’

Page 59: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.
Page 60: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Uniqueness?

• As I move up along MM, the marginal worker’s income goes up faster in B than in A:– The marginal worker has more H, which is more

valued in B– Fewer people work in B, whose relative price goes up

• Therefore, at most 1 point where it is the same in both sectors

• If that point does not exist, corner equilibrium exists where everybody works in 1 sector

Page 61: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

If E is in the lens, it is the only equilibrium

• Any point F on MM has a lower H/L ratio in A than E

• Its H/L ratio is higher in B

• Thus it has a lower ωB/wB,and a higher ωA/wB,than E

• But then the least skilled want to work in B, and the most skilled in A not an equilibrium

Page 62: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

h(s)/l(s)

z(s)/l(s)

Sector B

Sector A

Figure 6.5: The distribution of income under full specialization

Page 63: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

The impact of an increase in demand for good b

• Under FPE, we get the usual prediction: ω goes up and w goes down

• Under non FBE, same prediction, but we must move along MM– The effect on wages not only depends on

technology but also on the distribution of skills– If h/l varies little across people, that puts limits

on the inegalitarian effects

Page 64: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

L

H

Figure 6.6: The effect of an increase in p under full specialization

MM

MM’

E’

E’’

Page 65: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

Triggering segregation

• An increase in the demand for B may move the economy outside the lens

• Sectoral skill segregation emerges• As B bids for workers, it tends to drive ω/w up• The least skilled of B move to A, and the most

skilled of A move to B• At some point, B is no longer able to match its

H/L target, it attracts workers with a lower H/L, and offers a higher ω/w

• An opposite phenomenon occurs in sector A

Page 66: VIII. Supply effects and induced bias in innovation.

L

H

Figure 6.7: An increase in p may trigger full specialization

MM

MM’

E

E’’

F