THREE ESSAYS ON CROP INSURANCE: RMA’S RULES AND ...

123
THREE ESSAYS ON CROP INSURANCE: RMA’S RULES AND PARTICIPATION, AND PERCEPTIONS BY ALISHER UMAROV B.S., North Dakota State University, 2000 M.S., North Dakota State University, 2003 DISSERTATION Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Agricultural and Consumer Economics in the Graduate College of the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, 2009 Urbana, Illinois Doctoral Committee: Professor Bruce Sherrick, Chair Professor Philip Garcia Professor Scott Irwin Professor Gary Schnitkey Assistant Professor Joshua Pollet, Emory University

Transcript of THREE ESSAYS ON CROP INSURANCE: RMA’S RULES AND ...

THREE ESSAYS ON CROP INSURANCE: RMA’S RULES AND PARTICIPATION, AND PERCEPTIONS

BY

ALISHER UMAROV

B.S., North Dakota State University, 2000 M.S., North Dakota State University, 2003

DISSERTATION

Submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Agricultural and Consumer Economics

in the Graduate College of the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, 2009

Urbana, Illinois

Doctoral Committee:

Professor Bruce Sherrick, Chair Professor Philip Garcia Professor Scott Irwin Professor Gary Schnitkey Assistant Professor Joshua Pollet, Emory University

ii

TABLE OF CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION......................................................................................................... 1

CHAPTER 1: Effect of Rules for Calculating APH on the Performance of APH

Insurance ....................................................................................................................... 6

CHAPTER 2: Crop Insurance Usage in Lake Woebegone........................................ 45

CHAPTER 3: Farmers’ Subjective Yield Distributions and Elicitation Formats...... 81

CONCLUSION ......................................................................................................... 114

REFERENCES.......................................................................................................... 117

AUTHOR’S BIOGRAPHY ...................................................................................... 121

1

INTRODUCTION

Since its inception in 1930, crop insurance programs have grown from minor

government programs to a major instrument for delivering government assistance.

In 2008 there were 1.96 million crop insurance policies sold with a liability of $90

billion, covering 272 million acres. For context, the corresponding figures in 1998

were 1.2 million policies sold with a liability of $27.9 billion, covering 182 million

acres. While these numbers are impressive, current levels of participation and the

associated actuarial performance in the program have been achieved only after

significant producer subsidies were instituted, and the program has struggled with

low participation levels and the poor actuarial performance for the major part of its

existence.

Because a broad level of participation in crop insurance is necessary for sound

actuarial performance of the program, the factors determining participation have

received considerable research attention. Lack of participation is often cited as the

result of crop insurance interactions with other risk management tools (Mahul and

Wright, 2003), presence of government subsidies, and adverse selection. While the

moral hazard, adverse selection, or government assistance play an important role in

explaining participation, there are other issues that could be important as well. For

example, risk perceptions of the producers might be crucial in determining crop

insurance decisions. If a farmer perceives that his yield is above average (both in

terms of level and safety), he might conclude that the insurance is overpriced.

Another factor that could influence participation is the insurance rating process.

RMA has documented consistent complaints from farmers stating that the current

2

method for calculating APH yields and the insurance indemnity does not provide

sufficient level of protection.

The purpose of this dissertation is to further examine the factors that influence

farmers’ decisions to participate in crop insurance programs. The factors considered

are RMA rules and farmers’ yield perceptions. In particular, the first paper examines

the role of Risk Management Agency’s (RMA) APH calculation rules on the

performance, participation, and risk protection level of actual producer history

(APH) insurance. The second and third papers examine the presence of behavioral

biases, such as miscalibration and better-than-average (BTA) effect in farmers’

perceptions, and relate these biases to the participation.

Current RMA rules use a simple average of recent yields with required

substitution of lower “plugged” yield in period absent data. Several problems are

likely to arise as a result of using this formula. Because APH is a simple average

that relies on a small number of outcomes, it is easily affected by extremes and small

sample issues. Also, the APH effective coverage can be misstated if small sample of

outcomes contains several years of poor yields, or one or more years of well-above

average yields. Another problem involves trending yields and the process used to

compute APH. RMA rules ignoring trend induce an easily identified bias in

“expected” yields. As a result, an average of past data will result in APH values that

are on average below the “true” expected yield. This in turn will lead to a lower

effective protection level than would be the case if the APH accurately depicted the

mean of the contemporaneous yield distribution. A related problem is induced by

small sample variability. Because the APH mean utilizes a relatively small number

3

of outcomes, the mean is subject to high variability and is a low-efficiency estimate.

A simple simulation can show that even with 10 years of observation, the precision

of the mean is likely to be significantly compromised. The first chapter therefore

examines the impact of the trend and of the sample size variability on the

participation, performance, and risk protection of APH insurance. The simulation

model is developed with controllable “true” distributions constructed from NASS

data for each county in Illinois, but can be easily extended for any farm-level

situation of interest.

While the first paper examines the influence of RMA’s rules on the

participation and actuarial performance, the second and third papers analyze the role

that cognitive biases may play in insurance decisions. Since the first papers in

behavioral economics were published, the field of behavioral economics/finance has

experienced tremendous growth. Currently, there are several journals in economics

and finance that specialize in behavioral research, and some universities teach the

subject in advanced courses. The results from related behavioral research indicate

that cognitive biases influence individuals’ decision-making. Two of the more

commonly expressed biases are “miscalibration” (defined as systematically misstated

correspondence between subjective and objective distributions) and the “better than

average” (BTA) effect (defined as individuals’ tendency to maintain unrealistically

positive assessment of one’s skills and abilities, especially in relation to peer group).

These two possibilities are examined in this dissertation.

The second and third papers examine producers’ yield perceptions and relate

them to their behavior. Both papers use data from the crop yield risk survey (CYRS)

4

developed under a cooperative agreement with RMA and the University of Illinois.

Conducted in 2002, this survey covers corn and soybean producers from Indiana,

Iowa, and Illinois. The survey underwent an extensive reviewing process by

University personnel and economists from the Economic Research Service of USDA.

It elicited information on demographics, risk management, risk attributes and

perceptions, and the conjoint ranking of insurance products and attributes.

The second chapter examines the relationship between risk perceptions and crop

insurance by linking the BTA effect and miscalibration to crop insurance purchases.

Following numerous publications that showed the BTA effect and miscalibration

influence decision making and arguing that farming is likely to promote the BTA

effect, this chapter investigates whether the BTA effect systematically biases

farmers’ participation decisions. If a farmer believes that his/her farming skills are

above average, he/she may conclude that he/she is likely to outperform others and

consequently “average” priced insurance will be relatively less attractive. This

hypothesis was tested by using crop participation as a dependent variable and

subjective yield perceptions as independent variables. The analysis was

implemented on an individual product level (yield, revenue and CAT insurance) and

across all products.

The third paper examines the role of different elicitation formats on the

subjective perception by analyzing correspondence between yield perceptions and

county yield distribution. The subjective yield perceptions were elicited under two

different formats, directly and indirectly. Both directly and indirectly-stated

subjective yields were compared to the county yields. If one of these formats

5

displays systematic differences from county-level yields, the argument can be made

that the elicitation approach substantially influences the measures of risk recovered

from producers, therefore further confounding efforts to design attractive and effect

insurance products.

Overall, this dissertation presents interesting findings about the role of

perceptions and RMA’s rules on the participation. The findings from the papers

illustrate that the current RMA’s rules reduce protection level, participation, and

performance of the APH insurance. The dissertation also illustrates that, behavioral

biases, while present, do not reverse directional effects in insurance purchase

decisions, but only affect extent and intensity. Finally, it is know that the probability

conviction elicitation framework provides more accurate results than direct yield

elicitation.

6

CHAPTER 1

Effect of Rules for Calculating APH on the Performance of APH

Insurance

Abstract

The Risk Management Agency’s rules for calculating a farmer’s Actual

Production History (APH) yield create several problems for crop

insurance users. APH calculations ignore trend, are severely affected by

extreme values, and do not vary with the length of the observed history.

This study investigates the impact of these rules on the risk protection,

participation incentives, and actuarial performance by using a simulation

model with controllable “true” yield distributions. Existing rating

methods lead to a bias which results in wide differences in implied

subsidy impacts, variations across production regions, and reduce

incentives for participation.

Crop insurance products have become increasingly popular among farmers. In 2008

approximately 1.96 million of crop insurance policies were sold with a liability of

$90 billion covering 272 million acres of land compared to 1.2 million policies were

sold with a liability of $27.9 billion covering 182 million acres. The most popular

crop insurance products (such as actual production history, crop revenue coverage,

and revenue assurance) have covered 81% of insured acres in 2006. Calculation of

product guarantees and premium rates for these products depended on producers’

actual production history (APH) yields (Carriquiry, Babcock, Hart, 2005). In general

terms, under individual yield guarantee crop contracts, a farmer is eligible for

indemnity if the actual farm yield is less than the yield guarantee specified in the

contract. A grower can select the guarantee as a percentage (coverage level) of

historical average yield (4 to 10 years) the actual production history, and the

coverage levels range from 50% to 85% in 5% increments. A before-subsidy

premium for the insurance is the product of the yield guarantee, a price set by RMA,

7

and the RMA established premium rate, provided that actual yield is below the

guarantee. The indemnity is the difference between the yield guarantee and the actual

yield times the price set by RMA.

The rules for calculating a farmer’s Actual Production History (APH) are

straightforward, and are intended to provide a simple mechanism to predict a

farmer’s yield-risk exposure while limiting the incidence of adverse selection and

other rating problems. In essence, the current rule uses a simple average of recent

yields (4 to 10 years) with required substitution of lower “plugged” yields for

missing observations. No attempt is made to reflect yield trends, nor any attempt to

reflect systematic and observable differences from expected production evident in

area yields. Instead, APH relies exclusively on an individual’s own available yield

history and adjusted county yields to replace missing data.

The paper examines the impact of the RMA’s rules for calculating Actual

Production History (APH) yields on the implied degree of risk protection, on

participation, and on the actuarial performance of crop insurance across a set of

conditions that represent the experience of a wide set of farms in Illinois. The

analysis uses a simulation model with controllable “true” distributions constructed

from NASS data for each county in Illinois scaled to reflect farm-level conditions

based on information from a broad set of farms enrolled in the Farm Business Farm

Management record keeping association (FBFM). To assess the actuarial

implications, the iFARM crop insurance evaluation program is used1.

The paper identifies the directional impacts and implications for risk

protections afforded by yield insurance under the existing rules. It demonstrates that

8

both sample size variability and trend omission can have serious consequences on

participation decisions and risk protection. In particular, ignoring trend reduces risk

protection afforded by crop insurance (by introducing a lag in yields), and sample

size variability compromises the APH mean precision. While these results are

consistent with findings by Skees and Reed (1986), Carriquiry et al. (2005), the

paper contributes to the literature by modeling trend and sample size variability

simultaneously and doing so to examine the impact under the RMA premium rating

structure. The paper finds significant differences between actuarial costs and RMA

premiums and identifies the reasons for the discrepancies. The study also provides a

simple approach to adjust for the trend that would clearly and easily improve the

individual performance of crop insurance, and contribute to newly emerging

suggestions for improving APH style insurance.

Background

Currently the APH insurable yields and rates are calculated using at least four and

up to ten years of farm-level yields. If less than 4 years of yield data are available,

adjusted transition yields (which are county yields times a certain percentage),

known as t-yields are used as “plug-in” values in the farmer’s history. If the farmer

has more than 10 years of data, the most distant observations are ignored.

Importantly, RMA develops all insurance rates by county regardless of the

differences in participation rates, production intensities, and existing payout

experiences. RMA examines loss cost ratios (LCR - the ratio of indemnity to

liability) adjusted to 65% coverage level using liability dollar values for the last 20

or more years starting in 1975. To reduce the impact of a single year, RMA caps its

9

individual loss cost ratios at the 80th percentile of the historic LCR and distributes

the excess across all counties in a state (Josephson, Lord, and Mitchell, 2001). RMA

calculates a county insurance rate as a weighted average (weights are not disclosed)

of a given county LCR and circle LCR (an average of surrounding counties LCR).

The averaging is done to increase the predictive value of the loss ratio (Josephson,

Lord and Mitchell, 2001). The county insurance rate is known as the base county

unloaded rate. The base rate is then adjusted by APH, reference yields, and fixed rate

loading:

Exponentail

APH YieldBase Rate County Unloaded Rate Fixed Rate Loading

Reference Yield

= +

(1)

where

APH is the actual production history, or average of 4 to 10 individual farm-level

yields,

Reference Yield is the yield set by RMA intended to reflect an average yield index

for a given county,

Exponential is the an exponential factor to control for “yield variability

differences”.2 and

Fixed rate loading is the provision for catastrophic losses.

Two implicit assumptions become clear when examining the base rate

formula. First, RMA treats all APH yields the same, regardless of number of years

used to calculate the average. Yet, samples based on shorter time periods tend to be

more variable. Secondly, no adjustments for the trend are made despite increasing

yield levels across crops and regions.

10

Since yields exhibit an upward trend, the calculated APH yield is likely to lag

the expected yield. Consider a farmer with 10-year APH of 109 bu/acre but with an

expected yield due to increasing technology of 120 bu/acre. At 75% coverage level,

the APH insurance would cover 82 bu/acre (109 x 75%) rather than 90 bu/acre.

Skees and Reed recognized this effect and argued that “either RMA must attempt to

adjust APH yields for trends or they must reduce their rates to reflect the actual level

of coverage provided when trends are not adjusted”. Depending on the nature of the

underlying yield generating process, a significant probability mass could occur

between 82 and 90 bu/acre.

To examine the simultaneous impact of trend and sample size variability on

APH yield, consider figure 1.1. The figure illustrates the relationship between APH

and the expected (“true”) yield distribution. The figure depicts 5,000 simulated 4-

and 10-year APH yields with mean on the x-axis and standard deviation on y axis.

The figure illustrates the role of sample variations due to sample size on a

representative farm’s APH estimate. The simulation was constructed for a

representative case farm from Christian County, Illinois by first detrending corn

yields, fitting the resulting data to a Weibull distribution, and then simulating sets of

yields of various sample lengths, re-applying the trend and then calculating the

resulting APH mean and standard deviations for 4- and 10-year periods.3 The figure

highlights the potential variability in the mean and provides a sense of the rate at

which variability decreases as more observation/years are added, and how the mean

bias is affected by the sample length. In general, the shorter samples provide better

estimates of mean and worse estimates of variability. For example, the true

11

(expected) mean and standard deviation for the representative farm in this is example

is 174 bu/ac and 24 bu/ac (shown as red and black lines in color-printed versions,

light and dark otherwise). The ten year APH yield has a mean of 164 bu/ac and

standard deviation of 24 bu/ac, while 4 year APH yield has a mean of 167 bu/ac and

standard deviation of 22 bu/ac. Given additional incentives for farmers to self-select

based on their yield experience, either because of the trend, or because of the

abnormal yields, the precision of the APH estimate is likely to be further

compromised. The figure also illustrates another potential problem a possible

dependence between lower moments. Figure 1.1 displays this effect in the “clouds”

whose points move up and to the left relative to the “true” data generation process

used (i.e. there a possible inverse relationship between standard deviation and mean).

Farmers have repeatedly voiced concerns about the inability of the APH to

adequately represent their yield risk exposure. They argue that the insurance

provides inadequate protection when they experience several consecutive years of

low yields because the APH in this case does not accurately reflect farmers’ future

risk, leading to adverse selection incentives. The implication is that their yield

histories make insurance too expensive and provide inadequate levels of protection,

or simply transfer subsidies non-uniformly and inequitably. Because the APH can be

affected by extreme values, there is an incentive to report only higher values, or to

“switch” reporting units to take advantage of favorable, but random, yield variations.

Consistent with this observation, anecdotal evidence suggests that farmers tend to

switch insurance agents and “forget” somewhat distant bad years when applying for

crop insurance (Rejesus and Lovell 2003). RMA has defended its insurance rating

12

and pricing practices by arguing that under constant yield trends, stable yield

distributions, uniform participation, the current practices would lead to coverage

level selections that would misstate true coverage by a constant amount and the rates

would likewise adjust themselves through time. RMA also has stated that even

though the insurance premiums are set and a final pricing algorithm is available, the

specific mechanisms are intentionally undisclosed to prevent or dissuade moral

hazard and adverse selection.

Concerns about the role of the APH calculation on the performance of crop

insurance have become so well-known that the Risk Management Agency (RMA)

noted it is “the most frequent and consistent concern heard from producers” (U.S.

Congress, Subcommittee on General Farm Commodities and Risk Management of

the Committee on Agriculture, 2004). In April 2004, RMA requested proposals for

alternative methods for mitigating declines in approved yields due to successive

years of low yields. RMA’s administrator noted that the goals of request for such a

proposal were to find “…approaches to establishing approved APH yields that are

less subject to decreases during successive years of low yields as compared to

current procedures…”(U.S. Congress. House of Representatives. Subcommittee on

General Farm Commodities and Risk Management of the Committee on Agriculture

2006). RMA’s implicit recognition of the problems with the rating methodologies

remains at odds with their defense and continued use of the existing approaches. A

need for research to clarify the impacts and to identify potential improvements is

evident. Also, figure 1.1 highlights the error in logic of the implicit in the rules idea

that longer sample period should be a better estimator of the central tendency.

13

In addition, trend and sample size variability issues may be interrelated. It has

been postulated that advancements in seed technology and disease control have

altered the underlying yield generating process through time. These genetic

improvements might have increased the trend, reduced the yield variance, or simply

changed the relationship between mean and variability. In particular, recent

advances in genetic technology and “bio-traits” have resulted in what many call yield

acceleration or a quantum jump in trend. Cursory examination of NASS state level

average corn yields seems to confirm this, as the state linear trend is 0.9 bu./acre for

the time period from 1973 to 1983, 2.15 bu./acre for the time period from 1984 to

1994, and 3.94 bu./acre from 1995 to 2005. While additional time and data are

required to confirm this effect, the possibility would further exacerbate the problems

with existing ratings methodologies4 (i.e. farmers who use seeds with bio-traits and

pay “average” RMA premiums might be overcharged).

Literature Review

This section examines previous work on trend and sample variability issues, and the

relationship between RMA premiums and actuarial costs. The literature related to

the impact of trend and variability on the APH estimation is fairly direct in its

implications. While both trend and sample size variability issues have been

examined, the references remain limited. Skees and Reed (1986) were among the

first to point out that when the yield trend is present, the expected yield will be

higher than the APH yield. Using farm-level data from Illinois and Kentucky corn

and soybean producers, they regressed standard deviations and yield coefficient of

variations on mean yield. They calculated a theoretical (actuarially fair) insurance

14

rate as a function of yield and showed that the rates calculated under trend-adjusted

yields are consistently higher than the rates calculated under APH yield. They

further argued that RMA needs to introduce the rate adjustments for the trend. They

concluded that the rules are likely to lead to adverse selections since farmers with

high yields are less likely to receive indemnity payments, and the trend omission is

likely to result in lower indemnity payments. However, the authors did not examine

the impact from different base period APH yields and did not consider how the trend

omission influences the rates calculated under the RMA’s premium structure.

Barnett, Black, Hu, and Skees (2005) provided a brief theoretical argument

concerning the magnitude of the sample size error. Using a statistical rule stating that

the standard error of the estimate is the ratio of standard deviation of the true

underlying distribution to the square root of the sample’s size, they showed that the

samples with more observations should have a better precision. However, this rule is

true for detrended yields, since the presence of trend is likely to comprise yield mean

precision. Carriquiry et al. (2005) argued that since farmers whose past yields were

above expected yields were more likely to participate in crop insurance (they called

this a sampling error), the current rules for APH calculation were likely to lead to

adverse selection. This results because the sampling error would lead to higher loss-

to-cost ratios, and as a result, to higher insurance premiums. They used detrended

farm- and county-level corn yields from Iowa farmers to model the impact of

sampling error and suggested an alternative estimator to minimize the error. The

results showed that estimated ratio of APH indemnities to actuarially fair insurance

premiums is greater than 1 with and without adverse selection. The results also

15

showed that the return to crop insurance decreases as number of years in the APH

period increases. A limitation of their work is that they used detrended yields5,

implicitly ignoring the relationship between trends and sample size variability. In

addition, their comparison relied on actuarially fair premiums, while RMA employs

a complex rating structure that is likely to violate the assumption of actuarial fairness.

Zanini, Sherrick, Schnitkey, and Irwin (2001) examined yield probabilities,

actuarially-fair premiums, and RMA premiums under 5 different parametric

distributions. They used farm-level data from 26 corn and soybean producers in 12

Illinois counties. They detrended yields using linear trend, and fitted Weibull,

normal, lognormal, beta, and logistic distributions. They compared actuarially fair

payments under various distributions and found that beta and Weibull distributions

provide the most accurate measure of payments. They reported values for both

premiums, and the calculated simple (unweighted) average ratio of actuarially fair

payments, and found that on average RMA premiums exceed actuarially fair

premiums by 3.3 times6. They also compared the actuarially fair payments to RMA

premiums and found no correlations between the two. They concluded stating “the

results raise questions about the efficacy of crop insurance rating procedures. In

particular, if actual premiums are not closely correlated with expected payments, the

significant problems in controlling payout ratios would be expected.”

Some of the inconsistencies empirically observed by research in crop

insurance can be linked to the issues of trend and sample size variability. A report by

the integrated Financial Analytics and Research (iFAR) for the Illinois Corn

Marketing Board analyzed the loss ratios Illinois corn and soybean producers. The

16

report noted that the loss ratios for corn and soybean have been well below RMA’s

benchmark target ratios and that distribution of loss ratios is clearly not uniform.

The primary corn producing regions have much lower loss ratios (average loss ratio

for all crops from 1995 to 2005 are 0.52 for Illinois), than the areas in the fringes of

the corn belt. Such loss ratios imply that the farmers in these areas pay higher

premiums per unit of risk when compared to farmers from other states and regions.

The report lists possible explanations for the observed loss ratios emphasizing the

presence of high relative yield trends in corn and soybeans. Further, the report

argues that “yield acceleration” can create a situation where ratings based on

historical yields will overstate the premiums through understated coverage, stating

that “cursory examination verify that crops with higher rates of trend increase have

had lower loss ratios” by tabulating similar loss performance data across major crops.

The existing literature illustrates following gap in existing research. While

Skees and Reed (1986) examined the role of trend on the participation and Carriquiry

et al. (2005) examined the impact of sample size error, neither investigated trend and

sample size variability jointly. Since both trend and sample size variability impact

yield estimates simultaneously, they need to be examined jointly. Further, most of

the literature examined the impact from trend omission and sample size variability

on actuarially fair rates. In reality, farmers are charged RMA premiums, and RMA

premiums are not actuarially fair. Therefore, the impact of trend and sample size

variability needs to be examined under RMA’s premium structure.

17

Empirical Approach

The analysis presented is performed for a case farm in each county in Illinois to

illustrate how the results differ among regions that vary in average productivity,

variability, and under different insurance premium rate structures. The steps in used

in the empirical model are shown in figure 1.2. To create a representative farm in

each county, the county-level yield data for the period 1972 to 2005 (NASS) were

detrended to a base year of 2006 using a linear time trend7 (2006 was chosen to be

consistent with the premium calculation algorithms used)8 and the mean and standard

deviation for each county were calculated (step 1). Because the farm-level yields are

more variable than county yields, the standard deviations were scaled up to represent

the difference between county and farm level data using an empirical relationship to

actual farmer data from farms enrolled in the Illinois Farm Business Farm

Management record-keeping system. The county-level standard deviations were

multiplied by the average ratio of farm to county standard deviations,9 and a method

of moments’ estimator then used to fit Weibull distribution to recover the implied

farm-level yield distribution.10

The county trend was added back to the representative farm distributions for

each county to create the data generating process used in the simulations.

Specifically, these distributions were used to estimate probabilities of reaching

expected yields (true probabilities) (step 4) and to generate pseudo datasets of

varying lengths (from 4 to 10 years) (step 5). For convenience, @Risk11 was used to

generate the pseudodata and Monte Carlo simulations were run, with 10,00012

iterations, to generate the sets of samples for the insurance evaluation phase of the

18

study. The data were generated for representative farms in each Illinois county, and

the probabilities of reaching target yields under various scenarios estimated. Because

the representative farms differ in trends, mean, and standard deviation by county, the

model allows examination of the impact of these variables on the probability of

reaching different indemnified yields. Also, the model allows examining

probabilities across the counties, and for various sample periods.

To facilitate the explanation of the information presented, consider figure 1.3.

The figure shows two corn yield distributions for the case farm in Adams County,

Illinois. The continuous line denotes true or expected yield distribution; the dashed

line shows the distribution for the 10-year APH mean at a 0.85 coverage level. The

difference in the means between the representative distribution and the APH mean

distribution illustrates the bias induced by ignoring the trend. The graph also shows

the probabilities of receiving indemnity under the 10-year APH yield and under true

or expected yield distributions. The probability is shown as area to the left of the

dashed line that separates the lower left tail of the distribution. Since the area under

the case farm is smaller than the area under the 10-year APH, the probability of

receiving the indemnity is smaller under the representative yield distribution. Higher

levels of coverage are needed under the APH-mean yield distribution to provide the

same level of protection as warranted by the true yield distribution.

In step 6 (figure 1.2), we calculate actuarial costs and examine the role of

existing rules on the actuarial cost and expected participation. In step 7, the actual

premiums (under RMA’s “black box” approach for determining the coefficients)

were recovered to examine the impact of trend, sample size variability, and number

19

of years in the sample, on the RMA’s premiums. Figure 1.4 illustrates RMA’s

premium calculation for the hypothetical corn farm in Adams County with an APH

yield of 168 bu./acre, coverage level of 85%, and $4.50 /bu contract price. The

calculation starts with estimating guarantee per acre (product of APH yield and

coverage level), liability (premium guarantee times price election), yield ratio, and

preliminary base rate. The rate is then adjusted for coverage level and the subsidy.

The premiums calculated under RMA’s algorithm were compared to the

actuarial cost under the simulated data. Since RMA uses empirical crop losses to

derive the rates, it believes that there should be no difference between a large scale

simulation cost and the stated rates. Thus the differences imply unintended impacts

of the methods used to arrive at the APH or simply ratings mistakes. The approach

in this study allows an isolation of the role of the APH portion of the difference

between actual and actuarially fair rates.

Results

Table 1.1 presents results for six selected counties and the state by comparing the

impact on true and APH implied probabilities from counties’ representative farms13.

It also implicitly illustrates the relationship between sample moments and the

likelihood and frequency of APH payments relative to “true” (expected), given the

existing rules of the APH calculation. The results are presented in 5% coverage level

increments, for APH mean yields calculated from sets of 4, 7, and 10 years. The first

column shows county mean, standard deviation, and trend. The third labeled “True

Prob” column presents the probability of reaching a particular yield level under

farm-level representative “true distributions” for a given coverage level. For example,

20

in Jefferson County, the probability of a yield outcome under the “true” distribution

is 3.05% for the 0.55 coverage level, and 24.76% for the 0.85 coverage level. The

column labeled “APH implied probability” presents the probability for reaching a

particular yield level at the associated coverage level given the sample period and

implied yield under the existing rules for calculating the APH. To gauge the relative

impact of the APH sample period, a column labeled “Prob Ratio” is provided,

containing a ratio of implied APH probability to the “True Prob” probability. This

ratio shows the fraction of the actual protection provided by APH mean given true

probability, coverage level, and time period. For example, for Jefferson County,

under 0.55 coverage level, the mean value is 91.97%, under a 4-year sample period.

In other words, the protection level provided by 4-year APH level is reduced by 8%

as a result of using the APH mean rather than the true mean. The actual protection

level decreases as the coverage level increases, but the magnitude is small (91.97%

for 0.55 coverage level, compared to 89.93% for the 0.85 coverage level).

The probability ratio, however, is influenced by the number of years in the

APH sample period. For Jefferson County, for example, the ratio decreases from

91.97% (0.55 coverage level, 4-year APH) to 71.31% (0.55 coverage level, 10-year

APH). In effect, the protection level is reduced by 20% as the years in the base

period increase from 4 to 10. The pattern of relative probabilities is also influenced

importantly by trend. For instance, in Lee County where the trend is higher, the

impact is more pronounced with the relative probability decreasing at 0.85 coverage

level from 81.15% with 4 year coverage to 55.92% with 10 year coverage. Shifting

to the state level, the protection level is reduced by 24%, (from 88.23% for 0.55

21

coverage level and 4 year APH to 64.82% for 10 year APH same coverage level).

To the extent that rational producers respond to these differences, the implications of

the findings are clear. Use of APH yields decreases the probability of participation,

and the longer the number of years in the base period the less likely is the

participation decision. The results on interaction between APH yields and trend are

similar to results in Skees and Reed (1986) who showed that theoretical insurance

rates for trend-adjusted yields are always greater than the rates for APH yields and

argued that an adjustment is needed to prevent an adverse participation incentive.

If a farmer has experienced several years of abnormally high (low) yields, his

APH yield is likely to be greater (less) than his expected yield. In this situation, a

farmer is more likely to purchase crop insurance. This is an example of adverse

selection, and to model this propensity, a measure “participation prob” was

developed. For every iteration, a value of 1 was given if the APH sample yield was

greater than the actual expected yield, and zero otherwise. Averaged across all

iterations, the measure provides a farmer’s “pure participation probability” that arises

from experiencing several abnormal yield years that favorably classifies his yields

relative to true. The value of the probability can be indicative of the extent and

severity of adverse selection. For example, in Jefferson County, for 4 year APH

yield, this value is 36.59% indicating that there is a 36.59% chance that a given APH

mean will actually be greater than the true (expected) yield. As the number of years

in the base period increases from 4 years to 10, the probability decreases to 14.75%.

This decrease is due to the lag introduced by trend, where APH yield lags expected

yield so significantly that even random positive changes in yields are not large

22

enough to compensate for the lag. The probability differs across the counties due to

the interaction between trend and dispersion in yield, with lower trends and shorter

sample variability; it ranges from 33.21% for Macon, and 28.74% for Lee (4 year

APH mean). At the state level, the participation probability is 33.55% for 4 year

APH versus 10.15% for 10 year APH. High participation probability further

illustrates low efficiency of the APH estimate, and illustrates the impact of extreme

yield values on the APH yield.

RMA Premium Calculations

To examine the impact from trend and yield variability in a economic context, the

actual premium algorithm used by RMA14 was implemented to construct actual

premiums for each case farm. The model simply inputs true and simulated APH

yields into RMA’s pricing algorithm and compares the resulting impacts. The

algorithm calculates the actual price quoted to a farmer who wants to buy crop

insurance for each county using RMA’s technical coefficients and simulated APH

and true means. Figure 1.4 replicates RMA’s insurance pricing algorithm for a

hypothetical corn producer in Adams County that has an APH yield of 168 bu/ac,

selects 85% coverage level, with $4.5/bu contract price. The subsidized premium is

equal to $33.24 per acre; the unsubsidized premium is equal to $53.62 per acre.

Table 1.2 shows average, before subsidy, premium values for 0.85 coverage level15

for selected counties across the same APH base periods of 4, 7, and 10 years as were

in table 1.1. The table shows trend, true probability, APH mean, RMA premiums for

4, 7, 10 years and true yield. The results indicate that as the number of years in the

base period increases, the premium values increase as well but the change in the

23

values is small. In Christian County, for example, the difference between true dollar

premium and estimated dollar premium (10-year APH base period) is only $0.25

($28.87 minus $29.63) for an APH difference of 12 bushels. At the state level, the

difference of 7 bushels translates into premium difference of $0.90.

The insensitivity of the RMA insurance premiums to the changes in APH

yields is somewhat alarming, since RMA uses APH yield as an indicator for farm

yield variability. Such low sensitivity to APH yield could also potentially lead to

adverse selection, since originally APH yield was used as a proxy for the yield

variability and the premium values for the low and high APH yield do not seem to

differ substantially. One possible reason for low yield sensitivity could be the

provision for catastrophic losses used in ratemaking process. This loading is fixed,

and given high spatial correlation in yields is likely to be significant. This claim is

examined later in the chapter.

Actuarial Implications of Trend and Small Sample Variability of APH

Actual premiums are relatively insensitive to changes in the APH, and may not be

suitable to summarize the actuarial performance differences that exist in practice. As

a consequence, true actuarial costs are also calculated. The indemnity function can

be specified as [ ]max 0,k y p− , where k is coverage level times APH yield, y is

realized yield; and p is the indemnity price per bushel in the insurance contract. The

actuarially fair (expected) value of the contract can be calculated by Monte Carlo

integration and written as:

0

( ) ( )k

V p k y f y dy= −∫ (2)

24

where f(y) is the yield probability density function.

This framework provides the mechanism for calculating the actuarial values

and examines how the changes in underlying yield exposure and sample size

variability affect the fair values. These values and their changes across underlying

yield distributions can then be compared to the premiums calculated by RMA to

identify the effect of trend, sample period, and other variables. To make results

easily interpreted, the indemnity price is fixed at $4.50 and all results are presented

relative to that price.

Table 1.3 contains a summary of the actuarial costs for yield insurance across

the same representative counties, for the 0.85 coverage level that was chosen to be

consistent with RMA premium estimations. As shown, the actuarial costs are more

responsive to the trend and base period changes than the actual premiums. For

example, in Christian County, the cost decreases by $1.87 (from $7.11 for 4 year

APH to $5.24 for 10 year APH) as the number of years in the base period increases

due to the reduction in coverage provided. The magnitude provides direct

implications for the cost of the insurance program relative to actual premiums for

different sample. For counties with lower trends, the impact, or decrease in actual

costs is smaller. For Jefferson County (trend =1.3 bu/acre/year) the actuarial cost

decreases by $2.84 (from $14.54 to $11.70) as the number of years in the base period

increases, again despite the fact that the actual premiums paid would be unchanged

for the farmer.

More interestingly, the actuarial costs are substantially smaller than

unsubsidized premiums calculated in table 1.2. To facilitate the discussion, the

25

RMA premiums from table 1.2 and actuarial costs from table 1.3 are combined in

table 1.4 with the ratio of RMA premiums to actuarial costs. The ratios for all APH

base periods and for true (expected) yield premiums are greater than 2, and the ratios

decrease as number of years in APH yield decrease, reflecting the lag introduced by

trend. For instance, the ratio for 10 year APH yield ranges from 3.8 for Macon

County to 7.2 for Ogle County, and is equal to 3.8 at the state level. The ratio for 4

year APH yield ranges from 2.8 for Macon County to 5.2 for Ogle County, and is

equal to 3 at the state level. Using true (expected) yields, the ratio is 2.0 for Macon

County, 3.5 for Ogle County, and 2.2 at the state level. The premiums shown are for

0.85 coverage level, which currently has a subsidy level of 35%. After adjusted for

the subsidy, the ratios will be 35% smaller, but still greater than one. The ratios

calculated are in line with ratios obtained by Sherrick et al. (2004a), which ranged

from 1.3 to 7.6, with an average, unweighted value being equal to 3.3.

The reason for discrepancy between the actuarial and RMA premiums could lie

in RMA’s approach towards premium calculation. The actuarial cost calculated in

table 1.3 does not have a loading for catastrophe events (catastrophe rate). Since

yields losses tend to be spatially correlated, catastrophic provisions are likely to play

a significant role in determining premium value. To examine the premiums and the

cost on more comparable basis, the RMA premium values are re-calculated by

setting catastrophic provision equal to zero. The results are shown in table 1.5,

which compares RMA premiums without catastrophic provision to actuarial costs

and also provides the ratios of RMA’s premiums to actuarial costs. The RMA

premiums without catastrophic loading are significantly smaller than the premiums

26

with loading. For example, the premium for 4 year APH yield in Christian County is

only $14.87 compared to $29.36 (the premium with catastrophic provision in table 4).

At the state level, the same premium is $22.28 compared to $37.96. The ratios are

significantly smaller as well, they are near 2 for 4 year APH yields (4 with

catastrophic loading in table 1.4), and near 3 for 10 year APH (6 with catastrophic

loading in table 1.4). At true (expected) yield levels, the ratio is close to 1. The

results from the table suggest that the major reason for higher RMA premiums lies in

the catastrophic provision which seems to explain the significant differences between

the premiums and actuarial costs. Nonetheless, even after controlling for the

catastrophic provision, the ratios of the premiums to actuarial costs are still

significantly greater than one, reflecting the significant effect of the trend-introduced

lag.

Results after Trend Adjustment

Assuming linear trend, the bias in the mean induced by ignoring trend can be

expressed as ( 1) / 2nβ− + , where n is number of years in APH base period, and β is

yield trend. Here, we adjust for the trend bias using 4-year APH yields, and

calculate APH implied probabilities, RMA premiums, and actuarial costs. The

results are shown in table 1.6. The table also shows 4-year APH yield, 4-year trend

adjusted APH yield, and true (expected) yield. For example, for Christian county 4-

year APH yield is 167 bu/ac, however, when adjusted for trend, the yield increases to

171 bu/ac, which is about 3 bu/ac smaller than the true (expected) yield of 174 bu/ac.

APH implied probability increases from approximately 12% for 4 year APH to 14%

for when adjusted for trend. This value is close to the APH implied probability of

27

14%. There is a small reduction in premiums due to the APH trend adjustment for

Christian county. The premium decreases from $29.36 to $29.12, which is greater

than the RMA’s insurance premium under expected yield of $28.87. Finally,

actuarial cost increase from $7.11 to $9.20 due to the trend adjustment, with the

actuarial cost under true (expected) yield equal to $9.99. The adjustment improves

the protection level provided by APH insurance. It should also limit incentives to

report only recent yields, thus improving the APH mean precision (by reducing lag

introduced by the trend), reducing the negative impacts from sample size variability,

and potentially improving actuarial performance by limiting adverse selection.

Finally, note that suggested adjustment is relatively straightforward to implement, as

it does not require changing RMA’s current rating structure.

Scaler Sensitivity

In constructing county representative farms, we adjusted county-level yield

variability by the scaler (1.245) to make the county yields as variable as farm-level

yields. This ratio, while unbiased, remains subject to sample variation. To provide a

sense of its importance, we assess the sensitivity of presented results to different

scaler values. Table 1.7 contains estimates of the ratio of APH implied probabilities

to the probabilities obtained under true yield presented in table 1.1. Table 1.7

replicates the ratio under for values of 1.15, 1.2, 1.245 (base), 1.3, and 1. The ratio

steadily increases as the scaler value increases from 1 (county average yield standard

deviation) to 1.35. For example, for Christian county, the ratio increases from 52%

to 63%; at the state level the ratio increases from 56% to 67%. Arbitrary assuming

that the true scaler value lies between 1.15 to 1.35, the absolute level of error is 6

28

points at county level (67% minus 61%) or relative error is within 9% (6 points

divided by 64%). Thus, despite the fact that the scaling approach is subject to error,

it provides a strong sense of the magnitude of the most likely effect.

Summary and Conclusions

The current rules used to calculate a farmer’s APH yield are likely to result in

substantial departures from actuarial values, providing unintended incentives for

participation. Since the rules utilize an average based on a limited number of actual

farm observations, the resulting estimate is heavily influenced by extreme yield

observations. This influence is likely to lead to non-uniform impacts on probabilities

in indemnified ranges of farmers’ yield distributions. Due to the fact that the APH

yield is used in the calculation of yield guarantees and rates for the most popular

crop insurance products, the impact of the discussed problems is likely to affect large

number of farmers. We examine the impact of current RMA rules on a degree of risk

protection afforded by crop insurance, on participation incentives, and on the

actuarial performance of APH crop insurance. The approach utilized a simulation

model with controllable “true” distributions for each county in Illinois. Unlike

previous research, the paper models trend and sample size variability impact jointly

and examines the impact on actuarial costs and RMA premiums.

The results show the degree to which trends and sample size variability affect

the probabilities of reaching yield levels indemnified from lagged yield samples,

affect premiums, and actuarial costs of the actual versus APH implied distribution.

At the state level, the protection level afforded by the insurance drops by 21% as the

base period increases from 4 years to 10 years, and the counties with the high trend

29

tend to experience larger drops. The results also show that RMA premiums are not

highly influenced by actual APH yield changes. The findings suggested the large

differences between RMA premiums and actuarial costs are mostly due to the

catastrophic loading and lag in yields introduced by the trend. All these findings

have negative implications for the participation and actuarial costs.

We introduce the trend adjustment to correct the lag in the APH yields using

county trend. The adjustment improves the protection level provided by APH

insurance and should limit incentives to report only recent yields. The adjustment

seems to improve the APH mean precision, reduce the negative impacts from sample

size variability, and possibly improve actuarial performance by limiting adverse

selection.

Future research should examine spatial methods for calculating trend since

trend and yield variability issues seem to have spatial implications, and spatial

methods might lead to a better way to aggregate yields geographically. Another

potentially fruitful direction for research would be to examine impact of technology

on the trend and variability. If trends have accelerated in the last decade and

variance decreased, the current premiums are likely to be mispriced, since the current

rating structure does not take into account these developments.

Endnotes

1 The iFARM Crop Insurance Evaluation provides an evaluation of alternative crop

insurance choices for the case farm in the county and for the crop selected. The case

farm is intended to reflect conditions of a typical farm in each county and is based on

data from NASS, farm recordkeeping associations, and research at the University of

30

Illinois relating farm to county yields. The iFARM calculator is available at

http://www.farmdoc.uiuc.edu/cropins/index.asp

2 The exponential factor is an adjustment to reflect the inverse relationship between

APH yield and yield variability. Skees and Reed (1986) pointed out that the averages

of farm-level yields can be used as an (observable, but inaccurate) indicator of farm-

level yield variability. The RMA has nine discrete values for exponential factors that

are calculated by spreading county rates over a range of average yields using

proportional spanning procedures (Goodwin 1994). This factor ensures

(theoretically) that farmers who have APH above reference yield pay less in

premiums.

3 Christian County has a true mean of 174 bu/ac and a standard deviation of 24 bu/ac.

While a wide range of mean and standard deviations can be observed, Christian

County was selected to show the impact in what can be viewed as a county with low

trend.

4 Nonetheless, RMA has accepted the notion that particular biotech traits reduce

insurance exposure by recent implementation of Biotech Yield Endorsement (BYE)

in corn. This crop insurance product lowers premiums and recognizes growers who

plant certain biotech seeds.

5 Carriquiry et al. (2005) stated in the paper that “analysis abstracts somewhat from

reality and is conducted on detrended yield data” (p. 53).

6 The ratio was calculated using premiums reported here.

7 Sherrick, et al. (2004) find no evidence of a unit root in the yields.

31

8 RMA uses the same NASS data (but somewhat longer time periods) for crop

insurance rating, but does not disclose details on any use of detrending procedures.

9 To estimate the scaler, the following steps were performed. First, a sample of farms

(1056 producers) with 15 years of continuous farm-level yields was selected from

FBFM (15 years provided an optimal balance between the length of the sample and

number of observations). Farm yields for each county were detrended using a linear

trend. Second, the county-level yields (from NASS) for the same time periods were

selected and detrended using a linear time trend. The farm-level and county-level

standard deviations were calculated from the detrended samples. The standard

deviations for individual farms (from FBFM sample) were divided by respective

county standard deviations (from NASS). Third, simple averages of resulting ratios

for each county were calculated, and the simple average for Illinois was estimated

(individual county ratios were available for approximately 80 counties). An overall

average is used (following iFARM calculator algorithm) with sensitivity tests

performed around that value to illustrate the sensitivity of the results to that estimate

of relative farm variability. For Illinois, the multiplier was equal to 1.245, suggesting

that farm yields are on average 1.245 times more variable than county yields (the

same value is used in iFARM).

10 The choice of distribution is based on Sherrick et al. (2004) who suggested several

useful properties of the Weibull distribution for modeling crop yields including its

flexible non-symmetry, zero limit, and wide range of skewness and kurtosis.

32

11 @Risk is an “add-in” to Microsoft Excel; it has capabilities to model simulations

in Excel using Monte Carlo and Latin Hypercube sampling methods for any

specified parametric/non-parametric distribution.

12 Carriquiry et al. (2005) and others used the same number of iterations.

13 These six counties represent conditions in the north, center, and the south parts of

the state. The state averages were derived by weighting county data by percentage of

acres planted in the county in relation to the state

14 RMA publishes technical coefficients by county, but does not make public any

other ratings information. This allows rate quoting, but does not allow the

identification of how the technical coefficients would be affected by different

histories, nor provides a direct analytic method for relating items such as “bias” to a

pricing effect.

15 A maximum level of coverage (0.85) was chosen to illustrate the differences, the

premiums across coverage levels increase almost linearly.

33

Figures and Tables

0

10

20

30

40

50

110 120 130 140 150 160 170 180 190 200 210

Mean (bu/acre)

4 Year APH

10 year APH

True St.Dev

True Mean

10 year APH Mean =164 bu/acre 4 year APH Mean =167 bu/acre

St.Dev 10 Year APH = 24 bu/acre

St.Dev 4 Year APH = 22 bu/acre

Figure 1.1. Simulated 4 and 10 year APH yields (Christian County, IL, corn yield distribution for 2006, true (expected) mean of 174 bu and standard deviation of 24 bu, 5,000 iterations)

34

Figure 1.2. Steps in empirical model

Step 1: NASS county yields detrended using linear trend. Standard deviation and mean are calculated for each county

Step 2: Scaler (ratio of farm level variability to county level variability) is calculated using FBFM yields and standard deviations from Step 1 are multiplied by the scaler.

Step 3: Weibull distribution is fitted using means from step 1 and standard deviations from step 2 and method of moments is used to estimate representative “ true” farm- level yield distribution

Step 4: Trend is reapplied to the representative yield distributions. True probabilities are calculated by using mean of representative yield distribution times coverage level.

Step 5: APH implied probabilities are calculated by simulating yields and calculating 4- 10 years APHmean times coverage level.

Step 7: RMA ’ spremiums are calculated by feeding true and APH means through RMA ’ s premium structure. Contract price of $4.50/bu is assumed.

Step 6: Actuarial costs are calculated by simulating yields and using APH and true means as strikes. Contract price of $4.50/bu is assumed.

35

Figure 1.3. Representative case farm and APH based corn yield distributions for 2006 (Adams County, corn)

0

0.002

0.004

0.006

0.008

0.01

0.012

0.014

0.016

0.018

0.02

1 51 101 151 201 Yield (bu/acre)

Probability

True Yield Distribution 10-Year APH Yield Distribution Indemnity under 10-Year APH - 0.85 Coverage

Bias

36

APH yield 168 bu/ac

coverage level 85 %

indemnity price 4.50$ /bu

basic/optional 0.9 (.9 = basic, 1 = optional)

1. Calculate guarantee per acre

aph yield x coverage level

168 0.85 142.8

2. Calculate premium guarantee

premium guarantee x acres =

142.8 100 14280

3. Calculate premium liability

premium guarantee x price election x share

14280 4.5 1 64260

4. Calculate current year's yield ratio (rounded to 2 decimal places)

approved APH yield / Reference yield

168 125 1.34

5. Calculate the current year's continuous rate

1. Current year yield ratio** current year exponent

1.34 -1.926 0.5691099

2. 1's answer x current year reference rate + fixed rate load

0.5691099 0.038 0.023 0.0446262

9. Determine the preliminary base rate

lower of 5, 6, or 8 0.0446262

10. Adjusted base rate

preliminary base rate x adjustments

0.0446262 1 0.0446262

11. Calculate the base premium rate

adjusted base rate x coverage level

0.0446262 1.703 1.22 0.092718

12. Calculate the total premium

premium liability x base rate x unit factor x optional coverage factor

64260 0.092718 0.9 1 5362

13. Calculate subsidy

total premium x subsidy factor

5362 0.38 2038

14. Calculate producer premium

total premium - subsidy

5362 2038 3324

premium per acre 33.24

Figure 1.4. Illustration of premium calculation using RMA’s pricing algorithm (RMA’s black box) for a hypothetical corn farm in Adams County, Illinois

37

Tab

le1.1

. D

iffe

rence

s in

pro

bab

ilitie

s under

tru

e an

d A

PH

rule

s an

d m

iscl

assi

fica

tion r

ates

for

sele

cted

counties

in I

llin

ois

(co

rn)

County

Coverage

Levels

True

Proba

APH

implied

probb

Prob

Ratioc

Participation Prob

APH

implied

prob

Prob

Ratio

Participation

Prob

APH

implied

prob

Prob

Ratio

Participation Prob

Base Period

4 Years

7 Years

10 Years

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

Chri

stia

n

0.5

5

0.3

5

0.3

0

85.1

8

31.6

3

0.2

4

69.7

5

16.3

1

0.2

1

59.2

0

6.0

3

Tre

nd =

1.7

7 b

u/a

cre

0.6

0.7

3

0.6

3

85.1

5

31.6

3

0.5

1

69.7

7

16.3

1

0.4

4

59.2

4

6.0

3

Mea

n=

174 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

1.4

6

1.2

5

85.1

1

31.6

3

1.0

2

69.8

1

16.3

1

0.8

7

59.3

1

6.0

3

St.D

ev=

24 b

u/a

cre

0.7

2.7

6

2.3

5

85.0

4

31.6

3

1.9

3

69.8

8

16.3

1

1.6

4

59.4

3

6.0

3

0.7

5

4.9

6

4.2

1

84.9

1

31.6

3

3.4

7

70.0

1

16.3

1

2.9

6

59.6

4

6.0

3

0.8

8.5

2

7.2

1

84.7

2

31.6

3

5.9

8

70.2

2

16.3

1

5.1

1

60.0

0

6.0

3

0.8

5

13.9

7

11.7

9

84.4

3

31.6

3

9.8

6

70.5

7

16.3

1

8.4

6

60.5

7

6.0

3

Jeff

erso

n

0.5

5

3.0

5

2.8

1

91.9

7

36.5

9

2.4

4

80.0

8

25.4

3

2.1

8

71.3

1

14.7

5

Tre

nd =

1.3

0 b

u/a

cre

0.6

4.7

1

4.3

3

91.8

0

36.5

9

3.7

7

80.1

0

25.4

3

3.3

6

71.4

2

14.7

5

Mea

n=

111 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

7.0

0

6.4

1

91.5

7

36.5

9

5.6

1

80.1

4

25.4

3

5.0

1

71.5

8

14.7

5

St.D

ev=

25 b

u/a

cre

0.7

10.0

4

9.1

6

91.2

7

36.5

9

8.0

5

80.2

0

25.4

3

7.2

1

71.8

0

14.7

5

0.7

5

13.9

6

12.6

9

90.9

0

36.5

9

11.2

1

80.2

8

25.4

3

10.0

6

72.0

9

14.7

5

0.8

18.8

5

17.0

5

90.4

4

36.5

9

15.1

6

80.3

9

25.4

3

13.6

6

72.4

8

14.7

5

0.8

5

24.7

6

22.2

6

89.9

3

36.5

9

19.9

5

80.5

6

25.4

3

18.0

7

72.9

8

14.7

5

La

Sal

le

0.5

5

0.4

3

0.3

7

87.2

9

31.8

2

0.3

1

71.9

8

17.8

5

0.2

6

61.5

3

6.8

8

Tre

nd =

1.5

5 b

u/a

cre

0.6

0.8

8

0.7

6

87.2

6

31.8

2

0.6

3

72.0

0

17.8

5

0.5

4

61.5

7

6.8

8

Mea

n=

156 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

1.7

0

1.4

8

87.1

9

31.8

2

1.2

2

72.0

4

17.8

5

1.0

5

61.6

4

6.8

8

St.D

ev=

22 b

u/a

cre

0.7

3.1

2

2.7

2

87.0

7

31.8

2

2.2

5

72.1

1

17.8

5

1.9

3

61.7

7

6.8

8

0.7

5

5.4

7

4.7

5

86.8

9

31.8

2

3.9

5

72.2

2

17.8

5

3.3

9

61.9

9

6.8

8

0.8

9.1

8

7.9

5

86.6

0

31.8

2

6.6

5

72.4

1

17.8

5

5.7

2

62.3

4

6.8

8

0.8

5

14.7

4

12.7

0

86.1

9

31.8

2

10.7

2

72.7

1

17.8

5

9.2

7

62.9

0

6.8

8

Lee

0.5

5

0.3

5

0.2

9

81.6

4

28.7

4

0.2

3

65.5

2

12.5

3

0.1

9

54.4

4

3.6

8

Tre

nd =

1.8

9 b

u/a

cre

0.6

0.7

4

0.6

0

81.6

3

28.7

4

0.4

9

65.5

5

12.5

3

0.4

0

54.4

8

3.6

8

Mea

n=

163 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

1.4

7

1.2

0

81.6

0

28.7

4

0.9

7

65.6

0

12.5

3

0.8

0

54.5

5

3.6

8

St.D

ev=

22 b

u/a

cre

0.7

2.7

8

2.2

6

81.5

4

28.7

4

1.8

2

65.6

9

12.5

3

1.5

2

54.6

9

3.6

8

0.7

5

4.9

8

4.0

6

81.4

6

28.7

4

3.2

8

65.8

4

12.5

3

2.7

4

54.9

2

3.6

8

0.8

8.5

4

6.9

5

81.3

3

28.7

4

5.6

5

66.1

0

12.5

3

4.7

3

55.3

0

3.6

8

0.8

5

14.0

0

11.3

6

81.1

5

28.7

4

9.3

1

66.5

2

12.5

3

7.8

3

55.9

2

3.6

8

a D

enote

s pro

bab

ility o

f re

achin

g a

par

ticu

lar

yie

ld lev

el o

bta

ined

under

far

m-l

evel

rep

rese

nta

tive

“tru

e dis

trib

ution.”

bD

enote

s pro

bab

ilit

y o

f re

achin

g a

par

ticu

lar

yie

ld lev

el o

bta

ined

under

giv

en A

PH

yie

ld.

c Den

ote

s pro

port

ion o

f ti

mes

in s

imula

tion the

true

yie

ld p

robab

ilit

y w

as s

mal

ler

than

the

corr

espondin

g A

PH

yie

ld p

robab

ilit

y.

37

38

Tab

le 1

.1. V

alues

for

the

dif

fere

nce

and r

atio

bet

wee

n e

stim

ated

and tru

e pro

bab

ilitie

s, a

nd p

osi

tive

mis

clas

sifi

cation (

corn

) (c

onti

nued

) County

Coverage Levels True Proba

APH

implied

probb

Prob

Ratioc Participation Prob

APH

implied

prob

Prob

Ratio Participation Prob

APH

implied

prob

Prob

Ratio Participation Prob

Base Period

4 Years

7 Years

10 Years

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

%

Mac

on

0.5

5

0.6

8

0.5

9

87.7

0

33.2

1

0.4

9

72.7

8

18.7

2

0.4

2

62.5

4

7.8

8

Tre

nd =

1.8

6 b

u/a

cre

0.6

1.3

0

1.1

4

87.6

5

33.2

1

0.9

5

72.8

1

18.7

2

0.8

1

62.6

0

7.8

8

Mea

n=

177 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

2.3

7

2.0

7

87.5

7

33.2

1

1.7

2

72.8

6

18.7

2

1.4

8

62.6

9

7.8

8

St.D

ev=

28 b

u/a

cre

0.7

4.1

1

3.5

9

87.4

3

33.2

1

3.0

0

72.9

4

18.7

2

2.5

8

62.8

5

7.8

8

0.7

5

6.8

2

5.9

5

87.2

2

33.2

1

4.9

8

73.0

7

18.7

2

4.3

0

63.1

0

7.8

8

0.8

10.8

7

9.4

5

86.9

2

33.2

1

7.9

7

73.2

7

18.7

2

6.9

0

63.4

9

7.8

8

0.8

5

16.6

4

14.4

0

86.5

2

33.2

1

12.2

5

73.5

8

18.7

2

10.6

6

64.0

7

7.8

8

Ogle

0.5

5

0.3

8

0.3

1

83.0

1

30.1

1

0.2

5

67.1

1

13.8

5

0.2

1

56.0

4

4.1

2

Tre

nd =

1.8

1 b

u/a

cre

0.6

0.7

9

0.6

5

82.9

9

30.1

1

0.5

3

67.1

4

13.8

5

0.4

4

56.0

8

4.1

2

Mea

n=

160 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

1.5

5

1.2

9

82.9

5

30.1

1

1.0

4

67.1

8

13.8

5

0.8

7

56.1

6

4.1

2

St.D

ev=

22 b

u/a

cre

0.7

2.9

0

2.4

0

82.8

9

30.1

1

1.9

5

67.2

7

13.8

5

1.6

3

56.2

9

4.1

2

0.7

5

5.1

6

4.2

7

82.7

8

30.1

1

3.4

8

67.4

1

13.8

5

2.9

2

56.5

2

4.1

2

0.8

8.7

7

7.2

5

82.6

2

30.1

1

5.9

4

67.6

6

13.8

5

4.9

9

56.9

0

4.1

2

0.8

5

14.2

7

11.7

6

82.3

9

30.1

1

9.7

1

68.0

5

13.8

5

8.2

1

57.5

2

4.1

2

Sta

ted

0.5

5

2.4

0

2.1

9

88.2

3

33.5

5

1.9

3

74.4

7

20.4

6

1.7

4

64.8

2

10.1

5

Tre

nd =

1.6

8 b

u/a

cre

0.6

3.5

5

3.1

9

88.1

2

33.5

5

2.8

0

74.5

0

20.4

6

2.5

1

64.9

1

10.1

5

Mea

n =

125 b

u/a

cre

0.6

5

5.1

9

4.6

0

87.9

8

33.5

5

4.0

3

74.5

5

20.4

6

3.6

1

65.0

3

10.1

5

St.D

ev =

24 b

u/a

cre

0.7

7.5

0

6.5

8

87.7

9

33.5

5

5.7

5

74.6

2

20.4

6

5.1

3

65.2

1

10.1

5

0.7

5

10.6

8

9.3

1

87.5

3

33.5

5

8.1

3

74.7

4

20.4

6

7.2

4

65.4

7

10.1

5

0.8

14.9

8

13.0

0

87.2

0

33.5

5

11.3

6

74.9

2

20.4

6

10.1

2

65.8

5

10.1

5

0.8

5

20.6

7

18.8

6

86.8

0

33.5

5

15.6

5

75.1

9

20.4

6

13.9

5

66.4

0

10.1

5

a D

enote

s pro

bab

ilit

y o

f re

achin

g a

par

ticu

lar

yie

ld lev

el o

bta

ined

under

far

m-l

evel

rep

rese

nta

tive

“tru

e dis

trib

ution.”

bD

enote

s pro

bab

ilit

y o

f re

achin

g a

par

ticu

lar

yie

ld lev

el o

bta

ined

under

giv

en A

PH

yie

ld).

c D

enote

s pro

port

ion o

f ti

mes

in s

imula

tion the

true

yie

ld p

robab

ilit

y w

as s

mal

ler

than

the

corr

espondin

g A

PH

yie

ld p

robab

ilit

y.

dSta

te a

ver

ages

wer

e der

ived

by w

eighti

ng c

ounty

dat

a by p

erce

nta

ge

of

acre

s pla

nte

d in the

county

to s

tate

.

38

39

T

able

1.2

. Sim

ula

ted R

MA

pre

miu

m v

alues

for

sele

cted

counti

es (

bef

ore

subsi

die

s)

County

Coverage

Levels

Trend

True

Prob

APH

(bu)

RMA

Prem

($)

APH

(bu)

RMA

Prem

($)

APH

(bu)

RMA

Prem

($)

True

APH

(bu)

True

RMA

Prem

($)

Base Period

4 Years

7 Years

10 Years

Chri

stia

n

0.8

5

1.7

7

14

167

29.3

6

165

29.4

8

162

29.6

3

174

28.8

7

Jeff

erso

n

0.8

5

1.3

25

107

53.9

3

105

54.0

5

103

54.3

6

111

52.4

3

La

Sal

le

0.8

5

1.5

5

15

150

34.2

0

148

34.2

5

146

34.3

6

156

33.8

0

Lee

0.8

5

1.8

9

14

156

30.8

5

153

30.9

4

150

31.1

0

163

30.5

3

Mac

on

0.8

5

1.8

6

17

170

28.6

7

167

28.7

3

164

28.8

7

177

27.9

9

Ogle

0.8

5

1.8

1

14

154

33.8

9

151

33.9

8

148

34.0

9

160

33.5

3

Sta

tea

0.8

5

1.6

8

21

141

37.9

6

139

38.0

0

136

38.1

6

147

37.2

6

a Sta

te a

ver

ages

wer

e der

ived

by w

eighting c

ounty

dat

a by p

erce

nta

ge

of

acre

s pla

nte

d in the

county

to

sta

te.

39

40

Tab

le 1

.3.S

imula

ted a

ctuar

ial in

sura

nce

cost

s fo

r se

lect

ed I

llin

ois

counties

County

Coverage

Levels

Trend

True

Prob

APH

(bu)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

APH

(bu)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

APH

(bu)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

True

APH

(bu)

True

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Base Period

4 Years

7 Years

10 Years

Chri

stia

n

0.8

5

1.7

7

14

167

7.1

1

165

6.1

2

163

5.2

4

174

9.9

9

Jeff

erso

n

0.8

5

1.3

25

107

14.5

4

105

13.0

5

103

11.7

0

111

18.4

7

La

Sal

le

0.8

5

1.5

5

15

150

7.1

3

148

6.2

1

146

5.3

8

156

9.8

1

Lee

0.8

5

1.8

9

14

156

6.3

7

154

5.3

6

150

4.5

0

163

9.4

1

Mac

on

0.8

5

1.8

6

17

170

10.0

8

167

8.7

8

165

7.6

3

177

13.7

5

Ogle

0.8

5

1.8

1

14

154

6.5

7

151

5.5

8

148

4.7

0

160

9.5

4

Sta

tea

0.8

5

1.6

8

21

141

12.6

7

139

11.2

3

136

9.9

2

147

16.6

7

a Sta

te a

ver

ages

wer

e der

ived

by w

eighting c

ounty

dat

a by p

erce

nta

ge

of

acre

s pla

nte

d in the

county

in r

elat

ion to s

tate

.

40

41

Tab

le 1

.4. Sim

ula

ted R

MA

pre

miu

ms

and a

ctuar

ial co

sts

for

sele

cted

counties

County

RMA

Prem

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

RMA

Prem

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

RMA

Prem

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

RMA

Prem

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

Base Period

4

7

10

True

Chri

stia

n

29.3

6

7.1

1

4.1

29.4

8

6.1

2

4.8

29.6

3

5.2

4

5.7

28.8

7

9.9

9

2.9

Jeff

erso

n

53.9

3

14.5

4

3.7

54.0

5

13.0

5

4.1

54.3

6

11.7

0

4.6

52.4

3

18.4

7

2.8

La

Sal

le

34.2

0

7.1

3

4.8

34.2

5

6.2

1

5.5

34.3

6

5.3

8

6.4

33.8

0

9.8

1

3.4

Lee

30.8

5

6.3

7

4.8

30.9

4

5.3

6

5.8

31.1

0

4.5

0

6.9

30.5

3

9.4

1

3.2

Mac

on

28.6

7

10.0

8

2.8

28.7

3

8.7

8

3.3

28.8

7

7.6

3

3.8

27.9

9

13.7

5

2.0

Ogle

33.8

9

6.5

7

5.2

33.9

8

5.5

8

6.1

34.0

9

4.7

0

7.2

33.5

3

9.5

4

3.5

Sta

tea

37.9

6

12.6

7

3.0

38.0

0

11.2

3

3.4

38.1

6

9.9

2

3.8

37.2

6

16.6

7

2.2

a S

tate

aver

ages

wer

e der

ived

by w

eighting c

ounty

dat

a by p

erce

nta

ge

of

acre

s pla

nte

d in the

county

to s

tate

.

41

42

Tab

le 1

.5. Sim

ula

ted R

MA

pre

miu

ms

wit

hout ca

tast

rophic

load

ing f

or

sele

cted

counties

County

RMA

Prem,

no Cat.

Load ($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

RMA

Prem,

no Cat.

Load

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

RMA

Prem,

no Cat.

Load

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

RMA

Prem,

no Cat.

Load

($)

Actuarial

Cost ($)

Ratio

Base

Period

4

7

10

True

Chri

stia

n

14.8

7

7.1

1

2.1

15.2

1

6.1

2

2.5

15.5

9

5.2

4

3.0

13.8

6

9.9

9

1.4

Jeff

erso

n

36.3

2

14.5

4

2.5

36.7

9

13.0

5

2.8

37.4

0

11.7

0

3.2

34.2

9

18.4

7

1.9

La

Sal

le

17.9

1

7.1

3

2.5

18.2

3

6.2

1

2.9

18.5

6

5.3

8

3.5

16.9

2

9.8

1

1.7

Lee

16.2

0

6.3

7

2.5

16.5

6

5.3

6

3.1

16.9

9

4.5

0

3.8

15.2

6

9.4

1

1.6

Mac

on

15.2

1

10.0

8

1.5

15.5

0

8.7

8

1.8

15.8

9

7.6

3

2.1

14.0

4

13.7

5

1.0

Ogle

17.2

6

6.5

7

2.6

17.6

2

5.5

8

3.2

18.0

5

4.7

0

3.8

16.2

0

9.5

4

1.7

Sta

tea

22.2

8

12.6

7

1.8

22.6

1

11.2

3

2.0

23.0

9

9.9

2

2.3

20.0

0

16.6

7

1.2

a S

tate

aver

ages

wer

e der

ived

by w

eighting c

ounty

dat

a by p

erce

nta

ge

of

acre

s pla

nte

d in the

county

to s

tate

.

42

43

T

able

1.6

. T

rend a

dju

sted

APH

im

pli

ed y

ield

, pro

bab

ility, pre

miu

ms,

and a

ctuar

ial co

sts

Trend

Yield (bu)

Yield Implied Prob (%)

RMA Premiums ($)

Actuarial Cost ($)

(bu)

APH 4

APH

Adj.

Yield

b

True

APH 4

APH

Adj.

Yield

True

APH

4

APH

Adj.

Yield

True

APH

4

APH

Adj.

Yield

True

Chri

stia

n

1.7

7

167

171

174

12

14

14

29.3

6

29.1

2

28.8

7

7.1

1

9.2

0

9.9

9

Jeff

erso

n

1.3

107

110

111

22

25

25

53.9

3

53.3

9

52.4

3

14.5

4

18.7

9

18.4

7

La

Sal

le

1.5

5

150

154

156

13

15

15

34.2

0

34.0

2

33.8

0

7.1

3

9.1

1

9.8

1

Lee

1.8

9

156

161

163

11

14

14

30.8

5

30.6

2

30.5

3

6.3

7

8.0

3

9.4

1

Mac

on

1.8

6

170

175

177

14

17

17

28.6

7

28.4

0

27.9

9

10.0

8

12.7

8

13.7

5

Ogle

1.8

1

154

159

160

12

15

14

33.8

9

33.7

1

33.5

3

6.5

7

8.8

4

9.5

4

Sta

te

1.6

8

141

145

147

19

20

21

37.9

6

37.4

4

37.2

6

12.6

7

15.2

3

16.6

7

a S

tate

aver

ages

wer

e der

ived

by w

eighting c

ounty

dat

a by p

erce

nta

ge

of

acre

s pla

nte

d in the

county

to s

tate

.

bA

dju

sted

for

tren

d u

sing

(1)

/2n

β−

+, w

her

e n

is

num

ber

of

yea

rs in A

PH

bas

e per

iod, an

d β

is

yie

ld tre

nd.

43

44

Table 1.7. True and APH implied probabilities for different scaler values for APH period of 10 years and 0.85 coverage level

Scaler

1 1.15 1.2 1.245 1.3 1.35

Christian 52% 57% 59% 66% 62% 63%

Jefferson 66% 71% 72% 73% 74% 75%

La Salle 54% 60% 62% 63% 64% 66%

Lee 47% 53% 55% 56% 58% 59%

Macon 56% 61% 63% 64% 66% 67%

Ogle 49% 54% 56% 58% 59% 61%

Statea 56% 61% 63% 64% 65% 67% aState averages were derived by weighting county data by percentage of acres planted in the county state.

45

CHAPTER 2

Crop Insurance Usage in Lake Woebegone

Abstract

This paper assesses the extent of expression of a “Better Than Average”

(BTA) effect and the relationship between stated beliefs and implied

economic decisions by examining yield expectations elicited under two

different conceptual constructs from a sample of soybean producers. Using

simple risk measures and constructed proxies for the BTA effect, we

examined these effects in crop insurance demand models. The results

indicate the presence of the BTA effect; however, the demand model results

suggest that these biases are not likely to strongly influence the demand for

the insurance.

U.S. farmers have demonstrated a reluctance to purchase crop insurance unless

substantial premium subsidies are provided. Some researchers have argued that the

relationship between insurance and other risk management tools could explain the

need to offer subsidies to induce participation (Mahul and Wright, 2003); others have

cited the presence of large ad-hoc disaster payments and other forms of implicit

insurance against low incomes offered by government programs as explanation for

low participation (Van Asseldonk, Miranda, and Ruud 2002). However, the

relationship between subjective perceptions and decision to buy crop insurance has

not been extensively studied (Sherrick 2002; Egelkraut, Sherrick, Garcia, and

Pennings 2006a). A careful analysis of the farmers’ subjective perceptions is very

important for several reasons. Crop insurance is largely rated using county-level

yield data and minimal individual experiences. If a farmer does not possess well-

calibrated beliefs, he might perceive such crop insurance as mispriced. Such biased

perceptions may influence farmers’ participation decisions and could explain some

farmers’ reluctance to participate in crop insurance program. The paper investigates

whether yield risk perceptions influence farmers’ participation in crop insurance

46

program on an individual producer level. The study examines alternate measures of

risk and tests for impacts of these perceptions on crop insurance decisions, in the

presence of risk management alternatives.

Researchers in psychology have identified a number of misperceptions

(departures from reality) and heuristics (simplifications of reality) that individuals

tend to display in complex or uncertain decision-making situations. One recently

formalized misperception is known as the “better than average” (BTA) effect. The

BTA effect refers to an individual’s propensity to “judge themselves as better than

others with regard to skills or positive personality attributes.” The BTA effect occurs

particularly in situations where the individual believes his actions directly affect

outcomes (Glaser and Weber, 2003). Another bias is miscalibration which defined

as “an individual’s tendency to overestimate the precision of personal information”

(Biais, Hilton, Pouget and Mazurier, 2003). Lichtenstein, Fischhoff, and Phillips

(1982) provide a detailed overview of miscalibration and cite numerous examples

across professions. For example, they indicate that one of the few well-calibrated

professions seemed to be meteorology, although information that is available is

sometimes altered in presentation to mitigate asymmetric penalties for better or

worse than forecasted weather. Lichtenstein, Fischhoff, and Phillips argue that two

reasons could explain good calibration displayed by meteorologists: 1) repetitive

judgments and 2) regular, fast, and clear feedback.

The environment in which a farmer operates and makes decisions is likely to

promote both miscalibration and a BTA effect. For example, the actual yield

(feedback) is likely to be distant in time and influenced by weather and other

47

variables, thus not being clear or fast. Also, it is not unusual for a farmer to think that

his farming skills can influence yields. Such attitudes are likely to promote the BTA

effect. Despite growing evidence in the behavioral finance literature about the role

and the influence these misperceptions play in decision-making, few studies in the

agricultural economics literature analyze interactions between the crop insurance

participation and the misperceptions. One study by Egelkraut, Sherrick, Garcia, and

Pennings (2006b), found a negative relationship between the BTA effect and

likelihood of crop insurance purchase. Also, Eales, Engle, Hauser, and Thompson

(1991) found that farmers tend to underestimate the volatility of the futures and

options prices, and Sherrick (2002) showed that farmers maintained systematically

miscalibrated beliefs concerning precipitation. However, none of these papers

considered the relationship between the participation decision and misperceptions in

the presence of other risk management tools, a situation that a farmer faces.

The specific objective of the paper is to provide an assessment of the extent of

the BTA effect and miscalibration for the sample of soybean producers in Indiana,

Illinois, and Iowa, and to evaluate the effect of risk perceptions and other risk

management options on insurance purchasing decisions. The participants of the

study are commercial-scale farms, who are also likely to be intimately informed

about crop insurance. The analysis is conducted using data from the Crop Yield Risk

Survey (CYRS), conducted in 2002 covering corn and soybean producers in Iowa,

Illinois, and Indiana.

Along with demographic, business, and other information, the survey elicited

two separate measures of subjective yields. Yield perceptions were elicited directly

48

(by asking farmers to indicate their average yield and yield variability in relation to

the average county yield) and indirectly (by asking farmers to attach probabilities to

a sequence of yield intervals). The survey also elicited a likelihood of getting a crop

insurance payment and had extensive documentation of actual crop insurance

purchases and preferences for other risk management tools. In the analysis, the

elicited subjective yield measures were related to the county yields (estimated using

NASS county-level data). A regression analysis was conducted to examine the effect

of risk perceptions on insurance purchasing decisions on the individual product level

(yield insurance, revenue insurance, and CAT) and across insurance products.

The paper’s contributions are as follows. First, the study complements a

growing body of literature that analyzes interactions between risk perceptions and

financial decision making (in the context of crop insurance). Second, the study’s

results help in understanding the role of subjective perceptions in farmer insurance

decisions, which in turn will help design better crop insurance products, more

efficient crop insurance program, and highlight the need for an accurate

understanding of actual risks faced.

Background and Literature Review

The farm characteristics that might affect demand for crop insurance have been

examined extensively in the literature. For example, Smith and Baquet (1996) have

examined factors that influence demand for crop insurance using farm-level dataset

from a sample of wheat producers in Montana. They modeled participation decision

as two-step process; in the first step a farmer decides whether to purchase insurance

and (assuming the farmer has decided to purchase crop insurance) in the second step

49

a farmer chooses a coverage level. The results indicated that education, presence of

debt, perceived importance of yield variability, increased the probability of

participation and coverage level, and premium rates. Coble, Knight, Pope, and

Williams (1996) analyzed participation decisions of Kansas wheat farmers, where

they used participation decision as the dependent variable and farm-level data to

identify the variables that contributed to the probability of purchase. Results

indicated that returns from crop insurance increase the probability of purchase and

the variance of the return decreases likelihood of use of crop insurance. The market

returns from operations decreased purchase probability while the variance of market

returns increased it. Both net worth and diversification were likely to decrease the

probability of purchase. Sherrick, Barry, Ellinger, and Schnitkey (2004b) used

survey data, and modeled farmers’ participation decisions as a two-step choice. In

the first stage a farmer decides whether to insure or not, and in the second the

farmers makes a choice between yield insurance, revenue insurance, and or hail

insurance. The results indicated that size, age, leverage, greater share of leased land,

higher level of perceived risk, higher subjective yields, and a greater perceived

importance of risk management tools were likely to contribute to the probability of

insurance purchase. Overall, the econometric results of the demand for crop

insurance studies indicate that size is likely to increase participation, diversification

is likely to decrease participation, and higher yield/income variability is likely to

increase participation as well.

The role of farmers’ perceptions in the crop insurance decision has limited

presence in the literature. Sherrick et al.(2004b) using survey data analyzed demand

50

for crop insurance products found a significant and positive relationship between

decision to participate and subjective mean, indicating that producers with higher

mean yields are more likely to purchase insurance. They also document the roles of

education, size, tenure, and subjective means (estimated from indirectly elicited

subjective yield distributions) as a proxy for differences in soil quality or

management skills. However, Sherrick et al. (2004b) did not consider the impact of

miscalibration and the BTA effect. Shaik, Coble, and Knight (2005) elicited

subjective estimates of mean and variability for yield and price and also proxies for

risk aversion. Unlike Sherrick, Barry, Ellinger, and Schnitkey (2004b), they found a

negative and significant relationship between the subjective mean yield and the

participation decision, and a positive relationship between the participation and

subjective yield variability. For revenue insurance, the results indicated a negative

and significant relationship for subjective mean and a positive significant

relationship for the subjective yield variability. Shaik, Coble and Knight (2005) did

not consider the impact of the BTA effect on the crop insurance. Egelkraut et al.

(2006) investigated the influence of subjective perceptions on the producers’ crop

insurance decision using a dataset from a similar survey with responses from 258

Illinois corn producers. They elicited subjective yield perceptions using the

conviction weights approach (indirectly), and directly, by asking respondents open-

ended questions about farms’ yield level and variability in relation to an average

county farm. They used directly elicited yield perceptions as independent variables

in the regression analysis to explain the demand for crop insurance. The results from

the regression analysis indicated that farmers’ perceptions affected crop insurance, as

51

coefficients for the direct estimates for the mean yield and variability were

significant with expected signs. Egelkraut et al. (2006) did not consider the impact of

miscalibration on the participation decisions. Also, they did not consider the

influence of the BTA effect on the participation decisions in the presence of risk

management alternatives.

This paper continues investigating the role of cognitive biases on crop

insurance decisions by including information on alternative risk management tools

usage and miscalibration, in addition to the variables that were used in the previous

research. The inclusion of information on alternative risk management tools in the

analysis is relevant because when a farmer makes a decision regarding participation

she considers alternatives as well, so these alternatives should be included. Similarly,

as indicated by some of the findings, miscalibration and the BTA effect might

influence decision making. By adding these variables into the analysis, this paper

further contributes to the growing body of research and improves our understanding

of the producers’ perceptions and the role these perceptions play in decision making.

Survey

The study uses data from the crop yield risk survey (CYRS) conducted at the

University of Illinois under a cooperative agreement with the Economic Research

Service USDA and supported by the Risk Management Agency of USDA.

The mailing list used in the survey consisted of 3,000 farms from Illinois,

Indiana, and Iowa, purchased from “Progressive Farmer”, a company specializing in

communication with agricultural producers. Because the sample selected for the

survey was meant to be representative of large-scale, commercial farms, farms with

52

at least 100 acres or greater were selected. During the survey-formulation stage, two

focus groups with farmers were held by an independent market research firm; the

survey was reviewed by University of Illinois staff and economist from ERS USDA;

it also was pretested with a set of farmers who participate in the FBFM record

keeping association; and it was evaluated and tested by the Survey Design Research

Lab at the University of Illinois. The survey was mailed on March 2001 with a cover

letter, that stated the purpose, confidentiality, completion instructions, contact

information for any questions, and an honor payment for $3.00 to be cashed

conditional upon successful completion and mailing of the survey. The survey

included sections on demographic and business information, risk management; risk

perceptions, the conjoint ranking of insurance products and attributes, and other

related information (see Barry, Ellinger, Schnitkey, Sherrick, and Wansink 2002 for

more details about the survey and overall projects).

Indirect Yield Elicitation

The survey elicited subjective yields under two conceptually very different

constructs. Indirectly, the survey asked individuals to assign probabilities into

predefined yield categories (for an example see figure 2.1). The sum of the intervals

was stated as 100%, requiring respondents’ stated probabilities to add up to 100%.

This probabilistic approach, known as the conviction weights approach (Norris and

Cramer 1994), was employed by Bessler (1980) and Eales et al. (1990) as a means of

eliciting probabilistic beliefs by producers.

53

Direct Yield Elicitation

Yields also were elicited directly by asking respondents to indicate whether their

average farm yields are greater/smaller/same as their county average and whether

their farm yields experience greater/smaller/same degree of variability.16 If a farmer

indicated that his yield is smaller/greater than the county average, the survey asked

farmers to state the difference (in bushels) between county average and farm average.

Methods

Indirectly Elicited Subjective Yields

The survey elicited a subjective yield distribution by asking respondents to assign

probabilities to the yield intervals. These discrete probabilities were used to

parameterize subjective yield distributions by fitting a distribution using equation

(1):

( ) [ ]( )7 2 22

1 1 1 8 8

2

min ( ( | )) ( | ) ( | ) 1 ( | )i

i i ij j i j i i i

j

p D U p D U D U p D Uθ

θ θ θ θ−=

− + − − + − −

(1)

Where pij - producer i stated probability for interval j

Uij – upper bound of the interval

D(.) – cumulative distribution of farm-level yields

iθ - set of i two dimensional parameters for producer i’s subjective yield

distribution

The Weibull distribution as parametric form was chosen because Sherrick et al.

(2004a) suggested several of its useful properties for modeling crop yields including

54

its non-symmetry, zero limit, and wide range of skewness and kurtosis. The CDF of

the Weibull has the following functional form:

( ) 1 0 x< , , 0

i

i

x

i iF x e

− = − ≤ ∞ >

α

β α β (2)

Objective Yields

The respondent’s typical objective yield was set equal to average county yield (and

also to state differences where relevant). Because the average is subject to historic

yield data which had a strong upward trend, to calculate the average and standard

deviation, the soybean county yields were obtained from NASS for the years 1972-

2002 and detrended to the 2002 using a linear trend at a county level (following

Sherrick et al.(2004a)).

Correspondence between Subjective Yield Perceptions and Objective Yield

Distribution

To assess the correspondence between subjective and objective yield distributions,

this paper compares directly-stated yields, indirectly-stated yields, and county yields.

T-test and Wilcox tests were conducted to examine if objective yields were

statistically different from indirectly-elicited subjective yields. If a farmer’s stated

yield differs from the objective yield, a BTA effect could be a possible explanation.

Demand for Crop Insurance

The relationship between crop insurance and misperceptions is examined in two

related steps, at individual product level, across the products. The demand for each

insurance product (yield, revenue, and CAT insurance) is analyzed separately using a

logit model to assess the influence of miscalibration and the BTA effect. The

rationale behind conducting analysis on the individual basis is to examine whether

55

the BTA effect and miscalibration influence various insurance products differently,

(i.e., misperceptions affect demand for yield insurance differently than they affect

the demand for revenue insurance). For the analysis across insurance products, the

product choices are aggregated (effectively representing the crop insurance usage

index), and the Poisson regression used to examine the relationship between key

variables and the index that represents an individual overall propensity to use crop

insurance products17.

Individual products. The relationship between biases and crop insurance for

individual products are examined separately for each crop insurance product. For

using the specifications given below yield insurance, equation (3) is estimated, for

revenue insurance, equation (4) is estimated, and for CAT insurance equation (5) is

estimated. The variables for the equations were obtained from the past studies and

will be shown in the parentheses. Since crop insurance participation decisions are

discrete, a binomial logit model was employed to analyze the relationship:

0 1 2 3 4 4 5 6YI AGE LOAN MBTA VBTA MRATIO VRATIO SIZEβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + +

7 8 9 10 11 12 13LSTOC APROB FRMS MRMS PRMS OTT EDUβ β β β β β β+ + + + + + + +

14 15 16IL IA INβ β β ε+ + + + ,

where YI denotes choice for yield insurance (binary, equals 1 if a farmer bought yield

insurance, and zero otherwise), AGE denotes producer’s age (Sherrick et al. 2004b),

LOAN is a binary variable (equals 0 if farmer has no debt, 1 otherwise) (Sherrick et

al. 2004b, various proxies used by Barnett, Skees, and Hourigan, 1990) MBTA is

mean BTA effect (discrete choice variable, equals 1 if a farmer claims his yields are

above or equal to county average, 0 if he claims they are below), VTBA is variance

BTA effect (discrete choice variable, equals 1 if a farmer claims his yields are less

(3)

56

variable or as variable as county average yield, 0 if he claims they are more variable),

MRATIO denotes mean miscalibration (difference between indirectly-stated

subjective mean and corresponding objective mean), VRATIO denotes variance

miscalibration (ratio of indirectly-stated subjective standard deviation divided by

objective standard deviation), SIZE is variable for farm size (in acres) (used by

Sherrick et al. 2004b, Coble et al. 1996, and Barnett, Skees, and Hourigan, 1990

among others), LSTOC is the diversification variable for livestock sales as

percentage of gross farm sales (used by Sherrick et al. 2004, and Skees, and

Hourigan, 1990, among the others), APROB denotes farmers’ probability of

receiving indemnity payments under 85% APH coverage level (used Sherrick et al.

2004b), FRMS is a discrete count variable, which denotes a combination of financial

risk management tools such as credit line, savings, government disaster payments

used by farmers to manage the risks, and etc (various proxies for disaster payments

were used by Smith and Baquet, 1996 among others), MRMS is a discrete count

variable, which denotes a combination of marketing risk management tools such as

forward contracting, usage of futures and options, etc. used by farmers to manage the

risks, PRMS is discrete count denotes combination of production risk management

tools such as farming in multiple locations, usage of multicrop enterprises, etc. used

by farmers to manage the risks (Sherrick et al. (2004b) used FRMS, MRMS, and

PRMS as a combined index denoting farmer’s usage of risk management instruments

in the past), OTT is ratio of owned acres to total acres (various proxies for tenure

were used by Goodwin (1994) and Sherrick et al. (2004b)), EDU is a discrete count

variable, denotes farmers’ education level (equals 1 if farmer completed high school,

57

2 completed some college, 3 college graduate, and 4 if farmer has graduate degree)

(used by Sherrick et al.(2004b)), Smith and Baquet (1996), and IL, IA, and IN denote

binary variables for location (equals 1 if farm is located in corresponding state and 0

otherwise).

To examine the relationship between revenue insurance and the biases

equation (4) is estimated as:

0 1 2 3 4 4 5 6RI AGE LOAN MBTA VBTA MRATIO VRATIO SIZEβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + +

7 8 9 10 11 12 13LSTOC APROB FRMS MRMS PRMS OTT EDUβ β β β β β β+ + + + + + + +

14 15 16IL IA INβ β β ε+ + + + , (4)

where RI denotes choice for revenue insurance (binary, equals 1 if a farmer bought

revenue insurance, and zero otherwise).

Similarly, the relationship between CAT insurance and the biases is

examined by estimating equation (5)

0 1 2 3 4 4 5 6CAT AGE LOAN MBTA VBTA MDIFF VDIFF SIZEβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + +

7 8 9 10 11 12 13LSTOC APROB FRMS MRMS PRMS OTT EDUβ β β β β β β+ + + + + + + +

14 15 16IL IA INβ β β ε+ + + + , (5)

where the CAT denotes choice for catastrophic insurance (binary, equals 1 if a

farmer bought catastrophic insurance, and zero otherwise). Equations (3), (4), and

(5) are each estimated using binomial logit.

Aggregate Use. Finally to analyze aggregate use of crop insurance, the variable user

was created, which is the sum of all crop insurance products that a farmer used, and

equation (6) was estimated

58

0 1 2 3 4 4 5 6USER AGE LOAN MBTA VBTA MRATIO VRATIO SIZEβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + +

7 8 9 10 11 12 13LSTOC APROB FRMS MRMS PRMS OTT EDUβ β β β β β β+ + + + + + + +

14 15 16IL IA INβ β β ε+ + + + , (6)

where USER is the sum of all crop insurance products used by a farmer (count

variable, 0 if a farmer used no crop insurance product, 3 if a farmer used all

insurance products). Since “user” is a count variable, Poisson regression model was

used to estimate the relationship (Greene, 2004).

Expected Relationships

In this section, the expected relationship between insurance, the BTA effect,

miscalibration, and the control variables are presented and discussed. These

variables are grouped into categories corresponding to BTA characteristics,

miscalibration, personal characteristics, risk management characteristics, and farm-

level characteristics.

BTA Characteristics: It is expected that an overconfident farmer would view

premiums as being relatively expensive and, therefore, would be less likely to

purchase insurance.

Miscalibration Characteristics: The mean ratio (between implied mean of the

subjective Weibull distribution and implied mean of the objective Weibull

distributions) and standard deviation ratio (between implied standard deviation of the

subjective Weibull distribution and implied standard deviation of the objective

Weibull distribution) were included to allow the model to capture the incongruence

between subjective beliefs and empirical representations of the yields. The expected

relationship between the mean ratio and participation is negative -- if producer’s

subjective mean is smaller than the objective mean, he might think that there is a

59

good chance to receive an indemnity.18 Thus, such producer is thought to be more

likely to purchase crop insurance. Similarly, if a producer’s subjective yield

variability is greater than objective variability, then, he is more likely to participate

in insurance than a producer with lower subjective yield risk. Therefore, the

expected sign between standard deviation ratio and the participation is positive.

Personal Characteristics: Among the demographic characteristics included are age

and education. The expected relationship between insurance use and education is

positive; risk management has become significantly more complicated through time.

Furthermore, this paper postulates a positive relationship between insurance use and

age. As a farmer gets older, he is more likely to be risk averse and thus is more

likely to purchase insurance.

Risk Management Variables: Because farmers have other risk management tools

available that might act as complements or substitutes for insurance, the survey

asked subjects to indicate what risk management tools they have used in the past.

The survey listed several risk management alternatives and asked whether a

respondent used a particular risk management alternative. The alternatives were

grouped in three categories corresponding to: i) financial risk management tools

(such as government programs, financial savings/reserves, back-up credit lines); ii)

marketing risk management score (such as hedging/options, spreading sales over

time, production/marketing contracts, forward contracting); iii) and production risk

management score (such as multiple crop enterprises, crop share leases, multiple

seed varieties, farming in multiple locations). Thus, if a respondent used forward

contracting, credit lines and savings, his financial risk management score would be

60

equal to 2 (credit lines and savings), marketing risk management score would be

equal to 1 (forward contracting) and production risk management score would be

equal to 0. All farmers in the samples used at least one of the risk management

alternatives.

Farm-level Variables: Additional variables such as farm size, diversification, debt,

and wealth, were included in the analysis. Large farms tend to be better managed;

therefore, size is indicative of better management skills and possibly, economies of

scale. Large farms are likely to be more diversified. Both of factors are expected to

reduce demand for crop insurance.

Debt and insurance use might be positively correlated, as lenders often require

farmers to purchase insurance. Wealthier farmers tend to self-insure, therefore,

percentage of owned acres to total acres (a proxy for wealth) is likely to be

negatively related to insurance use. Livestock ownership is another method for a

farmer to diversify, therefore, livestock sales as a percentage of gross farm income is

likely to be negatively related to insurance. Finally, to measure the level of insurable

risk, the perceived probability of receiving an APH yield insurance payment was

included following Sherrick et al. (2004b). A positive relationship is expected,

because higher risk levels will increase the probability of insurance purchase.

Survey Data

The survey was mailed to 3000 farmers, 930 farmers responded, resulting in

approximately 29% survey response rate. After removing incomplete and/or

inconsistent responses, the final sample consisted of 382 farmers.19 Because soybean

distribution intervals in the survey’s subjective distribution section provided better

61

range for actual yield than the corn distribution intervals, the soybean subjective

distributions were used in the analysis (note that the majority of soybean producers

also likely to grow corn). Table 2.1 reports average farm values by insurance

products. Among insurance products, revenue insurance was used by the largest

farms (in acres, as suggested by size), youngest, and most leveraged users with fewer

years of experience. The revenue insurance users also utilize fewer financial risk

management tools, have the lowest tenure, and report the lowest subjective

probability of receiving an indemnity payment under 85% APH. CAT insurance is

the least popular insurance product, with the oldest, most experienced and tenured

users, who have the smallest farms and report the lowest probability of receiving

indemnity under 55% coverage level.

As with any survey, it is possible that selection bias could affect the results. If

for some reason, large farmers self selected this survey, the reported farmers’

tendency to indicate above average yields could be the consequence of having a

sample of larger than average farms, rather than the BTA effect. Therefore, if one

could compare the survey sample characteristics to the actual farm data, any

discrepancies could be indicative of the sample selection bias. This hypothesis is

examined in table 2.2, which compares actual farmer data from producers enrolled in

the Illinois Farm Business Farm Management (FBFM) record-keeping system to data

from the survey (since FBFM covers only Illinois farmers, the Illinois subset was

used). FBFM maintains detailed records of its members, very large, commercial-

scale farms in Illinois, the type of farms that were original target of the survey.

Results from the table suggest that in terms of age, the farms in the sample and the

62

FBFM are distributed similarly. However, in terms of size, FBFM farms are larger

across all categories. Because FBFM farms are larger across all categories, one can

conclude that the survey might not be subject to the size selection bias, assuming that

the sample selection bias could be manifested as size or age differences between the

sample and population.

Results

Yield Elicitation Results: Continuous parametric forms of subjective yield

distribution were derived by minimizing (1), and solving for the parameters of the

Weibull distribution. These parameters were used to estimate indirectly-stated mean

and standard deviation using (7) and (8) as:

1(1 )i i iµ β α −= Γ + (7)

1 2 1(1 2 ) (1 )i i i iσ β α α− − = Γ + −Γ + (8)

The mean for a county yield was calculated from detrended NASS county

yields and the standard deviation for a typical farm was derived as county-level

standard deviation.

Table 2.3 summarizes the respondents’ direct statements of their own mean

yield and yield risk relative to county’s average yield. The majority of respondents

(53% in Iowa, 57% in Indiana, 61% in Illinois), indicated that their yields are higher

than average (on average by 8.9 bu/ac in Iowa, 8.8 bu/ac in Indiana, and 8.4 bu/ac in

Illinois). Thirty eight percent of respondents in Iowa, 41% in Indiana, and 31% in

Illinois indicated that their yields are about the same as average yield, and 9% of

respondents in Iowa, 2% in Indiana, and 9% in Illinois indicated that their yields are

below average. Table 2.4 reports producers’ subjective assessment of their yield risk.

63

Forty one percent of respondents in Iowa, 48% in Indiana, and 47% in Illinois

perceived their yields to be less variable than the county yields, and 20% of

respondents in Iowa, 15% in Indiana, and 10% in Illinois reported their yields to be

more variable than the yields of a typical county. Combining results from the two

tables, 80% respondents in the sample indicated that their yields are better and/or

their yields are less variable or are of the same degree of variability than the county

yields. These results are consistent with the “Lake Woebegone Effect” where all

managers believe themselves to be “above average”.

Comparison of response weighted indirectly-stated yields and county average

yields reveal well-calibrated subjective beliefs. The average, indirectly-stated yield

for Iowa was 45.40 bu/ac (44.97 bu/ac for Indiana, 46.03 bu/ac for Illinois, and 45.56

bu/ac for total sample), and the subjective mean was not statistically different from

county average yield of 45.19 bu/ac for Iowa, (45.45 bu/ac for Indiana, 45.46 bu/ac

for Illinois, and 45.32 bu/ac for total sample) at p>0.00120. The differences in

directly-stated, county average, and indirectly-stated yields are consistent with the

results from previous literature. For example, Egelkraut et al. (2006a) reported that

directly-stated yields were above county average and indirectly-stated yields. They

further argued that “the results reveal a fundamental contrast between producer’s

beliefs when asked for a simple statement of average yield as opposed to assessing a

complete probabilities version of their yield distribution”.

Overall, the presented comparison raises a question. Why the same farmers

who reported reasonably calibrated yield distributions in one survey section, would

reveal distorted beliefs concerning yields in another? As argued in the third paper,

64

one possible explanation could be elicitation formats. Recent findings in contingent

valuation literature showed that donation amounts elicited using direct elicitation

method are almost always lower than actual donation amounts and the amounts

elicited through continuous type of questions (Champ and Bishop, 2001). The

proposed explanation in the literature is that direct elicitation results in an upward

bias as some respondents tend to be less sure about their answers. We argue that this

“unsureness” could be the function of complexity of the elicitation format.

Answering direct elicitation does not require significant efforts and as a result such

format might lead to the answers that respondents are not sure about or the answers

that have not been evaluated carefully. As task complexity of elicitation format

increases from direct elicitation to probabilistic assessment, respondents are forced to

carefully evaluate their responses and to provide more accurate yield assessments.

Also, while some farmers displayed the BTA effect, a particular farmer would make

careful assessment of yields before purchasing insurance. So the effect, while

present, might not be significant in determining insurance decisions. The next

section examines this question in greater detail.

Crop Insurance Use

In this section the results from the regressions are presented and discussed. While

coefficients for logit and the Poisson regression models are helpful in providing

direction and significance, to facilitate the discussion, the marginal fixed effects are

also reported for each model. These effects refer to df () dxt evaluated at x, where

f( ) is an endogenous variable, x is a vector of exogenous variables used to explain

f( ), and xt is one of the exogenous variables. The effects can be used to describe the

65

change in probability due to a change in independent variable of interest (holding

other exogenous variables at their averages).

Table 2.5 shows correlations for the variables used in the analysis. The results

indicate that insurance products are positively correlated with each other and the

correlation is statistically significant. Variable for age (AGE) is positively correlated

with CAT insurance, and debt (LOAN) is positively correlated with revenue

insurance. Risk management strategies (FRMS), (MRMS), (PRMS), are positively

correlated with insurance products. However, none of the variables for the

subjective perceptions (MBTA), (MRATIO), (VBTA), and (VRATIO) are correlated

with insurance products. Interestingly, BTA and miscalibration proxies are

correlated, mean BTA (MBTA) effect is positively and significantly correlated with

mean miscalibration (MRATIO) and variance BTA effect (VBTA). Similarly,

variance miscalibration (VRATIO) is negatively correlated with mean miscalibration

(MRATIO) and positively correlated with variance BTA effect (VBTA). Also, mean

BTA (MBTA) is correlated with usage of marketing risk management tools (MRMS).

The econometric results are reported in table 2.6. The table reports

coefficients, signs, marginal effects, and significance by product. It also reports

pseudo R square, the likelihood ratio, and the percentage of correctly predicted

observations. For the yield insurance model (model 1), the results in the table

indicate that age (AGE), size (SIZE), livestock sales as a percentage of total revenue

(LSTOCK), probability of receiving an indemnity (APROP), financial risk

management score (FRMS), market risk management score (MRMS), and production

risk management score (PRMS) contribute to the yield insurance use. Older farmers,

66

riskier farms, smaller farms, farms with larger percentage of livestock sales, and

farmers who are more likely to try other risk management tools, are also more likely

to purchase yield insurance. None of the proxies for the behavioral biases were

significant.

For the revenue insurance model (model 2), results show that age (AGE), debt

(LOAN), size (SIZE), livestock sales as a percentage of total revenue (LSTOCK),

probability of receiving indemnity (APROB), and production risk management

(PRMS) score contribute to revenue insurance usage. Thus, younger farmers with

smaller farms, more leveraged farmers, riskier farms, and farmers who are more

likely to try production risk management tools are more likely to purchase revenue

insurance. As with yield insurance, none of the proxies for the biases were

significant.

For the CAT insurance model (model 3), the results show that age (AGE),

leverage (LOAN), size (SIZE), livestock sales as a percentage of total revenue

(LSTOCK), probability of receiving indemnity (APROB), and the market risk

management score (MRMS) are likely to contribute to CAT insurance use. These

results indicate that older, less risky, more leveraged users, who use market risk

management tools, and have smaller farms are more likely to use crop insurance.

The negative relationship between probability of receiving APH insurance payment

and CAT purchase is especially interesting. The CAT insurance is provided for a

nominal fee and lender often require borrower to purchase some type of crop

insurance. It could be that farmers who purchase CAT insurance do so to satisfy

lending requirement and do not expect to benefit from it. Again, as with the previous

67

models, the proxies for the biases were not significant. Note that predictive ability is

much lower for CAT insurance.

Table 2.7 presents results for the Poisson regression model with dependent

variable user (model 4). The only significant variables are age (AGE), size (SIZE),

livestock sales as a percentage of total revenue (LSTOCK), perceived probability of

receiving APH payment (APROB), and risk management scores (FRMS), (MRMS),

and (PRMS). Older farmers with smaller, less diversified farms, higher perceived

probabilities of receiving insurance payments and higher usage of other risk

management tools are more likely to buy crop insurance products.

The pseudo R-squared is low across both individual and aggregate use models,

but the likelihood ratios are significant. Overall, the results suggest that age

increases probability of yield and CAT insurance purchase, and decreases the

probability of revenue insurance purchase, leverage increases probability of purchase

for revenue and CAT insurance and decreases the probability for yield insurance and

the size decreases likelihood of purchase. Also, the results suggest that farmers with

perceived higher probability of receiving APH payment are more likely to participate

in yield and revenue insurance program (both at individual product and aggregate

use level) and less likely to participate in CAT insurance. Livestock sales as a

percentage of total revenue increased probability of participation for yield insurance

and decreased participation for all other types of insurance. Also farmers who

actively used risk management tools are more likely to use insurance products.

Unlike Coble et al.(1996), Smith and Baquet (1996), and Sherrick et al.

(2004b), the results detect no relationship between participation and net worth and

68

education (Smith and Baquet, 1996). The results indicate a relationship between

crop insurance use and leverage (consistent with Smith and Baquet (1996), and

Sherrick et al (2004b)), size and diversification (consistent with Coble et al.(1996)).

Interestingly, the variables that were consistently significant in all models are

risk management scores. There could be two reasons explaining the significance.

One reason is past experience with risk management tools. If a farmer had a positive

experience using one risk management tool, he is more likely to continue using it,

and is more likely to use other risk management instruments as well. The positive

past experience with risk management tools would explain high significance, and

provide some further empirical support to the academic literature on experience

based crop insurance discounts (see for example Rejesus, Coble, Knight, Jin, 2006).

Another, possibly complimentary, explanation is risk aversion. If a farmer is a risk

averse, he is more likely to try any and all risk management instruments. Therefore,

simple risk aversion would explain high significance observed in the regression

models.

No significant relationship was detected between misperceptions (both the

BTA effect and miscalibration) and crop insurance purchase. Thus, the results

suggest that the effect does not seem to influence crop insurance decisions. The

results are not consistent with Egelkraut et al.(2006b) who reported a negative

significant relationship between insurance purchase and the BTA effect. One

possible explanation could be in different specifications of the model, for example,

presence of risk aversion variables in Egelkraut et al. model (which were not

available in this survey).

69

Conclusion

The purpose of this paper was to assess the extent of the BTA effect and

miscalibration and examine whether these biases influence insurance purchasing

decisions using data from a survey that covered soybeans producers from Illinois,

Iowa, and Indiana. The survey elicited subjective yield perceptions using two

different elicitation methods. While a majority of farmers indicated that their

average yield is greater than the county yield, and similarly, that their yields are less

variable than the county yields, the means of the subjective yield distribution

recovered from indirectly elicited yields, corresponded closely to the county yield

means. The results are consistent with Egelkraut et al. (2006b), Bessler (1980),

Pease (1993), and Eales et al. (1990). The results illustrated that age increases

probability of participation for revenue and CAT insurance and decrease the

probability for yield insurance. Therefore, encouraging older farmers to participate

in revenue insurance could be an effective strategy to increase participation.

Leverage increases probability of participation for revenue and CAT insurance

products, size decreases the probability for all insurance products. Diversification

(measured as sales of livestock) decreases the likelihood of purchase across all

insurance products, and probability of receiving insurance payments increases the

likelihood for yield and revenue insurance, and decreases it for CAT insurance. This

significance is consistent with the results from the first paper that showed presence

of adverse selection. The results also suggested that farmers who had used other risk

management tools before are more likely to participate in crop insurance program as

well; suggesting that RMA should consider providing discounts for a continuous use

70

of crop insurance and target farmers who actively use risk management tools.

Accounting for trend and bringing more farmers through effective targeting (both in

terms of risk management usage and age) could mitigate adverse selection. Both the

BTA effect and miscalibration do not seem to affect crop insurance purchasing

decisions. This finding contradicts results by Egelkraut et al. (2006b) who a found

negative relationship between the BTA effect and insurance participation using s

similar survey that covered only Illinois corn producers. While results suggested

little relationship between BTA effect and participation, further training and

education might benefit farmers by making farmers aware of the bias.

The results imply that the biases discussed are likely to be present in farmers’

decision making. However, these biases are not likely to substantially influence

actual producer insurance decisions, further supporting the argument that will be

made in the third paper that the BTA effect likely to be due to the elicitation format

that has been shown to result in upward bias, rather than fundamental miscalibration

of beliefs. A related implication is farmers are rational when crop insurance

participation is involved. These implications provide different view from previous

findings and suggest that the role these biases play in the decision making might not

be as significant as some economists have argued in the past. Of course the results

are generalizable only to the extent our sample is representative of the farmers’

population and to the extent that the specifics of the crop insurance underwriting and

purchasing process is similar to other insurance products underwriting and

purchasing process. For this reason, a goal of the future studies may be to test the

71

role of these biases using different insurance products, or using sample of crop

insurance users from different geographical region, growing different crops.

Endnotes

16 An example of the question: “Relative to your primary county’s average yield,

would you say you average yield is (check box, fill in blank) __higher,

by___bu/acres, _lower, by __by/acres, about the same”, “Relative to the same county,

would you say your yields are (check box) more stable, more variable, same degree

variability”

17 The survey asked respondents following question: “Which of the following risk

management tools have you used in the past?” Such wording allowed some

respondents to indicate that they have used several insurance products (for example,

yield insurance and revenue insurance or yield insurance and CAT insurance and so

on). Since the choice of insurance products in this case is not mutually exclusive and

simultaneous, Poisson regression was thought to be more relevant than the

multinomial logit/probit models.

18 Note that all farms in a county get same rated insurance so directional relative

effects should be fairly sensible

19 Surveys with less than 10% summing errors in distribution section were rescaled

(divided by total of the reported probabilities) and used. Also, because soybean

distribution intervals in the survey’s subjective distribution section provided a better

range for actual yield than the intervals for the corn distribution, only soybean

subjective distributions were used in the analysis. As a result of this selection

72

criterion, the sample could include soybean producers who might/might not be corn

producers. Producers, who indicated that they farmed in several primary counties,

were also eliminated. Furthermore, all observations that had missing entries for the

variables used in the analysis were eliminated as well

20 Statistical significance was assessed using paired t-test to account for a possible

dependence between subjective and county means. (Bluman, 2001)

73

Figures and Tables

Figure 2.1. Sample question for indirectly-elicited yields

Corn-Yield range Probability Soybeans- Yield Range Probability

Less than 40 bu/acre Less than 10 bu/acre

41 to 60 bu/acre 11 to 20 bu/acre

61 to 80 bu/acre 21 to 30 bu/acre

81 to 100 bu/acre 31 to 40 bu/acre

101 to 120 bu/acre 41 to 50 bu/acre

121 to 140 bu/acre 51 to 60 bu/acre

141 to 160 bu/acre 61 to 70 bu/acre

More than 160 bu/acre More than 70 bu/acre

Total (Should sum to 100%) 100% Total (Should sum to 100%) 100%

74

Tab

le 2.1

. R

esponden

ts’

char

acte

rist

ics

for

Illi

nois

, Io

wa,

and I

ndia

na

soybea

n p

roduce

rs b

y insu

rance

pro

duct

Yield

Revenue

CAT

Average

St.Dev

Average

St.Dev

Average

St.Dev

Use

r 40%

-

40%

-

19%

-

Siz

e 788

698

825

668

731

705

Age

52

12

50

11

54

11

Hig

h S

chool

43%

-

44%

-

43%

-

Som

e C

oll

ege

29%

-

27%

-

31%

-

Coll

ege

Gra

duat

e 26%

-

26%

-

22%

-

Gra

duat

e S

chool

3%

-

3%

-

5%

-

Per

centa

ge

wit

h D

ebta

72%

-

79%

-

75%

-

Fin

anci

al R

isk M

anag

emen

t S

core

(num

ber

of

tools

use

d)b

2.0

1.2

2.2

1.1

1.9

1.2

Mar

ket

Ris

k M

anag

emen

t S

core

(num

ber

of

tools

use

d)c

2.5

1.1

2.5

1.1

2.2

1.2

Pro

duct

ion R

isk M

anag

emen

t S

core

(num

ber

of

tools

use

d)d

2.5

1.1

2.5

1.1

2.2

1.2

Liv

esto

ck S

ales

As

Per

centa

ge

of

Gro

ss S

ales

15.8

24.1

15.3

23.6

15.3

23.8

O

wned

to T

ota

l A

cres

40%

36%

39%

34%

49%

36%

S

ubje

ctiv

e pro

bab

ilit

y o

f re

ceiv

ing a

n insu

rance

pay

men

t under

85%

AP

H c

ov.lev

el (%

) 27

24

26

22

21

17

a)

Den

ote

s a

dum

my v

aria

ble

, eq

ual

s 1 if

farm

er h

as d

ebt, z

ero o

ther

wis

e.

b)

Num

ber

of

finan

cial

ris

k m

anag

emen

t to

ols

far

mer

use

d (

gover

nm

ent pro

gra

ms,

bac

kup c

redit lin

e, f

inan

cial

sav

ings/

rese

rves

).

c)

Num

ber

of

mar

ket

ris

k m

anag

emen

t to

ols

far

er u

sed (

hed

gin

g/o

ptions,

spre

adin

g s

ales

over

tim

e, p

roduct

ion/m

arket

ing c

ontr

acts

, fo

rwar

d c

ontr

acting).

d)

Num

ber

of

pro

duct

ion r

isk m

anag

emen

t to

ols

far

mer

use

d (

multip

le c

rop e

nte

rpri

ses,

cro

p s

har

e le

ases

, m

ultip

le s

eed v

arie

ties

, fa

rmin

g in m

ultip

le loca

tions)

.

74

75

Table 2.2. Farm characteristics for survey sample (Illinois subset, soybean) and FBFM, by age

Age Category less than 30 30 – 39 40 - 49 50 - 59 60 & over

Farm Distribution 3% 9% 35% 31% 22% Survey Data Tillable Acres (acres) 880 728 893 734 601

Farm Distribution 3% 9% 29% 31% 28% FBFM Data for

2006 Tillable Acres (acres) 971 1034 1061 991 878

76

Table 2.3. Producers average subjective yields relative to average county yield

Higher About the Lower

Yield by… Same Yield By… Obs

% bu/ac % % bu/ac Count

IA 53 8.9 38 9 6.2 190

IN 57 8.8 41 2 3.2 55

IL 60 8.4 31 9 5 137

Total 56 8.7 36 8 5.6 382

77

Table 2.4. Producers subjective yield variability relative to county yield variability

Less About the Same More

Variable Variability Variable

% % %

IA 41 39 20

IN 48 37 15

IL 47 43 10

Total 44 40 16

78

T

able

2.5

. C

orr

elat

ions

Yield

Insura

nce

Reve

nue

Insura

nce

CAT

USER

ILIA

AGE

LOAN

MBTA

Size

LSTO

CKAP

ROP

FRMS

MRMS

PRMS

OTT

EDU

MRAT

IOVB

TAVR

ATIO

Yield

Insur

ance

1

Reve

nue I

nsuran

ce0.2

944*

**1

CAT

0.152

2***

0.100

7*1

USER

0.747

4***

0.727

7***

0.538

5***

1

IL-0.

0387

-0.07

36-0.

0253

-0.06

981

IA0.0

647

0.080

90.0

669

0.104

3**

-0.74

63**

*1

AGE

0.076

8-0.

0747

0.115

9**

0.047

80.0

83-0.

0444

1

LOAN

-0.01

180.1

437*

**0.0

310.0

826

-0.05

980.0

442

-0.23

19**

*1

MBTA

-0.04

55-0.

0202

-0.00

24-0.

0358

-0.01

16-0.

0517

-0.02

830.0

164

1

SIZE

0.005

0.066

6-0.

0585

0.014

40.0

938*

-0.15

42**

*-0.

1714

***

0.208

1***

0.126

8**

1

LSTO

CK0.0

153

-0.00

530.0

008

0.005

6-0.

1698

***

0.175

3***

-0.17

13**

*0.1

187*

*0.0

205

-0.09

31*

1

APRO

P0.1

879*

**0.1

313*

*-0.

0246

0.159

3***

0.017

10.0

087

-0.06

850.1

337*

**0.0

042

0.061

50.0

171

1

FRMS

0.303

6***

0.256

8***

0.182

8***

0.371

***

0.049

7-0.

0389

-0.02

04-0.

0252

0.042

60.0

966*

-0.00

69-0.

0154

1

MRMS

0.269

8***

0.345

8***

0.110

4**

0.371

1***

0.025

8-0.

0661

-0.08

93*

0.069

70.1

051*

*0.2

97**

*-0.

0295

-0.04

890.6

313*

**1

PRMS

0.323

9***

0.354

7***

0.070

50.3

884*

**0.0

111

-0.01

94-0.

0166

0.078

80.0

198

0.205

6***

-0.06

0.027

20.6

638*

**0.6

456*

**1

OTT

-0.02

96-0.

0624

0.098

*-0.

0092

-0.06

10.0

684

0.342

3***

-0.19

42**

*-0.

0039

-0.13

18**

0.104

5**

0.005

3-0.

0201

-0.06

69-0.

0867

*1

EDU

-0.04

27-0.

0413

-0.02

72-0.

0555

0.122

4**

-0.14

64**

*-0.

122*

*-0.

0046

0.021

10.2

375*

**-0.

0822

-0.11

3**

0.068

50.1

483*

**0.0

552

0.009

71

MRAT

IO-0.

0509

-0.03

3-0.

018

-0.05

170.0

62-0.

0125

-0.14

11**

*-0.

0096

0.261

1***

0.128

7**

0.017

5-0.

058

-0.03

520.0

520.0

011

0.017

90.11

18**

1

VBTA

-0.00

08-0.

0833

0.019

5-0.

0368

0.126

5**

-0.12

74**

0.034

7-0.

0295

0.367

8***

0.06

0.067

20.0

147

0.025

10.0

438

0.002

40.0

451

-0.02

680.2

564*

**1

VRAT

IO-0.

0163

0.029

1-0.

0259

-0.00

360.0

317

-0.03

72-0.

0524

0.003

70.0

023

0.075

40.09

73*

0.142

1-0.

0263

0.034

1-0.

0285

0.039

7-0.

0295

-0.11

42**

-0.09

56*

1 N

ote

: *,*

*,a

nd *

** d

enote

sta

tist

ical

sig

nif

ican

ce a

t 0.1

, 0.0

5, an

d 0

.01 lev

el.

78

79

Tab

le 2

.6. In

div

idual

pro

duct

use

res

ult

s

Note

: *,*

*,a

nd *

** d

enote

s st

atis

tica

l si

gnif

ican

ce a

t 0.1

, 0.0

5, an

d 0

.01 lev

el.

a) T

he

ratio f

ollow

s C

hi-

squar

e dis

trib

ution w

ith d

egre

e of

free

dom

s eq

ual

to the

num

ber

of

indep

enden

t var

iable

s in

the

regre

ssio

n. T

he

null h

ypoth

esis

is

that

the

coef

fici

ents

are

not

signif

ican

tly d

iffe

rent fr

om

zer

o.

Model 1 (Dependent Variable: Yield

Insurance)

Model 2 (Dependent Variable: Revenue

Insurance)

Model 3 (Dependent Variable: CAT

Insurance

Coefficients

Marginal Effects

Coefficients

Marginal Effects

Coefficients

Marginal Effects

IL

-0.0

244053

-0.0

092963

-0.0

426071

-0.0

16279

0.1

466636

0.0

344139

IA

0.2

041488

0.0

777348

0.1

975291

0.0

755054

0.3

378917

0.0

777174

AG

E

0.0

168969**

0.0

06443

-0.0

035567**

-0.0

013614

0.0

171388***

0.0

039364

LO

AN

-0

.1421098

-0.0

546205

0.3

231633**

0.1

204951

0.3

413364***

0.0

724738

MB

TA

-0

.3619703

-0.1

420759

-0.0

425053

-0.0

163498

-0.0

141176

-0.0

032628

SIZ

E

-0.0

001353***

-0.0

000516

-0.0

001531***

-0.0

000586

-0.0

001856***

-0.0

000426

LS

TO

CK

0.0

025734***

0.0

009813

-0.0

014998**

-0.0

00574

-0.0

004989**

-0.0

001146

AP

RO

B

0.0

146075**

0.0

055701

0.0

083329**

0.0

031895

-0.0

010342***

-0.0

002375

FR

MS

0.2

163897**

0.0

825124

-0.0

158211

-0.0

060557

0.3

520407

0.0

808565

MR

MS

0.1

625625**

0.0

619874

0.2

900972

0.1

11038

0.1

03286*

0.0

237227

PR

MS

0.1

805055**

0.0

688293

0.2

286728**

0.0

875271

-0.0

959031

-0.0

22027

OT

T

-0.3

251529

-0.1

239854

-0.0

285801

-0.0

109394

0.2

730707

0.0

627187

ED

U

-0.0

344841

-0.0

131493

-0.1

069324

-0.0

409296

-0.0

344643

-0.0

079157

MR

AT

IO

-0.0

694492

-0.0

26482

-0.0

15978

-0.0

061158

0.0

273877

0.0

062904

VB

TA

0.0

499754

0.0

189543

-0.3

149895

-0.1

231454

0.1

185324

0.0

260726

VR

AT

IO

-0.0

987317

-0.0

376478

0.0

138567

0.0

053038

-0.0

262012

-0.0

060179

IN

-1.6

52185

-0

.8393554

-2

.780922

Pse

udo R

2

0.1

57

0.1

65

0.0

85

L

ikel

ihood

Rat

ioa

78.9

83.4

28.5

C

orr

ectl

y

Pre

dic

ted (

%)

36

37

15

79

80

Table 2.7. Aggregate product use results

Model 4 (Dependent Variable: User)

Coefficients Marginal Effects

IL -0.0202067 -0.0174616 IA 0.2117762 0.1839693 AGE 0.0088856*** 0.0077001 LOAN 0.1515867 0.1272708 MBTA -0.109015 -0.0989674 SIZE -0.0001423*** -0.0001234 LSTOCK -0.0003079*** -0.0002668 APROB 0.0068083*** 0.0058999 FRMS 0.1585426** 0.1373902 MRMS 0.1931505* 0.1673807 PRMS 0.1325118** 0.1148324 OTT -0.0280902 -0.0243425 EDU -0.0606925 -0.052595 MRATIO -0.0432156 -0.0374498 VBTA -0.0482842 -0.0425418 VRATIO -0.0314923 -0.0272906 IN -1.272242 - Pseudo R2 0.1 Likelihood Ratioa 87.9 Note: *,**,and *** denotes statistical significance at 0.1, 0.05, and 0.01 level. a) The ratio follows Chi-square distribution with degree of freedoms equal to the number of independent variables in the regression. The null hypothesis is that the coefficients are not significantly different from zero.

81

CHAPTER 3

Farmers’ Subjective Yield Distributions and Elicitation Formats

Abstract

Subjective yield perceptions were elicited in two different formats from

Illinois, Indiana, and Iowa farmers and compared to objective county-level

yields. The results indicate that subjective perceptions elicited in a

probabilistic framework provide a reasonably accurate representation of

yields, suggesting that as a group, farmers’ perceptions are well-calibrated.

Importantly, this elicitation method is shown to be more accurate than

direct yield elicitation. The findings have important implications for survey

design/use and for the analysis of subjective beliefs elicited through surveys

involving direct elicitation.

Farmers’ beliefs about probabilistic events directly influence their production and

risk management decisions. However, since these beliefs cannot be directly

observed or measured through simple means, subjective estimates are often elicited

from farmers themselves through variously designed surveys. A natural question

emerges as to the reliability of these estimates relative to objective or resulting

distributions of outcomes. While it is reasonable to expect farmers’ subjective

perceptions to correspond to reality, the existence of such biases as overconfidence,

and person’s reliance on certain heuristics in decision-making might distort farmers’

perceptions. While this question has been examined in the past, Nerlove and Bessler

(2001) examining current evidence of our understanding regarding how individuals

form expectations and respond to these expectations, noted that “When asked in a

survey what they expect with respect to such-and-such, and what and how do

respondents answer? On the whole we remain ignorant of respondents’ state of mind,

and really carefully designed surveys directed to elucidating these matters remain to

be carried out.” (pg 199). In a related question, it is important to consider

82

differences in encoding or response validity among alternative elicitation methods.

This is especially relevant given recently observed differences in elicitation formats

in contingent valuation literature (Ready, Navrud, and Dubourgh, 2001).

The study addresses these issues by analyzing yield risk perceptions of

soybean producers from Illinois, Indiana, and Iowa. The paper utilizes data from

comprehensive survey mailed to 3,000 corn and soybean producers in the three states

identified. In addition to demographic, business, and other basic informational items,

the survey elicited subjective yield perceptions from respondents under two different

formats, referred to as direct and indirect approaches. The purpose of this paper is to

compare responses between the formats, identify differences, and to provide

plausible explanations. The accuracy of each approach is assessed by comparing

elicited subjective yield values from set of farmers to the county-level yield data

from which the responses were generated. So, apart from chapter two which

examined the influence of cognitive biases on the individual’s decisions to purchase

crop insurance in the presence of alternative risk management options, this paper

investigates the role of different elicitation formats on the accuracy of yield

perceptions by comparing farmers’ perceptions (as a group) to their county yields.

The county-level data was used in this analysis because farm-level data for the

respondents’ were not available. While this complicates the investigation, note that

because farm-level data are often not available, the county-level data is used instead,

in a variety of applications that might influence farmer’s decision making (for

example, crop insurance is rated at the county level, using county-level yields).

Therefore, in some cases, the comparison to county-level yields is more relevant than

83

the comparison to the farm-level yields. In addition, the addendum develops an

approach that allows one to adjust county-level yields for the higher variability by

estimating an average ratio of standard deviations of county level and farm level

yields.

The paper contributes to understanding in two areas: accuracy of subjective

yield perceptions and the role of elicitation format on the accuracy of subjective

yield perceptions. The producer’s ability to accurately process yield information has

significant implications for many purposes – in particular, in cases that require

farmers to begin with accurate understanding of the probabilities associated with

some random variables. Producers routinely rely on their yield perceptions,

especially when decisions involve risk management, crop insurance,

marketing/hedging, and others. Yet, research assessing the accuracy of the

perceptions is relatively limited (Sherrick, 2002). Role of elicitation format on the

accuracy of perceptions is also important. If one elicitation method is consistently

more accurate than another, there are obvious implications for survey design and use.

To aggravate the problem further, the yield elicitation methods are commonly used

in isolation in surveys, making comparison of elicitation methods challenging. By

examining the subjective perceptions elicited under different formats from the same

respondent, the paper addresses an issue in existing research that has not been

extensively targeted in the past.

Literature Review

Most of the literature on risk perceptions in agricultural economics is related to yield

perceptions, and particularly, to the correspondence between subjective and objective

84

yields. Because underlying assumptions regarding the true data-generation process

for crop yields are very important for the comparison of subjective and objective

yields, crop yield distributions (parametric and non-parametric) have been

extensively analyzed. For example, Nelson and Preckel (1989) used beta distribution,

while Jung and Ramezani (1999) used lognormal distribution. Others, such as Ker

and Goodwin (2000) used non-parametric distributions. Sherrick, Zanini, Schnitkey,

and Irwin (2004a) analyzed implications of using different distributional forms to

model yields using farm-level data for corn and soybeans. They detrended yields

using a linear trend (unit root test showed that yields time series were not stochastic),

and fitted normal, logistic, Weibull, beta, and lognormal distributions, and assessed

the fit using the Anderson-Darling and likelihood tests. The results indicated that the

Weibull provided a suitable representation for the crop yields. Further, the flexibility

of the Weibull makes it attractive as a measure across a wide set of moments

conditions.

While the subjective beliefs are important in forming expectations and making

decision, the number of articles that analyzed the producers’ subjective beliefs in

agriculture is limited. The second chapter of this dissertation analyzed the role of the

misperception biases in insurance-purchasing decisions. Results showed that the

BTA effect is present in farmers’ decision making, since majority of farmers were

overstating their yields in relation to the county average. The results from the

regression analysis indicated that the variables for age, likelihood to receive an

indemnity, diversification, and usage of alternative risk management tools were

significant in determining the demand for crop insurance. However, none of proxies

85

for the biases were significant, suggesting that farmers are rational in crop insurance

decisions, and that the biases could a product of elicitation format.

Sherrick (2002), using a conviction weights approach (probabilistic approach),

elicited subjective distribution for precipitation and compared the parameterized

subjective distribution to the parameterized actual rainfall distribution. Sherrick

found that farmers tend to overstate average precipitation levels for April rainfall and

understate average precipitation for July rainfall. Similarly, he found that farmers

tend to understate the precipitation variability for July rainfall, and overstate the

variability for April rainfall. Eales, Engel, Hauser, and Thompson (1990) elicited

subjective distribution for options and futures prices from various market

participants and, assuming lognormal distribution compared the prices to actual

market values. They found that while their reported subjective means agreed in most

cases with corresponding market values, the respondents’ reported subjective

variances were significantly smaller than their market estimates. Pease (1993)

elicited yield distributions from corn and soybean producers and compared them

with producers’ production history. Using subjective means as a forecast, he

compared the means with linearly detrended farm-level historical yields. He reports

that while subjective means were slightly higher for soybeans, they were lower for

corn. He also reports that producers significantly underestimated yield risk.

Similarly, Bessler (1980) elicited yield distribution from farmers using conviction

weights or probabilistic approach. Aggregating the subjective yield distributions and

comparing the resulting values with the ARIMA forecast (derived based on actual

yields), he reported no significant differences between the forecast and subjective

86

mean values. He also noted that subjective forecasts tend to display a greater

variability. Using a format similar survey to the one employed here, Egelkraut,

Sherrick, Garcia, and Pennings (2006a) elicited subjective crop distribution from

Illinois corn producers. They elicited subjective yields directly (by asking farmers to

state their average yield and yield variability in relation to the typical farm in the

county) and indirectly (by asking farmers to assign weights to yield intervals) and

compared these estimates to the county-level data. They found that the differences

between county averages and directly stated yields were statistically significant.

Also, the differences between indirectly elicited measures and directly elicited

measures were significant as well, while differences between county estimates and

indirect estimates for mean and variability were not statistically significant. Nerlove

and Bessler (2001) provide an overview of the studies that examined correspondence

between respondents’ expectations (elicited in surveys among other methods)

regarding economic variables to the objective representation of these variables.

Major findings of their overview were as follows. First, the result indicated that

aggregated individual expectations approximated objective data better than

individual expectations. Second, respondents displayed a significant heterogeneity

in their expectations. Third, respondents were capable of identifying underlying data

generation process (i.e. random walk versus autoregressive pattern) but did not

always optimally incorporated the process into the expectations and forecast.

Overall, the results from past literature suggest that farmers (as a group) possess

reasonably accurate subjective estimates of mean and less accurate estimates of yield

87

variability. In addition, the findings indicate that indirectly elicited yields provide a

more accurate representation then directly-elicited yields.

In addition to the publications in agricultural economics, the literature related

to contingent valuation might provide insights toward a better understanding of the

role that elicitation format plays in recovering subjective beliefs. In contingent

valuation studies, information on donations is usually elicited in two ways: through

dichotomous choice (“Would you pay X for Y?” type of questions) and traditional

payment card, where individuals are asked to choose among several choices of

payment amounts. It has been observed in the literature that the donations elicited

through dichotomous choice tend to exceed actual donations, resulting in an upward

bias, which has been referred to as a “hypothetical bias” (Champ and Bishop, 2001),

while donations elicited through more continuous elicitation methods such as the

payment card tended to be lower and more in line with actual donations. It also has

been noticed that respondents in dichotomous-choice type questions tended to be less

certain about their answers. For example, Champ and Bishop (2001) after eliciting

responses in dichotomous-choice, followed up with “How certain are you that you

would (would not) donate the requested amount?” with a response scale ranging

from 1 (very uncertain) to 10 (very certain). They compared the responses to the

second sample where respondents actually donated money. The results indicated

that the donation amount elicited through dichotomous-choice has exceeded actual

amount donated. Also the proportion of the respondents who stated that they would

donate certain amount and are very certain to donate (10 on the scale) was similar to

the proportion that actually donated money. Ready, Navrud, and Dubourgh (2001)

88

argued that the differences between two methods could be explained by “how unsure

respondents answer these two types of questions.” (pg 325). Under dichotomous-

choice, the respondents who are not completely sure of their answers would be

classified as “yes”, because the question usually asks “would you pay X amount for

Y?” This does not happen under continuous choice because respondents are given

choices and therefore, could be more specific in their answers. In other words,

dichotomous choice might classify some of the “may be” answers as “yes”, resulting

in an upward bias. Ready, Navrud, and Dubourgh (2001) reported that the

differences between two elicitation methods were reduced if the respondents under

dichotomous choice were elicited certainty level (i.e. “I am 95% certain that I would

pay X amount for Y.”), and the answers were controlled for it. The obvious question

that arises from these findings is whether the differences in elicitation formats play a

similar role in elicitations of other variables, such as yield perceptions.

Given the limited research, the need for further analysis of producers’

perceptions is evident. Various audiences can gain from more a detailed analysis of

subjective yield elicitation. Findings can be helpful for researchers and survey users

since, direct elicitation of mean yield and yield variability is used extensively in

research; see for example Shaik, Coble, and Knight (2005). If different elicitation

formats lead to different responses, the discrepancies need to be accounted for in

survey designs and use. To date, only Egelkraut et al.(2006b) is known to have

considered directly and indirectly elicited yields elicitation in the same survey. This

study represents improvement over Egelkraut et al. (2006b) work by examining the

89

yield differences from different elicitation formats as function of age, education, size

using a bigger sample and a different crop.

Survey Description

The study uses data from a crop yield risk survey, which was conducted under a

cooperative agreement with the Economic Research Service USDA and supported by

the Risk Management Agency of USDA. While the survey is described in detail in

the second paper, elicitation methods used in the survey need additional discussion.

Yield perceptions for soybeans were elicited directly and indirectly, in separate

sections of the survey. The partitioning of these two sections was done by design to

separate task and context. For the indirect section, the perceptions were elicited by

asking respondents to assign probabilities into the predefined yield categories (figure

3.1). This probabilistic approach, known as the conviction weights approach (Norris

and Kramer 1990), was employed by Bessler (1980) and Eales et al. (1990). The

sum of the intervals was identified as 100%, requiring respondents’ stated

probabilities to sum to 100%, and readjust interval weights until probability is fully

assigned.

Farmers’ yield perceptions were also elicited by directly asking respondents to

indicate whether their yields are above primary county average (if yes, by how many

bushels), below the county average (if yes, by how many bushels), or the same as the

county average (figure 3.2 shows that part of the survey). Besides eliciting average

yield, the survey elicited yield variability by asking a respondent to state whether

respondent’s subjective yields are more variable than county average, less variable

than county average, or have the same degree of variability.

90

Methods

The directly-stated subjective yield averages were estimated as follows. If a

respondent indicated that his farm-individual yield is not different from county

average, his directly-stated yield average was set equal to the county average (since

the survey asked a respondent to refer to his county average). If the respondent

indicated that his yield is below/above the average, the directly stated yield was

coded as the county average yield minus/plus the stated difference.

In the indirectly-stated yield section, discrete probabilities were used to both

calculate implied weighted averages and to convert each individual response set was

to a continuous subjective yield distribution using:

( ) [ ]( )7 2 22

1 1 1 8 8

2

min ( ( | )) ( | ) ( | ) 1 ( | )i

i i ij j i j i i i

j

p D U p D U D U p D Uθ

θ θ θ θ−=

− + − − + − −

(1)

where pij - producer i stated probability for interval j

Uij – upper bound of the interval

D(.) – cumulative distribution of farm-level yields

iθ - set of parameters for producer i’s subjective yield21

Distribution functions for Weibull, normal, and lognormal distributions were

fitted. Results are presented for the Weibull distribution because 1) it provides the

best fit22 and 2) to take advantage of useful properties of the Weibull distribution for

modeling crop yields including its non-symmetry, zero limit, and wide range of

skewness and kurtosis. The CDF of the Weibull has the following functional form:

91

( ) 1 0 x< , , 0

i

i

x

i iF x e

α

β α β

− = − ≤ ∞ >

(2)

The CDF for normal distribution has following function form:

1 x - ( ) 1 + erf 0 x< , - , 0

2 2F x

µµ σ

σ

= ≤ ∞ ∞ < < ∞ >

(3)

And CDF for lognormal has following distributional form:

1 ln(x) - ( ) 1 + erf 0 x< , - , 0

2 2F x

µµ σ

σ

= ≤ ∞ ∞ < < ∞ >

(4)

Where erf is defined as:

2

0

2( )

z

terf z e dtπ

−= ∫

The implied mean and implied standard deviation are then calculated under the fitted

distributions for each farmer and used as proxies for the indirectly-stated average

yield and yield variability.

The county distribution was used as a representative objective yield distribution

from the location indicated in the response as the primary county. Soybean county

yields were obtained from NASS for the years 1972-2002 and detrended to 2002 (the

survey date) using a linear trend at county level (Sherrick et al. (2004a)) found that

yields series tend to be stationary with s strong upward trend due to improved seed

technology). To estimate parameters for continuous distributional form equation (5)

was minimized;

( )22

,min | , ( | , )fit fitα β

µ µ α β σ σ α β− + − (5)

92

Where µ is equal to the county mean.

fitµ is the fitted county mean

σ is the county standard deviation

fitσ is the fitted county standard deviation

,α β are the Weibull parameters for fitted distribution

Solving (5) for ,α β provides Weibull parameters for a continuous county yield

distribution with objective mean and objective standard deviation.

Survey Data

Of the 930 surveys returned, 896 were sufficiently complete to be usable, producing

a usable response rate of approximately 29%. This response rate exceeded (as

indicated by Progressive Farmer) anticipated total response rate of 15% to 20%.

Because soybean distribution intervals in the survey’s subjective distribution section

provided a better range for actual yield than the intervals for the corn distribution,

only soybean subjective distributions were used in the analysis. As a result of this

selection criterion, the sample could include soybean producers who might/might not

be corn producers.

Table 3.1 shows summary statistics for various farm characteristics for a raw

data sample (containing 930 observations) and a cleaned data sample (containing 382

observations). Various criteria were applied to the raw data sample that resulted in

elimination of the observations. If an observation had sum of the yield distribution

intervals less than 90% or more than 110%, it was eliminated (the observations with

greater than 90% or above 100% were rescaled by norming to their own sum). This

restriction eliminated 212 observations, with the majority of the eliminated

93

observations having all yield intervals fields blank. The observations with less then

3 yield intervals were eliminated as well, resulting in 85 eliminated observations.

Such observations led to unreasonably high/low distribution moments. The

observations with more than one primary county (i.e. the county where a producers

mainly operates) were eliminated as well, resulting in 97 eliminated observations.

This restriction was imposed because farm-level yields would need to be compared

to specific (primary) county yields. Seventy one observations were eliminated

because they did not contain information on state or primary county (i.e. the fields

were left blank). Finally, eliminating missing observations for the variables used in

the analysis (age, education, debt, and so on) led to the elimination of 83

observations. These eliminations resulted in a clean survey sample of 382

observations. Because the raw data sample contains observations with missing

state/county fields, the characteristics for the raw sample were not sorted by state.

Table 3.1 shows average and standard deviation for raw and cleaned sample.

The standard deviations were not available for the proportions (for example,

proportion of farmers who graduated from high school). The farm sizes are similar

in the both samples; however, size in a raw sample has higher standard deviation.

Percentage of farmers with debt is higher in the raw sample, there are more insurance

users and more farmers own land in the clean sample (as owned to total acres much

higher).

The state comparison of a clean sample leads to the following conclusions.

Indiana has the largest farms in the sample and the youngest users, while Iowa has

the smallest size farms, with highest percentage of livestock sales.

94

Equation 1 is used to estimate parameters for each of the candidate

distributional forms. Figure 3.3 shows an example of the fitted subjective and

county soybean yield distributions for Fayette County, Iowa, (the county and farmers

from each county were selected for illustration purposes only). As the figure

suggests, producers in the county display various yield expectations. Respondent 1

has a lower subjective mean and smaller variance, while respondent 2 has higher

mean and smaller yield variability.

Results

Table 3.2 summarizes the direct assessments of individual-farm yields by respondent.

The majority of respondents indicated that their yields are greater than the county

average (53% in Iowa, 57% in Indiana, and 60% in Illinois), or equal to county

average (38% in Iowa, 41% in Indiana, and 31% in Illinois). Similarly, the majority

of the respondents viewed their yield variability to be smaller than the county

average (41% in Iowa, 48% in Indiana, and 47% in Illinois) or equal to the county

average (39% in Iowa, 37% in Indiana, and 43 in Illinois). Approximately 79% of

farmers reported both less than or equal yield variability and same or greater average

yields.

To contrast these results with the indirect method, table 3.3 contains a summary

of the directly-stated yields, indirectly-stated yields (Weibull implied), county

average yields, the differences between directly-stated yields and county averages,

and the differences between indirectly stated yields and county averages for each

state. The average directly-stated yield for Iowa is 49.09 bu/ac (50.02 bu/ac for

Indiana, 49.95 bu/ac for Illinois), which is 6.8 bu/ac greater than the weighted county

95

average (8.38 bu/ac bu/ac for Indiana, 6.75 bu/ac for Illinois) and 3.69 bu/ac greater

than indirectly-stated for Iowa (5.06 bu/ac for Indiana, 3.91 bu/ac for Illinois). The

corresponding differences between indirectly-stated and the county average yields

are 0.21, -0.49, 0.57, and 0.24 bu/ac. The paired t-test23 for the differences between

the directly-stated and county average yields indicated that the differences are

statistically significant while no such significance was detected in yield differences

between indirectly stated and county average. 24 Figure 3.4 illustrates the frequency

count of the differences between indirectly-elicited subjective yields and county

average yields for the respondents in each state. Overall, the mean differences

appear reasonably distributed, with subjective means being slightly greater than

county average means

This significance suggests that the farmers, as a group, display the “better-

than-average” effect when yields are directly elicited. On the other hand, the

differences between indirectly-stated yields and county average yields were not

statistically significant suggesting that farmers as a group, display well-calibrated

mean yield perceptions when yields are elicited in a probabilistic framework.

Contrary to the earlier directly-stated yields analysis, the results from

indirectly-stated yields analysis suggest that systematic differences do not exist

between subjective yield distribution and its objective counterpart, and subjective

yields assessed in probabilistic framework provide more accurate estimates of yield.

The effect disappears when the yield distribution is elicited from the farmers

indirectly.

96

The observed discrepancies are an example is the “better than average” (BTA)

effect. The BTA effect refers to an individual propensity to “judge themselves as

better than others with regard to skills or positive attributes.” (Glaser and Weber,

2003). Since yields could be viewed as an assessment of producer’s farming skills, it

is natural to expect such yield exaggeration from a farmer (Taylor and Brown, 1998).

What is not clear, however, is why the BTA effect is not observed in the probabilistic

yield assessment. After all, it is possible for a farmer to assign weights to the higher

yield intervals, thus increasing the mean of the yield distribution.

Recall that findings from contingent valuation literature were cited earlier with

similar results reported. After all, the respondents who overstated their donations in

the dichotomous choice could have overstated their donations in the payment card as

well. The proposed explanation by the contingent valuation literature is

dichotomous-choice questions result in an upward bias as the respondents tend to be

less certain in answering discrete-choice type question than answering continuous

choice or open end questions (see for example Champ and Bishop, 2001). We make

related argument by hypothesizing that the “unsureness” in our case could be a

function of task complexity. Answering direct yield elicitation questions (i.e.“Is

your yield above/same/below county average”) is an easy task; it does not require a

significant mental effort. As a result, some respondents might provide answers they

are not sure about or have not evaluated carefully. However, as a task-complexity

increases, as in estimating yield intervals for example, these respondents might be

forced to consider entire distribution of the variable of interest and as a result

97

carefully assess their choices. Note that the yield discrepancy could also be driven

by other factors, such as age, farm size (examined later in the section)25.

These results are consistent with findings from the previous literature. In

particular, the results are in agreement with the second paper’s findings, where

Weibull implied yields were not statistically different from county average yields.

These conclusions are also in line with findings by Nerlove and Bessler (2001),

Bessler (1980) and Eales et al. (1990) who did not find significant differences

between objectives and aggregated subjective estimates, and Egelkraut et al.(2006a)

who did not find statistically significant differences between county mean and

individual implied means. Furthermore, Egelkraut et al.(2006a) argued that farmers

are likely to recall yields in more recent years rather then yields in more distant years.

If a farmer experienced several favorable years, he is more likely to overstate the

yield in his direct yield statements. This hypothesis is examined by constructing

averages using 5 years (from 2002 to 1998) and 10 years (from 2002 to1993) of

NASS county-level yields. While the average differences between directly-stated

and 5 and 10 year averages were smaller (5 year average: IA=5.6 bu/ac, IN=4.7

bu/ac, IL=4.3 bu/ac, 10 year average IA=2.7 bu/ac, IN=4.3 bu/ac, IL=3.9 bu/ac) than

the differences reported in table 3.3, these differences remained statistically

significant at p<0.0001. These findings are consistent with Egelkraut et al. (2006a),

who reported similar results for corn producers.

To examine the correspondence between subjective perception and objective

measures of yield risk, the implied and county average standard deviations were also

compared. If a farmer assesses the yield risk accurately, his measure of yield

98

variability should be greater than county-level variability, because aggregated yields

tend to be less volatile than individual yields. Results from a paired t-test suggest

that implied standard deviations (IA = 8.03 bu/ac, IN = 7.63 bu/ac, IL = 7.33 bu/ac)

are statistically different (p<0.0001) from county-level standard deviations (IA =

4.87 bu/ac, IN = 4.81 bu/ac, IL = 4.70 bu/ac). As expected, the farm variability

measures were larger then their county counterparts. Figure 3.5 illustrates the

frequency count of the differences between indirectly-elicited subjective yields and

county average standard deviations for the respondents in each state. While the bin

containing zero has the greatest frequency, the subjective standard deviations tend to

be larger than county yield standard deviations

The findings differ somewhat from those presented by Eales, et al. and

Egelkraut, et al.(2006b), whose results suggested apparent overconfidence. In

particular, Egelkraut et al. (2006b)reported that corn producers’ subjective standard

deviations were not statistically different from county-level standard deviations. The

discrepancy in the findings might be attributed to the differences in crops (Egelkraut

et al. (2006b) used subjective perceptions of corn producers, while this paper uses

subjective perceptions of soybean farmers), as the ratio of farm-level to countywide

risk for soybean yields tend to be slightly greater than the same ratio for corn yields.

The reported discrepancy between directly-elicited yields and county-level

yields could also be a function of various characteristic such as farmer’s education

level, farm size, experience, and etc. For example, more experienced farmer could

possess more accurate yield perceptions. To investigate this claim, following

equation is estimated:

99

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7YD SIZE AGE EDU IN IL IA SSDβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + (6)

Where YD is the difference between means of directly elicited yields and county

average yields, SIZE is size of the farm, AGE is respondent’s age, EDU is

respondent’s education level (discrete variable, 1 denoting high school graduate, and

4 denoting graduate school graduate), IN, IL, and IA are dummy variables for states,

and SSD is implied (subjective) standard deviation. Also, following variations of the

equations (6) were tested:

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7YDD SIZE AGE EDU IN IL IA SSDβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + (7)

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7YV SIZE AGE EDU IN IL IA SSDβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + (8)

Where YDD was decoded as 1 if directly elicited yields were greater than county

average yields 0 otherwise in equation 7, and YV was decoded as 1 if a farmer

indicated that the yields had the same/less variability then county yields and 0 if the

yields were more variable then county yields.

The results from this test are shown in table 3.4. Equation 6 is estimated as

model 1, equation 7 and 8, as models 2 and 3 respectively. None of the variables for

the regression is significant and an F-test for overall significance suggests that

coefficients jointly are not significantly different from zero. The results indicate that

none of the considered variables explain the discrepancies observed. It is of course,

still possible that other variables not captured in this survey (risk aversion for

example), could explain the relationship.

Conclusion

This paper uses subjective yield perceptions elicited in two different formats from

soybean producers in Illinois, Iowa, and Indiana, and compares them to county-level

100

data. The results suggest that subjective yield perceptions elicited in a probabilistic

framework can provide a more reliable yield assessment of county-level yield data,

in particular with regard to a central tendency, and farmers as a group possess well-

calibrated yield expectations. In addition, the findings indicate that the probabilistic

elicitation approach is more accurate than direct yield elicitation at representing

county-level yield data and that the BTA effect observed in directly-elicited

subjective yields could be due to the elicitation format. The results suggested that

the aggregated indirectly-elicited farm-level yields were not different from the

county average yields, which is consistent with the second paper, with Nerlove and

Bessler (2001), Bessler (1980), Eales et al. (1990), and Egelkraut et al. (2006b).

However, unlike Eales et al. and Egelkraut et al. (2006b) no evidence of the

overconfidence is found when subjective standard deviation is compared with

county-level standard deviations.

The results are consistent with the findings from contingent valuation literature

that indicated that the dichotomous-choice type questions have an upward bias that is

not present in the continuous or open-end type questions. We argue that the

observed BTA effect could be due to task-complexity. As task complexity of

elicitation format increases from direct elicitation to probabilistic assessment,

respondents are forced to carefully evaluate their responses and to provide more

accurate assessments. Future research could test this hypothesis through yield

elicitation under gradually increasing complexity of the elicitation formats. The

major implication of this paper for researchers is that care should be exercised in

interpreting and using directly-elicited yields as true measures of producers’ beliefs.

101

Addendum

The purpose of this addendum is to introduce an approach that allows for an

adjustment of county-level yields for the higher variability of farm-level yields. The

approach is implemented in Schnitkey Sherrick, and Irwin (2003), where the ratio of

farm-level variability to county-level variability (scaler) was estimated, the county

level standard deviations were multiplied by this scaler to account for the higher

level of variability. Schnitkey, Sherrick, and Irwin estimated the scaler using FBFM

data, by detrending farm-level yields, and estimating the average (at the state level)

ratio of county level to farm level yields.

We adopted a similar approach and calculated the scaler values using two

methods. Firstly, the scaler was calculated using actual farmer data from farms

enrolled in the Illinois Farm Business Farm Management (FBFM) record-keeping

system, by detrending farm level yields (soybean yields from 1987 to 2002), and

estimating the average (at the state level) ratio of county level yield standard

deviation to farm level yield standard deviation. Secondly, the scaler was estimated

by calculating the ratio of subjective standard deviation (as implied by subjective

yield distribution from survey respondents) to objective (county level) standard

deviation. Because the FBFM has records for Illinois farms only, the survey sample

was limited to Illinois producers as well. The purpose of calculating the scaler using

two different approaches is the comparison of the resulting values. If the survey’s

respondents possess well-calibrated beliefs, then the two scaler values should

correspond to each other.

102

Table 3.5 shows scaler statistics from both approaches. The second column

shows scaler statistics estimated using survey data and the third column shows scaler

statistics estimated using FBFM data. The average value for subjective scaler is 1.67,

for FBFM scaler the average is 1.52, the difference of 0.15. The subjective scaler

has larger dispersion as measured by standard deviation and minimum and maximum

values. Given the difference of 0.15 between the scalers, one can say that there is a

close correspondence between the scaler values.

Endnotes

21 The optimization was implemented in Excel, by minimizing differences between

farmer’s stated probabilities and specified fitted distribution for each interval by

changing fitted distribution parameters.

22 The results confirm that the Weibull distribution provides the best overall fit by

displaying smallest sum of squared errors (41,213) across all surveys, followed by

the normal (47,502) and lognormal (633,360) distributions.

23 Because farmers' subjective means are paired to the county means where

producers farm, such samples are likely to be dependent. To account for this, a

paired t-test was used (Bluman, 2001). Note that t-test assumes that underlying

observations are normally distributed. To account for the possible non-normality,

Wilcoxon test was used as well.

24 Paired t-test and Wilcoxon test were conducted on two levels. First, individual

farmer’s subjective means were paired to the respective county means and critical

test values were calculated. Second, county-average subjective means were

103

calculated (equally weighted) and paired with respective county means. In both

cases, the differences between subjective and objective means were statistically

significant at p>0.001.

25 The discrepancy could also be the result of sample selection bias. However, in this

case, one would expect the selection bias manifest itself in both elicitation formats.

104

Figures and Tables

Figure 3.1. Survey section that elicited indirectly-stated yield perceptions

Corn-Yield range Probability Soybeans- Yield Range Probability

Less than 40 bu/acre Less than 10 bu/acre

41 to 60 bu/acre 11 to 20 bu/acre

61 to 80 bu/acre 21 to 30 bu/acre

81 to 100 bu/acre 31 to 40 bu/acre

101 to 120 bu/acre 41 to 50 bu/acre

121 to 140 bu/acre 51 to 60 bu/acre

141 to 160 bu/acre 61 to 70 bu/acre

More than 160 bu/acre More than 70 bu/acre

Total (Should sum to 100%) 100% Total (Should sum to 100%) 100%

105

Figure 3.2. Survey section that elicited directly-stated yield perceptions

106

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

1 11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91 101

Yield (bu/ac)

Probability

Respondent 1 Respondent 2 Respondent 3 County-Level

Figure 3.3. Subjective and county PDFs for Fayette county Iowa soybean producers

107

F

igure

3.4

. Y

ield

dif

fere

nce

s bet

wee

n indir

ectl

y-s

tate

d a

nd c

ounty

aver

age

yie

lds

020406080

-20

-15

-10

-50

510

1520

Yield Difference (bu/ac)

Frequency

05101520

-20

-15

-10

-50

510

1520

Yield Difference (bu/ac)

Frequency

0102030405060

-20

-15

-10

-50

510

1520

Yield Difference (bu/ac)

Frequency

Iowa

Indiana

Illinois

107

108

Fig

ure

3.5

. Y

ield

dif

fere

nce

s bet

wee

n indir

ectly-s

tate

d a

nd c

ounty

aver

age

stan

dar

d d

evia

tions

01020304050

-10

-8-6

-4-2

02

46

810

Yield Difference (bu/ac)

Frequency

05101520

-10

-8-6

-4-2

02

46

810

Yield Differen

ce (b

u/ac)

Frequency

0102030405060

-10

-8-6

-4-2

02

46

810

Yield Differen

ce (b

u/ac

)

Frequency

108

Iowa

Indiana

Illinois

109

Tab

le 3

.1. R

esponden

ts’

char

acte

rist

ics

by p

roduct

type

and s

tate

(av

erag

e an

d s

tandar

d d

evia

tion w

her

e ap

plica

ble

)

Raw Sample

Cleaned Sample

IA

IN

IL

Average

St.Dev

Average

St.Dev

Average

St.Dev

Average

St.Dev

Average

St.Dev

Siz

e 772

1193

769

630

657

537

909

742

867

676

Age

(yea

rs)

54

13

51

11

51

11

50

12

53

12

Hig

h S

chool

45%

-

40%

-

46%

-

44%

-

31%

-

Som

e C

oll

ege

27%

-

30%

-

30%

-

16%

-

36%

-

Coll

ege

Gra

duat

e 24%

-

25%

-

22%

-

35%

-

27%

-

Gra

duat

e S

chool

5%

-

4%

-

2%

-

5%

-

6%

-

Per

centa

ge

wit

h D

ebt

60%

-

42%

-

44%

-

42%

-

39%

-

Insu

rance

U

ser

49%

-

63%

-

70%

-

55%

-

57%

-

Ow

ned

to

Tota

l A

cres

49%

38%

71%

45%

73%

45%

73%

45%

69%

47%

L

ives

tock

(%

of

Sal

es)

16

26

15

25

20

27

14

24

10

22

Num

ber

of

Obse

rvat

ions

930

382

This

tab

le c

ame

from

KS

for

Wei

bull

, L

ognorm

al, N

orm

al, w

ith o

bs

count.xls

fil

e

109

110

Tab

le 3

.2. R

esponden

ts’

per

ceiv

ed a

ver

age

yie

ld a

nd y

ield

var

iability r

elat

ive

to the

pri

mar

y c

ounty

Average Yield

Yield Variability

Higher

Same

Lower

Less

Variable

Same

Variability

More

Variable

%

%

%

%

%

%

IA

53

38

9

41

39

20

IN

57

41

2

48

37

15

IL

60

31

9

47

43

10

110

111

Tab

le 3

.3. R

esponden

ts’

per

ceiv

ed d

irec

tly-s

tate

d a

nd indir

ectly s

tate

d s

ubje

ctiv

e av

erag

e yie

ld a

nd v

aria

bility a

nd c

ounty

aver

age

State

Directly-stated

average yield

Indirectly-stated

yield (Weibull

implied mean

yield)

County

average

yield

Directly- stated

minus county

average yield

a

Indirectly-stated

minus county

average yield

a

Observations

Count

bu/ac

bu/ac

bu/ac

bu/ac

bu/ac

IA

49.0

9

45.4

0

45.1

9

6.8

0***

0.2

1

190

IN

50.0

2

44.9

7

45.4

5

8.3

8***

-0.4

9

55

IL

49.9

5

46.0

3

45.4

6

6.7

5***

0.5

7

137

Tota

l 49.5

3

45.5

6

45.3

2

6.9

9***

0.2

4

382

a Sig

nif

ican

tly g

reat

er than

zer

o a

t p<0.0

5(*

), p

<0.0

1(*

*)

and p

<0.0

01 (

***).

111

112

Table 3.4. Regression results

Model 1: Yield

Difference

(Subjective -

Objective Mean)

Model 2: Yield Mean

(1 if above county

average, 0 below)

Model 3: Yield

Variability (1 if less or

as variable then county

average, 0 below)

Coefficientsa Coefficients

a Coefficients

a

Intercept 5.61367* 0.97256* 0.94782* SIZE 0.00103 0.00003 0.00004 AGE -0.02706 -0.0009 -0.00064 EDU -0.49932 0.0048 -0.02849 IA -0.51656 -0.06089 -0.05044 IL 0.07491 -0.06266 0.06428 SSD 0.04937 0.00044 -0.00748 Ajd R2 0.00215 -0.00638 0.01314

F(7, 382) 1.30745 0.76533 2.02008* a Significantly greater than zero at p<0.05(*), p<0.01(**) and p<0.001 (***).

113

Table 3.5. Subjective and objective scalers calculated using survey (Illinois producers) and FBFM data (averages, at state level)

Scaler Scaler Difference

Subjective

(Survey) FBFM Survey - FBFM

Average 1.67 1.52 0.15 Min 0.74 0.62 -1.54 Max 4.03 3.03 2.42 St.Dev 0.62 0.54 0.83 Count 137 1054 -

114

CONCLUSION

The purpose of this dissertation was to examine factors that affect farmers’

participation in crop insurance programs. In particular, the dissertation examined the

impact from RMA rules on the participation and relationship between farmers’

perceptions and crop insurance purchasing decisions. The first chapter analyzed the

impact of RMA’s rules on the performance, participation, and risk protection level of

APH insurance, using NASS county-level yield data. The second chapter

investigated the role of the misperception biases in insurance-purchasing decisions in

presence of risk management tools. The third chapter considered correspondence

between subjective yield perceptions recovered under different elicitation formats

and county-level yields.

The findings revealed a series of insights explaining the relationship between

participation, RMA rules, and farmers’ perceptions. Examination of RMA rules that

omit trend and sample size variability revealed that the current rules create a

significant lag in yields (relatively to the expected yields) leading to the lower

protection levels under APH yields (reductions from 16% to 34% depending on the

length of the APH period). Results also suggested the presence of adverse selection

as probability of APH yield being greater than expected yields ranged from 10% to

33% depending on APH base period. The results also revealed that the current RMA

premiums exceed actuarial costs even after controlling for catastrophic loading by

factor of 1.8 to 2.3. The lag in yields along with the resulting declines in protection

levels and increases in the premiums relatively to the actuarial costs, explain the

farmers’ reluctance to participate in the crop insurance program and justify current

115

provision of subsidies. The approach toward adjusting yields for the trend is

suggested that has potential to improve the protection levels and reduce RMA

premiums in relation to the actuarial costs. Implementing this adjustment would not

require changes in the current rating structure and has potential improving

participation and actuarial performance of the crop insurance.

The examination of the econometric results from demand model provides

further insights into farmers’ behavior. The results illustrated that age increases

probability of participation for revenue and CAT insurance, and decrease the

probability for yield insurance. Leverage increases the probability of participation

for revenue and CAT insurance products, while farm size decreases the probability

for all insurance products. Diversification (measured as sales of livestock) decreases

the likelihood of purchase across all insurance products, and the probability of

receiving insurance payments increases the likelihood for the use of yield and

revenue insurance, and decreases it for CAT insurance. This significance is

consistent with the results from simulation model that showed presence of adverse

selection. Results also suggested that farmers who had used other risk management

tools before are more likely to participate in crop insurance program as well. An

implication could be that RMA should consider providing discounts for a continuous

use of crop insurance, and target farmers who actively use other risk management

tools. Accounting for trend and bringing more farmers through effective targeting

(both in terms of risk management usage and age) could mitigate adverse selection.

Results also showed presence of the BTA effect in directly elicited yields while

revealing no such relationship for yield elicited under probabilistic framework.

116

However, the econometric results showed no relationship between subjective yields

and crop insurance purchase, suggesting that the BTA effect could be due mainly to

the elicitation format. We argued that direct elicitation does not require significant

mental efforts and may be viewed as less serious by the subjects, and as a result

directly-elicited yields tend to be less reliable. While results suggested little

relationship between BTA effect and participation, further training and education

might benefit farmers by making farmers aware of the bias.

The findings presented here are as with all empirical studies, subject to the

data and methods limitations. Future examinations of RMA rules for trend and

sample size variability might benefit greatly from incorporating spatial analysis of

crop yields, since spatial element in yields is likely to play a significant role in

determining yield trend and variability. Furthermore, continuous improvement in

seed varieties is likely to impact trend and sample size variability further. In

particular, for the behavioral implications, future analysis will benefit from a more

detailed examination of the factors that determine the discrepancies between

objective and subjective yield elicited in the probabilistic framework and subjective

yields elicited using open-ended questions. The future analyses of risk perceptions

and crop insurance participation would benefit from inclusion of more psychological

variables (such as risk aversion for example) in econometric demand models and

extending the analyses to different crops and geographical regions.

117

REFERENCES Babcock B.A., and C.E. Hart, and D. J. Hayes. “Crop Insurance Rates and the Laws of Probability” Center for Agricultural and Rural Development (CARD) Publications 02-WP 298, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development (CARD) at Iowa State University. April-2002. Bakshi G., and Z. Chen. “Baby Boom, Population Aging, and Capital Markets.” The

Journal of Business, 67(1994): 165-202. Barnett B.J.,, J. R. Black, Y. Hu, and J. R. Skees, "Is Area Yield Insurance Competitive With Farm Yield Insurance?" Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Vol. 30, No. 2 (2005): 285-301. Barnett, B.J., J.R. Skees, and J.D. Hourigan. “Examining Participation in Federal Crop Insurance.” Staff paper 275, Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Kentucky, Lexington, August 1990. Barry P., Ellinger P., Schnitkey G., Sherrick B., Wansink B. “The Crop Insurance Market: Producer Preferences and Product Attributes.” Report prepared for Risk Management Agency USDA. University of Illinois, Urbana Champaign, 2002. Bessler, D. “Aggregated Personalistic Beliefs on Yields of Selected Crops Estimated Using ARIMA Processes.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 62(1980): 666-674. Biais B., Hilton D., Mazurier K., and Pouget S. “Judgmental Overconfidence, Self-Monitoring, and Trading Performance in an Experimental Financial Market.” Review

of Economic Studies, 72(2005): 287-312. Bluman A. Elementary Statistics: A Step by Step Approach. New York: McGraw-Hill Companies (2001): 433-441. Carriquiry M., B. Babcock, and E. Hart. "Using a Farmer's Beta for Improved Estimation of Actual Production History (APH) Yields," Center for Agricultural and Rural Development (CARD) Publications 05-wp387, Center for Agricultural and Rural Development (CARD) at Iowa State University. May 2005. Champ, P.A., and R.C. Bishop. “Donation Payment Mechanisms and Contingent Valuation: An Empirical Study of Hypothetical Bias.” Environmental and Resource

Economics 19 (2001): 383-402. Coble K., T. Knight, R. Pope, J. Williams. “Modeling Farm-Level Crop Insurance Demand with Panel Data.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78(1996): 439-447.

118

Eales J., B., Engel, R., Hauser, and S. Thompson. “Grain Price Expectations of Illinois Farmers and Grain Merchandisers.” American Journal of Agricultural

Economics, 72(1990): 701-708. Egelkraut, T.M., B.J.S. Sherrick, P. Garcia, and J. M. E. Pennings. 2006a. Farmers’ Subjective Perceptions of Yield and Yield Risk. Proceedings of 2006 NCCC-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk. Egelkraut, T.M., B.J.S. Sherrick, P. Garcia, and J. M. E. Pennings. 2006b. Producers’ Yield and Yield Risk: Perceptions versus Reality and Crop Insurance Use. Proceedings of 2006 AAEA Conference Long Beach, California.

Glaser, M, and M. Weber. "Overconfidence and Trading Volume," University of Mannheim Working Paper, 2003. Goodwin, B.K. “Premium Rate Determination in the Federal Crop Insurance Program: What Do Averages Have to Say About Risk?” Journal of Agricultural and

Resource Economics, 19(1994): 382-95. Josephson, G. R., R. B. Lord, and C. W. Mitchell. “Actuarial Documentation of Multiple Peril Crop Insurance Ratemaking Procedures.” Report prepared for the U.S. Department of Agriculture, Risk Management Agency, by Milliman and Robertson, Inc, 2001. http://www.rma.usda.gov/pubs/2000/MPCI_Ratemaking.pdf (accessed March 2006). Jung A., and C. Ramezani. “Valuing Risk Management Tools as Complex Derivatives: An Application to Revenue Insurance.” Journal of Financial

Engineering, 8(1999): 99-120. Ker A., and B. Goodwin. “Nonparametric Estimation of Crop Insurance Revisited.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(2000): 463-78. Lichtenstein, S., B. Fischhoff, and L. Philips (1982) Calibration of probabilities: ed.: Judgment Under Uncertainty : Heuristics And Biases 306-334, New York. Mahul O., and B. Wright. “Designing Optimal Crop Revenue Insurance,” American

Journal of Agricultural Economics, 85(2003): 580:589. Nerlove, Marc and D.A. Bessler 2001. “Expectations, Information, and Dynamics,” Chapter 3 in Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Bruce Gardner and Gordon Rausser editors, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, pages 155-206. Norris P., and R. Kramer. “Elicitation of Subjective Probabilities with Applications in Agricultural Economics.” Review of Marketing and Agricultural Economics, 58(1990):127-147.

119

Pease J. “A Comparisons between Subjective and Historical Crop Yield Probability Distributions.” Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics 15(1993): 339-350. Ready, R.C., S. Navrud, and W.R. Dubourg. “How Do Respondents with Uncertain Willingness to Pay Answer Contingent Valuation Questions?” Land Economics 77(2001): 315-326. Rejesus R.M., and A.C. Lovell. “Are added land and new producer provisions in crop insurance vulnerable to abuse? The case of insured Texas cotton producers.” Journal of

Cotton Science, 7(2003): 75-85. Rejesus, R.M., K.H. Coble, T.O. Knight, and Y. Jin. “Developing Experience-Based Premium Rate Discounts in Crop Insurance.” American Journal of Agricultural

Economics. Vol. 8, No. 2 (2006): 409-419 Schnitkey G, Sherrick B., and Irwin S. “Evaluation of Risk Reductions Associated with Multi-Peril Crop Insurance Products” Agricultural Finance Review, 63(2003): 1-21. Shaik S., K., Coble K. and T., Knight T.2005. “Revenue Crop Insurance Demand.” Proceedings of 2005 AAEA Conference Rhode Island, Providence. Sherrick, B. “The Accuracy of Producers’ Probability Beliefs: Evidence and Implications for Insurance Valuation.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource

Economics, 27(2002): 77-93. Sherrick, B. J., F. C. Zanini, G. D. Schnitkey, and S. H. Irwin. “Crop Insurance Valuation under Alternative Yield Distributions.” American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 86(2004a): 406-419. Sherrick B., Barry P., Ellinger P., and Schnitkey D. “Factors Influencing Farmers' Crop Insurance Decisions.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 86(2004b): 103-114. Skees J. R., and M. R. Reed. “Rate-Making and Farm-Level Crop Insurance: Implications for Adverse Selection.” American Journal Agricultural Economics 68(August 1986): 653-59. Smith H., and Baquet A. “The Demand for Multiple Peril Crop Insurance: Evidence from Montana Wheat Farms.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 78(1996): 189-201. Svenson, O. “Are We All Less Risky and More Skillful Than Our Fellow Drivers?” Acta Psychologica, 47(1981): 143-148.

120

Taylor, S. E., & Brown, J. D. “Illusion and Well-Being - a Social Psychological Perspective on Mental-Health.” Psychological Bulletin, 103(1988): 193-210. U.S. Congress. House of Representatives. Subcommittee on General Farm Commodities and Risk Management of the Committee on Agriculture 109th Cong., 2nd sess., 2006. U.S. Congress. House of Representatives. Subcommittee on General Farm Commodities and Risk Management of the Committee on Agriculture 108th Cong., 2nd sess., (Addendum: Issues from 2003 public hearings) 2004 Van Asseldonk, M, M. Miranda, and H. Ruud. “Belief in Disaster Relief and the Demand for A Public-Private Insurance Program,” Review of Agricultural

Economics 24(2002): 196-207. Zanini F., Sherrick B., Schnitkey G., and, S.Irwin. Crop Insurance Valuation Under Alternative Yield Distributions. (2001) Proceedings of 2001 NCCC-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk

121

AUTHOR’S BIOGRAPHY Alisher Umarov was born in Parkent, Uzbekistan, on May 29, 1978. He graduated

from North Dakota State University in 2000 with a degree in economics. He

completed a Master of Science in Economics from North Dakota University in 2003.

He is currently employed as a senior consultant for J.D. Power and Associates.