Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in...

39
1 Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of extra-territorial patent filings Richard Perkins* and Eric Neumayer Address, both: Department of Geography and Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK Fax: +44 (0)20 7955 7412 Tel: +44 (020) 7955 7605 *Richard Perkins = [email protected] Eric Neumayer = [email protected] *Corresponding author

Transcript of Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in...

Page 1: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

1

Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the

geography of extra-territorial patent filings

Richard Perkins* and Eric Neumayer

Address, both: Department of Geography and Environment, London School of

Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK

Fax: +44 (0)20 7955 7412

Tel: +44 (020) 7955 7605

*Richard Perkins = [email protected]

Eric Neumayer = [email protected]

*Corresponding author

Page 2: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

2

Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of extra-

territorial patent filings

Abstract

This article provides new insights into how geography shapes spatio-temporal variations

in the propensity of countries to file for non-resident patents in specific foreign

economies. Our major contribution is to show that, in addition to bi-lateral exports and

outward foreign direct investment, the geography of extra-territorial patenting is

influenced by strategic interdependencies with third-countries. We therefore find that

countries are more likely to file for patent protection in focal foreign economies where

their regional peers and, to a lesser extent, competitors with similar export product

structures have filed for a larger number of patents.

Keywords: patents, knowledge, imitation, economic linkages

Page 3: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

3

Introduction

Within the context of economic globalisation, the rise of emerging markets, and the

growing importance of knowledge as a source of competitive advantage, the number of

extra-territorial patents has grown significantly over the past two decades (Archibugi and

Michie 1995; WIPO 2008). As a form of legally-enforceable property right1, patents

allow firms to protect their intellectual assets, and more securely innovate or deploy

technologies outside their home country. Yet, individual countries differ in the number of

patents that their nationals hold abroad and, moreover, demonstrate a greater propensity

to file for patent protection in certain foreign economies than others (Chan et al. 2004;

Sun 2003; van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and van Zeebroeck 2008; Yang and Kuo

2007). This article seeks to provide new insights into how geography shapes spatio-

temporal variations in the propensity of country nationals to make non-resident patent

filings (NRPFs) in specific foreign economies.

Previous quantitative studies have established that differences in the number of

NRPFs can be explained by countries’ level of exports and foreign direct investment

(FDI) to recipient countries. They have also found some, but not always unambiguous,

support for the idea that distance to potential recipients, intellectual property rights (IPR)

protection, and market attractiveness influence the numbers of NRPFs (Bosworth 1984;

Hoti and McAleer 2006; O’Keeffe 2005; Sun 2003; Xu and Chiang 2005; Yang and Kuo

2007). Our analysis advances on these studies in two important ways.

1 More formally, a patent can be defined as an exclusive intellectual property right granted to a novel process and/or product innovation, which provides the owner with protection over a specified period of time.

Page 4: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

4

First, and most importantly, we explore a further set of explanations for

differences in extra-territorial patenting by citizens of individual countries. More

specifically, we examine whether the decision by residents of one country to file for

patents in another economy is influenced by the prior applications of other “reference”

third-countries, specified here as (a) states located in the same geographic macro-region

and (b) states with a similar export product structure. There are a number of compelling

reasons to expect strategic interdependencies in the geography of extra-territorial

patenting, but previous work has ignored this possibility outright.

A second advance is to use a sample of larger spatial and temporal dimensions.

Past studies have either examined a medium-sized sample of countries over a small

number of years (Falvey et al. 2006; Yang and Kuo 2007), or examined a single country

over a longer period of time (Bosworth 1984; O’Keeffe 2005). The panel analysed in the

present article not only includes a far larger number of countries than any equivalent

study (up to 143 applicant and 108 recipient countries2, compared to 30 countries in both

categories for Yang and Kuo (2007), the study closest to our own), but also for a

substantial period of time (10 years versus 3 in the case of Yang and Kuo). This larger

sample means that we are able to produce more generalisable insights and examine

whether previous findings are robust to the inclusion of countries outside the core of

economies which account for the vast bulk of international non-resident patent

applications and receipts.

The article also contributes to wider debates in economic geography. By

analysing unevenness in extra-territorial patenting, our study helps to advance

understanding into the conditions under which (codified) knowledge is transferred across 2 Note, the sample falls to 128 applicant and 97 recipient economies with the inclusion of FDI and exports.

Page 5: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

5

borders (Faulconbridge 2006; Gertler 2003; Ivarsson 2002; Neumayer and Perkins 2005;

Verspagen and Schoenmakers 2004). Our article also contributes to debates about

relational economic geographies (Bathelt and Gluckler 2003; Bunnell and Coe 2001;

Yeung 2005). While work in relational geography distinguishes itself in its central

recognition that actors’ economic behaviour is strongly influenced by external economic

networks, it has not gone far in examining how extra-local linkages with firms based in

third-countries may affect the spatiality of firms’ international business strategy. Through

an examination of cross-border strategic interdependence in extra-territorial patenting,

this article sheds fresh light into one under-explored aspect of relational geography, and

points towards the need for more complex accounts of the relational context.

Unevenness in patterns of internationalisation

The number of patents filed in the majority of countries’ patent offices has risen

dramatically over the past two decades (Kortum and Lerner 1999; van Pottelsberghe de la

Potterie and van Zeebroeck 2008). Accounting for a large share of this expansion are

NRPFs, i.e. patents filed in offices outside the country of the owner/inventor of a

technology, which have been growing faster than patents filed by a country’s domestic

residents. Although indicative of a trend towards the international transfer and

exploitation of technology, as with other manifestations of internationalisation, large

geographic variations exist in patenting activity. A handful of countries – the United

States, Japan, Germany and the Republic of Korea – accounted for the majority (59.5%)

of NRPFs in 2006 (WIPO 2008, p.32). NRPFs received by individual countries also

Page 6: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

6

varies markedly. The US receives by far the largest number of patent filings by non-

residents, followed some distance behind by various European states covered by the

European Patent Office3, China, Japan, the Republic of Korea, Canada, Australia, Brazil

and India.

Interesting as these disparities in the absolute number of patent filing and receipts

are in their own right, they mask even more interesting differences in disaggregated

bilateral patenting activity. Focusing on these latter variations, this article seeks to

explain why some countries demonstrate a greater propensity to file for patents in certain

economies than others. Our main concern is thus not with generic attributes of sending or

receiving states which influence the total number of non-resident patent applications or

receipts. For this reason, we relegate two sets of territorially-bounded attributes identified

in previous research to the status of control variables, namely: (a) the innovativeness of

(potential) applicant countries and (b) the market attractiveness of (potential) recipient

countries (Bosworth 1984; Scherer 1983; Sun 2003; Xu and Chiang 2005; Yang and Kuo

2007). Rather, our central concern is with attributes which vary across dyads, comprising

pairs of potential applicant and recipient countries. It is our contention that relational ties

between applicant and recipient countries, as well as between third-party countries and

their residents involved in extra-territorial patenting, have a significant influence on

NRPF activity.

Motives for patenting

3 The European Patent Office (EPO) provides a route for inventors to apply for patent protection, using a single grant procedure, in one or more of 35 contracting states of the European Patent Convention (EPC).

Page 7: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

7

Applying for patents is costly (Sternitzke 2009). A considerable amount of time, effort

and money is required in order to prepare a patent application for consideration by a

patent office, which itself typically charges various administrative fees to cover

examination expenses. These costs will, if anything, be greater for extra-territorial

applications. An important corollary is that inventors and/or owners of a technology are

unlikely to file for a patent in another country unless there are benefits from doing so

which offset these costs (Bosworth 1984; Inkmann et al. 2000; O’Keeffe 2005).

Orthodox, economic (“appropriation”) accounts have largely conceptualised these

benefits in terms of the protection of IPRs (Mazzoleni and Nelson 1998). A patent creates

a temporary monopoly, empowering inventors/owners with a legal right to stop other

parties from copying, manufacturing, selling or importing a technology, or to seek

damages for infringement of intellectual property. By granting exclusive use, or the right

to sell or licence a specific invention, patents allow inventors to appropriate rents from

their innovative efforts (Inkmann et al. 2000). Another (related) payoff from patents

protection identified in the literature derives from strategic deterrence (Gilbert and

Newbery 1982). A firm, or group of firms, may pre-emptively acquire a portfolio of

patents in a particular industrial field in order to raise the barriers to entry, potentially

enabling firms to establish or defend a dominant market position (Sankaran 2000).

More recently, scholars have hypothesised that the returns from obtaining patents

lie in their ability to facilitate co-ordination amongst firms involved in innovating and

commercialising new technology (Kortum and Lerner 1999). Penin (2005: 648-650)

identifies a number of such benefits, including: (a) signalling that a firm possesses

technological competencies and is therefore a valuable technological partner; (b) creating

Page 8: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

8

a market for a new product by advertising its presence and providing assurance against

free-riding among potential buyers; and (c) providing a ‘“legal bargaining chip”…[that]

will be traded when firms need to use technologies that are protected by patents held by

other firms’ (pg.649).

In the next section, we draw from and, moreover, extend these insights to develop

a series of propositions about the attributes which are likely to influence the propensity of

residents from one country to file for patents in another country.

Economic links via exports and FDI

The ownership of proprietary technology potentially provides firms wishing to export

their products and services with a competitive advantage – vis-à-vis their rivals – in

foreign markets. Precisely for this reason, we expect exporters to attempt to protect their

technology in foreign markets, namely by filing for patent protection (O’Keeffe 2005,

pg.125). Without patent protection, domestic competitors (as well as third-country ones

operating in the same market) could well engage in copy-cat engineering, eroding a

firm’s core competitive competencies and inflicting significant commercial damage

(Vishwasrao 1994).4

The literature on FDI has similarly made much of firm-specific technological

assets. According to Dunning’s (2001) influential eclectic framework, a company will

make direct investments in other countries where it possesses ownership-specific

advantages, including technology-based ones. As in the case of exports, these

4 Non-resident patent holders potentially face working requirements, which commit them to manufacture the patented technology locally within a specified period of time. Yet not all countries enforce this requirement and, even when they do, patents may provide temporary protection during which time non-working may be allowed or a patent holder locates a local licensee (Azmi and Alavi 2001; Bosworth 1984).

Page 9: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

9

technological resources may allow a transnational corporation (TNC) to compete with

foreign competitors. TNCs innovate, own and control a large share of the world’s

advanced technology, and evidence suggests that access to proprietary technologies plays

an important role in many firms’ competitive strategies (Dicken 2007; Globerman et al.

2000). It follows that TNCs will possess strong incentives to protect their intellectual

property, notably, by filing for patent protection in countries where they operate (Sun

2003).5 As outlined in models of strategic blocking, FDI may additionally be

accompanied by attempts to “build walls” around foreign markets, with a view to

deterring the entry of other competitors. TNCs may file for a large number of patents in

particular technology fields, whether or not they intend to use or licence the technology,

in countries where they operate. They may also file for patents in the host economy to

facilitate interaction, transactions and co-operation with other firms.

Whether by exports or FDI, what is likely to determine the actual number of

NRPFs is a country’s absolute level of cross-border economic involvement in the

recipient economy (Yang and Kuo 2007). A higher amount of exports to a particular

country implies a greater diversity of transferred technologies, for which patent

protection must be sought, and therefore a greater number of NRPFs. Similarly, higher

inward stocks of FDI suggest greater foreign involvement in the host economy, bringing

with it a larger number of proprietary technologies, which again is likely to lead to more

filings by non-residents.

5 The eclectic paradigm also identifies location-specific advantages as a motive for FDI which, of note in the present context, is known to include technological capabilities not available in the TNC’s home country (Dicken, 2007). Yet while these asset-seeking and asset-augmenting investments may give rise to new patents, we do not consider these in the present context because, as noted by Archibugi and Michie (1995), patented inventions are credited to the country of the inventor rather than the owner.

Page 10: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

10

These expectations are confirmed by recent empirical work. Previous statistical

studies have all reached a broadly similar conclusion: countries’ exports and the number

of NRPFs in receiving countries are positively correlated (Bosworth 1984; Eto and Lee

1993; Inkmann et al. 2000; Schiffel and Kitti 1978; Xu and Chiang 2005; Yang and Kuo

2007). A similar pattern emerges for FDI: levels of direct investment or numbers of

TNCs located in host economies exhibit a positive relationship with NRPFs (Bosworth

1984; Eto and Lee 1993; Sun 2003; Yang and Kuo 2007).

Yet, before concluding that exports and FDI unambiguously drive NRPFs in

recipient countries, several qualifications are in order. First, some of the above cited

studies are based on fairly rudimentary, bi-variate correlations, such that they potentially

suffer from problems of omitted variable bias (Bosworth 1984; Eto and Lee 1993; Sun

2003). Second, almost all of these studies have analysed exports and investment

separately, instead of together. This is potentially problematic, in the sense that exports

and inward FDI are not independent of one other, meaning that it is unclear from past

studies whether one, the other, or indeed both, are drivers of NRPF. And third, most

previous studies are based on relatively small geographic samples, mainly comprising

developed countries and a handful of more dynamic industrialising economies. On the

recipient side, samples vary from one country for Sun (2003) to 50 for Bosworth (1984),6

while on the applicant side, samples range from a single patenting country for Bosworth

(1984) to 30 for Yang and Kuo (2007). Indeed, all that we can conclude from previous

work is that exports and investment possibly have a positive influence on extra-territorial

patenting in a sub-set of patent-intensive developed economies.

6 Moreover, this study does not employ a dyadic dataset, such that it merely suggests that countries with more inward FDI receive more NRPF filings, but not that they receive these filings from the major investors.

Page 11: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

11

This article seeks to address some of these shortcomings, namely, by (a) using a

multivariate research design in which exports and investment are analysed in the same

estimation model, and (b) analysing a substantially larger sample of years and

applicant/recipient countries, including a large number of developing countries omitted in

previous work.

Strategic interdependencies

The decision to file for patent protection in another country may be relatively

straightforward for firms transferring critical, high-value technology via exports and/or

investment (Lanjouw et al. 1998). Yet, in many other situations, the choice to patent may

be far from straightforward. These difficulties arise because, as in other business

contexts, corporate decision-makers face considerable uncertainty over the need for and

payoffs from patent protection (Sternitzke 2009; Vishwasrao 1994).

One source of uncertainty centres on an invention’s medium- to long-term market

returns (van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and van Zeebroeck 2008). Most inventions do

not result in commercially viable technologies and, even when they do, it is likely to be

difficult to predict a technology’s future profitability in foreign markets. Indeed, these

uncertainties are likely to be amplified where a firm is unsure as to whether it is going to

participate in a particular country, or to what degree. Another source of ambiguity is

whether a particular patent system offers sufficient protection from imitation, so as to

justify the financial or other costs of NRPF. Along similar lines, a company may not

know whether there is a genuine risk that its proprietary technology will be copied,

Page 12: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

12

applied or re-exported by firms operating in the (potential) recipient country. Adding to

the difficulties of evaluating the financial payoffs from patents is uncertainty about the

costs of acquiring protection through domestic patent systems.

Going further, even if a firm does decide that it wishes to defend its proprietary

knowledge, it is by no means certain that patents will be used. In practice, there are a

number of ways in which economic actors can attempt to prevent imitation. Especially in

R&D-intensive industries, evidence suggests that many firms rely just as much or more

heavily on methods other than patents, especially secrecy (Arundel 2001; Inkmann et al.

2000; Levin et al. 1987).

Previous work on extra-territorial patenting has largely ignored these

uncertainties. Instead, studies have implicitly or explicitly assumed that decision-makers

are rational, profit-maximising agents, endowed with perfect information about the range

of alternatives and the costs, benefits and returns associated with each of these options.

They have also portrayed decision-makers as atomistic agents, isolated from the

influences of other firms (Bosworth 1984; Hoti and McAleer 2006; O’Keeffe 2005; Xu

and Chiang 2005). However, we believe that these assumptions are highly questionable,

and that the failure to properly acknowledge uncertainty and relational influences

represents an important oversight.

Accepting that economic actors are not perfectly rational, knowledgeable and

operate in uncertain, relational environments has far-reaching implications. In particular,

it suggests that firms may be influenced to file for patents not only by internal

calculations regarding profitability or strategic value, but also by the actions of other

firms. According to an established body of work, therefore, decision-makers frequently

Page 13: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

13

resort to imitating significant reference groups when confronted with uncertainty

(DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Guler et al. 2002; Haveman 1993; Henisz and Delios 2001).

Drawing from these ideas, we argue that the decision to file for patent protection in a

particular country will be shaped by the choices of firms from third-countries.

A number of causal mechanisms have been advanced to predict, or else explain,

imitative dynamics (Lieberman and Asaba 2006; Ordanini et al. 2008). One broad class

focuses on information. For economic variants, managers may copy others, either

assuming that they have better quality information, or because doing so economises on

search, information and experimentation costs (Bikhchandani et al. 1992; Cyert and

March 1963). Another related idea, which has its roots in the new-institutionalism in

economic sociology, is that managers turn to other agents in their inter-organizational

environments when making decisions, because doing so provides legitimacy for a

particular course of action (DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Fligstein 1985). Applied to

extra-territorial patenting, corporate decision-makers lacking adequate information might

plausibly look towards other firms’ prior filings as a signal that patent protection is a

necessary, profitable or otherwise worthy activity (Henisz and Delios 2001). Similarly,

from a new-institutionalist perspective, domestic firms could well follow the lead of

foreign peers in order to align themselves with organizations whose choices are perceived

as more legitimate, progressive or appropriate (Abrahamson 1996; Neumayer and Perkins

2005).

A second set of causal mechanisms conceptualise imitation ‘as a response

designed to mitigate competitive risk or rivalry’ (Lieberman and Asaba 2006, pg.374).

According to theories of competitive diffusion, firms will emulate their (potential) rivals

Page 14: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

14

so as to minimise the risk of becoming competitively disadvantaged, resulting in “follow-

the-leader”-type behaviour (Elkins et al. 2006; Haveman 1993). Again, these predications

can be logically extended to patenting, where theories of competitive emulation would

anticipate cross-country interdependence in NRPF. A firm based in country A may be

uncertain about whether to seek patent protection in country B. However, with a view to

mitigating the risk that rivals will steal a competitive march by acquiring a position of

technologically-based leadership, firms from country A may copy the patenting activities

of peers from “competitor” economy C operating in focal country B. Indeed, competitive

emulation of this sort may be important in view of strategic blocking, with firms hedging

against market lock-out via extra-territorial patenting.

Although the possibility of strategic interdependence has been neglected in the

literature on extra-territorial patenting, its existence is nevertheless beginning to be

documented in other areas of business internationalisation. Several large-N studies have

shown that firms imitate their domestic rivals in making choices about foreign market

entry (Delios et al. 2008; Guillén 2002; Henisz and Delios 2001). Going further, studies

have found evidence that firms may also imitate their counterparts located in other

countries, including in relation to foreign entry/exit decisions (Chan et al. 2006), and the

adoption of management standards (Albuquerque et al. 2007; Guler et al. 2002). This

article extends the analysis of cross-border strategic interdependencies to extra-territorial

patenting decisions.

An important question concerns the identity of countries which might plausibly

exert imitative influence. A number of different possible country “peer” groups exist.

Within the present study, however, we focus on two reference groups, namely: (a)

Page 15: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

15

countries which are located in the same geographic macro-region; and (b) economies

with a similar export product structure. Guiding our choice of the first of these two

groups is the idea that macro-regions comprise distinctive spaces of interaction,

comparison and learning. Work in economic geography – as well as business studies –

has identified a distinctive macro-regional configuration to cross-border trade,

investment, R&D and production strategies (Dicken 2007; Rugman and Verbeke 2004;

Yeung 2001). An important consequence – and, to a greater or lesser extent, a cause – of

these economic dependencies is that firms are likely to communicate more frequently

with their counterparts located in the same geographic region, share information with

them, observe their actions, and take cues from their strategic choices (Albuquerque et al.

2007). Indeed, greater familiarity or socio-cultural propinquity with actors located in the

same region means that economic actors are more likely to identify with their regional

peers, such that their actions carry greater weight (Bunnell and Coe 2001; Gertler 2003).

Inspiration for our second hypothesized peer group comes from theories of

competitive emulation. If, as economic accounts emphasise, imitation is driven by the

threat of competition, it follows that firms are more likely to mimic their counterparts in

countries which are perceived as important competitors. According to previous work, one

such set of firms are located in countries with an equivalent economic structure,

competing internationally in similar export products (Elkins et al. 2006; Guler et al. 2002;

Poon and Thompson 2004). As well as potential competitors, firms located in countries

with similar export product structures might be perceived as providing more relevant

signals of appropriate market behavior, stemming from the fact that they are more likely

to face similar economic circumstances.

Page 16: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

16

Of course, our two hypothesised relational attributes are not mutually exclusive,

and it is quite possible that the extra-territorial patenting behaviour of firms located in

both sets of country reference groups may play a role in influencing the strategic choices

of firms to file for patent protection. However, to the extent that they capture contrasting

aspects, our study provides a useful test case to examine whether strategic

interdependence is locational, structural or both.

Dependent and main explanatory variables

Our dependent variable is a directed country dyadic variable, namely, the number of non-

resident patents filed by nationals of country i in foreign country j. The data, obtained

from the World International Property Organization (WIPO 2008), cover a 10-year period

from 1995-2005.

We analyse four main explanatory variables – each corresponding to a hypothesis

regarding the influence of economic or strategic dependence. Our export variable is

measured by the value of bilateral exports – from patent applicant country i to recipient

country j – using data obtained from UN (2007). Foreign investment dependence is

measured using the value of outward bilateral FDI stock of country i in host economy j,

with data taken from UNCTAD (2008). Values of exports and investment were converted

to constant US$.

In order to capture strategic interdependence, we use spatial lag variables. More

precisely, we employ what Neumayer and Plümper (2009) call specific source contagion

spatial lag variables, which can be defined formally as:

Page 17: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

17

1 1 ...iktijt ijtkjtk i

y yρ εω − −≠

= + +∑ (1)

In words, the patenting activity of nationals from country i in foreign country j

depends spatially on the number of patents that nationals from all other third-party

countries k have filed in the same focal economy j in the previous year, weighted by

some connectivity matrix capturing the degree of linkage between country i and countries

k ( 1iktω − ). We thus assume that residents of any one country are influenced in their

patenting activity in recipient country j by the number of patents filed by nationals of

other countries in the same focal economy j, but they are influenced more by some third-

countries than others, as given by the connectivity matrix. As is standard practice, we

“row-standardize” the weighting matrix (Anselin 2002). Note, the spatial lag refers to

patenting activity in the previous year to mitigate endogeneity bias.7

In the case of our hypothesis of spatial dependence through export product

equivalence, the connectivity variable entering the weighting matrix captures the

similarity of export product shares. Other countries k exporting a similar set of products

as country i have a larger hypothesized influence on its patenting activity in focal

economy j than countries that export a more dissimilar set of products. After Elkins et al.

(2006), we calculate export product similarity as the correlation between two countries’

export shares for 13 key product sectors among their total exports. If two countries

exported exactly the same share of products in these sectors, the variable would be one,

while it would be minus one if they exported entirely different products.

7 The potential endogeneity arises because, while countries k have an impact on country i, country i’s activity also has a (small) reverse impact on countries k. Fully accounting for potential endogeneity would require a negative binomial spatial maximum likelihood estimator which, to our knowledge, does not currently exist.

Page 18: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

18

For our second hypothesis of spatial dependence via the regional location of

countries, our connectivity variable is constructed using a simple dichotomous measure

that is set to one if country i and country k are located in the same macro-region, and zero

otherwise. Thus, as country i’s regional peers file for more patents in foreign recipient

economy j, which itself may or may not be located in the same region, we expect

residents of country i to file for more patents in country j. To identify regional location,

we use the UNWTO’s (2007) classification of countries into sixteen macro-regions,

rather than the World Bank’s eight macro-region classification. The latter is too highly

aggregated. To take one example: the World Bank places all countries in Central

America, the Caribbean and South America into one large regional group, but actors in,

say, Chile are unlikely to strategically depend on the choices made by actors in distant

Guatemala. The appendix lists the UNWTO classification.

Control variables

We also include two sets of control variable. The first seeks to account for differences in

the innovativeness of potential applicant countries. The underlying logic is that more

innovative countries are likely to develop, commercialise and own a greater number of

inventions which require patent protection in foreign markets (Sun 2003). In order to

capture the innovativeness of countries, we use two variables: gross domestic product

(GDP) and GDP per capita. Larger countries should, all else equal, have a larger number

of actors involved in inventing, innovating and commercialising technologies and

therefore have more inventions to patent. Likewise, actors in wealthier countries possess

Page 19: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

19

greater technological capabilities required to develop new technologies, together with the

financial capabilities needed to finance technological development (Furman et al. 2002).

Actors in richer economies should also be in a better position to afford the costs of

acquiring patents (Chan et al. 2004).

A second set of variables seek to control for the real and/or perceived

attractiveness of countries as a location for foreign firms to transfer technologies and file

for patent protection. We use three controls. One is the degree of protection afforded by

patent systems. We anticipate that foreigners will be more willing to transfer their

inventions to countries whose national patents systems offer greater protection. Although

the relationship between IPR and technology transfer is complex, patent systems which

offer greater protection should reduce the risk of appropriation, and increase the

economic value of patent applications (Lerner 2002; Smith 1999; Xu and Chiang 2005).

We use Park’s (2008) recently-constructed index of patent rights. The index scores

national patent systems according to their: (i) coverage; (ii) a country’s membership in

international (IPR-related) treaties; (iii) enforcement mechanisms; and (iv) restrictions on

patent rights.8

Additionally, we control for country market size (GDP) of (potential) recipients of

NRPFs. As hypothesised elsewhere, owners/inventors are more likely to file for patent

protection in larger markets, where greater demand for a more diverse set of innovations

makes it more profitable for firms to deploy, exploit and protect their technology

(Lanjouw et al. 1998; O’Keeffe 2005; Sun 2003). Previous empirical work supports these

predictions (Bosworth 1984; Inkmann et al. 2000; van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and

van Zeebroeck 2008). 8 Park provides data for 1995, 2000 and 2005. We linearly interpolate for the missing in-between years.

Page 20: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

20

Neither IPR protection nor market size can fully capture the attractiveness of a

foreign country j for NRPFs. We therefore additionally include the total number of

NRPFs taken out by any foreigner in the previous year. A larger total number of NRPFs

in country j in the previous year should, all other things equal, signal to potential foreign

patent applicants in country i that country j is an attractive market in which to file for

patent proection. This variable can also capture the lower transactions costs and therefore

greater attractiveness of filing patents in European states party to the European Patent

Convention, which allows applicants to acquire a national patent in more than one

country through a single application procedure.

Next, we seek to control for the likelihood that actors are more likely to patent

their inventions in spatially proximate countries. Conceptually, this is typically explained

in terms of the liabilities of foreignness, with potential applicants finding it more

difficult, costly and risky to evaluate, make and manage investments in distant countries.

Early empirical work provided support for these ideas, finding that neighbouring

countries have high levels of inter-country patent flows (Sláma 1981; Soete and Wyatt

1983). More recently, Yang and Kuo (2007) show that physical distance is negatively

correlated with non-resident patents, although Sun (2003) finds no such relationship with

distance and/or same geographic region. Still, to the extent that the literature suggests that

spatial proximity continues to exert an influence over technology transfer, we seek to

control for neighbourhood effects (Keller 2004; van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and

Lichtenberg 2001; Won Sonn and Storper 2008). In order to capture spatial proximity, we

use two measures: (a) physical distance, in kilometres between the patent applicant

country i’s and patent recipient country j’s capital cities, using data from Bennett and

Page 21: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

21

Stam (2005); and (b) regional location, again using UNWTO (2007) to code whether the

applicant country i and recipient country j are located in the same geographic macro-

region.

Finally, we include year-specific time dummies to control for common shocks and

trends which affect all countries equally. A failure to control for common shocks and

trends may lead to biased estimates for the spatial dependence variables (Plümper and

Neumayer 2009).

Most continuous variables enter the regressions in logged form to account for our

expectation that the relationship between, say, measures of economic dependence and

NRPF is non-linear: greater exports and FDI give rise to more extra-territorial patents,

but diminishingly so as the value of these increase.9 Based on the above, we estimate

variants of the following model (leaving out the coefficients to be estimated):

1 21 1 1 ln ...ln lnlnln ijtikt ik it jtijt kjt kjt ijt itk i k i

y y y exp GDPpcGDP GDPFDIω ω− − −≠ ≠

= + + + + + + +∑ ∑

1 lnjt ij ijtijt ij ti

y sameregion yeardistIPRP ε−+ + + + + +∑ , (2)

where 1 1iktω − stands for export product structure similarity and 2 ikω captures same

regional location of countries i and k.

Estimation technique

9 This model also has a much better fit than an alternative one with these variables entered linearly.

Page 22: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

22

The dependent variable is a strictly non-negative count variable (number of patents)

meaning that we cannot use ordinary least squares (OLS) because doing so would violate

the estimation model’s underlying assumptions. There are two main estimation models

suitable for count data: poisson and negative binomial. The sample variance largely

exceeds the sample mean and we therefore opt for the negative binomial model. Standard

errors are adjusted for clustering of observations on country dyads.

Results

Table 1 shows our estimation results. We start with a model that does not include any of

the four main explanatory variables of interest (column 1). With the exception of the

sameregion variable, all of the control variables are statistically significant with the

expected coefficient sign. As previously hypothesised in the literature, we thus find that

larger and wealthier countries account for a larger number of NRPFs, as do countries

which are physically closer (Chan et al. 2004; Furman et al. 2002; Sun 2003). Turning to

recipient countries, confirming the findings of previous work, we estimate that larger

markets attract more non-resident filings (Bosworth 1984; Inkmann et al. 2000; van

Pottelsberghe de la Potterie and van Zeebroeck 2008). Also consistent with expectations,

we estimate a positive relationship between NRPFs filed by citizens of country i on the

one hand and the strength of patent system protection in recipient economies as well as

our general measure of a country’s attractiveness for foreign patenting on the other.

In column 2, we add the dyadic export and FDI stock variables. The previously

insignificant sameregion variable now becomes statistically significant, but with an

Page 23: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

23

unexpected negative coefficient sign, while the previously significant distance variable

now becomes statistically insignificant. A possible explanation for these changes is that

countries typically trade and invest more with spatially proximate/same region

economies, such that our economic dependence and locational variables are likely to be

correlated with one another. All of the other control variables remain largely similar. The

same is true for the remaining estimation models, which is why we no longer report

control variable results below.

Turning to the first of our two main explanatory variables, we estimate a positive

and statistically significant relationship between the measure of bilateral exports and

NRPFs, indicating that countries make a greater number of patent filings in countries to

which they export more. Also supporting the idea that extra-territorial patenting is

mapped onto cross-border economic linkages, our coefficient for outward FDI stock and

NRPFs is positive and statistically significant. Simply put: our results suggest that greater

stocks of foreign investment in a particular economy is likely to be accompanied by more

NRPFs from the country of the investors. We thus find evidence supporting our first two

hypotheses.

Of even greater interest to us is whether there is evidence of strategic

interdependence in the decision to file for patents. Entered separately, coefficients for

each of the two spatial lag variables capturing trait-based country categories are positive

and statistically significant (see columns 3 and 4, respectively). As anticipated, our

results suggest that a country is more likely to file for patents in a particular recipient

economy where other countries exhibiting a similar export product structure have taken

out a higher number of NRPFs. Also in line with expectations, countries’ propensity to

Page 24: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

24

file for patent protection in recipient economies rises as their regional peers account for a

larger number of extra-territorial patents in these countries.

How do these results change when both variables of strategic interdependence are

entered into the estimation model simultaneously (column 5)? The spatial lag capturing

export product structure becomes statistically insignificant. Yet the spatial lag linking

countries from the same macro-region remains statistically significant. Caution must be

exercised when interpreting these findings, but they do tentatively suggest that there is

more robust evidence that the NRPF decisions of countries depend spatially on the patent

activity of other countries in the same region rather than of other countries with a similar

export product structure.

Conclusion

Our goal in the present article has been to advance understanding into the factors which

explain variations in the propensity of individual countries to file for patent protection in

specific foreign countries. As in previous work, we demonstrate a major role for

economic links, although our findings are based on a significantly larger sample of

developed and developing countries. Higher levels of exports and outward foreign

investment are therefore found to be associated with more NRPF in destination countries.

A plausible explanation for these findings is that the economic value of patents is

greater in major foreign markets where, presumably, inventors and/or owners have more

to lose from failing to protect their proprietary technology (Lanjouw et al. 1998). Another

possible reason why exports and foreign investment matter is that firms may pre-

Page 25: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

25

emptively acquire patents in particular countries – whether or not they intend to actually

deploy, work or sell the technology locally – in order to “block” competitors from

entering their major markets (Gilbert and Newbery 1982). Especially in the case of FDI,

it is also possible that acquiring patents facilitates co-ordination, better allowing foreign

transnationals to transact, co-operate and manage disputes with other firms in host

economies (Penin 2005).

As well as providing more generalisable evidence about the role of exports and

investment, a major contribution of the present article is to demonstrate the existence of

strategic interdependence in the decision by non-residents to apply for patent protection

in particular markets. The idea of strategically interdependent decision-making has been

documented in other areas of international business activity (Albuquerque et al. 2007;

Guillén 2002; Guler et al. 2002). Yet, to the best of our knowledge, it has remained

unexplored in the field of patenting.

Filling an important gap in current understanding, we thus find statistically robust

evidence that the decision to file for patent protection in particular markets is influenced

by the prior actions of actors from specific groups of other countries. The number of

patents filed in a specific foreign economy by residents from one country increase with a

higher number of prior non-resident filings by regional peers in this same economy. A

similar relationship exists where the peer group comprises countries which are

structurally equivalent in terms of their export products, although the relationship is not

statistically significant when both sets of strategic interdependence are accounted for in

the regression equation.

Page 26: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

26

According to the literature, imitative behaviour has its roots in uncertainty and

ambiguity (Lieberman and Asaba 2006), conditions which are likely to confront decision-

makers in relation to many extra-territorial patenting decisions (Sternitzke 2009;

Vishwasrao 1994). Thus, it is possible that uncertainty about the costs, benefits and

overall business value of holding patents in particular markets prompts firms to turn to

their foreign peers for information, guidance and strategic cues. Understood as a form of

imitative behaviour, the influence of regional location could plausibly arise from a

number of geographically-bounded attributes, including: the greater propensity of actors

to communicate, share information and observe regional peers; social, political and/or

cultural similarities which render the choices of regional peers more relevant, appropriate

and legitimate; and firms located in the same macro-region being seen as competitors,

such that their choices prompt competitive emulation (Bunnell and Coe 2001). Similar

factors might explain the imitative influence of structurally equivalent exporters, with

actors based in these countries more likely to be seen as rivals, whose decisions have

competitive implications.

These insights have wider implications for understanding in economic geography.

Our results therefore contribute to debates about the pathways through which (codified)

knowledge diffuses across borders (Faulconbridge 2006; Gertler 2003; Verspagen and

Schoenmakers 2004). Although a share of patents will be filed in countries for strategic

blocking purposes, we nevertheless provide large-N, statistical confirmation of work

which has suggested that exports and outward FDI are major vehicles for international

knowledge transfer (Dicken 2007; Globerman et al. 2000; Ivarsson 2002; Keller 2004;

Perkins and Neumayer 2005).

Page 27: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

27

Our findings also speak to debates about relational economic geographies. Recent

work within this paradigm has usefully drawn attention to the influence of the external

context within which firms operate, transact and make strategic decisions (Bathelt and

Gluckler 2003; Yeung 2005). An important contribution of the present article is to

expand the boundaries of this relational context to include complex, extra-local

interactions and dynamics. The finding that patent filings by regional peers and

structurally equivalent exporters are correlated with own country residents’ patent filings

in particular target markets suggest that corporate decision-making is shaped by actors

based in third-countries. That is, relational influences are not only governed by direct

contact, but also through distanciated forms of learning, comparison and emulation.

Finally, our study is instructive in relation to debates about the ongoing

importance of regional location. We find that region matters, but not in the way

commonly hypothesised. On the one hand, we find that same regional location of the

potential patenter and the country in which the patent is taken fails to exert a positive

influence on the geography of NRPFs. Of note, this would appear to contradict recent

work which suggests that patterns of economic internalisation, knowledge diffusion and

exploitation have a regional dimension (Dicken 2007; Globerman et al. 2000; Keller

2004; Rugman and Verbeke 2004). On the other hand, we show that location matters in

the sense that patenting activity by regional peers in focal economies exerts imitative

influence over the decision by own country residents to file for patent protection. Indeed,

although more tentative than our other findings, the fact that same region patenting would

appear to be a more robust predictor than patenting by countries with a similar export

composition suggests that (if anything) location trumps structure. That is, despite

Page 28: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

28

evidence suggesting that countries file for patents in an increasing number and diversity

of economies worldwide, countries would appear to pay more attention to the actions of

actors from the same region than those with whom they compete internationally in export

products.

Page 29: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

29

Table 1. Estimation results. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

base model

exports & FDI added

SL (export product similarity) added

SL (same region) added

Both SL variables added

0.001 0.001 1 1 1ikt kjt

k i

yω − −≠∑

(2.08)** (1.16)

0.001 0.001 2

1ik kjtk i

yω −≠∑

(2.27)** (2.02)**

0.246 0.250 0.245 0.247 ln ijtexp (5.78)*** (5.84)*** (5.64)*** (5.69)*** 0.072 0.076 0.079 0.080 ln ijtFDI (4.48)*** (4.67)*** (5.01)*** (5.01)***

0.681 0.412 0.402 0.392 0.390 ln itGDP (27.18)*** (8.82)*** (8.64)*** (8.59)*** (8.55)***

0.462 0.334 0.335 0.331 0.331 ln itGDPpc (8.89)*** (5.39)*** (5.33)*** (5.35)*** (5.34)***

0.517 0.254 0.224 0.236 0.226 ln jtGDP (25.08)*** (7.39)*** (6.96)*** (7.31)*** (6.90)***

0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 1ijt

i

y −∑ (8.77)*** (8.05)*** (5.00)*** (7.89)*** (6.25)***

0.411 0.280 0.268 0.280 0.274 jtIPRP (4.90)*** (2.66)*** (2.52)** (2.64)*** (2.58)***

-0.058 -0.414 -0.457 -0.639 -0.629 ijsameregion

(0.35) (2.16)** (2.58)*** (4.18)*** (4.11)*** -0.144 -0.025 -0.028 -0.037 -0.036 ln ijdist

(6.21)*** (0.87) (0.96) (1.25) (1.23) Constant -33.171 -20.038 -18.981 -18.905 -18.595 (38.33)*** (11.67)*** (11.61)*** (11.80)*** (11.56)*** Observations 15754 10691 10689 10691 10689 Notes: 1 1iktω − is an export product similarity, 2 ikω is a same region weighting matrix. *, **, *** significant at 10, 5 and 1 percent, respectively. Negative binomial regression with observations clustered on country dyads. Absolute z-statistics in brackets. Year-specific time dummies included, but coefficients not reported.

Page 30: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

30

Appendix. Regional classification of countries in sample. North America: Canada, United States. Central America: Dominica, El Salvador, Guatemala, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, St. Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Trinidad and Tobago. South America: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Uruguay, Venezuela. Western Europe: Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom. Eastern Europe: Belarus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Moldova, Poland, Russian Federation, Slovak Republic, Ukraine. Balkan: Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, Greece, Macedonia, Romania, Slovenia, Yugoslavia, FR (Serbia/Montenegro). Northern Africa: Algeria, Egypt, Morocco, Tunisia. Eastern Africa: Burundi, Ethiopia, Kenya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mauritius, Rwanda, Seychelles, Zambia. Western and Middle Africa: Congo, Rep., Liberia, Sierra Leone. Southern Africa: Lesotho, South Africa, Zimbabwe. Middle East: Iran, Israel, Saudi Arabia, Turkey. Central Asia: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Georgia, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyz Republic, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, Uzbekistan. South Asia: Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan, Sri Lanka. East Asia: China, Japan, Mongolia, South Korea. South-East Asia: Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand, Vietnam. Pacific: Australia, New Zealand.

Page 31: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

31

Acknowledgements This work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC) [grant number RES-000-22-27530]

Page 32: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

32

References Abrahamson, E. (1996) Management fashion. Academy of Management Review, 21: 254-

285.

Albuquerque, P., B. J. Bronnenberg, and C. J. Corbett (2007) A spatiotemporal analysis

of the global diffusion of ISO9000 and ISO14000 certification. Management

Science, 53: 451-468.

Anselin, L. (2002) Under the hood: Issues in the specification and interpretation of spatial

regression models. Agricultural Economics, 27: 247-267.

Archibugi, D., and J. Michie (1995) The globalisation of technology: A new taxonomy.

Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19: 121-140.

Arundel, A. (2001) The relative effectiveness of patents and secrecy for appropriation.

Research Policy, 30: 611-624.

Azmi, I. M., and Rokiah, A. (2001). Trips, patents, technology transfer, foreign direct

investment and the pharmaceutical industry in Malaysia. Journal of World

Intellectual Property, 4: 947-976.

Bathelt, H., and J. Gluckler (2003) Toward a relational economic geography. Journal of

Economic Geography, 3: 117-144.

Bennett, D. S., and A. Stam (2005). EUGene: Expected utility generation and data

management program, version 3.1. Available at: http://eugenesoftware.org

Bertrand, O., J.-L. Mucchielli, and H. Zitouna (2007) Location choices of multinational

firms: The case of mergers and acquisitions. Journal of Economic Integration, 22:

181-209.

Page 33: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

33

Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch (1992) A theory of fads, fashion, custom,

and cultural change as informational cascades. Journal of Political Economy, 100:

992-1026.

Bosworth, D. L. (1984) Foreign patent flows to and from the United Kingdom. Research

Policy, 13: 115-124.

Bunnell, T. G., and N. M. Coe (2001) Spaces and scales of innovation. Progress in

Human Geography, 25: 569-589.

Chan, C. M., S. Makino, and T. Isobe (2006) Interdependent behavior in foreign direct

investment: The multi-level effects of prior entry and prior exit on foreign market

entry. Journal of International Business Studies, 37: 642-665.

Chan, F., D. Marinova, and M. McAleer (2004) Trends and volatilities in foreign patents

registered in the USA. Applied Economics, 36: 585-592.

Cyert, R., and J. March (1963) A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. New Jersey: Prentice

Hall.

Delios, A., A. S. Gaur, and S. Makino (2008) The timing of international expansion:

Information, rivalry and imitation among Japanese firms, 1980-2002. Journal of

Management Studies, 45: 169-195.

Dicken, P. (2007) Global Shift: Mapping the Changing Contours of the World Economy.

5th ed. London: Sage.

DiMaggio, P. J., and W. W. Powell (1983) The iron cage revisited: Institutional

isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American

Sociological Review, 48: 147-160.

Page 34: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

34

Dunning, J. H. (2001) The eclectic (OLI) paradigm of international production: Past,

present and future. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8: 173-

190.

Elkins, Z., A. T. Guzman, and B. A. Simmons (2006) Competing for capital: The

diffusion of bilateral investment treaties, 1960–2000. International Organization,

60: 811-846.

Eto, H., and J. H. Lee (1993) Foreign patenting and trade with regard to competitiveness.

Technovation, 13: 221-233.

Falvey, R., N. Foster, and O. Memedovic (2006) The role of intellectual property rights

in technology transfer and economic growth: Theory and evidence. Vienna:

United Nations Industrial Development Organization (UNIDO).

Faulconbridge, J. R. (2006) Stretching tacit knowledge beyond a local fix? Global spaces

of learning in advertising professional service firms. Journal of Economic

Geography, 6: 517-540.

Fligstein, N. (1985) The spread of the multidivisional form among large firms, 1919-

1979. American Sociological Review, 50: 377-91.

Furman, J. L., M. E. Porter, and S. Stern (2002) The determinants of national innovative

capacity. Research Policy, 31: 899-933.

Gertler, M. S. (2003) Tacit knowledge and the economic geography of context, or The

undefinable tacitness of being (there). Journal of Economic Geography, 3: 75-99.

Gilbert, R. J., and D. M. G. Newbery (1982) Pre-emptive patenting and the persistence of

monopoly. American Economic Review, 73: 514-526.

Page 35: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

35

Globerman, S., A. Kokko, and F. Sjöholm (2000) International technology diffusion:

Evidence from Swedish patent data. Kyklos, 53: 17-38.

Guillén, M. F. (2002) Structural inertia, imitation, and foreign expansion: South Korean

firms and business groups in China, 1987-95. The Academy of Management

Journal, 45: 509-525.

Guler, I., M. F. Guillén, and J. M. Macpherson (2002) Global competition, institutions,

and the diffusion of organizational practices: The international spread of ISO

9000 quality certificates. Administrative Science Quarterly, 47: 207-232.

Haveman, H. A. (1993) Follow the leader: Mimetic isomorphism and entry into new

markets. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38: 593-627.

Henisz, W. J., and A. Delios (2001) Uncertainty, imitation, and plant location: Japanese

multinational corporations, 1990-1996. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46:

443-475.

Hoti, S., and M. McAleer (2006) How does country risk affect innovation? An

application of foreign patents registered in the USA. Journal of Economic

Surveys, 20: 691-714.

Inkmann, J., W. Pohlmeier, and L. A. Ricci (2000). Where to patent? Theory and

evidence on international patenting. In Institutional arrangements for global

economic integration, ed. H-J. Vosgerau, Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan, 122-

140.

Ivarsson, I. (2002) Transnational corporations and the geographical transfer of localised

technology: A multi-industry study of foreign affiliates in Sweden. Journal of

Economic Geography, 2: 221-247.

Page 36: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

36

Keller, W. (2004) International technology diffusion. Journal of Economic Literature, 42:

752-782.

Kortum, S., and J. Lerner (1999) What is behind the recent surge in patenting? Research

Policy, 28: 1-22.

Lanjouw, J. O., A. Pakes, and J. Putnam (1998) How to count patents and value

intellectual property: The uses of patent renewal and application data. Journal of

Industrial Economics, 46: 405-432.

Lerner, J. (2002) Patent protection and innovation over 150 years. NBER Working Paper

No. W897.

Levin, R. C., A. K. Klevorick, R. R. Nelson, and S. G. Winter (1987) Appropriating the

returns from industrial R&D. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3: 783-

820.

Lieberman, M. B., and S. Asaba (2006) Why do firms imitate each other? Academy of

Management Review, 32: 366-385.

Mazzoleni, R., and R. R. Nelson (1998) Economic theories about the benefits and costs

of patents. Journal of Economic Issues, 32: 1031-1052.

Neumayer, E., and R. Perkins (2005) Uneven geographies of organizational practice:

Explaining the cross-national transfer and diffusion of ISO 9000. Economic

Geography, 81: 237-259.

Neumayer, E., and T. Plümper (2009) Spatial effects in dyadic data. International

Organization (forthcoming).

Page 37: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

37

O’Keeffe, M. (2005) Cross comparison of US, EU, JP and Korean companies patenting

activity in Japan and in the Peoples Republic of China. World Patent Information,

27: 125-134.

Ordanini, A., G. Rubera, and R. DeFillippi (2008) The many moods of inter-

organizational imitation: A critical review. International Journal of Management

Reviews, 10: 375-398.

Park, W. G. (2008) International patent protection: 1960–2005. Research Policy, 37: 761-

766.

Penin, J. (2005) Patents versus ex post rewards: A new look. Research Policy, 34: 641-

656.

Perkins, R., and E. Neumayer (2005) The international diffusion of new technologies: A

multitechnology analysis of latecomer advantage and global economic

integration. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 95: 789-808.

Plümper, T., and E. Neumayer (2009) Model specification in the analysis of spatial

dependence. Working Paper, University of Essex and London School of

Economics and Political Science.

Poon, J. H., and E. R. Thompson (2004) Convergence or differentiation? American and

Japanese transnational corporations in the Asia Pacific. Geoforum 35:111-125.

Rugman, A. M., and A. Verbeke (2004) A perspective on regional and global strategies

of multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 35: 3-18.

Sankaran, K. (2000) Patent flooding in the United States and Japan. IDEA: The

Intellectual Property Law Review, 40: 393-428.

Page 38: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

38

Scherer, F. M. (1983) The propensity to patent. International Journal of Industrial

Organization, 1: 107-128.

Schiffel, D., and C. Kitti (1978) Rates of invention: International patent comparisons.

Research Policy, 7: 324-340.

Sláma, J. (1981) Analysis by means of a gravitational model of international flows of

patent applications in the period 1967-1978. World Patent Information, 3: 1-8.

Smith, P. J. (1999) Are weak patent rights a barrier to U.S. exports? Journal of

International Economics, 48: 151-177.

Soete, L., and S. Wyatt (1983) The use of foreign patenting as an internationally

comparable science and technology output indicator. Scientometrics, 5: 31-54.

Sternitzke, C. (2009) Reducing uncertainty in the patent application procedure – insights

from malicious prior art in European patent applications. World Patent

Information, 31: 36-47.

Sun, Y. (2003) Determinants of foreign patents in China. World Patent Information, 25:

27-37.

UNCTAD (2008) Foreign direct investment database. Geneva: UNCTAD.

UNWTO (2007). Statistical data in Excel format. Geneva: UNWTO.

van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B., and F. Lichtenberg (2001) Does foreign direct

investment transfer technology across borders? The Review of Economics and

Statistics, 83: 490-497.

van Pottelsberghe de la Potterie, B., and N. van Zeebroeck (2008) A brief history of

space and time: The scope-year index as a patent value indicator based on

families and renewals. Scientometrics, 75: 319-338.

Page 39: Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in ...personal.lse.ac.uk/PERKINSR/patents.pdf · Transnational economic and strategic interdependencies in the geography of

39

Verspagen, B., and W. Schoenmakers (2004) The spatial dimension of patenting by

multinational firms in Europe. Journal of Economic Geography, 4: 23-42.

Vishwasrao, S. (1994) Intellectual property rights and the mode of technology transfer.

Journal of Development Economics, 44: 381-402.

WIPO (2008) World patent report: A statistical review. Geneva: WIPO.

Won Sonn, J., and M. Storper (2008) The increasing importance of geographical

proximity in knowledge production: An analysis of US patent citations, 1975-

1997. Environment and Planning A, 40: 1020-1039.

Xu, B., and E. Chiang (2005) Trade, patents and international technology diffusion.

Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 14: 115-135.

Yang, C-H., and N-F. Kuo (2007) Trade-related influences, foreign intellectual property

rights and outbound international patenting. Research Policy, 37: 446-459.

Yeung, H. W-C. (2001) Organizing regional production networks in Southeast Asia:

Implications for production fragmentation, trade, and rules of origin. Journal of

Economic Geography, 1: 299-321.

Yeung, H. W-C. (2005) Rethinking relational economic geography. Transactions of the

Institute of British Geographers, 30: 37-51.