Underwriting Strategy and Underwriting Cycle in the … Meetings/3B-Underwriting Strategy.pdf ·...

of 33 /33
0 Underwriting Strategy and Underwriting Cycle in the Medical Malpractice Insurance Industry Yu Lei Barney School of Business University of Hartford 200 Bloomfield Ave. West Hartford, CT Phone: 860-768-4682 Email: [email protected] Mark J. Browne 975 University Avenue Madison, WI 53706-1323 Phone: (608) 263-3030 Fax: (608) 265-4195 Email: [email protected] July 2012 To be Presented at the 2012 American Risk and Insurance Association Meeting Preliminary draft. Please do not quote without permission.

Embed Size (px)

Transcript of Underwriting Strategy and Underwriting Cycle in the … Meetings/3B-Underwriting Strategy.pdf ·...

  • 0

    Underwriting Strategy and Underwriting Cycle in the Medical Malpractice

    Insurance Industry

    Yu Lei Barney School of Business

    University of Hartford 200 Bloomfield Ave. West Hartford, CT

    Phone: 860-768-4682 Email: [email protected]

    Mark J. Browne

    975 University Avenue Madison, WI 53706-1323

    Phone: (608) 263-3030 Fax: (608) 265-4195

    Email: [email protected]

    July 2012 To be Presented at the 2012 American Risk and Insurance Association Meeting

    Preliminary draft. Please do not quote without permission.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]

  • 1

    Underwriting Strategy and Underwriting Cycle in the Medical Malpractice Insurance Industry

    ABSTRACT

    Even though underwriting cycles have been extensively studied, one area seems to receive little

    attention. This article fills the gap by examining whether medical malpractice insurers underwriting strategy

    exhibits any cyclical behavior. Our analysis of the NAIC data indicates that some aspects of malpractice

    carriers underwriting strategy do show certain degrees of cyclical nature and they display trend that seem to be

    opposite that of the combined loss ratio in medical malpractice insurance, which we use in this study as a

    measure of the underwriting cycle. We find that when insurers underwriting performance worsens, there are

    fewer insurers offering medical malpractice, there are more exits than entries, insurers are less geographically

    concentrated in selling malpractice, and the significance of malpractice in terms of this lines premium share

    declines. Moreover, when we look at which states in which malpractice carriers do business, we see that the

    percentage of safer states (states that have caps on general damages or patient compensation funds) in which

    insurers write malpractice and the percentage of insurers that choose to do business only in safer states are both

    negatively associated with the combined loss ratio of the medical malpractice insurance industry. Taken all

    together, it seems that at the industry level, insurers underwriting performance has a negative association with

    their risk taking behavior in terms of how much to focus on malpractice line of business and where to write such

    business. Less focus on malpractice and wider distribution of malpractice products are seen to accompany

    worsened underwriting performance.

    We also test whether the capacity constraint theory can help explain the cyclical nature of medical

    malpractice insurers underwriting strategy. We find that when the total surplus of all single-line insurers (those

    only selling medical malpractice) shrinks, insurers are less likely to go single-line. We observe the same trend

    when we examine single-state insurers (those selling medical malpractice in just one state) and ONLY-CAP-

    State insurers (those selling medical malpractice only in states with caps on general damages). In other words,

    our results provide some support for the capacity constraint theory which predicts an inadequate capacity will

    shrink insurance supply.

  • 2

    INTRODUCTION

    It is well recognized that many property/liability insurance markets exhibit cyclical nature. Soft market

    periods, where prices are low and coverage is abundant, are followed by hard markets, where prices are high

    and coverage is scarce. Medical malpractice insurance, which provides coverage against professional liability

    for health-care providers, is a great example of the recurring soft and hard markets. Over the past several

    decades medical malpractice insurance has experienced periodic performance crises evidenced by rising

    premiums and decreasing supply of malpractice carriers.

    Even though underwriting cycles have been extensively studied, previous literature usually focuses on

    the cyclical behavior of prices, premium growth, underwriting performance (loss ratios or combined loss ratios)

    or insurance availability. On the other hand, most research on medical malpractice insurance crisis concentrates

    on the causes of price volatility during hard markets.

    This paper intends to examine one little-studied area of the medical malpractice insurance market. We

    will examine malpractice insurers underwriting strategy during the underwriting cycle and see if it exhibits any

    cyclical behavior. If so, we want to see whether the capacity constraint theory can help explain such

    phenomenon.

    This paper makes contribution to both the underwriting cycle study and the medical malpractice

    insurance literature by focusing on various aspects of insurers underwriting strategy. When the insurance

    industry swings from soft (or hard) to hard (or soft) markets, it is natural for insurers to re-evaluate and adjust

    their underwriting strategy to gain a competitive hold. It is likely the underwriting cycle causes changes in

    underwriting strategy, but it is also plausible for the modified underwriting strategy to have an impact on the

    depth and length of the underwriting cycle. It is not this papers intention to discuss how the two-way feedback

    works. Well instead try to identify if there is any cyclical pattern in insurers underwriting strategy during the

    medical malpractice insurance cycle, which we will measure using the malpractice industrys combined loss

    ratios.

    Insurers underwriting strategy could encompass many aspects. For instance, in response to medical

    malpractice crises, do insurers establish tighter claims frequency and severity standards for potential insured

    health care providers? Do they increase deductible amount and/or decrease the policy limit theyre willing to

    insure? Do they choose to exclude certain high-risk specialties to cover? Ideally, wed like to explore how

    insurers adjust their underwriting strategy in reality. Unfortunately, we do not have such information available.

  • 3

    Instead, well utilize the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) database and focus on the

    following things which we call underwriting strategy in our paper.

    First, do insurers choose to enter or exit the medical malpractice market? Lei and Browne (2008) study

    malpractice insurers entry and exit during the period of 1994-2006 and find that exits are less frequent in states

    where there are caps on general (noneconomic) damages. We extend their study by looking at how insurers

    move in and out of the market in accordance with the underwriting cycle.

    Second, when insurers do choose to enter the malpractice market, how much do they want to focus on

    the malpractice line of business? Do they want to devote the entire business to malpractice or do they also write

    other lines of business? In other words, we want to examine how the significance of medical malpractice (which

    will be measured by malpractice lines premium share) changes in accordance with the underwriting cycle.

    Third, where do insurers sell medical malpractice? Do they write malpractice in just one state or

    multiple states? When they go multi-state, how do they allocate malpractice premiums across states?

    Fourth, do insurers choose to sell malpractice in safer states? In response to malpractice crises, many

    states enacted tort reforms (such as caps on awards for non-economic damages) and/or created alternative

    mechanisms (such as joint underwriting associations and patients compensation funds that provide coverage

    for substandard risks or limit an insurers loss exposure on catastrophic claims). These efforts are intended to

    reduce the claims cost as well as the uncertainty associated with them. In this paper, we call states with either

    caps on general damages or patient compensation funds safer states. Viscusi and Born (2005) find that many

    tort reforms help reduce losses, lower premiums, and enhance insurer profitability, with limits on noneconomic

    damages being the most influential in affecting insurance market outcomes.

    Lastly, do insurers choose to insure more physicians or hospitals? Or do they choose to specialize in

    covering just one type of health care providers since different policyholders have different risk implications?

    It is not hard to imagine that these various aspects of insurers underwriting strategy, namely, entry and

    exit, geographic concentration of malpractice business, significance of malpractice line of business, distribution

    of malpractice business between safer states and less safe states (those without tort reform measures in place),

    and choice of prospective policyholders to cover, will have different implications on firms performance.

    Different strategies may have their own comparative advantages and will likely affect insurers differently.1

    1 There is not much study on the underwriting strategy mentioned here yet. The few available studies on geographic diversification and product diversification produce mixed results. Liebenberg and Sommer (2008) find that single-line property-liability insurers consistently outperform multiline insurers. Elango et al. (2008) discover that performance advantages associated with product diversification are contingent upon an insurers degree of geographic diversification. Their results indicate that a highly diversified product profile with low geographic diversification is associated with the highest performance. Insurers that have relatively low

    We

  • 4

    do not intend to evaluate the effectiveness of insurers underwriting strategy in this paper, but rather we will

    show how they change in the underwriting cycle.

    In the next section, we discuss our data and definitions of medical malpractice insurers. We generate two

    samples for our empirical study and we offer a brief overview of the samples in the same section. In the next

    five sections that follow, we show how the above-mentioned five aspects of insurers underwriting strategy,

    namely, entry and exit, geographic concentration, significance of malpractice line of business, distribution of

    malpractice business between safer states and less safe states, and choice of prospective policyholders to cover,

    evolve as the underwriting cycle unfolds. We then test the capacity constraint theory in the subsequent section.

    In the last section, we summarize our findings and conclude the paper.

    DATA AND DEFINITION OF MEDICAL MALPRACTICE INSURERS

    We utilize the 1992-2010 NAIC property/casualty data to conduct our research. Since our focus is the

    underwriting strategy of medical malpractice insurers, we need to define such carriers in the first place. A

    natural response is to include all insurers that report positive direct premiums written in medical malpractice.

    We call the resulting sample Large Sample. This sample includes all possible medical malpractice insurers,

    yet some of them report to the NAIC even after they have stopped selling new policies. They continue to report

    positive premiums from existing relationships, but are not truly active in the market. To account for this issue,

    we also follow Nordman, Cermak and McDaniel (2004) and define a medical malpractice insurer as one that

    wrote at least 2 percent of the medical malpractice premium in at least one state in that year. We call the

    resulting sample Small Sample.

    Since we need to examine insurers geographic concentration, we make use of the state-level financial

    information in the NAIC database. The major financial statement we rely on is Exhibit of Premiums and

    Losses in different states, which we refer to as the Stage Page throughout the paper. The Stage Page provides

    information on premiums written/earned, losses incurred/unpaid/paid and loss adjustment and other expenses by

    line of business for each firm in all 50 states and Washington D.C. each year. With such information, we can

    analyze the underwriting performance of medical malpractice insurers both at the state-level and at the country-

    level.

    product and geography diversification have medium level performance. Lei and Schmit (2008) find no significant impact of geographic diversification on firm performance of malpractice insurers, but show that more product diversification is associated with stronger firm performance.

  • 5

    Using our two definitions of medical malpractice insurers and the Stage Page, we generate our Large

    Sample and Small Sample. Table 1 provides a snapshot of the two samples. Table 1: Comparison of Large Sample and Small Sample

    Large Sample Small Sample

    Year N of MM

    Insurers

    Median Loss Ratio

    Median Expense

    Ratio

    Median Combined

    Ratio

    N of MM

    Insurers

    Country-level

    Premium Share in Large

    Sample

    State-level

    Average Premium Share in Large

    Sample

    Median Loss Ratio

    Median Expense

    Ratio

    Median Combined

    Ratio

    1992 297 0.73 0.11 0.87 117 0.823 0.852 0.88 0.05 0.95 1993 294 0.74 0.11 0.85 121 0.801 0.834 0.89 0.06 0.94 1994 268 0.70 0.10 0.80 108 0.822 0.851 0.77 0.05 0.83 1995 264 0.77 0.10 0.86 108 0.817 0.846 0.82 0.05 0.89 1996 273 0.72 0.09 0.81 109 0.806 0.836 0.79 0.05 0.85 1997 275 0.72 0.10 0.86 105 0.789 0.827 0.86 0.05 0.92 1998 268 0.71 0.11 0.85 108 0.800 0.831 0.90 0.06 0.97 1999 268 0.82 0.11 0.93 114 0.798 0.831 0.87 0.06 0.93 2000 257 0.81 0.11 0.91 114 0.788 0.816 1.04 0.06 1.07 2001 243 0.96 0.11 1.02 106 0.795 0.825 1.08 0.08 1.12 2002 251 0.82 0.09 0.92 104 0.809 0.829 0.98 0.07 1.02 2003 276 0.73 0.08 0.82 112 0.803 0.824 0.88 0.06 0.94 2004 301 0.65 0.07 0.73 113 0.793 0.816 0.71 0.06 0.78 2005 310 0.63 0.07 0.71 116 0.787 0.817 0.66 0.05 0.73 2006 324 0.55 0.06 0.63 123 0.781 0.811 0.57 0.05 0.62 2007 323 0.50 0.07 0.59 124 0.773 0.800 0.52 0.05 0.58 2008 337 0.49 0.07 0.59 125 0.761 0.789 0.51 0.06 0.62 2009 337 0.51 0.07 0.60 122 0.745 0.782 0.53 0.07 0.61 2010 345 0.49 0.07 0.57 124 0.737 0.775 0.50 0.07 0.59 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    As we can see from Table 1, from 1992 to 2010, insurers that report positive premiums in medical

    malpractice business number from a low 243 in 2001 to an all time high of 345 in 2010. When we require that

    insurers must write at least 2% of medical malpractice in at least one state, the sample size drops significantly.

    Though the small sample is less than 45% of the large sample in terms of its size, its insurers are very active and

    meaningful malpractice writers, as evidenced by the premium shares they have when compared to the large

    sample. For instance, in year 2010, the small samples total premiums account for 73.7% of the large samples

    total premiums at the country level. At the state-level, we see that on average in each state, the small sample

    writes about 77.5% of the large samples premiums. In other words, the small sample is very representative of

    the entire medical malpractice industry. For all the analyses we do, we use both samples as a robustness test to

    each other and we can also see how the entire industry and the major active writers differ or behave similarly in

    various aspects of their underwriting strategy.

  • 6

    In this paper we use the medical malpractice insurance industrys loss ratios as a proxy to the

    underwriting cycle. The State Page allows us to calculate three ratios for each malpractice carrier both at the

    state-level and at the country-level. Loss ratios are losses and loss adjustment expenses incurred divided by

    premiums earned. Expense ratios are commissions, taxes and fees divided by premiums written. Combined ratio

    is the sum of loss ratio and expense ratio. Since here we are not doing any other sample selection besides

    imposing definitions of medical malpractice insurers, we do have insurers that report negative premiums and

    losses. As a result, the mean values of loss ratios are not reliable. Instead, we use median values to show the

    trend of the underwriting cycle. Table 1 also shows the ratios for both samples over time. Figure 1 presents the

    same information in a more visual form.

    Figure 1: Comparison of Large and Small Samples Loss Ratios

    As we can see, expense ratios are relatively stable over time for both samples, with the small sample

    enjoying lower expense ratios. Volatility in combined ratios is thus largely driven by changes in loss ratios. The

    small sample tends to have higher loss ratios and combined loss ratios (except for 2006-2007). Both samples

    reached their peak in 2001 with the highest loss ratios during our study period. Overall, the two samples follow

    very similar pattern in terms of their loss ratios movement. In the analyses that follow, we use the combined

    ratio as a measure of the underwriting cycle. We next show how insurers underwriting strategy evolves in the

    underwriting cycle.

  • 7

    NUMBER OF TOTAL INSURERS, ENTRANTS AND EXITERS

    The first aspect of the underwriting strategy we study is whether or not an insurer chooses to enter or

    exit medical malpractice line of business. For this purpose, we study the movement both at the country-level

    and at the state-level. We define an insurer as entering the market in a state in a given year if its direct

    premiums written (DPW) for medical malpractice insurance in that state exceeded the 2% threshold for Small

    Sample (or 0% threshold for Large Sample) for the first time in that year. Similarly, we define a firm as exiting

    a state in a particular year if it wrote malpractice coverage in a particular state in a particular year, but in no

    subsequent years wrote 2% or more for Small Sample of the direct premiums in that state (or wrote no positive

    premium for Large Sample). Country-level entry and exit are similarly defined, with national entrant of a

    certain year being one that had positive premiums in medical malpractice for the first time in that year (for

    Large Sample), or that wrote at least 2% of premium in at least one state in that year (for Small Sample). Table

    2 reports the total number of medical malpractice insurers, entrants or exiters at the country level. It also shows

    the mean values of total number of insurers, entrants and exiters at the state level.

    Table 2: Total Number of Medical Malpractice Insurers, Entrants and Exiters

    Year Country-level Mean Values at State-level

    Large Sample Small Sample Large Sample Small Sample Total Entry Exit Total Entry Exit Total Entry Exit Total Entry Exit

    1992 297 - 32 117 - 8 65.53 - 6.43 7.82 0.88 1993 294 29 55 121 12 26 70.37 11.27 22.53 7.86 0.92 3.06 1994 268 29 22 108 13 10 55.29 7.45 4.88 6.75 1.94 0.67 1995 264 18 10 108 10 10 60.80 10.39 8.69 7.37 1.29 0.94 1996 273 19 21 109 11 13 59.69 7.57 5.94 7.67 1.24 1.22 1997 275 23 26 105 9 8 64.12 10.37 6.90 7.82 1.37 1.14 1998 268 19 23 108 11 9 66.94 9.73 7.61 8.06 1.37 1.43 1999 268 23 31 114 15 11 69.61 10.27 12.47 8.02 1.39 1.69 2000 257 20 35 114 11 17 65.61 8.47 10.35 7.78 1.45 1.76 2001 243 21 27 106 9 17 64.71 9.45 12.53 8.39 2.37 2.22 2002 251 35 29 104 15 11 62.14 9.96 9.92 8.57 2.39 1.96 2003 276 54 39 112 19 17 62.63 10.41 10.24 8.18 1.57 1.71 2004 301 64 20 113 18 7 64.63 12.24 8.69 7.71 1.24 0.88 2005 310 29 21 116 10 10 63.12 7.18 7.02 7.96 1.14 1.14 2006 324 35 23 123 17 11 62.33 6.24 5.16 7.71 0.88 1.12 2007 323 22 16 124 12 8 63.33 6.16 3.75 7.45 0.86 0.65 2008 337 30 19 125 9 12 68.02 8.43 4.84 7.55 0.75 0.82 2009 337 19 17 122 9 3 71.16 7.98 3.67 7.61 0.88 0.61 2010 345 25 - 124 5 - 76.51 9.02 - 7.94 0.94 - Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

  • 8

    Figures 2 and 3 provide a visual description of how the total number of insurers, entrants and exiters

    correspond to the combined loss ratios in the medical malpractice industry. State-level average values, though

    not graphed, show similar patterns.

    Figure 2: Large Sample: Total N. of Firms, Entrants and Exiters

    As we can see the combined ratio seems to be moving in opposite direction of the total number of

    insurers. Around the year of 2001 when the combined ratios worsened for both small and large samples, we see

    a dip in the total number of insurers. When loss ratios improved in recent years, we see gradual increase in the

    total number of malpractice insurers.

    During our study period, year 1993 saw the most exits in both large sample and small sample. In Large

    Sample, we notice more exits than entries leading up to the 2001 crisis period. In Small Sample, such

    phenomenon coincides with the worsened 2001 combined ratio. In general, we notice that when loss ratios are

    high, there tend to be more exits than entries (though there may be a time lag). When loss ratios improve, we

    see more entries than exits in both samples, contributing to the increased size of the malpractice market.

  • 9

    Figure 3: Small Sample: Total N. of Firms, Entrants and Exiters

    GEOGRAPHIC CONCENTRATION OF MALPRACTICE BUSINESS

    The second aspect of the underwriting strategy we examine is how insurers spread out their malpractice

    business across states. We first look at the number of states in which insurers sell medical malpractice. Table 3

    reports the median values of this information for both samples over time. Though the number of states in which

    insurers write malpractice ranges from 1 to 51, the median values are pretty low in both samples. In Large

    Sample, half of the insurers write malpractice in less than 4 states. The small sample insurers write in even

    fewer states, with 1 or 2 being the median values. In order to see how insurers allocate their malpractice

    premiums across states, we also calculate a geographic Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) for each firm, which

    is defined as the sum of the squares of its premium share in each state 2

    . A higher HHI indicates more

    geographic concentration. Table 3 also reports the median values of geographic HHI over time for both samples.

    As we can see more clearly from Figure 4, the geographic HHI shows an opposite trend to that of the combined

    loss ratios. In other words, higher loss ratios are shown to be associated with lower geographic HHI. When loss

    ratios improve, we see higher geographic HHI. In other words, a worsening (improving) underwriting

    performance seems to be linked with less (more) geographic concentration of malpractice business.

    2 Premium share is the firms malpractice premium in each state divided by its country-level total malpractice premiums.

  • 10

    Table 3: Analysis of Geographic Concentration of Medical Malpractice Insurers

    Year

    Large Sample Small Sample Small Sample Large Sample

    Geographic HHI

    N of States

    Insurers Sell MM

    Geographic HHI

    N of States

    Insurers Sell MM

    N of SS Insurers

    % of SS Insurers

    % of SS Premium

    N of SS Insurers

    % of SS Insurers

    % of SS Premium

    1992 0.893 3 0.943 1 74 0.633 0.409 116 0.391 0.278 1993 0.777 3 0.888 1 80 0.661 0.410 105 0.357 0.258 1994 0.871 2 0.962 1 71 0.657 0.456 99 0.369 0.312 1995 0.816 3 0.951 1 65 0.602 0.418 84 0.318 0.287 1996 0.841 3 0.886 1 62 0.569 0.405 95 0.348 0.259 1997 0.828 3 0.744 1 55 0.524 0.389 90 0.327 0.249 1998 0.769 4 0.661 1 57 0.528 0.341 87 0.325 0.223 1999 0.706 4 0.650 1 61 0.535 0.334 80 0.299 0.231 2000 0.696 4 0.602 1 62 0.544 0.347 70 0.272 0.206 2001 0.614 4 0.496 2 46 0.434 0.226 71 0.292 0.147 2002 0.691 4 0.610 2 48 0.462 0.198 80 0.319 0.133 2003 0.855 3 0.591 1 59 0.527 0.245 103 0.373 0.149 2004 0.917 2 0.778 1 62 0.549 0.243 121 0.402 0.146 2005 0.964 2 0.848 1 68 0.586 0.329 132 0.426 0.177 2006 0.970 2 0.893 1 78 0.634 0.384 144 0.444 0.224 2007 0.961 2 0.922 1 80 0.645 0.422 139 0.430 0.232 2008 0.919 2 0.849 1 78 0.624 0.400 143 0.424 0.243 2009 0.919 2 0.799 1 73 0.598 0.384 138 0.410 0.239 2010 0.931 2 0.774 1 70 0.565 0.385 146 0.423 0.244 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    Figure 4: Dynamics of Geographic Concentration

  • 11

    We next look at an extreme case of geographic concentration, given that many medical malpractice

    insurers operate in just one state. Table 3 also shows how many (and what percentage of) insurers sell medical

    malpractice in just one state, and the premium share these single-state insurers have when compared to the

    entire malpractice industry. Figure 5 graphs the same information. Again, we notice similar pattern. When

    insurers underwriting performance worsens, we see fewer insurers that sell malpractice in just one state.

    Improved loss ratios are shown to be associated with more insurers selling malpractice in just one state.

    Figure 5: Analysis of Single-state MM Insurers

    Single-state (SS) and multi-state (MS) insurers each have their own competitive advantage. Operating

    in just one state may gain insurers superior knowledge in dealing with state legal and regulatory environments

    and thus enable them to have better loss control. On the other hand, multi-state insurers may enjoy the benefits

    of diversification should a certain state suddenly changes its legal or regulatory environments in a way thats

    detrimental to the firms. Table 4 shows that usually multi-state insurers have higher expense ratios than single-

    state insurers (except in year 2001 when in large sample, MS insurers have a higher median value of expense

    ratio than SS insurers). Figure 6 presents the same information in a more straightforward way.

    We also notice that single-state insurers have lower combined ratio than multi-state insurers from 1995

    to 2004, but in other times they underperform. We suspect it is the comparative advantage of different

    underwriting strategies that are at play. Figures 7-8 provide a better presentation of the loss ratio information.

  • 12

    Table 4: Median Loss Ratios of Single-state vs Multi-state Insurers

    year Small Sample MS Insurers Small Sample SS Insurers Large Sample MS Insurers Large Sample SSInsurers

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio Comb Ratio

    1992 0.102 0.888 0.987 0.035 0.873 0.907 0.138 0.718 0.883 0.057 0.735 0.833

    1993 0.095 0.812 0.931 0.042 0.901 0.942 0.131 0.733 0.867 0.075 0.754 0.798

    1994 0.069 0.754 0.815 0.038 0.789 0.841 0.122 0.702 0.814 0.060 0.676 0.750

    1995 0.074 0.849 0.933 0.046 0.808 0.850 0.117 0.789 0.902 0.055 0.687 0.769

    1996 0.070 0.861 0.912 0.039 0.746 0.776 0.103 0.732 0.848 0.048 0.675 0.752

    1997 0.066 0.868 0.955 0.038 0.795 0.874 0.110 0.750 0.873 0.069 0.638 0.687

    1998 0.064 0.910 0.991 0.053 0.898 0.915 0.122 0.770 0.942 0.085 0.506 0.638

    1999 0.074 0.936 0.998 0.059 0.802 0.870 0.110 0.821 0.927 0.089 0.851 0.932

    2000 0.066 1.069 1.132 0.053 1.010 1.030 0.108 0.833 0.962 0.135 0.670 0.826

    2001 0.079 1.131 1.189 0.056 0.908 0.916 0.117 0.993 1.106 0.089 0.834 0.916

    2002 0.075 1.047 1.101 0.050 0.866 0.910 0.101 0.962 1.010 0.067 0.674 0.775

    2003 0.071 0.903 0.986 0.041 0.807 0.887 0.084 0.745 0.826 0.064 0.710 0.750

    2004 0.062 0.758 0.833 0.049 0.651 0.733 0.077 0.665 0.751 0.044 0.612 0.693

    2005 0.068 0.666 0.716 0.041 0.659 0.731 0.080 0.627 0.718 0.045 0.643 0.696

    2006 0.065 0.575 0.620 0.046 0.545 0.625 0.082 0.553 0.636 0.046 0.530 0.617

    2007 0.070 0.453 0.553 0.046 0.556 0.624 0.084 0.475 0.582 0.044 0.528 0.603

    2008 0.071 0.445 0.523 0.045 0.587 0.651 0.095 0.473 0.591 0.041 0.513 0.593

    2009 0.076 0.515 0.605 0.043 0.545 0.632 0.094 0.495 0.613 0.047 0.518 0.567 2010 0.078 0.530 0.592 0.045 0.487 0.574 0.100 0.479 0.574 0.041 0.496 0.559 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    Figure 6: Expense Ratio: Single-state vs Multi-state Insurers

  • 13

    Figure 7: Loss Ratio: Single-state vs Multi-state Insurers

    Figure 8: Combined Ratio: Single-state vs Multi-state Insurers

  • 14

    SIGNIFICANCE OF MEDICAL MALPRACTICE IN INSURERS PORTFOLIO

    The third aspect of the underwriting strategy we examine is the significance of malpractice insurance in

    insurers entire portfolio. We first look at the percentage of insurers total premiums written in malpractice line

    of business. Table 5 reports both mean and median values of such percentages over time. We observe that since

    2003 theres been increased significance of malpractice business. By 2010, on average medical malpractice

    accounts for about 68.7% of total property/liability insurance premiums in Large Sample, and 84.9% in Small

    Sample. When we turn to median values of such premium percentages, we notice that half of malpractice

    insurers write more than 98% of premiums in this particular line. When we graph such information in Figures 9

    and 10, we see that overall the percentage of malpractice premiums shares a negative association with the

    combined loss ratios. When insurers underwriting performance worsens, there is less significance of

    malpractice insurance (meaning insurers are writing less malpractice). When performance improves, we see

    insurers focus more on malpractice. This makes intuitive sense since its natural for profit-driven firms to move

    away from less profitable business.

    Table 5: Analysis of Significance of Medical Malpractice Business

    Year

    Large Sample Small Sample N of SL

    % of SL

    % of SL Premiums

    % of MM Premiums

    (Mean)

    % of MM Premiums (Median)

    N of SL

    % of SL

    % of SL Premiums

    % of MM Premiums

    (Mean)

    % of MM Premiums (Median)

    1992 62 0.209 0.206 0.444 0.150 41 0.350 0.218 0.778 0.995 1993 62 0.211 0.196 0.447 0.187 36 0.298 0.210 0.741 0.979 1994 56 0.209 0.230 0.464 0.256 34 0.315 0.238 0.812 0.992 1995 57 0.216 0.194 0.493 0.381 26 0.241 0.194 0.786 0.983 1996 55 0.202 0.094 0.482 0.341 21 0.193 0.078 0.793 0.980 1997 46 0.167 0.069 0.465 0.243 17 0.162 0.060 0.795 0.967 1998 37 0.138 0.106 0.443 0.198 15 0.139 0.096 0.776 0.920 1999 35 0.131 0.108 0.440 0.157 14 0.123 0.099 0.736 0.909 2000 29 0.113 0.111 0.416 0.145 14 0.123 0.109 0.723 0.915 2001 30 0.124 0.110 0.427 0.167 14 0.132 0.115 0.737 0.950 2002 38 0.151 0.066 0.489 0.461 13 0.125 0.065 0.781 0.961 2003 60 0.217 0.081 0.527 0.626 18 0.161 0.072 0.798 0.965 2004 103 0.342 0.113 0.641 0.969 25 0.221 0.100 0.828 0.977 2005 110 0.355 0.150 0.659 0.973 32 0.276 0.134 0.849 0.983 2006 133 0.411 0.198 0.692 0.981 38 0.309 0.180 0.846 0.981 2007 139 0.430 0.212 0.704 0.989 42 0.339 0.188 0.839 0.985 2008 143 0.424 0.228 0.696 0.983 43 0.344 0.202 0.854 0.985 2009 138 0.410 0.222 0.682 0.975 41 0.336 0.198 0.850 0.981 2010 139 0.403 0.223 0.687 0.976 42 0.339 0.199 0.849 0.983 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

  • 15

    Figure 9: Significance of MM in Large Sample

    Figure 10: Significance of MM in Small Sample

  • 16

    We also examine an extreme case where insurers devote its entire business to medical malpractice.

    Table 5 also shows that the total number and percentage of single-line (SL) insurers that only sell medical

    malpractice, as well as the premium share these single-line insurers have among all medical malpractice

    insurers. From 1996 to 2002, we see fewer single-line insurers only selling medical malpractice. The number

    and percentage picked up since 2002. In Large Sample, 40.3% of insurers are single-line insurers in 2010,

    contributing 22.3% to total medical malpractice premiums. In Small Sample, we see a slightly lower percentage

    of single-line insurers representing 19.9% of the medical malpractice market.

    Figure 11 shows that for the most part the percentage of the number and premium share of single-line

    insurers move in opposite direction to that of the combined loss ratios. When loss ratios improve, we see more

    single-line insurers focusing on malpractice.

    Figure 11: Analysis of Single-line (SL) Insurers

    Table 6 shows how single-line (SL) insurers fare as opposed to multi-line (ML) insurers. Figure 12

    indicates that SL insurers usually have lower expense ratios. The only exception is in year 2005 when ML

    insurers have lower expense ratios in Small Sample.

  • 17

    Table 6: Median Loss Ratios of Single-line vs Multi-line Insurers

    Year Large Sample SL Insurers Large Sample ML Insurers Small Sample SL Insurers Small Sample ML Insurers Exp

    Ratio Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    1992 0.024 0.800 0.823 0.151 0.717 0.882 0.028 0.891 0.914 0.080 0.870 0.974

    1993 0.032 0.851 0.913 0.144 0.683 0.827 0.033 0.942 0.960 0.075 0.827 0.930

    1994 0.031 0.709 0.743 0.141 0.701 0.813 0.024 0.723 0.749 0.061 0.803 0.857

    1995 0.030 0.724 0.817 0.125 0.795 0.904 0.026 0.750 0.831 0.064 0.875 0.931

    1996 0.034 0.756 0.862 0.103 0.694 0.799 0.024 0.812 0.831 0.061 0.784 0.852

    1997 0.029 0.652 0.709 0.112 0.734 0.869 0.026 0.718 0.735 0.067 0.872 0.928

    1998 0.036 0.692 0.788 0.122 0.715 0.872 0.031 0.900 0.926 0.065 0.904 0.977

    1999 0.030 0.759 0.867 0.119 0.859 0.947 0.030 0.842 0.900 0.074 0.868 0.938

    2000 0.025 0.766 0.812 0.121 0.816 0.918 0.021 1.121 1.145 0.071 1.034 1.059

    2001 0.026 0.975 1.002 0.125 0.960 1.026 0.024 1.005 1.015 0.085 1.081 1.133

    2002 0.032 0.718 0.785 0.105 0.860 0.987 0.029 1.001 1.021 0.069 0.976 1.028

    2003 0.045 0.648 0.710 0.086 0.798 0.887 0.055 0.719 0.825 0.064 0.899 0.986

    2004 0.038 0.613 0.688 0.077 0.658 0.753 0.055 0.754 0.856 0.060 0.704 0.773

    2005 0.042 0.645 0.716 0.077 0.630 0.703 0.058 0.682 0.756 0.048 0.644 0.691

    2006 0.044 0.552 0.620 0.085 0.540 0.643 0.049 0.522 0.615 0.058 0.595 0.632

    2007 0.046 0.526 0.584 0.089 0.473 0.585 0.051 0.438 0.493 0.058 0.563 0.649

    2008 0.047 0.515 0.603 0.093 0.454 0.567 0.056 0.501 0.622 0.065 0.514 0.614

    2009 0.051 0.505 0.605 0.092 0.505 0.593 0.055 0.542 0.613 0.069 0.524 0.605 2010 0.048 0.512 0.555 0.093 0.481 0.578 0.051 0.542 0.593 0.071 0.487 0.579 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    Figure 12: Expense Ratio: Single-line (SL) vs Multi-line (ML) Insurers

  • 18

    Figure 13: Loss Ratio: Single-line (SL) vs Multi-line (ML) Insurers

    Figure 14: Combined Ratio: Single-line (SL) vs Multi-line (ML) Insurers

  • 19

    Figures 13-14 show that in terms of loss ratios and combined ratios, SL and ML insurers have their

    comparative advantage at different times of the underwriting cycle. From 1997 to 2004, single-line insurers

    perform better. Multi-line insurers have better results at other times.

    DISTRIBUTION OF MALPRACTICE INSURANCE BETWEEN SAFER AND LESS SAFE STATES

    The fourth aspect of the underwriting strategy we study is how insurers allocate their malpractice

    business between safer states (those that have caps on general damages and/or patient compensation funds) and

    less safe states (states that do not have tort reform measures in place). Table 7 counts how many firms sell

    malpractice in CAP- or PCF- states (those that have caps on general damages and/or patient compensation

    funds), and how many in less safe states. Since a firm may sell in both safer and less safe states, the number of

    firms selling in CAP states and the number of firms selling in NO-CAP states do not add up to the total number

    of firms. We see some sharp increase in the number of firms operating in PCF states in recent years.

    Table 7: Analysis of Number of Firms in States of Different Regulatory Environments

    Year

    Large Sample Small Sample

    N of Firms

    N of Firms in

    PCF States

    N of Firms in

    CAP states

    N of Firms in No-PCF States

    N of Firms in No-CAP

    States

    N of Firms

    N of Firms in PCF States

    N of Firms in CAP states

    N of Firms in No-PCF States

    N of Firms in No-CAP

    States

    1992 297 149 195 280 260 117 39 63 102 89 1993 294 146 198 280 256 121 36 66 107 89 1994 268 129 183 251 228 108 36 52 94 82 1995 264 134 189 249 226 108 39 62 93 80 1996 273 140 199 260 229 109 37 62 99 82 1997 275 144 205 265 236 105 37 65 96 78 1998 268 146 210 257 222 108 33 68 101 78 1999 268 148 207 258 232 114 37 70 106 87 2000 257 140 196 245 225 114 41 73 105 84 2001 243 131 187 238 211 106 44 72 97 80 2002 251 148 184 233 220 104 44 68 92 80 2003 276 170 199 243 227 112 53 73 94 85 2004 301 185 219 257 242 113 48 74 97 81 2005 310 186 232 268 236 116 49 74 97 78 2006 324 193 242 270 239 123 46 78 104 79 2007 323 191 234 279 248 124 48 78 106 78 2008 337 196 242 292 260 125 47 78 109 84 2009 337 197 241 292 266 122 49 75 106 83 2010 345 208 253 296 266 124 55 82 105 81 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

  • 20

    Next we examine how many CAP- or PCF-states each firm sells malpractice in. Table 8 shows the

    average values across insurers. For instance, in 2010, insurers in Large Sample write malpractice in 4.27 PCF

    states, which represents 45.4% of the states in which firms sell malpractice. Similarly we find that insurers sell

    malpractice in an average number of 8.07 CAP states, which account for 66.8% of total states in which insurers

    have malpractice business.

    Table 8: Average Number of States of Different Regulatory Environments Insurers Sell Medical Malpractice

    Year Large Sample Small Sample

    N of PCF States

    % of PCF States

    N of CAP States

    % of CAP States

    N of PCF States

    % of PCF States

    N of CAP States

    % of CAP States

    1992 3.91 0.321 5.70 0.495 1.897 0.558 2.381 0.692 1993 4.21 0.297 6.02 0.489 1.972 0.575 2.242 0.716 1994 3.77 0.338 5.11 0.510 2.000 0.579 2.173 0.700 1995 4.01 0.315 5.88 0.514 2.051 0.570 2.274 0.687 1996 3.81 0.304 5.76 0.533 2.135 0.483 2.403 0.680 1997 3.97 0.278 6.35 0.522 2.108 0.474 2.492 0.680 1998 4.08 0.278 6.59 0.540 2.485 0.473 2.529 0.688 1999 4.22 0.275 6.93 0.517 2.243 0.492 2.429 0.662 2000 4.14 0.284 6.81 0.504 1.976 0.477 2.370 0.685 2001 4.43 0.254 7.08 0.509 2.068 0.467 2.431 0.634 2002 4.28 0.341 6.80 0.511 2.227 0.513 2.632 0.641 2003 4.29 0.423 7.22 0.598 2.094 0.577 2.575 0.665 2004 4.04 0.451 7.04 0.620 2.042 0.565 2.581 0.706 2005 3.90 0.439 7.54 0.690 2.061 0.593 3.095 0.792 2006 3.85 0.482 6.96 0.696 2.130 0.639 2.782 0.808 2007 3.92 0.452 7.30 0.687 1.958 0.588 2.718 0.823 2008 4.07 0.451 7.49 0.673 1.936 0.586 2.718 0.792 2009 4.17 0.449 7.90 0.666 1.918 0.574 2.813 0.788 2010 4.27 0.454 8.07 0.668 1.855 0.590 2.622 0.778 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    Figure 15 shows that the average percentage of CAP- or PCF- states in which firms sell medical

    malpractice insurance moves in opposite direction to the combined loss ratios. Overall, we notice that higher

    loss ratios are associated with fewer CAP- or PCF-states in which insurers write malpractice. In other words,

    underwriting performance worsens when insurers write in fewer safer states. It is likely that operating in riskier

    states lead to worsened loss ratios in the first place. Since its hard to identify cause and effect, we can only

    conclude that less business in safer states is associated with higher loss ratios.

  • 21

    Figure 15: % of PCF/CAP States Insurers Sell MM In

    We now turn to an extreme case where insurers choose to write malpractice only in safer states (CAP- or

    PCF- states). For simplicity purpose, we call such firms Only-CAP firms or Only-PCF firms. Table 9 shows the

    number, percentage and premium share of Only-CAP and Only-PCF firms. We notice since 2003 theres been

    an increase in the number of insurers that choose to sell malpractice only in PCF-states, or CAP-states. When

    we graph such information in Figures 16 and 17, we observe that the percentage of Only-CAP firms and Only-

    PCF firms share a negative relationship between the loss ratios. Such firms premium shares also seem to move

    in opposite direction to the combined ratios, though not as closely as the percentage of the number of firms. In

    other words, when loss ratios are high, we have fewer insurers that choose to sell malpractice only in safer

    states. When loss ratios improve, we see more firms preferring to write malpractice only in CAP- or PCF- states.

    This is consistent with our earlier observation in that fewer firms operating in safer states may have caused the

    underwriting performance to decline in the first place.

  • 22

    Table 9: Number, Percentage and Premium Share of Insurers that Only Sell MM in Cap-/PCF- States

    Year

    Large Sample Small Sample Only-CAP Firms Only-PCF Firms Only-CAP Firms Only-PCF Firms

    N % of

    N % of

    Premium N % of

    N % of

    Premium N % of

    N % of

    Premium N % of

    N % of

    Premium 1992 37 0.125 0.073 17 0.057 0.018 28 0.239 0.107 15 0.128 0.035 1993 38 0.129 0.071 14 0.048 0.019 32 0.264 0.107 14 0.116 0.037 1994 40 0.149 0.104 17 0.063 0.025 26 0.241 0.144 14 0.130 0.048 1995 38 0.144 0.097 15 0.057 0.023 28 0.259 0.138 15 0.139 0.037 1996 44 0.161 0.080 13 0.048 0.011 27 0.248 0.139 10 0.092 0.038 1997 39 0.142 0.083 10 0.036 0.007 27 0.257 0.156 9 0.086 0.038 1998 46 0.172 0.076 11 0.041 0.007 30 0.278 0.133 7 0.065 0.018 1999 36 0.134 0.070 10 0.037 0.008 27 0.237 0.117 8 0.070 0.020 2000 32 0.125 0.058 12 0.047 0.006 30 0.263 0.122 9 0.079 0.020 2001 32 0.132 0.063 5 0.021 0.005 26 0.245 0.107 9 0.085 0.015 2002 31 0.124 0.052 18 0.072 0.016 24 0.231 0.089 12 0.115 0.034 2003 49 0.178 0.054 33 0.120 0.021 27 0.241 0.091 18 0.161 0.043 2004 59 0.196 0.071 44 0.146 0.037 32 0.283 0.114 16 0.142 0.049 2005 74 0.239 0.086 42 0.135 0.041 38 0.328 0.144 19 0.164 0.055 2006 85 0.262 0.089 54 0.167 0.043 44 0.358 0.152 19 0.154 0.052 2007 75 0.232 0.088 44 0.136 0.029 46 0.371 0.158 18 0.145 0.050 2008 77 0.228 0.087 45 0.134 0.028 41 0.328 0.149 16 0.128 0.049 2009 71 0.211 0.076 45 0.134 0.032 39 0.320 0.136 16 0.131 0.048 2010 79 0.229 0.082 49 0.142 0.035 43 0.347 0.144 19 0.153 0.051 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

  • 23

    Figure 16: Large Sample: % and P-Share of Only Cap- or PCF- Firms

    Figure 17: Small Sample: % and P-Share of Only Cap- or PCF- Firms

  • 24

    Table 10: Median Loss Ratios: Only-CAP Firms vs. Others

    Year

    Large Sample Only-CAP Firms

    Large Sample All Other Firms

    Small Sample Only-CAP Firms

    Small Sample All Other Firms

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    Exp Ratio

    Loss Ratio

    Comb Ratio

    1992 0.049 0.701 0.766 0.128 0.742 0.889 0.037 0.864 0.921 0.057 0.888 0.971

    1993 0.058 0.798 0.892 0.125 0.733 0.845 0.059 0.940 0.954 0.053 0.848 0.931

    1994 0.057 0.749 0.812 0.111 0.693 0.799 0.049 0.789 0.841 0.046 0.766 0.815

    1995 0.046 0.625 0.691 0.113 0.779 0.902 0.048 0.693 0.747 0.047 0.896 0.937

    1996 0.050 0.699 0.769 0.097 0.719 0.828 0.038 0.739 0.805 0.054 0.816 0.882

    1997 0.070 0.639 0.794 0.107 0.727 0.863 0.070 0.813 0.827 0.047 0.864 0.916

    1998 0.081 0.553 0.686 0.119 0.759 0.902 0.067 0.796 0.868 0.060 0.908 0.987

    1999 0.065 0.732 0.845 0.114 0.854 0.958 0.063 0.806 0.847 0.063 0.900 0.963

    2000 0.102 0.537 0.616 0.113 0.816 0.928 0.081 0.850 0.952 0.058 1.097 1.132

    2001 0.082 0.847 0.905 0.117 0.986 1.063 0.070 1.101 1.103 0.077 1.074 1.120

    2002 0.075 0.670 0.695 0.097 0.857 0.936 0.032 0.809 0.839 0.069 1.027 1.086

    2003 0.084 0.711 0.741 0.077 0.741 0.825 0.047 0.807 0.834 0.065 0.892 0.975

    2004 0.075 0.564 0.685 0.067 0.659 0.750 0.054 0.653 0.724 0.058 0.722 0.785

    2005 0.064 0.580 0.647 0.069 0.659 0.734 0.050 0.634 0.661 0.055 0.682 0.749

    2006 0.067 0.478 0.565 0.059 0.580 0.663 0.072 0.505 0.564 0.049 0.612 0.683

    2007 0.068 0.489 0.584 0.070 0.506 0.586 0.076 0.488 0.556 0.051 0.529 0.600

    2008 0.056 0.454 0.563 0.075 0.498 0.600 0.084 0.487 0.599 0.053 0.541 0.628

    2009 0.064 0.436 0.513 0.073 0.520 0.618 0.064 0.500 0.548 0.068 0.545 0.657

    2010 0.061 0.390 0.455 0.074 0.524 0.611 0.070 0.428 0.480 0.069 0.548 0.650 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    To gain some basic understanding of potential comparative advantage insurers that choose to write

    malpractice only in safer states, we compare the underwriting performance of Only-Cap firms to that of their

    counterparts. Table 10 reports the median values over time. We notice that firms that only sell medical

    malpractice insurance in CAP-states have lower expense ratios for most years in Large Sample, but such

    advantage is not as evident in Small Sample. In terms of loss ratios, from 1995 to 2010, firms that operate in

    only CAP states have lower loss ratios than their counterparts. This is consistent with our observation when we

    compare CAP-states versus No-CAP states and find that states that impose limits on general damages on

    average have better underwriting performance in their jurisdictions than states with no such limits on awards.

    This shows that caps on general damages indeed have effects on mitigating the crisis. The same pattern

    regarding loss ratio and combined ratio is also observed in Small Sample, as evidenced in Figures 18 and 19.

  • 25

    Figure 18: Large Sample Loss Ratios: Only-CAP Firms vs Others

    Figure 19: Small Sample Loss Ratios: Only-CAP Firms vs Others

  • 26

    CHOICE OF PROSPECTIVE POLICYHOLDERS TO COVER

    The last aspect of the underwriting strategy we study is the types of health care providers insurers

    choose to cover. Ideally, we want to find out what kind of high- or low-risk specialties carriers tend to cover

    less or more. However, we do not have such information. In this study we utilize the best available data to do

    some preliminary analysis. For this purpose we turn to Supplement A To Schedule T Exhibit Of Medical

    Malpractice Premiums Written Allocated By States And Territories, which is an exhibit the NAIC didnt start

    providing until 2001. This exhibit shows premiums and losses each insurer incurs in medical malpractice in

    each state each year for each of the following four policyholder types defined by NAIC: PH (= physicians); OP

    (= other health care professionals); HS (= hospitals); OF (= other health care facilities). In Table 11 we show

    the total number of malpractice insurers each year3

    and the percentage of premiums written to cover each type

    of health care providers. We also show the median loss ratios of these providers. For instance, in 2001, 64% of

    premiums are written to cover physicians who as a group have a median loss ratio of 0.83. Note that the loss

    ratios discussed in this section are losses incurred divided by premiums earned since there is no information on

    loss adjustment expense and underwriting expense by types of providers.

    Table 11: Mean Premium Share and Median Loss Ratios to Cover Each Type of Provider

    year

    Small Sample Large Sample % of Premiums Written to

    Cover Median Loss Ratios of % of Premiums Written to

    Cover Median Loss Ratios of

    N PH HS OP OF PH HS OP OF N PH HS OP OF PH HS OP OF 2001 87 0.64 0.22 0.09 0.06 0.83 0.94 0.33 0.85 188 0.45 0.17 0.30 0.09 0.71 0.84 0.35 0.55 2002 90 0.57 0.25 0.09 0.09 0.66 0.81 0.48 0.56 208 0.42 0.18 0.30 0.10 0.60 0.72 0.35 0.52 2003 97 0.58 0.28 0.06 0.08 0.66 0.61 0.30 0.46 227 0.45 0.17 0.57 -0.18 0.54 0.62 0.34 0.41 2004 102 0.60 0.28 0.05 0.07 0.50 0.54 0.31 0.51 251 0.49 0.21 0.18 0.12 0.47 0.49 0.31 0.48 2005 106 0.62 0.26 0.06 0.07 0.44 0.47 0.29 0.36 254 0.51 0.23 0.14 0.12 0.44 0.44 0.27 0.43 2006 109 0.61 0.26 0.06 0.07 0.38 0.49 0.38 0.31 269 0.49 0.21 0.15 0.15 0.37 0.43 0.32 0.31 2007 115 0.61 0.24 0.08 0.07 0.32 0.41 0.23 0.13 289 0.51 0.17 0.17 0.15 0.35 0.40 0.20 0.12 2008 115 0.61 0.25 0.06 0.08 0.31 0.34 0.28 0.37 309 0.52 0.17 0.17 0.14 0.31 0.33 0.22 0.27 2009 120 0.57 0.28 0.08 0.06 0.33 0.42 0.34 0.36 326 0.51 0.18 0.12 0.20 0.32 0.40 0.31 0.20 2010 122 0.58 0.28 0.08 0.06 0.33 0.33 0.24 0.23 327 0.50 0.19 0.17 0.14 0.33 0.32 0.19 0.33 Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    As we can see from both samples, the majority of premiums are written to cover physicians, followed by

    hospitals. Over the years, there is some fluctuation in physicians premium share, though hospitals premium

    3 Note the total numbers somehow differ from our earlier analysis based on the State Page. The reason is that not every firm provides information on both the State Page and the Supplement A page.

  • 27

    share remains relatively stable. Also hospitals tend to have higher loss ratios which explain why insurers cover

    less of them. As a matter of fact, many hospitals formed self-insured entities and do not report to NAIC.

    Since there are no earlier years of premiums/losses breakdown by types of health care providers, we do

    not observe significant trend during the years 2001-2010 by examining providers premium share and loss ratios.

    We next turn to specialists that cover only one type of health care providers. Table 12 shows the percentage of

    such specialist-insurers as well as their premium shares. We graph the same information in Figure 20.

    Table 12: Analysis of Specialists Covering Only One Type of Health Care Providers

    Year

    Large Sample Small Sample % of Number of Firms

    Covering Only Premium Share of Firms

    Covering Only % of Number of Firms

    Covering Only Premium Share of Firms

    Covering Only HS PH OP OF S HS PH OP OF S HS PH OP OF S HS PH OP OF S

    2001 0.04 0.13 0.17 0.03 0.36 0.09 0.04 0.03 0.00 0.16 0.03 0.12 0.02 0.01 0.18 0.08 0.05 0.02 0.00 0.14 2002 0.05 0.15 0.17 0.03 0.40 0.08 0.05 0.03 0.01 0.17 0.07 0.13 0.03 0.01 0.23 0.08 0.06 0.03 0.00 0.16 2003 0.07 0.18 0.12 0.05 0.41 0.09 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.14 0.07 0.13 0.01 0.02 0.23 0.09 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.12 2004 0.06 0.21 0.07 0.07 0.41 0.13 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.16 0.06 0.16 0.01 0.02 0.25 0.12 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.14 2005 0.06 0.22 0.06 0.06 0.40 0.13 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.17 0.07 0.20 0.01 0.03 0.30 0.12 0.02 0.00 0.00 0.15 2006 0.08 0.21 0.07 0.08 0.44 0.18 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.23 0.08 0.21 0.01 0.02 0.32 0.17 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.20 2007 0.06 0.25 0.09 0.08 0.48 0.16 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.22 0.07 0.21 0.02 0.02 0.32 0.14 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.17 2008 0.06 0.26 0.09 0.08 0.51 0.15 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.21 0.06 0.20 0.02 0.02 0.29 0.13 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.17 2009 0.07 0.29 0.10 0.10 0.57 0.17 0.07 0.03 0.01 0.27 0.08 0.23 0.03 0.02 0.36 0.14 0.07 0.01 0.00 0.23 2010 0.08 0.28 0.11 0.08 0.55 0.13 0.06 0.04 0.01 0.24 0.08 0.22 0.03 0.02 0.35 0.12 0.07 0.01 0.00 0.20 Note: S refers to specialists that cover only one type of health care providers. Source: authors analysis of NAIC data.

    Figure 20: Analysis of % of Specialist-insurers

  • 28

    In 2001, 4% of firms in Large Sample cover only hospitals (HS), representing 9% of the total premiums

    written in medical malpractice. Similarly, 36% of firms in Large Sample are specialists covering only one type

    of health care providers in 2001, yet on average their premium share is 16% among all medical malpractice

    insurers. In both samples, we see a largely increasing trend in the number of specialist-insurers over time, yet

    their premium shares do not go up that much. Overall, were seeing more and more insurers covering only

    physicians in their malpractice business, close to 28% in the Large Sample and about 22% in Small Sample by

    2010, though their premium shares are still relatively small and stable. Figure 20 shows that for most years

    (except 2010), the percentage of insurers only covering physicians and that of all specialist-insurers display an

    opposite trend to that of the combined loss ratios. When we see insurers underwriting performance improve in

    recent years, we also observe an increasing percentage of specilist insurers.

    Test of Capacity Constraint Theory

    Having discovered some aspects of insurers underwriting strategy display certain cyclical nature, we

    now test whether the capacity constraint theory can explain such phenomenon in the medical malpractice

    industry. The causes of insurance cycles have been extensively studied and in this section we want to focus on

    the capacity constraint theory, while keeping in mind that tests of other cycle theories could be future research

    topics.

    Weiss and Chung (2004) summarize the capacity constraint theory well, The capacity constraint

    hypothesis postulates that capital does not flow freely into and out of the insurance indutry due to market

    imperfections As a result, insurers will be inclined to hold on to seemingly excess capital in profitable years, so

    as to have capital available to pursue opportunities in lean years. The capacity constraint hypothessi assumes

    also that claims are uncetain and correlated across policies, and insurers (combined) equity determins industry

    supply. Because losses are correlated, all insurers will be affected similarly by a loss chock (e.g., adverse

    interpretation of tort law for general liability insurers in the 1980s leading to a general liability crisis). Thus

    industry-wide soft and hard markets will occur. In soft markets capital is plentiful, while in hard markets it is

    relatively scarce. As a result, in periods of excess capacity, insurance price is relatively low, and it is relatively

    high in periods with relatively low capitabization. Therefore prices are hypothesized to be sensitive to industry-

    wide capital. (p442)

    In our study we do not intend to examine how malpractice prices change in response to capacity change.

    Instead, we will test the capacity constraint theory by examining whether an increase (or decrease) in capacity

  • 29

    will expand (or shrink) insurance supply. More specifically, we will use the following general form of

    regression equation:

    Y = f (lagged total surplus, lagged overall loss ratio, lagged firm-specific loss ratio).

    We have the following four dependent variables, which are all binary variables.

    Single_line: equals 1 if an insurer only sells medical malpractice in a particular year.

    Single_state: equals 1 if an insurer sells medical malpractice in one single state in a particular year.

    Only_CAP_state: equals 1 if an insurer only sells medical malpractice in states that have caps on general

    damanges.

    Specialist: equals 1 if an insurer only covers one type of health care providers.

    The major independent variable is the capacity, which we measure using insurers surplus. Since we

    have four different dependent variables, we have also four corresponding surplus variables, which are

    constructed in the same manner though.

    When we analyze how capacity affects insurers decision to go single-line, the surplus we are looking at

    is the total surplus of all single-line insurers in a particular year. Similary, the surplus variable for the dependent

    variable of Single_state (Only_CAP_state) is the total surplus of all single-state (Only_CAP_state) insurers.

    The loss ratio variables in the regression equation refer to combined loss ratios when the dependent

    variables are Single_line, Single_state or Only_CAP_state. When the dependent variable is Specialist, the loss

    ratios are simply loss incurred divided by premiums earned.

    The overall loss ratio variables are constructed in a similar manner to that of surplus variables. When the

    dependent variable is Single_line, the overall loss ratio is the combined loss ratio of all single-line insurers.

    Lastly, firm-specific loss ratios are firm-year level loss ratios.

    Given the binary nature of our dependent variables, we run four firm-year level logistic regressions and

    report our results in Tables 13 and 14, respectively. Table 13 shows the regression results of dependent

    variables Single_line, Single_state and Only_CAP_state. We group them together because the relevant

    information is all from the State Page. We have 4807 observations in Large Sample and 1891 in Small Sample.

    The probability modeled here is Y equal to 1, which is the probability that an insurer is a single_line insurer,

    single-state insurer or Only_CAP_state insurer. To account for potential endogeneity issue, we use lagged

    values for all independent variables.

    Our results show that lagged surplus has a positive relationship with the three dependent variables

    derived from the State Page. A lower surplus in the previous year will reduce the probability that a firm will be

  • 30

    a single-line insurer, single-state insurer or Only_CAP_state insurer. This is consistent with the capacity

    constraint theory in that a shrinking capacity will suppress the insurance supply. Our innovation here is that

    instead of studying the entire malpractice industrys surplus, we look at segments of the industry and see how

    capacity in a particular segment affects supply of insurance in that segment. When we divide the industry into

    single-line and multi-line insurers, we have segments of single-line insurers and multi-line insurers. Similarly,

    when we study geographic concentration and distribution of malpractice insurance between safer and less safe

    states, we have different segementations. We show that capacity of a particular segment does positively affect

    supply of insurance in that segement. Our empirical study provides evidence to support the capacity constraint

    theory in the malpractice market.

    Table 13: Logistic Regression of Underwriting Strategy: Probability modeled is Y=1

    Large Sample (N=4807)

    Y Results Intercept Lagged Total Surplus

    Lagged Overall Loss Ratio

    Lagged Firm-specific Loss Ratio

    Single_line Estimate 0.3463

  • 31

    In the large sample, we also find that overall loss ratio of single-line insurers has a negative impact on

    firms decision to go single-line. In other words, if loss ratios for single-line insurers go up, insurers are less

    likely to just sell medical malpractice. This makes sense since insurers tend to move away from less profitable

    business. In our small sample, we find that firm-specific loss ratios play a more significant role in determining

    insurers likelihood of becoming single-state or only_CAP_state firms.

    Table 14: Logistic Regression: Y=Specialist, Probability modeled is Y=1

    Variables Large Sample N=2424 Small Sample N=947

    Estimate ProbChiSq Estimate ProbChiSq Intercept 0.6348 0.0849 -0.3988 0.2755 Lagged Total Surplus

  • 32

    Moreover, when we look at which states in which malpractice carriers do business, we see that the percentage

    of safer states (states that have caps on general damages or patient compensation funds) in which insurers write

    malpractice and the percentage of insurers that choose to do business only in safer states are both negatively

    associated with the combined loss ratio of the medical malpractice insurance industry. Taken all together, it

    seems that at the industry level, insurers underwriting performance has a negative association with their risk

    taking behavior in terms of how much to focus on malpractice line of business and where to write such business.

    Less focus on malpractice and wider distribution of malpractice products are seen to accompany worsened

    underwriting performance.

    We also test whether the capacity constraint theory can help explain the cyclical nature of medical

    malpractice insurers underwriting strategy. We find that when the total surplus of all single-line insurers (those

    only selling medical malpractice) shrinks, insurers are less likely to go single-line. We observe the same trend

    when we examine single-state insurers (those selling medical malpractice in just one state) and ONLY-CAP-

    State insurers (those selling medical malpractice only in states with caps on general damages). In other words,

    our results provide some support for the capacity constraint theory which predicts an inadequate capacity will

    shrink insurance supply.

    References 1. Elango B, Y Ma, and N Pope, 2008, An Investigation Into The Diversification-Performance Relationship In The

    U.S. Property-Liability Insurance Industry, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 75 (3): 567-591.

    2. Lei, Yu and Mark Browne, Fall 2008, Medical Malpractice Insurance Market Entry and Exit: 1994-2006,

    Journal of Insurance Regulation, 27 (1), 47-71.

    3. Lei, Yu and Joan Schmit, 2010, Influences of Organizational Structure and Diversification on Medical

    Malpractice Insurer Performance, Journal of Insurance Issues, 33 (2): 152177.

    4. Liebenberg AP and DW Sommer, 2008, Effects Of Corporate Diversification: Evidence From The Property-

    Liability Insurance Industry, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 75 (4): 893-919.

    5. Nordman, E., D. Cermak and K. McDaniel, 2004, Medical Malpractice Insurance Report: A Study of Market

    Conditions and Potential Solutions to the Recent Crisis. Kansas City, Mo.: National Association of Insurance

    Commissioners.

    6. Viscusi, W Kip and Born, Patricia H, 2005, Damages Caps, Insurability, and the Performance of Medical

    Malpractice Insurance, Journal of Risk and Insurance, 72 (1): 23-43.

    7. Weiss, Mary A. and Joon-Hai Chung, 2004, U.S. Reinsurance Prices, Financial Quality, and Global Capacity, Journal of risk and Insurance, 71 (3): 437-467.