Trade, markup heterogeneity and...

13
Trade, markup heterogeneity and misallocations Paolo Epifani a , Gino Gancia b, a Department of Economics and KITeS, Università Bocconi, via Sarfatti 25, 20136, Milano, Italy b CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and CEPR, Ramon Trias Fargas 25-27, 08005, Barcelona, Spain abstract article info Article history: Received 15 December 2008 Received in revised form 6 August 2010 Accepted 11 October 2010 Available online 17 October 2010 JEL classication: F12 F15 Keywords: Markups Dispersion of market power Procompetitive effect Trade and welfare Markups vary widely across industries and countries, their heterogeneity has increased overtime and asymmetric exposure to international trade seems partly responsible for this phenomenon. In this paper, we study how the entire distribution of markups affects resource misallocation and welfare in a general equilibrium framework encompassing a large class of models with imperfect competition. We then identify conditions under which trade opening, by changing the distribution of markups, may reduce welfare. Our approach is novel both in its generality and in the emphasis on the second moment of the markup distribution. Two broad policy recommendations stand out from the analysis. First, whenever there is heterogeneity in markups, be it due to trade or other distortions, there is also an intersectoral misallocation, so that the equilibrium can be improved upon with an appropriate intervention. This suggests that trade liberalization and domestic industrial policy are complementary. Second, ensuring free entry is a crucial precondition to prevent adverse effects from asymmetric trade opening. © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. What is relevant for the general analysis is not the sum of individual degrees of monopoly but their deviations A.P. Lerner 1. Introduction Monopoly power varies widely across industries and rms. Data on 4-digit US manufacturing industries show that Price-Cost Margins (PCMs), a common measure of markups, range from 1% in the rst percentile of the distribution, to 60% in the 99th percentile. Cross- country evidence suggests these asymmetries to be even larger in less developed economies. Moreover, monopoly power varies systemat- ically with exposure to international competition. For instance, the average PCM is a slim 13% in US manufacturing, producing goods that are typically traded, versus a fat 33% in nontraded business sector services. The conventional wisdom is that, as the process of globalization continues, competition among rms participating in international markets will intensify, thereby alleviating the distor- tions associated with monopoly power. The latter presumption is not however granted, because the exact mapping between the economy- wide distribution of markups and the extent of misallocations is not an obvious one. The textbook partial-equilibrium analysis of the deadweight loss from monopoly seems to imply that market power, by raising prices above marginal costs, is always distortionary. Yet, this reasoning neglects the fact that, as pointed out by Lerner (1934) and Samuleson (1947), in general equilibrium misallocations depend on relative rather than absolute prices. If all prices incorporate the same markup, Lerner noted that relative prices would signal relative costs correctly and, absent other sources of inefciencies, would lead to the optimal allocation. This suggests that distortions only come from the dispersion of market power across rms and industries. The implications of this principle are far-reaching. For instance, it implies the seemingly paradoxical result that an increase in competition in industries with below-average markups, such as those producing tradeable goods, is deemed to amplify monopoly distortions. It also raises warnings that the increased heterogeneity in observed measures of market power across industries may indicate growing misallocations. Yet, when market power is coupled with free entry, so that markups affect the equilibrium number of rms, new welfare effects arise. For instance, when rms produce differentiated products and consumers like variety, it is desirable that markups be high enough to induce the socially optimal level of entry. The aim of this paper is to study how the economy-wide distribution of markups distorts the allocation of resources in a general framework that encompasses a large class of models of imperfect competition. In doing so, we revisit and qualify the Lerner condition that markups should be uniform across industries and illustrate when and how the level and dispersion of markups matter. Our second goal is to relate the degree of monopoly power in an industry to the presence of foreign competition and to study how trade can affect welfare by changing the dispersion of market power. Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 113 Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (P. Epifani), [email protected] (G. Gancia). 0022-1996/$ see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2010.10.005 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of International Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jie

Transcript of Trade, markup heterogeneity and...

Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of International Economics

j ourna l homepage: www.e lsev ie r.com/ locate / j i e

Trade, markup heterogeneity and misallocations

Paolo Epifani a, Gino Gancia b,⁎a Department of Economics and KITeS, Università Bocconi, via Sarfatti 25, 20136, Milano, Italyb CREI, Universitat Pompeu Fabra and CEPR, Ramon Trias Fargas 25-27, 08005, Barcelona, Spain

⁎ Corresponding author.E-mail addresses: [email protected] (P. Ep

(G. Gancia).

0022-1996/$ – see front matter © 2010 Elsevier B.V. Aldoi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2010.10.005

a b s t r a c t

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:Received 15 December 2008Received in revised form 6 August 2010Accepted 11 October 2010Available online 17 October 2010

JEL classification:F12F15

Keywords:MarkupsDispersion of market powerProcompetitive effectTrade and welfare

Markups vary widely across industries and countries, their heterogeneity has increased overtime andasymmetric exposure to international trade seems partly responsible for this phenomenon. In this paper, westudy how the entire distribution of markups affects resource misallocation and welfare in a generalequilibrium framework encompassing a large class of models with imperfect competition. We then identifyconditions under which trade opening, by changing the distribution of markups, may reduce welfare. Ourapproach is novel both in its generality and in the emphasis on the second moment of the markupdistribution. Two broad policy recommendations stand out from the analysis. First, whenever there isheterogeneity inmarkups, be it due to trade or other distortions, there is also an intersectoral misallocation, sothat the equilibrium can be improved upon with an appropriate intervention. This suggests that tradeliberalization and domestic industrial policy are complementary. Second, ensuring free entry is a crucialprecondition to prevent adverse effects from asymmetric trade opening.

ifani), [email protected]

l rights reserved.

© 2010 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

“What is relevant for the general analysis is not the sum ofindividual degrees of monopoly but their deviations ”

A.P. Lerner

1. Introduction

Monopoly power varies widely across industries and firms. Dataon 4-digit US manufacturing industries show that Price-Cost Margins(PCMs), a common measure of markups, range from 1% in the firstpercentile of the distribution, to 60% in the 99th percentile. Cross-country evidence suggests these asymmetries to be even larger in lessdeveloped economies. Moreover, monopoly power varies systemat-ically with exposure to international competition. For instance, theaverage PCM is a slim 13% in US manufacturing, producing goods thatare typically traded, versus a fat 33% in nontraded business sectorservices. The conventional wisdom is that, as the process ofglobalization continues, competition among firms participating ininternational markets will intensify, thereby alleviating the distor-tions associated with monopoly power. The latter presumption is nothowever granted, because the exact mapping between the economy-wide distribution of markups and the extent of misallocations is notan obvious one.

The textbook partial-equilibrium analysis of the deadweight lossfrom monopoly seems to imply that market power, by raising prices

above marginal costs, is always distortionary. Yet, this reasoningneglects the fact that, as pointed out by Lerner (1934) andSamuleson (1947), in general equilibrium misallocations dependon relative rather than absolute prices. If all prices incorporate thesame markup, Lerner noted that relative prices would signal relativecosts correctly and, absent other sources of inefficiencies, wouldlead to the optimal allocation. This suggests that distortions onlycome from the dispersion of market power across firms andindustries. The implications of this principle are far-reaching. Forinstance, it implies the seemingly paradoxical result that an increasein competition in industries with below-average markups, such asthose producing tradeable goods, is deemed to amplify monopolydistortions. It also raises warnings that the increased heterogeneityin observed measures of market power across industries mayindicate growing misallocations. Yet, when market power is coupledwith free entry, so that markups affect the equilibrium number offirms, new welfare effects arise. For instance, when firms producedifferentiated products and consumers like variety, it is desirablethat markups be high enough to induce the socially optimal level ofentry.

The aim of this paper is to study how the economy-widedistribution of markups distorts the allocation of resources in ageneral framework that encompasses a large class of models ofimperfect competition. In doing so, we revisit and qualify the Lernercondition that markups should be uniform across industries andillustrate when and how the level and dispersion of markups matter.Our second goal is to relate the degree of monopoly power in anindustry to the presence of foreign competition and to study howtrade can affect welfare by changing the dispersion of market power.

1 Bhagwati (1971) and Johnson (1965) where the first to argue that trade can lowerwelfare if it exacerbates an existing distortion. Later studies have examined sufficientconditions for positive gains from trade in the presence of various distortions. See, forexample, Eaton and Panagariya (1979) and references therein.

2 Basu and Fernald (2002) stress the distinction between aggregate productivity andaggregate technology and recognize that technology improvements could reducewelfare if they lead sectors with smaller-than-average markups to increase input use.Yet, they do not pursue this idea, nor they relate it to trade liberalization. Gancia andZilibotti (2009) shows how markup asymmetries may also distort the development oftechnology in dynamic models with innovation.

3 An important advantage of PCMs is that they can vary both across industries andovertime. An alternative approach would be to estimate markups from a structuralregression a là Hall (1988). One problem with this approach is that, to estimatemarkups across industries or over time, either the time or industry dimension is to besacrificed, implying that markups have to be assumed constant overtime or acrossindustries.

4 This database allows to compute PCMs for broad aggregates of traded andnontraded industries for a sample of OECD countries.

5 This dataset is based on information from the World Bank, the OECD and theUNIDO. It allows to compute PCMs across broad manufacturing aggregates for asample of developed and developing countries.

2 P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

In particular, we are interested in finding under what circumstancesasymmetric trade liberalization may turn out to be welfare reducing.

To this end, we build a model with a continuum of industries thatare heterogeneous in both costs and demand conditions. Firms mayproduce homogenous or differentiated goods and entry may or maynot be restricted. By comparing the market equilibrium with the onechosen by a benevolent social planner, we identify the misallocationsdue to the entire markup distribution. The results crucially depend onthe assumptions about entry. If entry is restricted, we confirm Lerner'sprinciple that markup symmetry across industries and firms is anecessary and sufficient condition for efficiency. Whenever thiscondition is violated, there is an intersectoral misallocation wherebyrelatively less competitive industries underproduce and relativelymore competitive ones overproduce relative to the socially optimalquantity. Perhaps surprisingly, we find the extent of this misallocationto be stronger when the elasticity of substitution between industriesis high and we show that its welfare cost may be quantitativelysignificant. We also show that trade liberalization affecting only someindustries may have adverse welfare effects when it raises markupheterogeneity. In other words, contrary to the conventional wisdom,procompetitive losses from trade are possible.

With free entry, the level of markups matters too and the Lernercondition about symmetry turns out to be necessary, but notsufficient, for efficiency. Moreover, contrary to the previous case, weshow that in general there exists no markup distribution capable ofreplicating the first best allocation. This means that policy interven-tions aimed at controlling prices only are not enough to correct all thedistortions and other instruments, such as subsidies, are needed.Moreover, we find that some heterogeneity in markups, despite themisallocation it induces, may well be welfare improving. Finally, weshow that free entrymakes procompetitive losses from trade unlikely,even when trade increases markup dispersion.

Two general policy recommendations stand out from our analysis.First, whenever there is heterogeneity in markups, be it due to trade,regulations or differential ability to collude across sectors, there is anintersectoral misallocation. Industries with above-average markupsalways underproduce (either in terms of output per firm or of productvariety), so that the equilibrium can be improved upon with anappropriate intervention. This also suggests that trade liberalizationand domestic industrial policy are complementary. Second, free entryis an important condition to prevent asymmetric trade liberalizationfrom having possibly adverse welfare effects. A novel implication ofour findings is that the relative competitiveness of the industriesaffected by trade liberalization matters. This observation should betaken into account when designing trade policy. Interestingly, ouranalysis may also help rationalize the often heard concern that trademay be detrimental in countries (especially the less developed ones)where domestic markets are not competitive enough. The reason isnot that domestic firms are unable to survive foreign competition (asemphasized by the infant-industry theory), but rather that interna-tional competition may inefficiently increase asymmetries acrossindustries in the economy.

This paper makes contact with three strands of literature. The firststudies monopoly distortions in general equilibrium and includesclassics such as Lerner (1934), Samuleson (1947), Dixit and Stiglitz(1977), but also more recent works by Neary (2003), Koeniger andLicandro (2006), Bilbiie et al. (2006) and others. Although all thesepapers made important contributions, they all present a collection ofspecial cases. Our approach is more general in modelling preferences,imperfect competition (with and without free entry) and sectorialasymmetries. We believe that such a unified framework is key tounderstanding how monopoly distortions interact with more specificmodelling assumptions.

Second, this paper is related to the literature studying the welfareeffects of trade in models with imperfect competition, including theworks of Brander and Krugman (1983), Helpman and Krugman

(1985) and more recently Eckel (2008). The observation that, in thepresence of distortions, trade might have adverse welfare effects is anapplication of the second-best theory and goes back to Bhagwati(1971) and Johnson (1965).1 Yet, what we findmore interesting is themore specific insight, so far neglected, that trade can affect welfare bychanging the cross-sectoral dispersion of market power.

Third, this paper relates to a recent literature on the macroeco-nomic effects of misallocations. Noteworthy contributions by Banerjeeand Duflo (2005), Restuccia and Rogerson (2008) Hsieh and Klenow(2009), Song et al. (forthcoming) and Jones (2009) provide strikingevidence that wedges distorting the allocation of resources betweenfirms and industries within a country are quantitatively very impor-tant in explaining low aggregate productivity, particularly in lessdeveloped economies. Yet, they leave to future research the task ofidentifying the origin of suchwedges. Our paper contributes to this lineof investigation by studying how asymmetries in market power, thatappear to be especially large in poor countries, may be one source ofmisallocations.2

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 documents a numberof little known stylized facts that motivate our analysis. Section 3builds a general theoretical framework that encompasses the mostpopular models of imperfect competition. Section 4 studies thewelfare effects of markup dispersion and trade when entry isrestricted. Section 5 extends the analysis to the case of free entry.Section 6 concludes.

2. Motivating evidence

In this section, we document a number of little known stylizedfacts that motivate our theoretical investigations: (1) markups varywidely across sectors and their dispersion has increased overtime;(2) asymmetric exposure to trade seems to be a likely explanation forthe rise in markup heterogeneity; (3) markup asymmetries aresystematically related to the level of economic development, with lessasymmetries in wealthier countries.

Following a vast empirical literature (see, e.g., Roberts and Tybout,1996; Tybout, 2003; Aghion et al., 2005), we use price-cost margins(PCMs) as a proxy for market power.3 To compute them, we drawproduction data from the OECD STAN database,4 the CEPII ‘Trade,Production and Bilateral Protection’ database5 and the NBER Produc-tivity database by Bartelsman and Gray. The latter is the mostcomprehensive and highest quality database on industry-level inputsand outputs, covering roughly 450 US manufacturing (4-digit SIC)industries for the period 1958–1996. Price-cost margins are computedas the value of shipments (adjusted for inventory change) less the costof labor, capital, materials and energy, divided by the value of

Fig. 1. Trade openness across US industries.

3P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

shipments.6 Capital expenditures are computed as (rt+δ)Kit−1,where Kit−1 is the capital stock, rt is the real interest rate and δ isthe depreciation rate.7 As a proxy for trade exposure at the industrylevel, we use the openness ratio, defined as the value imports plusexports, taken from the NBER Trade database by Feenstra, divided bythe value of shipments.

2.1. Markup heterogeneity across sectors and overtime

We start by showing asymmetries in markups across broadsectorial aggregates. Using economy-wide data for the US in 2003(from the OECD dataset), we find that the average PCM equals 33% inthe business sector services (mostly nontraded industries), 28% inagriculture (a heavily protected industry) and 13% in manufacturing.As for services, the average PCM equals 24% in the transport andstorage industry, 28% in post and telecommunication, 38% in financeand insurance, 48% in electricity, and reaches a peak of 66% in realestate activities. Interestingly, in the renting of machinery andequipment industry, selling nontraded services, the average PCMequals 41.5%, whereas in the machinery and equipment industry,producing traded manufacturing goods, the average PCM is 9.5%.These huge asymmetries in price-cost margins between traded andnontraded industries immediately suggest that markups may crucial-ly depend on the degree of tradeabililty of an industry's output, andhence that asymmetric exposure to international competition may bean important determinant of markup heterogeneity across industries.

Perhaps surprisingly, exposure to international competition variesdramatically also among manufacturing industries. Fig. 1 reports thetime evolution of the openness ratio for selected 2-digit SIC industrieswithin US manufacturing. Note that, at one extreme, the leatherindustry has increased its trade share from 4% in the late 50s to 230% inthe mid 90s. Other industries, such as miscellaneous products orapparel, show a similar upward trend in the trade share. At the otherextreme, however, there are industries, such as printing, fabricated

6 Due to data availability, we do not net out capital expenditures and inventorychange when using the OECD and CEPII datasets.

7 The US real interest rate, drawn from the World Bank-World DevelopmentIndicators, has a mean value of 3.75% (with a standard deviation of 2.5%) over theperiod of analysis. As for the depreciation rate, the values for δ used in the empiricalstudies generally vary from 5% for buildings to 10% for machinery. We choose a valueof 7%, implying that capital expenditures equal, on average, roughly 10% of the capitalstock.

metal products or food, whose openness ratio has increased by only afew percentage points over the past 40 years. More generally, whenconsidering the entire distribution of the trade share across 4-digitmanufacturing industries, we find that the openness ratio increased byonly 6 percentage points in the first quintile of the distribution (from1.2% in 1958 to 7.2% in 1994), and bymore than 47 percentage points inthe fourth quintile of the distribution (from 10.2% to 57.7%). Thesefigures suggest that, by affecting some industries more than others,trade opening may have increased asymmetries in market power.

Figs. 2 and 3 provide suggestive evidence consistent with thisconjecture. The former reports the evolution of the standard deviationof PCMs across 450 USmanufacturing industries (broken line) and theaverage trade openness of the same industries (solid line) over theperiods 1959–96 and 1958–94, respectively. It is immediate to seethat, starting in themid 70s, the dispersion of PCMs shows a relentlessincrease. Moreover, the standard deviation of PCMs and the averageopenness chase each other closely. The simple correlation betweenthe two series equals 0.90 (0.40 after removing a linear trend). InFig. 3, we replace the first moment of the openness ratio with itssecond moment, again across 4-digit industries. Note that thestandard deviation of trade openness closely follows the standarddeviation of PCMs; the simple correlation between the two series isagain very high, as it equals 0.88 (0.45 for the detrended series). Thus,a first look at the data suggests that markup heterogeneity hasincreased overtime and that growing asymmetries in trade exposuremay be partly responsible for it.

2.2. Trade and markup heterogeneity

We now look for more systematic evidence on the link betweentrade openness and the dispersion of market power. To this purpose,we exploit information contained in the cross-sectional and temporalvariation in the NBER datasets 8 to construct the following time-varying, industry-level proxies for the dispersion of markups andtrade openness: for each 3-digit SIC industry, we compute thestandard deviation of PCMs and the standard deviation of the

8 We focus on US manufacturing because of the high level of disaggregation ofindustry data on sales and costs provided by the NBER dataset. This should provide alower bound for the effects we aim to illustrate, as international trade may raise thedispersion of markups also by increasing asymmetries between manufacturing andservice industries.

Fig. 2. Openness and cross-industry markup heterogeneity.

Fig. 3. Asymmetries in trade exposure and markup heterogeneity.

9 Our measure of TFP is TFP5, from the Bartelsman and Gray's database. Skill-intensity is proxied by the ratio of non-production to production workers, and capital-intensity by plant and equipment per unit of output.

4 P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

openness ratio among the 4-digit industries belonging to it. Next, werun Fixed-Effects regressions of the former on the latter to testwhether markup heterogeneity increases systematically in those 3-digit industries where trade exposure becomes more asymmetric. Themain results are reported in Table 1. In column 1, we run a univariateregression of the standard deviation of PCMs on the standarddeviation of the openness ratio and find that the two variables arestrongly positively correlated, with a t-statistic around 8. In column 2,we add a full set of time dummies to control for spurious correlationdue to time effects, e.g., the deregulation of the US economy initiatedby the Carter Administration in the mid '70s. The coefficient of thestandard deviation of openness is somewhat reduced but is still veryprecisely estimated, with a t-statistic of 5.

The cross-industry dispersion of price-cost margins may also beaffected by technological characteristics. Although Fixed-Effectsestimates implicitly account for time-invariant technological hetero-geneity, our results may still be driven by asymmetric technicalchange. Hence, to control for variation in industry technology, in

column 3 we add the standard deviation (again within 3-digit SICindustries) of total factor productivity (TFP), skill-intensity (H/L) andcapital-intensity (K/Y).9 While these controls are generally significant,they leave the sign and significance of our coefficient of interestunaffected. In column 4, we run a most severe test by adding a full setof sector-specific linear trends. Notwithstanding the loss of identify-ing variance, the results are unchanged.

In column 5, we add the average value of all RHS variables to checkwhether the correlation between the second moments of PCMs andopenness is driven by variation in the first moment of our covariates.It is not. Interestingly, the coefficient of average openness is small andinsignificant, which suggests that the strong positive correlationbetween average openness and the standard deviation of PCMsillustrated in Fig. 2 was mediated by the induced increase in the

Table 1Fixed-effects regressions for the standard deviation of PCMs. Dependent variable: standard deviation of PCMs within 3-digit SIC industries.

1 2 3 4 5 6 7

St. dev. openness 0.016*** 0.010*** 0.010*** 0.012*** 0.012*** 0.012** 0.011***[0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.003] [0.005] [0.003]

St. dev. TFP 0.041*** 0.063*** 0.072*** 0.072*** 0.072***[0.008] [0.009] [0.010] [0.009] [0.010]

St. dev. H/L 0.008 0.031*** 0.032*** 0.032*** 0.035***[0.007] [0.008] [0.010] [0.010] [0.010]

St. dev. K/Y 0.001*** −0.000* −0.000** −0.000** −0.000***[0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000] [0.000]

Average openness 0.000 −0.002[0.011] [0.011]

Average TFP −0.033*** −0.033*** −0.005[0.010] [0.010] [0.011]

Average H/L −0.000 −0.000 −0.006[0.013] [0.013] [0.013]

Average K/Y 0.000** 0.000** 0.000[0.000] [0.000] [0.000]

Average PCM −0.136***[0.024]

Time dummies YES YES YES YES YES YESIndustry-specific trends YES YES YES YESObservations 3456 3456 3456 3456 3456 3456 3456# 3-digit SIC industries 96 96 96 96 96 96 96R-squared (within) 0.03 0.11 0.14 0.39 0.39 0.39 0.41

Notes: Fixed-Effects (within) estimates with robust standard errors in parentheses. ***,**,* = significant at the 1, 5 and 10-percent levels, respectively. The mean and standarddeviation of all variables is computed within 3-digit SIC industries. In column 6, estimation is by Instrumental Variables, with the second moment of openness instrumented with itsfirst moment. Data sources: NBER Productivity Database (by Bartelsman and Gray) and NBER Trade Database (by Feenstra).

5P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

standard deviation of openness. In column 6, we therefore instrumentthe standard deviation of the openness ratio with its mean value tosee how the rise in the second moment of openness attributable to arise in its first moment affects the dispersion of markups. Estimation isby Two-Stage Least Squares. In the first stage regression for thestandard deviation of openness, not reported to save space, averageopenness is found to be a strong instrument for its standard deviation,with a coefficient of 1.65 and a t-statistic of 11.5. In the second stageregression, the coefficient of the standard deviation of openness isinstead the same as in the OLS regression, with a slightly largerstandard error. These results are consistent with the idea thatglobalization increases asymmetries in trade exposure, which inturn increase markup heterogeneity across industries.

Finally, in column 7 we also control for the average PCM. Althoughthis variable is obviously endogenous, including it ensures that the

Fig. 4. Economic development and cros

secondmoment of the distribution of PCMs is not mechanically drivenby variation in the first moment. The size and significance of thecoefficient of interest are unaffected. Moreover, the coefficient of theaverage PCM is negative and significant, consistent with the idea thatprocompetitive forces may have induced a simultaneous fall inaveragemarkups and an increase in their dispersion across industries.

2.3. Economic development and markup heterogeneity

Finally, we show how the dispersion of markups is correlated withthe level of economic development. To this purpose, we havecomputed the standard deviation of PCMs across three-digit ISICmanufacturing industries for a sample of 49 countries in the year 2001(from the CEPII dataset). In Fig. 4, we plot the log standard deviation ofPCMs against the log of real per capita GDP. Note that higher-income

s-industry markup heterogeneity.

Fig. 5. Economic development and markup asymmetries between manufacturing and services.

11

6 P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

countries are characterized by a significantly lower dispersion ofPCMs. This stylized fact is even stronger when considering asymme-tries in the PCMs between manufacturing and services. In Fig. 5, weplot the log difference between the average PCM in services andmanufacturing for a sample of 22 OECD countries in the year 2002.Note, again, that more developed countries are characterized bymuchlower asymmetries in the PCMs.We thus conclude that misallocationsdue to asymmetries in market power seem potentially relevant forunderstanding economic performance.

3. General model of imperfect competition

A preliminary step for a comprehensive analysis of the distortionscaused by an entire markup distribution is to build a tractable multi-sector model of imperfect competition that is general enough. This isthe goal of the present section. We start by presenting a convenientrepresentation of preferences, technology and market structure thatencompasses as special cases a large class of models used in theliterature. Next, we will use this model as a workhorse to study threeissues: (1) themisallocation arising in amarket equilibrium, (2) whenand how regulations affecting markups can replicate the first bestequilibrium and, finally, (3) the welfare effects of asymmetricexposure to international trade. In modeling trade, we will focus ona symmetric-country case that will allow us to discuss the procom-petitive effect of liberalization. In the interest of clarity, however, webegin our investigation with the closed economy.

3.1. Preferences and technology

We focus on economies that admit a representative agent whoseutility function can be used for normative purposes. We assume thatthere is a unit measure of agents (implying that averages coincide withaggregates), each supplying oneunit of labor inelastically.10 Preferencesare given by the following CES utility function:

W = ∫1

0Cαi di

h i1=α; α∈ −∞;1ð �; ð1Þ

10 We take labor supply as inelastic for simplicity. The effects of competition andtrade when labor supply is elastic are extensively discussed in Bilbiie et al. (2006)Corsetti et al. (2007). In these models, imperfect competition also distorts the trade-offbetween work and leisure.

where Ci is the sub-utility derived from consumption of possiblydifferentiated varieties produced in industry i∈ [0,1], andα governs theelasticity of substitution between industries, σ=1/(1−α). Maximiza-tion of (1) subject to a budget constraint yields relative demand:

PiPj

=Cj

Ci

� �1−α

; ð2Þ

where Pi and Pjdenote the cost of oneunit of consumptionbasketsCi andCj, respectively.

To preserve tractability, we assume that varieties within a givenindustry are symmetric, so that in equilibrium eachwill be consumed inthe same amount. This assumption is in linewith our focus on between-industry rather than within-industry heterogeneity and is not essen-tial.11 It is particularly useful in that it allows us to use a simple andgeneral reduced-form representation for the sub-utility derived fromconsumption in a given industry. Specifically, Ci is given by:

Ci = Nið Þνi + 1ci; ð3Þ

where ci is consumption of the typical variety in industry i andNi is thenumber of available varieties, equal to the number of firms in industryi. The parameter νi in Eq. (3) captures the preference for variety and isallowed to vary across industries. From Eq. (3), a greater variety Ni isassociated with higher utility whenever νiN0.

Given the price of a single variety pi, the industry price index Pi , equalto theminimumcost of one unit of Ci, can be found setting expenditure inindustry i equal to the value of demand, PiCi=Nipici. Substituting (3)yields:

Pi = N−νii pi: ð4Þ

Each variety is produced by a single firm. Firms are owned by thetotality of consumers so that any positive profits or losses are rebated, butthe exact form of redistribution is irrelevant in our representative-agent

Extending our results to models featuring firm heterogeneity, such as Melitz(2003) and Melitz and Ottaviano (2008), would be an interesting exercise that weleave for future work. Unfortunately, combining between and within sectorheterogeneity complicates substantially the analysis, making it convenient to studythem separately.

13 An important assumption behind this result is that labor supply is inelastic. Thereason is that markups lower wages below the marginal product of labor (MPL) andthus distort the work-leisure decision. For example, in the case Φi=1,∀ i∈ [0,1] we

can show that:

7P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

economy. Production requires a fixed cost fi and a marginal cost 1/φi inunits of labor. Firms charge a price equal to a markup over the marginalcost:

pi =μ i ·ð Þwφi

; ð5Þ

wherew is the wage rate and μi(d )≥1 denotes themarkup function. Ingeneral, the equilibrium markup is a function of the price elasticity ofdemand perceived by each firm, �i:

μ i = 1− 1�i

� �−1with �i≡−

∂lnyi∂lnpi

;

where yi is production by a given firm. The perceived elasticity may inturn depend on the number of firms in an industry and/or theelasticity of substitution in consumption across goods. We impose therestriction �iNσ, implying that goods are more substitutable withinindustries than between industries.

The markup may also depend on regulations that affect marketcontestability. For example, there might be a competitive fringe offirms that can copy and produce any variety without incurring thefixed cost, but at a higher marginal cost. The higher marginal cost maycapture the lower expertise of outsiders, but can also depend on entryregulations that make production more costly for external competi-tors. In this case, firms may be forced to charge a limit price below Eq.(5) and equal to the marginal cost of the external competitors, inorder to keep them out of the market.

In what follows, we do not impose any restriction on the markupfunction so as topreserve generality.Moreover, to ease notation,wewilldenote the markup simply as μi, with the understanding that itrepresents a function rather than a parameter. Rather than providinga list of examples of markup functions, we just recall some of the mostcommon reasons for markup heterogeneity. In models with differen-tiated products (νiN0), these include: (1) cross-industry differences inthe within-industry elasticity of substitution among varieties, as inmonopolistic competition a lá Dixit–Stiglitz with a continuum of firms;(2) cross-industry differences in the (low) integer number offirmsand acommon elasticity of substitution, as in Dixit–Stiglitz with a discretenumber of firms or in Atkeson and Burstein (2008).With homogeneousproducts (νi=0), variable markups may instead result from: (3)Cournot or Bertrand competition, as in Epifani and Gancia (2006) andBernard et al. (2003). In cases (2) and (3), more firms leads to highercompetitive pressure and lower markups, i.e., ∂μi/∂Nib0. In sum, ourframework can encompass the most common models of imperfectcompetition, describing environments where firms produce homoge-neous or differentiated goods and compete in quantity or price.12

4. Restricted entry

We consider now the case in which the number of firms perindustry Ni is exogenously given, so that entry and exit are notallowed. Although free entry might be a reasonable assumption inmany industries, entry restrictions are fairly common too, particularlyin less developed countries. For instance, the number of active firmsmay depend on the presence of government regulations, such aslicences. Restricted entry may also provide an adequate description ofa short-run equilibrium in which entry has not taken place yet andfixed costs are sunk, making exit never optimal. Be as it may, this case

12 See the working paper version, Epifani and Gancia (2009), for specific examples.Other models of imperfect competition that can be represented within our approachinclude monopolistic competition with translog demand in Feenstra (2003), thegeneralization of Dixit–Stiglitz preferences by Benassy (1998), Melitz and Ottaviano(2008), and models of price competition with differentiated products that use the“ideal variety” approach, such as Salop (1979), Lancaster (1979) and Epifani andGancia (2006).

is useful to understand the effects of trade and monopoly power in asituation when firms make pure profits.

Note that when the number of firms is not a choice variable, the fixedcost in production has no bearings on the efficiency property of theequilibrium. Therefore, without loss of generality, we simplify theexposition by setting fi=0. Recall also that profits are rebated toconsumers.

4.1. Market equilibrium

We start by characterizing the laissez-faire equilibrium. Denote Li asthe number ofworkers employed in industry i. By virtue of symmetry andthe absenceoffixedcosts (fi=0), productionbyagivenfirm isyi=φiLi/Ni.Then, imposing market clearing (yi=ci) into Eq. (3) we obtain:

Ci = φiLi Nið Þνi : ð6Þ

The allocation of labor across sectors can be found using Eqs. (2),(4), (5) and (6):

LiLj

=μ j

μ i

� � 11−α Φi

Φj

! α1−α

; ð7Þ

where Φi≡φiNiνi is a measure of aggregate “productivity” at the

industry level, taking into account that consumption delivers a higherutility in industries where there are many firms and a strongpreference for variety. As expected, whenever goods are gross-substitutes (αN0), more productive industries hire more workers.Further, for any finite value of α, more competitive industries (low μi)also employ more workers. Integrating Eq. (7) and imposing labormarket clearing yields:

Li =μ ið Þ 1

α−1 Φið Þ α1−α

∫1

0μ j

� � 1α−1 Φj

� � α1−αdj

: ð8Þ

Finally, substituting Eq. (8) into Eq. (6) and then into preferencesEq. (1), we obtain the utility of the representative agent:

W = ∫1

0LiΦið Þαdi

� �1α

=∫1

0μ−1i Φi

� � α1−αdi

� �1α

∫1

0μ−1i Φα

i

� 11−αdi

: ð9Þ

This is our welfare measure. Inspection of Eq. (9) immediatelyreveals that utility is homogeneous of degree zero in markups:multiplying all μ i by any positive constant leaves welfare unaffected.In other words, as originally argued by Lerner (1934), in this economywelfare is independent of the average markup.13

4.2. Social planner solution

To illustrate the distortions that may arise in the marketequilibrium, we now solve for the allocation that maximizes theutility of the representative agent, subject to the resource constraint

w = ∫1

0μ ið Þ−α = 1−αð Þdi

� � 1−αð Þ=αbMPL = 1;

where the latter equality follows from the fact that, with Φi=1, labor productivity isequal to one. The strength of this distortion depends upon the elasticity of laborsupply. However, as already noted by Lerner, even in this setting a markup on leisure(or leisure goods) would restore his principle that only dispersion matters.

8 P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

of the economy. This is equivalent to solving the following planningproblem:

maxLi

W = ∫1

0LiΦið Þαdi

� �1α

; ð10Þ

subject to the resource constraint:

∫1

0Lidi = 1:

Taking the ratio of any two first order conditions yields the optimallabor allocation:

LiLj

=Φi

Φj

! α1−α

: ð11Þ

Comparing Eq. (11) with Eq. (7) we see immediately that, for anyfinite α, the decentralized equilibrium is Pareto-efficient if and only ifμi=μj, ∀ i, j∈ [0,1].

We summarize these results in the following proposition:

Proposition 1. When the number of firms is exogenous, welfare ishomogeneous of degree zero in markups. A necessary and sufficientcondition to replicate the first best allocation is that markups be identicalacross all industries.

4.3. The cost of heterogeneity: intersectoral misallocations

If a uniformmarkup is sufficient to replicate the optimal allocation,what is then the cost of asymmetric market power? From Eq. (8), itcan be shown that the market equilibrium entails underproduction inindustries where the markup is above the following productivity-weighted average:

μ�≡∫1

0μ j

� � 1α−1 Φj

� � α1−αdj

∫1

0Φj

� � α1−αdj

264

375α−1

;

and overproduction in industries where μ ibμ � .14 Thus, the problem isone of an intersectoral misallocation whereby less competitiveindustries attract a sub-optimally low number of workers. Thishappens because high markups compress the wage bill.

The welfare cost of the misallocation due to markup heterogeneitydepends in an interesting way on the curvature of the utility functionEq. (1). To see this, suppose that the μi can be approximated by a log-normal distribution and, to isolate the effect of markup heterogeneity,consider the case Φi=Φ. Then, Eq. (9) can be rewritten as15:

lnW = lnΦ−var lnμð Þ2 1−αð Þ ; ð12Þ

showing that markup dispersion is more costly when goods are highlysubstitutable (high α).

The effect of substitutability across goods on the monopolydistortion induced by asymmetric markups is not an obvious one.On the one hand, a high substitutability means that the cost ofoverproduction in some industries is small: indeed, this cost goes tozero as goods become perfect substitutes. On the other hand, Eq. (7)

14 Interestingly, this means that monopoly power is associated to overproduction inindustries where 1bμibμ � . Thus, the conventional wisdom that a monopolist alwaysproduces less than the socially optimal quantity turns out to be wrong.15 To derive Eq. (12), recall that, if x~log Normal, then:

lnE xn�

= nE lnxð Þ + n2var lnxð Þ2

:

shows that, for a given asymmetry in markups μi/μj, a highsubstitutability magnifies the misallocation of labor towards themore competitive industries. It turns out that the latter effectdominates, so that perhaps counter-intuitively a flatter curvature ofthe utility function leads to a higher cost of markup dispersion. On thecontrary, Eqs. (7), (11), and (12) show that, as we approach theLeontief case (α→−∞), the intersectoral misallocation disappears.

It is also interesting to observe that the distortion induced bymarkups differs fundamentally from distortions that manifestthemselves as higher production costs. To see this, consider the caseof no markup dispersion. When μi=μ, the welfare function becomes:

W = ∫1

0Φið Þ α

1−αdi� �1−α

α

: ð13Þ

Assuming Φi to be log-normal and using the properties of log-normal distributions (twice), welfare becomes:

lnW = lnE Φð Þ + 2α−11−α

� �var lnΦð Þ

2: ð14Þ

Intuitively, welfare is an increasing function of average produc-tivity, lnE(Φ). Perhaps more surprisingly, Eq. (14) shows that, despitethe symmetry in preferences, the variance of productivityΦi becomeswelfare increasing whenαN0.5, i.e., when the elasticity of substitutionbetween goods is greater than two. This happens because, when α issufficiently high, agents can easily substitute consumption fromunproductive industries to high Φi ones.16

In the general case, welfare is a complex function of the entiredistributions of both μi and Φi. Although it is difficult to make moreprecise statements regarding the impact of a particular change inthose distribution and their correlation, from Eq. (9) we can derive asimple formula that can be used to measure welfare given data on μiand Φi:

Wα =E μ

α� �E Φ� �

+ cov μα;Φ

� �E μ

� �E Φ� �

+ cov μ;Φ

� �h iα ; ð15Þ

where Φ = Φið Þα= 1−αð Þ and μ= μ ið Þ1= α−1ð Þ.

We summarize the main findings of this section in the followingproposition:

Proposition 2. Markup heterogeneity introduces an intersectoralmisallocation, whereby industries with below-average markups over-produce, and industries with above-average markups underproduce. Theextent and the cost of this misallocation are proportional to the elasticityof substitution between industries.

4.4. Procompetitive losses from trade

We now open the model to international trade to show that, whenentry is restricted, trade integration tightening competition in someindustries may amplify monopoly distortions. Moreover, the effect canbe so strong that an equilibrium with trade may be Pareto-inferior toautarky for all the countries. Although rather extreme, this example isillustrative of the neglected principle that trade can affect welfare bychanging the cross-sectoral dispersion of market power. A notewor-thy corollary is that the characteristics of industries affected by tradeliberalization and particularly their competitiveness relative to therest of the economy are important factors to correctly foresee theeffects of globalization. In turn, the result that welfare may fall withtrade liberalization is an application of second-best theory. As pointed

16 Interestingly, this also suggests that price dispersion may be beneficial when itoriginates from technology and the elasticity of substitution is high enough. See alsoJones (2009) on the role of complementarity in amplifying industry-level distortions.

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.00.85

0.90

0.95

1.00

1.05

1.10

tau

W

Fig. 6. Trade and welfare: solid line ν=0, broken line νN0.

9P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

out by Bhagwati (1971) and Johnson (1965), if trade induces acontraction of industries that were already underproducing comparedto the optimum, it exacerbates an existing distortion and may thuslower welfare.

To isolate the point we want to make, we adopt the followingsimplifying assumptions. First, we consider a world populated byMN1 identical countries so as to abstract from specialization effects.Second, to remove any unnecessary heterogeneity, we normalize thenumber of firms in each country to one (Ni=1), and setφi=1 for all i .Third, we assume that in some industries goods can be freely traded,while in others trade costs are prohibitive. Accordingly, the unitmeasure of sectors is partitioned into two subsets of traded andnontraded industries, ordered such that industries with an indexi≤τ∈ [0,1] are subject to negligible trade costs while the others, withan index iNτ, face prohibitive trade costs. This simple description ofimperfect trade integration accords well with the evidence that tradevolumes are high in some industries and very low in others. Weconsider two complementary aspects of international integration:(1) an increase in the range τ of traded industries and (2) an increasein the number M of trading partners. Finally, we assume the markupto be a negative function of the number of competing firms in a givenindustry. This immediately delivers the procompetitive effect of trade,as the number of firms is one in nontraded industries andMN1 in theothers.17

For convenience, we denote the relative markup in nontradedindustries as x≡μ(1)/μ(M). Under our assumptions, x is greater thanone and increasing inM. After some straightforward substitutions intoEq. (9), we obtain:

W =1−τ + τ xMν� α = 1−αð Þh i1=α1−τ + τ xMναð Þ1= 1−αð Þ : ð16Þ

This expression shows that welfare is a function of the measure oftraded industries, τ, the number of trading countries, M, and themarkup asymmetry x between open and closed industries.

Fig. 6 plots welfare as a function of τ for the case ν=0 (solid line) andthe caseνN0 (broken line). In thefirst case (corresponding for example toCournot competition), the economy attains the same level of welfare inautarky (τ=0) and when trade is free in all industries (τ=1). For anyintermediate case, an equilibriumwith trade is Pareto inferior to autarky.The intuition for this result should be by now clear. When ν=0, there isno gain from consuming foreign varieties and the only effect of trade is tolower markups in industries exposed to foreign competition. In bothextremecases,τ=0andτ=1,markupsareuniformacross industries andthere is no distortion. As τ moves from zero to one, trade breaks thissymmetry: it increasesmarkupdispersion as long as open industries are aminority and lowers it afterwards. Moreover, when ν=0 and τ∈(0,1) itis easy to see that welfare declines with an increase in the number oftrading countries, M. The reason, again, is that a larger number ofinternational competitors increases the markup asymmetry betweentraded and nontraded industries.

When νN0, consumers derive a higher utility from the possibilityto buy foreign varieties. In our model, we can think of this varietyeffect as capturing any source of gains from trade that is independentof the procompetitive effect. As the figure shows, in this case anequilibrium with some trade might still be Pareto inferior to autarkywhen τ is low, for the gains from small volumes of trade might be toolow to dominate the price distortion (this happening for low enoughν). However, when τ is large enough, the gains from variety willeventually dominate the (falling) cost of misallocations. With gains

17 The procompetitive effect of trade, whereby exposure to international competitionreduces markups features prominently in Krugman (1979) and Melitz and Ottaviano(2008), among others. See Chen et al. (2009) for recent evidence.

from trade of any sort, the equilibrium with full integration (τ=1)must necessarily dominate autarky.

Even when a high νN0 assures positive gains from trade, whenliberalization increases markup dispersion, it generates or exacerbatethe intersectoral misallocation discussed above. What can then bedone to counteract this negative effect of market integration? Wehave seen that the first-best solution is attained with a uniformmarkup. Thus, if trade lowers markups in some sectors, competitionpolicy might be used to match the change in market power innontraded sectors too. If competition policy cannot be used, the firstbest solution can still be achieved by giving an appropriate subsidy toindustries producing nontraded goods.

Note also that the likelihood that trade is harmful increases with xand that positive gains from trade will surely materialize if aneconomy is perfectly competitive (x=1). In other words, thepotential for welfare losses is higher when domestic markets arenot competitive enough and trade brings large asymmetries betweenindustries selling in worldmarkets and the rest of the economy. Theseconsiderations may be particularly relevant for less developedcountries, suggesting that in some cases promoting competition maybe a prerequisite to ensuring positive gains from trade.

In sum:

Proposition 3. Withanexogenousnumber offirms, procompetitivewelfarelosses from trade are possible when trade increases markup dispersion.

4.5. Simple quantitative exercise

The example discussed in the previous section was admittedlyprovocative. We now show, however, that a simple quantitative exercisesuggests the welfare cost of markup heterogeneity to be potentially largewhen entry is restricted. To this end, we use ourmodel, togetherwith theevidence and the data discussed in Section 2, to compute the cost ofmarkup dispersion across USmanufacturing industries, relative to a first-best allocation in which markups are instead uniform. Using Eq. (9), anddenoting by WFB welfare in the first-best allocation, we obtain:

WWFB =

∫1

0μ−1i Φi

� � α1−αdi

� �1=α∫1

0μ−1i Φα

i

� 11−αdi⋅ ∫

1

α1−αi di

� �1−αα: ð17Þ

Computing Eq. (17) requires an empirical measure of theproductivity index Φi=φiNi

vi for each industry i. To build suchmeasure, we proceed as follows. Eqs. (4) and (5) imply:

Φi =μ iwPi

: ð18Þ

Table 2Welfare cost of markup dispersion.

Constant Φi Time-varying Φi

W/WFB W/WFB ΔW/WFB W/WFB W/WFB ΔW/WFB

(1959) (1994) (94–59) (1959) (1994) (94–59)

σ=2 (α=0.5) 0.983 0.97 −1.3% 0.986 0.961 −2.5%σ=5 (α=0.8) 0.947 0.913 −3.6% 0.957 0.863 −9.8%σ=10 (α=0.9) 0.854 0.785 −8.1% 0.88 0.666 −24.3%

10 P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

From utility maximization, we obtain:

Ci =PiP

� � 1α−1

W = P1

α−1i E; ð19Þ

where E is total expenditure, P = ∫1

0P

αα−1i di

� �α−1α

is the ideal price index

associated to Eq. (1), and the latter equality follows from choosing P asthe numeraire. Eq. (19) allows us to express the unobserved industryprice index Pi as a function of the observed expenditure share on anindustry's products, θi≡PiCi/E:

Pi = θα−1α

i : ð20Þ

Finally, using Eq. (20) into Eq. (18) gives:

Φi = wμ iθ1−αα

i : ð21Þ

Note thatW/WFB is homogeneous of degree zero with respect to alltheΦi. Hence,without any loss of generality, we can disregard the factorw, which is constant across sectors, and calibrate Φi using data onmarkups, μ i, and expenditure shares, θi, for the US 4-digit SIC industriesover the period 1959–1994. In particular, to compute μi, we use thedefinition of price-cost margins (PCMs) in Section 2 and set μi=(1−PCMi)−1.18 θi, is instead computed as the value of an industry'sshipments plus net imports, divided by the total expenditure onmanufacturing goods, using again the NBER datasets. Calibrated in thisway, Φi accounts for factors, such as parameters of technology but alsopreferences, that affect expenditure shares other than relativemarkups.

Computing Φi and W/WFB also requires choosing a value for theelasticity of substitution in consumption amongmanufacturing goods,σ=1/(1−α). Although available estimates of σ vary widely acrossstudies, most of them are in the range [2,10] and a value around σ=5is most frequently used in quantitative exercises. We therefore setσ=2, 5 and 10 (implying α=0.5, 0.8 and 0.9) as benchmark cases.We then perform two distinct exercises.

First, we assume theΦi to be constant overtime and compute theircross-section from Eq. (21) by taking, for each 4-digit industry, themean value of μi and θi overtime. Then, we compute W/WFB over theperiod 1959–94 using Eq. (17). This exercise allows us to isolate thewelfare loss induced by the change in the distribution of markups,holding constant preferences and other technological factors. Theresults are reported in the left panel of Table 2. For an intermediatevalue of the elasticity of substitution (σ=5), utility falls by 3.6% in theperiod of analysis. For σ=2, the welfare cost of the observed rise inmarkup dispersion is lower (1.3%), whereas it is much larger (8.1%)for σ=10.

Second, we allow the Φi to be time-varying and compute themyear by year. We use these time-varying coefficients again into Eq.(17) to obtain the value ofW/WFB. This exercise provides informationon the overall welfare cost of changes in the markup distributiontaking into account that other parameters (such as tastes andtechnology) have also affected expenditure shares simultaneously.The results are in the right panel of Table 2, showing that in this casethe welfare cost of markup dispersion is even larger. This indicatesthat the evolution of the exogenous parameters contained in the Φi

18 Price-cost margins are defined as the value of shipments minus costs divided bythe value of shipments. Thus:

PCMi = piyi−wφi

yi

� �= piyi = 1−1 = μi;

where piyi is the value of a firm's shipments in industry i, and (w/φi)yi is its variablecost. Although in our simple model labor is the only variable cost, we also net outmaterials and capital expenditures in our empirical definition of price-cost margins.This avoids spurious variation in the PCMs due to variation in materials intensity andcapital intensity across industries.

has contributed to amplify monopoly distortions. In particular, overthe period of analysis, relative utility falls by 2.5% for σ=2, by 9.8% forσ=5, and by as much as 24.3% for σ=10.

In sum, these numerical exercises suggest that, abstracting fromany effect that changes in the average PCMs may have had, theobserved increase in markup heterogeneity can entail substantialwelfare costs. Howmuch of these costs can then be attributed to tradeintegration? Given that the impact of trade on markup dispersion canbe ambiguous, the answer to this question is ultimately an empiricalone. Although identifying and quantifying how trade has affected themarkup distribution goes beyond the scope of the current paper, theevidence discussed in Section 2 does suggest that trade may be amajor determinant of observed asymmetries in market power.19 Wetherefore conclude that markup heterogeneity matters for misalloca-tions and that procompetitive losses from trade may be more than atheoretical curiosum in this class of models.

5. Free entry

So far, firms are making positive profits and barriers to entryprevent potential competitors from challenging incumbent firms andsharing the rents. Without those barriers, entry will take place untilpure profits are driven to zero. We now allow for this possibility withthe aim of extending our results to a widely-used class of modelswhere entry is free. This exercise will lead to remarkably differentconclusions, which qualify some of Lerner's original statements.

We start by presenting the market equilibrium and show that,contrary to the previous case, welfare is a function of the averagemarkup too. Next, we compare it with the social planner solution anddiscuss the inefficiencies that arise in the decentralized equilibrium.Finally, we study the effect of trade between identical countries andargue that, while procompetitive losses are now unlikely, asymmetrictrade liberalization may still exacerbate misallocations, therebyproviding a rationale for policy intervention.

5.1. Market equilibrium

We now reintroduce the fixed cost of production, fi, defined inunits of labor, and let the number of firms vary so as to guarantee thateach breaks even. In this way, in equilibrium all operating profits areused to cover the fixed cost:

piyi−yiwφi

= fiwi:

Substituting pi from Eq. (5) and rearranging gives:

yi =φi fiμ i−1

: ð22Þ

19 In particular, if we rerun the regressions in Table 1 computing the standarddeviation of markups and other variables across all the 4-digit SIC industries, weobtain that the increase in trade openness (or its standard deviation) over the period1959–94 can explain the entire observed increase in markup dispersion across USmanufacturing industries. The results are available upon request.

11P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

As is well-known, the free-entry condition pins down uniquelyfirm size.

Given firm size, the number of active firmsmust be proportional tothe amount of labor employed in each industry. More precisely, thedemand for labor in industry i is:

Li = Niyiφi

+ fi

� �:

Substituting Eq. (22) we obtain:

Ni =μ i−1fiμ i

Li: ð23Þ

Finally, to solve for Li, we manipulate the demand Eq. (2 ) to yield:

CiPiCjPj

=Cj

Ci

� �−α

=LiLj;

where the latter equality follows from the fact that, with a fixed cost inunits of labor and without extra-profits, industry revenue equals thewage bill. Using Eq. (3), the market clearing condition ci=yi, Eqs. (22)and (23), we obtain:

LiLj

=φiN

νii μ j

φjNνj

j μ i

0@

1A α

1−α

: ð24Þ

Note that Eq. (24) differs from the analogous condition in themodel without free entry Eq. (7). The key reason is that, in the modelwith free entry, the entire industry revenue is used up to pay workers(both for the fixed and variable production costs), while in the othercase a fraction of revenue is captured by profits.20 Combining Eqs.(22), (23) and ( 24) we obtain an equation linking the number offirms in any two industries to relative firm size and other exogenousparameters:

N1−α−ανii

N1−α−ανj

j

=yjyi

� �1−α φi

φj

μ j

μ i: ð25Þ

This condition will turn out to be useful below.To understand the role of markups in the model with free entry,

consider for the moment the simpler Cobb–Douglas casecorresponding to α=0. Then, using Eqs. (22), (23) and (24), we canwrite welfare as:

lnW = ∫1

0ln Nνi + 1

i yαi� �

di = ∫1

0νiln

1−μ−1i

fi

!di

zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{variety

+ ∫1

0lnφiμ

−1i di:

zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{f−saving

ð26Þ

This equation shows that the level of markups has now bothpositive and negative direct effects on welfare. The first term in Eq.(26) is increasing in μi and captures the fact that a high profit marginstimulates entry, thereby raising the number of firms and welfare solong as variety has value (νiN0). The second term in Eq. (26) is insteaddecreasing in μi and captures the fact that entry implies that moreproductive resources are taken by the fixed costs. Thus, contrary to therestricted-entry case, when νiN0 markups now pose a trade-offbetween diversity and fixed costs at the industry level.

20 A second, less important, difference is that, in the model without entry we set thefixed cost to zero. Of course, the equilibrium allocation of labor would coincide in thetwo models if we had the same fixed cost and if the exogenous number of firmswithout entry happened to be equal to the equilibrium number of firms with entry.

5.2. Social planner

What are the distortions in the market equilibrium? Is markupasymmetry desirable or does it impose any welfare costs? To answerthese questions, we now compute the allocation that maximizes theutility of the representative agent. A benevolent social plannerchooses Ni and yi=ci so as to solve:

maxNi ;yi

W = ∫1

0Nνi + 1i yi

� �αdi

� �1=α;

subject to the resource constraint:

∫1

0Ni

yiφi

+ fi

� �di = 1:

The Lagrangian for the above program is:

L = ∫1

0Nνi + 1i yi

� �αdi

� �1=α−λ ∫1

0Ni

yiφi

+ fi

� �di−1

� �;

and the first order conditions for an optimum are:

∂L∂Ni

= 0→W1−α νi + 1ð Þyαi N νi + 1ð Þα−1i = λ

yiφi

+ fi

� �;

∂L∂yi

= 0→W1−αN νi + 1ð Þαi yα−1

i =λNi

φi:

Substituting the second first order condition into the first yields:

yi =φi fiνi

: ð27Þ

Taking the ratio of the second first order condition in industries iand j delivers:

N1−α−ανii

N1−α−ανj

j

=yjyi

� �1−α φi

φj: ð28Þ

Comparing the optimal firm scale Eq. (27) to the market outcomeEq. (22), we see that the two coincide when:

μ i−1 = νi; ð29Þ

that is, when the markup is equal to the preference for variety, as in theDixit–Stiglitz case.However, comparingEq. (28)withEq. (25),wealso seethat the optimal allocation of resources across industries requires μi=μ j,that is, a uniform markup. When the preference for variety is unequalacross industries (the most realistic case) these two requirements areincompatible and we thus have the following impossibility result21:

Proposition 4. When entry is free and the preference for variety isheterogeneous across industries (νi≠νj for at least two i, j∈ [0,1]), thereexists no markup distribution such that the market equilibrium replicatesthe first-best allocation.

These results show that, in general, a uniform markup acrossindustries and firms is still a necessary condition for efficiency but,contrary to Lerner's original claim, it is not sufficient anymore. Thereason is that profits now have a dual role: they affect the allocation ofresources across industries and the equilibrium number of firms perindustry. As we know from the previous section, avoiding inter-sectoral misallocations requires μi=μj. However, markups should also

21 Epifani and Gancia (2008) review some evidence suggesting that externaleconomies due to love for variety differ across industries.

12 P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

correctly signal the social value of entry and this requires higher profitmargins in industries where variety is more valuable.

Finally, recall that the intersectoral misallocation tends todisappear as preferences approach the Leontief case. This is true ingeneral and the model with free entry makes no exception. In fact,taking the limit of Eqs. (28) and (25) for α→−∞ reveals that the twoequations converge to the same condition:

yjyi

=N1+νii

N1+νj

j

;

which is of course equivalent to Ci=Cj. In this case, the marketequilibrium converges to the first-best allocation when μ i−1=νi .

5.3. Optimal competition policy, markup heterogeneity and welfare

We now ask what is the markup distribution that maximizes theutility of the representative agent. In other words, we are interested infinding the constrained efficient allocation that a planner can achieveby controlling markups and without using lump-sum transfers. Tofind it, we use Eqs. (22) and (23) to rewrite the welfare function as:

W = ∫1

0

Liμ i

� �νi +1 μ i−1fi

� �νi

φi

� �αdi

� �1=α

= ∫1

0Lið Þνi +1Φi

h iαdi

� �1=α;

ð30Þ

where now Φi≡1μ i

� �νi +1 μ i−1fi

� �νi

φi. Note that W is increasing in Φi.

Thus, maximizing Eq. (30) is equivalent to maximizingΦi industry byindustry. Then, the first order condition is:

∂Φi

∂μ i= 0→

νi

μ i−1=

νi + 1μ i

→ μ i−1 = νi; ð31Þ

which is identical to Eq. (29).22 Thus, it is optimal to let the markupreflect the social value of entry, irrespective of the intersectoralinefficiency. This means that, so long as νi≠νj, an increase in markupdispersion may be welfare improving if the resulting markupdistribution gets closer to the one implied by condition (29). It alsoimplies that computing the welfare cost of a given markupdistribution becomes much harder, as it now requires data on νi.

Finally, it is instructive to consider the welfare costs of markupheterogeneity in the special case of νi=0, that is, when entry has nosocial value per se. This case is of particular interest because it servesas a metaphor for all models where profits are dissipated inequilibrium through rent-seeking activities that are socially wasteful.When νi=0, it is of course optimal to have μi=1; yet, this may not befeasible. What is less obvious, instead, is the cost of markupdispersion. From Eq. (24) and ∫1

0 Lidi = 1, we obtain:

Li =φiμ

−1i

� � α1−α

∫1

0φjμ

−1j

� � α1−αdj

:

Substituting this into the welfare function (30) yields:

W = ∫1

0φiμ

−1i

� � α1−αdi

� �1−αα

;

which takes the same form as Eq. (13). Remarkably, this means thatmarkup heterogeneity is welfare improving when αN0.5, precisely aswe found for productivity heterogeneity. This result can be under-stood by noting that, in an equilibrium with free entry, the markup is

22 It follows immediately that there is no room for welfare-improving interventionon markups in the Dixit–Stiglitz case. Yet, this is admittedly not the most interestingcase to study procompetitive effects.

nothing but the per unit equivalent of the fixed cost fi. Thus, whenentry is free but has no social value, themarkup acts a pure cost for theeconomy and it affects welfare just as the marginal cost (1/φ) in themodel of Section 4 did.

We summarize the main findings in the following proposition:

Proposition 5. With free entry, markup symmetry is a necessary, butnot a sufficient condition for efficiency. Markup heterogeneity alwaysleads to an intersectoral misallocation, but does not necessarily lowerwelfare: it may be welfare improving when the preference for variety isheterogeneous across industries, or when variety has no value (νi=0,i∈ [0,1]) and the elasticity of substitution is high (αN0.5).

5.4. The procompetitive effect of trade, welfare and misallocations

Are procompetitive losses from trade possible when entry is free?Does asymmetric trade liberalization introduce distortions that maybe corrected by policy makers? To briefly address these questions wenow open themodel to trade, as in Section 4.4. For simplicity, we focuson the Cobb–Douglas case, i.e., α=0. We consider a world of Msymmetric countries and we denote by Ni the number of firms percountry in industry i. Consumption of a given traded variety in a givencountry becomes ci=yi/Mi, so that the industry consumption basketcan be written as:

Ci = Nið Þνi + 1 Mið Þνi yi:

Substituting this into Eq. (1) and using Eqs. (22) and (23), weobtain our welfare measure:

lnW = ∫1

0lnCidi = ∫1

0ln Ni⋅Mið Þνiφiμ

−1i

h idi: ð32Þ

As before, we model imperfect market integration by allowingsome industries to be closed to trade. In other words, we setMi=1 inthe subset of nontraded industries.

When the markup function is such that μi= f(Ni⋅Mi) with f′(⋅)b0,as in Krugman (1979), then the procompetitive effect of trade isalways welfare improving. To see this, note that if trade has to lowerthe markup in an industry, it should also increase the equilibriumnumber of firms. Both the fall in μi and the rise in Ni ⋅Mi increase W.Interestingly, this is true even when variety has no value, νi=0!Procompetitive losses from trade are still possible, but only when thefall in markups due to foreign competition is so strong as to reduce theequilibrium number of firms in an industry below the optimal level.23

While this is impossible when μi= f(Ni ⋅Mi) with f′(⋅)b0, thisoutcome is conceivable if trade liberalization affects the markup notthrough the number of firms.

In conclusion, when there is free entry, procompetitive losses fromtrade seemmuchmore unlikely. Thus, an important benefit of entry isthat it prevents some of the possibly large costs identified in Section 4.Yet, asymmetric trade liberalization that increases markup heteroge-neity exacerbates the intersectoral misallocation of resources andopens the way to Pareto improving intervention. In particular, theremight be excessive product diversity or firm output in tradedindustries that can be corrected with an appropriate subsidy tonontraded industries.

We therefore conclude with the following proposition:

Proposition 6. When entry is free andmarkups are a negative function ofthe number of firms in an industry (μi= f(Ni⋅Mi), f′(⋅)b0, i∈[0,1]), theprocompetitive effect of trade is welfare improving, even when tradeamplifiesmisallocations due tomarkup dispersion and variety has no value.

23 Eckel (2008) provides conditions for this outcome. In other models, such as Melitz(2003) and Corsetti et al. (2007), trade liberalization increases welfare even when thenumber of varieties falls.

13P. Epifani, G. Gancia / Journal of International Economics 83 (2011) 1–13

6. Conclusions

Competition is imperfect in most sectors of economic activity. Byexposing firms to foreign competition, trade is widely believed to helpalleviate the distortions stemming from monopolistic pricing. Whilethis argument is often well-grounded, it neglects that in generalequilibrium pricing distortions depend on both absolute and relativemarket power, and that a trade-induced fall in markups brings aboutmisallocations when it raises their variance. The latter event is morethan a theoretical curiosity, for market globalization affects predom-inantly industries that are already relatively more competitive. At thesame time, misallocations across firms and industries have recentlybeen identified as a strikingly important factor behind cross-countrydifferences in economic performance. Studying how such misalloca-tions may be rooted in the economy-wide markup distribution andhow this may interact with trade liberalization is therefore crucial forthe design of optimal trade and competition policies and for a betterunderstanding of the welfare effects of trade opening in the presenceof market power. This was the aim of our paper.

We now summarize what we view as the main results. When firmentry is restricted, we find that markup heterogeneity entails significantcosts and that asymmetric trade liberalizationmay reduce welfare. Withfree entry of firms, instead, markup heterogeneity is not necessarilywelfare reducing, although it generates an intersectoral misallocationthat policy makers can correct. In this case, we also find that a trade-induced increase in competition is typically welfare increasing. Yet, iftrade integration raises markup dispersion, the allocation of resourcescan be improved upon by subsidizing production in industries thatremain relatively more protected. In this sense, trade liberalization anddomestic industrial policy complement each other. More in general, ouranalysis has emphasized theneglectedprinciple that, in order to correctlyforesee the effects of trade and competition policy, the evolution of theeconomy-wide markup distribution has to be taken into account, andthat whether entry is restricted or not makes an important difference.

By focusingon special cases, the existing literature on the topic offersa partial view only. One goal of this paper was precisely to clarify themisconceptions that may arise when restricting the analysis to specialcases. A major benefit of our general framework is that it illustrates theexact role of alternative assumptions in shaping the relationshipbetween competition, misallocations and welfare. We hope that sucha unified framework may prove useful in studying other issues, such asthe effects of competition on growth, and in guiding future empiricaland quantitativework. In particular,whilewehave emphasizedmarkupheterogeneity across industries, we think that extending the analysis toheterogeneity across firms may be at least as much important. Yet,accounting for it poses a new difficulty, in that it requires disentanglingfirm-level estimates of productivity frommarkups.Weview this as a keychallenge for future research.

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Giancarlo Corsetti, Jonathan Eaton, NezihGuner, Winfried Koeniger, Omar Licandro, Enrico Sette, GuidoTabellini, Jaume Ventura, Fabrizio Zilibotti and an anonymous refereefor the helpful comments and discussion. We also thank participantsat the EEA Annual Congress (Barcelona, 2009), ITSGMeeting (Cagliari,2009), RIEF Meeting (Aix-an-Provence, 2009), ESSIM (Tarragona,2008), XXXII Symposium of Economic Analysis (Granada, 2007),Universidad Carlos III de Madrid, Banco de España, the UPF FacultyLunch, the Macro Workshop at IEW, Zurich University and the IADB-ELSNIT (Paris, 2006). All errors are our own. Gino Gancia acknowl-edges financial support from the Barcelona GSE, the Government ofCatalonia (2009SGR1157) and the ERC Grant GOPG 240989. Part of

this research was done while Gino Gancia was visiting as ResearchAssociate the Chair of Political Economy and Macroeconomics of theIEW-University of Zurich. We thank the IEW for the hospitality.

References

Aghion, P., Bloom,N., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P., 2005. Competition and innovation:an inverted u relationship. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 701–728.

Atkeson, A., Burstein, A., 2008. Pricing-to-market, trade costs, and international relativeprices. American Economic Review 98, 1998–2031.

Banerjee, A., Duflo, E., 2005. Growth theory through the lens of developmenteconomics. In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S. (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth(Amsterdam: North-Holland).

Basu, S., Fernald, J.G., 2002. Aggregate productivity and aggregate technology. EuropeanEconomic Review 46, 963–991.

Benassy, J.P., 1998. Is there always too little research in endogenous growth withexpanding product variety? European Economic Review 42, 61–69.

Bernard, A., Eaton, J., Jensen, B., Kortum, S., 2003. Plants and productivity ininternational trade. American Economic Review 93, 1268–1290.

Bhagwati, J., 1971. “The generalized theory of distortions and welfare. In: Bhagwati, J.,et al. (Ed.), Trade balance of payments and growth (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

Bilbiie, F., F. Ghironi and M. Melitz (2006). “Monopoly Power and Endogenous Varietyin Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium: Distortions and Remedies,” mimeo.

Brander, J., Krugman, P., 1983. A reciprocal dumping model of international trade.Journal of International Economics 15, 313–321.

Chen, N., Imbs, J., Scott, A., 2009. The dynamics of trade and competition. Journal ofInternational Economics 77, 50–62.

Corsetti, G., Martin, P., Pesenti, P., 2007. Productivity, terms of trade and the homemarket effect. Journal of International Economics 73, 99–127.

Dixit, A., Stiglitz, J., 1977. Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity.American Economic Review 67, 297–308.

Eaton, J., Panagariya, A., 1979. Gains from trade under variables returns to scale,commodity taxation, tariffs and factor market distortions. Journal of InternationalEconomics 9, 481–501.

Eckel, C., 2008. Globalization and specialization. Journal of International Economics 75,219–228.

Epifani, P., Gancia, G., 2006. Increasing returns, imperfect competition and factor prices.Review of Economics and Statistics 88, 583–598.

Epifani, P., Gancia, G., 2008. The skill bias of world trade. Economic Journal 118, 927–960.Epifani, P., Gancia, G., 2009. “Trade, markup heterogeneity andmisallocations,” CEPR DP

7217.Feenstra, R., 2003. A homothetic utility function for monopolistic competition models,

without constant price elasticity. Economics Letters 78, 79–86.Gancia, G., Zilibotti, F., 2009. Technological change and the wealth of nations. Annual

Review of Economics 1, 93–120.Hall, R.E., 1988. The relations between price and marginal cost in U.S. industry. Journal

of Political Economy 96, 921–947.Helpman, E., Krugman, P., 1985. Market structure and foreign trade. (Cambridge MIT

Press), MA.Hsieh, C.T., Klenow, P., 2009. Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India.

Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 1403–1448.Johnson, H.G., 1965. Optimal trade intervention in the presence of domestic distortions.

In: Baldwin, R.E., et al. (Ed.), Trade, Growth and the Balance of Payments. Rand-McNally, Chicago.

Jones, C. (2009). “Intermediate Goods and Weak Links: A Theory of EconomicDevelopment,” mimeo Stanford.

Koeniger, W., Licandro, O., 2006. On the use of substitutability as a measure ofcompetition. Topics in Macroeconomics 6, Issue 1, Article 2.

Krugman, P., 1979. Increasing returns, monopolistic competition and internationaltrade. Journal of International Economics 9, 469–479.

Lancaster, K., 1979. Variety, equity and efficiency. Columbia University, New York.Lerner, A.P., 1934. The concept of monopoly and the measurement of monopoly power.

Review of Economic Studies 1, 157–175.Melitz, M., 2003. The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate

industry productivity. Econometrica 71, 1695–1725.Melitz, M., Ottaviano, G., 2008. Market size, trade and productivity. Review of Economic

Studies 75, 295–316.Neary, J.P., 2003. Globalization and market structure. Journal of the European Economic

Association 1, 245–271.Restuccia, D., Rogerson, R., 2008. Policy distortions and aggregate productivity with

heterogeneous establishments. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 707–720.Roberts, M.J., Tybout, J.R., 1996. Industrial evolution in developing countries. Oxford

University Press, Oxford.Salop, S.C., 1979. Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell Journal of

Economics 10, 141–156.Samuleson, P., 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. (Cambridge Harvard University

Press), MA.Song, Z., Storesletten, K., Zilibotti, F., forthcoming. Growing Like China. American

Economic Review.Tybout, J.R., 2003. “Plant-and firm-level evidence on ‘new’ trade theories,”. In: Choi, E.K.,

Harrigan, J. (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics. Basil-Blackwell, Oxford.