Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

download Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

of 39

Transcript of Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    1/39

    A CRITIQUE OF EXISTING THEORIES OF THATCHERISM

    AND A CONTRIBUTION TO A MARXIST THEORY OF

    CAPITALIST DECAYPETER KENNEDY

    Making sense of Thatcherism' has preoccupied the Marxist left in Britain

    for the past decade or more. Much has been written on how 'Thatcherism's'

    'authoritarian style populism' has swept the 'hegemonic' board in terms of

    ideology, politics and culture.1 As Andrew Gamble observes:

    The term 'Thatcherism' was widely adopted and used to indicate

    the style of Thatcher's political leadership, the new ideology

    which she endorsed, and the policies of the Thatcher Government.

    All these elements are important, but Thatcherism is best

    understood as a specific political project, not just of Thatcher

    herself, but of an important current within the Conservative

    Party.2

    To Andrew Gamble's credit he has at least attempted to provide a

    structural explanation for the emergence of so called 'Thatcherism' (see A.

    Gamble 1990). As he acknowledges above, however, his concern has been

    primarily with a wholly politically based structural analysis. He has placed

    Thatcherism within the Right wing tendency which has emphasised the

    two-fold need for 'a free economy/strong State' and a rejection of

    'collectivism' and 'social Democracy'. At this political level, questions of

    what exactly constitutes a 'free economy' or 'collectivism' are never

    discussed. In other words a wholly political account generally rests upon

    the acceptance of the empirically given and so by-passes, or takes for

    granted, the all important social categories of explanation that could be

    1 See in particular Marxism Today throughout the 1980s.

    2 Social Studies Revue, VoI6 No3 Jan 1991, p 88.

    95

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    2/39

    provided by Marxism. In this sense a Marxist political economy of

    'Thatcherism' is still required.

    Marxist categories must surely be the basis upon which to construct theories

    of ideological and political hegemonies. More importantly, a Marxist

    political economy may well lead one to re-examine and place in a new

    context the whole concept of a 'Thatcherite hegemony'. Looked at from

    this point of view, it will hopefully become clear that present day Marxism

    has surely been running before it has learnt to walk. Confirmation that this

    is the case comes easily to hand. For example, we know that 'Thatcherism'

    emerged out of the ashes of 'Labourism' but Marxists have yet to explain

    the full implications of 'Labourism'. How then can they possibly offer an

    adequate explanation of 'Thatcherism'? Certainly, no one denies the link

    between the two.

    There are two main strands to current Marxist theory on the subject of

    Labourism. On the one hand, Labourism is reduced to two amorphous

    concepts which have preoccupied the minds of the left: 'Fordism' and

    'Keynesianism'. As such, Thatcherism then becomes aligned with theemergence of an equally ambiguous concept, 'Post-Fordism'. On the other

    hand, Labourism is linked to the failed project of halting capitalist decline.

    Thatcherism is then aligned with the emergence of a new capitalist strategy

    to halt the process of decline. The latter point of view offers most potential

    for both an understanding of Thatcherism and Labourism. However, to

    date, Marxists have failed to adequately explain what exactly capitalist

    decline means. These criticisms will be taken up further in section 1 below.

    There it will be argued that the ambiguities of'Fordism/Post-Fordism'" are

    so profound that they cannot be used as the political economic basis of

    either Labourism or Thatcherism. Following this, in section 2, a brief

    outline of Marx's labour theory of value is provided. Here the emphasis is

    placed on the contradiction within labour. It is this contradiction and morespecifically, its negation, that lies at the heart of a Marxist understanding

    of Labourism and Thatcherism. This latter claim will be taken up and

    expanded on in section 3. In section 3 we are specifically interested with

    the emergence of "Labourism" and 'Thatcherism'; the article does not

    concern itself with a detailed analysis of the two social categories once

    consolidated. To understand why they emerged is the key to understanding

    the nature of capitalist decay in Britain, which is really the central concern

    of this article. The argument in this section is as follows. Firstly, Marxism

    must come to terms with 'Labourism' as a social category which itself

    96

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    3/39

    emerges out of a decaying form of capitalism and which extends

    capitalism's life beyond its years. Secondly, the emergence of

    'Thatcherism', for all its minor successes, has served only to escalate

    capitalism's decay and so bring closer the day when workers must take

    democratic power into their own hands, as capital wanes and conscious

    regulation of social labour becomes a political necessity. The subjective

    factor now becomes the important question.

    1.1: THE AMBIGUITIES OF 'FORDISM/POST-FORDISM'

    For Stuart Hall, who has written extensively on the topic, "Thatcherism's

    project can be understood as operating on the ground of longer, deeper,

    more profound movements of change". These longer deeper, more

    profound movements turn out to be a loose ensemble of technical changes

    all and sundry have termed 'Post-Fordism'. Given 'Post-Fordism's'

    apparent importance for understanding 'Thatcherism', it is essential to

    define it. Unfortunately 'Post-Fordism' has evaded all attempted

    explanation. As such it has remained a catch-all phrase for every passingflight of fancy in society in the past 15 years. Hall and most others who

    adhere to this ambiguous concept are at least certain about one thing:

    'Post-Fordism' is no "epochal shift, of the order of the famous transition

    from feudalism to capitalism"; it is merely another onward and upward

    phase in the life of capitalism, or, as Hall puts it: the transition "from one

    regime of accumulation to another, within capitalism".

    According to Hall anyone expecting a precise definition of such an

    important social category is simply misguided. As Hall would have it, "This

    stand and deliver way of assessing things may itself be the product of an

    earlier type of totalising logic which is beginning to be superseded. In a

    permanently transitional age we must expect unevenness, contradictory

    outcomes, disjunctures, delays, contingencies, uncompleted projectsoverlapping emergent ones". One response to this might well be to ask

    3 S Hall and M Jaques, New Times, p126, 1990, Lawrence and Wishart

    4 Ibid. p 127 (emphasis mine).

    97

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    4/39

    why one should give the status of a totalising concept such as Tost-Fordism'

    to what Hall admits is an ensemble of accidents. Firstly, as noted, he

    informs us that 'Thatcherism' is the product of something 'deeper' and

    'more profound', namely Post-Fordism; then we are told 'Post-Fordism' is

    part of a set of 'contradictory outcomes' and 'uncompleted projects'. So

    which is it to be? Of course, tendentially, they can be both, however Hall

    does not explain why or how this could be so. This is not just Hall's problem,

    but a problem for a whole epoch of 'Marxisms'.

    The lack of clarity is to be expected due to the fact that 'Post-Fordism' itself

    is the amorphous offspring of that reified concept 'Fordism': reify 'Fordism'

    and one reifies 'Post-Fordism'. The theory of 'Fordism' was, it has to be

    said, a gross reification of capitalist social development. Its history is a long

    one, however, for Marxists, 'Fordism' came to prominence with the 'french

    regulation school' of Marxism. Basically Fordism, as conceived by the

    'regulation school', is an 'ideal-type' concept in the best tradition of

    Weberian sociology and the worst traditions of Marxism. A technically

    determined capitalist historical development is invoked, in which twodistinct capitalist stages follow, one after the other, in chronological time.

    The first stage was characterised by absolute surplus value extraction

    (extensive accumulation) and an unstructured distribution/consumption

    sphere (competitive regulation). The second stage was relative surplus

    extraction (intensive accumulation, or 'Fordism') and a

    structured/managed distribution/consumption sphere. The reason for the

    change from one to the other had little to do with the specifically capitalist

    valorisation process and Capital-Labour contradiction. Instead the change

    was said to be a product of the mismatch between production Departments

    'one' and 'two' which was, in turn, exacerbated by a lack of consumer

    demand for final products.

    The movement from stage one to stage two of capitalist development soughtthe resolution of, what was effectively claimed to be, a realisation problem.

    This was to be accomplished by the management of consumer demand via

    Keynesian inspired fiscal policy. However, no sooner had 'Fordism'

    98

    5 Ibid.

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    5/39

    resolved the contradiction than it began to falter under yet another value

    realisation problem as consumer demand failed to keep up with

    accumulation once again. This gave birth to the next stage in capitalism's

    apparent quest to regulate production with consumption - 'Post-Fordism'.

    Here it is argued 'Fordism' -characterised by relative surplus value

    extraction, monopoly capitalism, the standardised product and worker -

    had given way to a Tost-Fordist' world, characterised by the break up of

    monopoly, product differentiation and the flexible, privatised worker. This

    is not to suggest these tendencies within modern capitalist relations do not

    exist. However the nature of such changes are only superficially

    understood within a 'Fordist-to-Post Fordist' paradigm.

    As Brenner has pointed out the whole foundation of

    'Fordism/Post-Fordism' is profoundly ahistoric, depicting as it does a linear

    path of ever higher stages of capitalist development. It is also

    technologically deterministic, in that each stage is a particular type of

    productive technique driven by the mismatch within the mode of

    distributing the final product. It is fair to comment that the socialcontradiction between Capital and Labour never gets beyond a cameo part

    in the whole proceedings. Because of this, such paradigms cannot explain

    why Labourism had to be dissolved. Surely the whole point of the

    regulation theory approach to capitalist development is to stress

    capitalism's ability to regulate the turnover of commodities in production

    with the realisation of their values in the act of exchange? If this follows,

    then the regulation of production and consumption must still remain of

    paramount importance to capitalism. As such, one would expect the

    'Post-Fordist' transition would be towards greater regulation, perhaps an

    increased dosage of Labourism? Yet the new 'mode of regulation' -

    'Post-Fordism' - has brought deregulation of patterns of consumption, the

    removal of Labourism, and a further uncoupling of finance capital vis-a-visproductive capital. This latter dominance of circulatory capital over its

    fixed nature in production is intimately linked with the emergence of

    Thatcherism. However, 'Post-Fordism' and 'regulation theory* has had

    99

    6 See R. Brenner's article, "The Regulation Approach: Theory and History", in New Left

    Review 188, Sept 1991.

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    6/39

    little of real relevance to say on this matter. On the whole it has to be said

    that 'Post-Fordism' is more a category of the mind than a real abstraction

    from reality. As such it is hardly the sort of stuff on which to base an

    understanding of 'Thatcherism'. But what of that other category which has

    been used as a basis of explanation for the emergence of 'Thatcherism' -

    capitalist decline? The chief problem here is that Marxism has failed to

    adequately explain what exactly it is about capitalism that is in decline.

    Some of the Marxist offerings in this are critically assessed below.

    12: MARXISM AND THEORIES OF CAPITALIST DECLINE INBRITAIN

    Given the 'twilight state' of capitalist social relations in Britain, one might

    think that Marxists would have developed a clear analysis of what exactly

    is in decline. Unfortunately this has not been the case. Of course there has

    been no shortage of theory which puts class struggle at centre stage of

    enquiry into decline. The problem is most of it is intra capitalist class

    struggle and hardly any concerns itself with the Capital-Labour conflict. Inthis respect much Marxist analysis of British capitalism has pumped out a

    surplus of theory depicting the intra class rivalry between finance capital

    and industrial capital. Some, like Coakley and Harris (1983), are

    concerned to reveal the institutional intricacies of the 'City1, and the conflict

    of interest which emerges between this financial network and industry over

    the allocation of money capital (see also G. Ingham, for the more intricate

    analysis of commercial capital). Others (Anderson 1964,1987: Overbeek

    1990) have sought to emphasise the political conflict within factions of

    capital. Their stress is on the 'hegemonic block' which one faction

    (finance) has held over the British economy.

    P. Anderson (1964,1987) has argued that the source of decline has nothing

    to do "with factors internal to the capitalist social relation". His basicargument is as follows: Despite the fact that 'the present crisis is a malady

    of the whole society", it has had nothing to do with the working class or

    production relations. This class has "achieved no victories, but its defeats

    were astonishing", claims Anderson. Outmanoeuvred in the 1832 reform

    movement by industrial capital; its political economy of 'Owenism'

    defeated by 1836; its Chartist alliance crushed by 1848; politically

    decapitated by Fabianism and patronised by a labourist elite; the working

    class had, according to Anderson, become acquiescent and conservative

    and remains so to this day. The problem of decline, then, for Anderson,

    100

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    7/39

    has nothing to do with labour. In fact it has nothing essentially to do with

    the capitalist class! The problem, we are told, is outside the internal

    relations of capitalism, it is in fact pre-capitalist in nature. Apparently a

    landed aristocratic elite have never relinquished state power and are thus

    able to block the road to capitalist development by stifling the

    entrepreneurial spirit with traditional aristocratic values of immediate

    gratification and abhorrence of thrift.7

    Another important study of British decline has been G. Ingham's

    Capitalism Divided(1984). Ingham's stated task was to go beyondAnderson's 'anti-industrial capitalist aristocratic hegemony" thesis, not so

    much to reject it, on the basis that Anderson sought to explain capitalism's

    decline via social groups outwith the capital-labour relation, but to theorise

    it more deeply by breaking down the distinct features and functions of

    'money capital' and its dominance over 'productive capital'. Ingham, like

    Anderson, rejects the explanatory power of the labour theory of value and

    takes the next logical step of rejecting the applicability of Marxist historical

    materialism to an analysis of British capitalism. This is because, for himalso, decline is perceived as the product of something external to the

    capital-labour production relation. The external factor being the

    hegemonic stranglehold that commercial money capital has held since at

    least as far back as the restoration of the Monarchy in 1688. In this latter

    period commercial capital bailed out the State; constituted the Bank of

    England in its own interests; and, through the nexus of City-Treasury links,

    systematically sacrificed the interests of capitalism proper (productive

    capital) to the more lucrative commercial laundering of money via the

    matrix of 'Bills of Exchange' on the world market. As Ingham explains in

    a quite sophisticated manner, commercial capital ruled in this way

    throughout the 18th and 19th century and continues to do so in the 20th

    century, predominantly through the euro-money markets established postworld war two. There cannot be many Marxists that doubt this is the case.

    The essential question is why? This is what Ingham fails to explain

    adequately.

    101

    7 Quotes and claims are to be found in Anderson's, "Origins of the Present Crisis", New

    Left Review, No23 Jan-Feb 1964, pp 49-53.

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    8/39

    The important point here is that Ingham ignores the more substantial

    source of decline in the social form of production. In doing so he ignores

    the valorisation process. The result of this omission is critical because

    production from then on in becomes a material technical arena for the

    production of use-values. In turn the essential relation between Capital

    and Labour becomes displaced as a class struggle over the finished

    product; and the 'money form', so central to Ingham's analysis, loses its

    conceptual weight and owes more to Weber and neoclassical economics

    than Marx. Given this, it is little wonder Ingham views historical

    materialism as being economic determinism and so of little use in

    understanding the trajectory of British capitalist social relations. This

    leaves him only one recourse: an empirically based historical explanation.

    Ingham proceeds to glean, from a historical enquiry of British capitalism,

    that financial concerns appear to be consistently at the expense of

    productive capitalism; that the state bureaucratic institutions have a

    separate rational calculating relation which fosters the practice of 'sound

    money" and so inadvertently promotes financial interests; and from this that'Capitalism Divided' is the source of decline and not the Capital-Labour

    value relation. As Longstreth (1979) has pointed out, if the sterling lobby

    or the Treasury dominated economic policy, it was because there was no

    serious opposition to the policies they put forward and not because the

    triad of City-Treasury-Bank of England forced their interests upon the

    policy makers. Longstreth pointed out in 1979 that the picture of banking

    capital forcing through policy measures 'in the teeth of strident opposition

    is indeed a false one'. If it was false in 1979 it is certainly false today after

    15 years of Thatcherism wherein the CBI has remained muted, offering in

    some cases encouragement from the sidelines, whilst the devalorisation of

    the British economy deepened. In other words industrial capital has also

    had an interest in deciding the trajectory British capitalist social relationshave taken. The essential questions then became: What is the nature of that

    interest? Why did it manifest? And, how has it developed?

    A number of other studies appear to take a similar route. For example, the

    extensive work by H. Overbeek (1990). In Overbeek's case the

    'divide-equals-decline' syndrome takes on different aspects. It becomes

    one between 'concepts of control', namely: the 'money concept' versus the

    'productive concept' and how each in turn strive for control of the state and

    the nation's economic course of development. The study offers a useful

    empirical and historical overview of the development of British Capital and

    decline. Unfortunately in no manner of understanding can it be classed a

    102

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    9/39

    Marxist offering, for it too neglects the Capital-Labour conflict in favour of

    the well worn Capital-Capital conflict.

    All these theories have singularly failed to answer the fundamental

    question: what exactly is it about capitalism that is in decline? Instead the

    tendency has been to jump immediately to phenomena which lie outside

    capitalist production; for example, within the circulation of capital (see G.

    Ingham 1984), or, in the so called 'superstructure' (see P. Anderson 1964,

    1987). Decline theses soon become engrossed in the measurement of a

    phenomena Marxists have singularly failed to get to the heart of. In this

    respect analysis, unable to penetrate deeper into the social form of

    production, becomes entranced with comparative studies of decline

    between Britain and other western capitalist nations. Inadequate theory,

    of course, soon leads to reactionary practice as some Marxists, bereft of a

    grounding in Marxist categories, align themselves with

    'De-industrialisation' theory. They then proceed to support bourgeois

    policy designed to curb Britain's 'De-industrialisation' by controlling 'the

    city of London' and so place 'Britain' back on the rails of an 'ideal-typicalcapitalism' such as Germany.

    This has a highly debilitating effect on Marxism's approach to the political

    economy of the Thatcher years. The essential problem here is that Marx's

    categories such as 'abstract labour', 'value', 'fixed' and 'circulating' capital

    have either been ignored, seen as a 'Hegelian detour', of no relevance to

    the 20th century, or else reified into a quantitative 'law of value'; seen as a

    useful analytical tool, or else as a backdrop to 'crisis theory". The 'law* of

    value then arises intact and phoenix like from the ashes of every capitalist

    crisis.

    This failure to make use of Marx's central categories in the spirit with which

    he himself made use of them, has had one result: the Marxist understanding

    of so called 'Thatcherism' has had to make do with that vacuous category'Post-Fordism'. How else is one to speak of a category which is so

    ambiguous and devoid of class content that it can be used to 'prove' two

    entirely opposite theses? For example, for some 'Post-Fordism' bears

    witness' to the rejuvenating ability of capitalism (S. Hall, 1990); for others

    'Post-Fordism' is the product of capitalism in decline (H. Overbeek, 1990)!

    An explanatory category that cannot distinguish whether an entity such as

    capitalism is flourishing or decaying is of little use to Marxists wishing to

    103

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    10/39

    come to terms with the so called 'Thatcher era'. The most fruitful route is

    that taken by 'decline' theorists, yet they either leave out, or, just as bad,

    reify the central categories of a Marxist explanation - abstract labour, value,

    fixed and circulating capital, the formal and real subsumption of labour

    etc... In the third section of this article I bring these categories back to

    centre stage of enquiry and use them to analyze capitalist decline in Britain.

    By doing so I lay the basis for a Marxist understanding of the present epoch

    (so called 'Thatcherism'). Before this, section two will briefly outline the

    essence of Marx's 'value theory of labour'.

    2: THE DIALECTICAL GENESIS OF CAPITALIST DECLINE

    THE CONTRADICTION WITHIN LABOUR (OBJECTIVE

    COMMODITY FETISHISM)

    For Marx an acknowledgement of 'The two-fold character of labour' was

    pivotal for a 'clear comprehension' of capitalism. As capitalism is still with

    us, albeit in a seriously sclerotic form, then any Marxist notions of capitalist

    decay must expose the development and decay of this two-fold character.

    Indeed, as will be made clear, the contradiction within labour and its

    dialectical process of a development and decay are the roots out of which

    firstly Labourism and then Thatcherism grew. It therefore, becomes vital

    to the flow of the argument here that we briefly emphasise the essential

    aspects of Marx's 'value theory of labour'. As will become clear, it is

    primarily an ontological statement about the contradiction between the

    forms of labour in capitalism - on the one hand, concrete, useful, need

    satisfying labour; on the other hand, abstract, value creating labour. After

    detailing this contradiction, we then link its development tendencies to its

    highest form of expression - 'money capital' and the accumulation process.

    In doing so, the contradictions internal to capitalism, which negates the

    contradiction within labour will be all the more clearly exposed (to bedeveloped in section 3). Also in section 3 a tentative 'dialectical history of

    capitalist decay in Britain' will be offered concerning the effects that the

    negation of the contradiction within labour has had on the formation of the

    8 K. Marx, Capital Vol 1, p 49, Lawrence and Wishart, 1983.

    104

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    11/39

    working class and the ruling class in Britain. Firstly, then, a brief outline of

    Marx's 'value theory of labour'.

    As stressed above, the value theory of labour Marx offers is primarily an

    ontological statement concerning the essential social production relations

    endured within capitalism. In capitalist society labour is divorced from the

    means of production and must sell only its own labour power, which now

    stands opposed to it in the form of capital. This simple fact has important

    ramifications, for, if one considers that it is through productive activity that

    labourers are associated, then it is obvious that divorcing labour from the

    means of production atomises every individual labourer, one from another.

    Additionally, the owners and controllers of capital also stand atomised

    from each other. Therefore, all become commodity owners.The above form is the basis of the contradiction within labour: as individuals

    with use value needs and 'bearers of the exchange value producing process'.

    For example, labourers own their own capacity to labour, a useful activity

    which must become an exchange value creating activity if the capacity is to

    be realised. Capitalists, having realised labour's capacity by exchanging itfor a wage and uniting it with the means of production, are also commodity

    owners of many potential use-values at the end of the production process.

    However, like the worker's labour power, commodities remain only

    potential use values until they are exchanged. In this way the capitalist too

    is the bearer of a particular part of the universal value relation. Clearly,

    the 'ideal' for capitalism is to have no directly social production relation

    between individuals (whether intra or inter class). Social relations outwith,

    such as feudal, are crushed under the 'juggernaut of expanding capital', to

    paraphrase Marx; until individuals are of necessity mediated by exchange atevery turn. It is at this point that one has the ontological basis for the riseof the value form and its dominance over society. Stated simply, capitalist

    society ,as an organic whole, expends and distributes social labour, howeverits essential social relations atomise individuals. This ontological fact poses

    the real ontological problem of how individual private concrete labour

    (whether it is the worker offering his commodity labour power or the

    capitalist with a factory full of potential use-values worked up by concrete

    labour) is to be socially sanctioned in such a manner as to reveal its

    expenditure and distribution as socially necessary.

    Clearly it is through market exchange of commodities and so the 'price

    mechanism', that this ontological problem is resolved. For Marx,

    105

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    12/39

    commodity exchange, as its hold deepened on society, was, stripped of all

    unessential content becomes nothing other than the social process between

    individuals which has reduced their holdings of concrete private labour

    to abstract social labour. This social valuation of private labour is achieved

    through the exchange of commodities. In this manner, as Marx remarked

    constantly, our social relations take the form of things because things take

    the social form of value relations. As our social exchange relations develop

    so too does the expression of value, and as such, abstract labour. Eventually

    the social practice of abstracting value creating labour develops out of itself

    a universal equivalent: money gold and, at a more concrete level, the world

    currencies that at different periods of capitalism's history act 'as good as

    gold', namely: Sterling and latterly the Dollar in a more brutalised form.

    The point is the universal equivalent is universal because it is an active

    reflection of capitalism's growing potential to realise its ideal of totally

    atomising individuals as mere commodities and so functions of capital

    expansion. This is why the universal equivalent, or, 'money capital' is the

    value relations most developed form. As such it is abstract social labour'smost attainable bodily form. In effect, it is the material realisation of the

    contradiction within labour; the material embodiment of a social relation.

    One side of the contradiction - abstract universal labour in the value or

    money capital form - allows the other side of the contradiction - concrete

    individual labour - and every other particular commodity, to express their

    exchange value and the value relation between people more adequately. It

    is a situation wherein the particular expresses its existence as a universal.

    Following this, the changes taking place in production, namely, increases

    in productivity, leading to less socially necessary labour time; become

    transmitted via the exchange of commodities for money, which, as abstract

    social labour, is the bodily form of value and as such reveals to the

    commodity its new value. It is this social ontology which the more concreteprice mechanism of supply and demand reflect. The whole drive behind

    such social relations of course evolves out of the capitalist's need to extract

    a surplus from labour. This brief excursion into the basic ontology of Marx's

    Labour Theory of Values leaves one with these initial conclusions: the

    contradiction within labour is that between concrete useful labour and

    abstract labour; abstract labour is the basis of value and value is the basis

    of 'money capital'.

    The above describes capital's 'ideal', it is also clear that a Marxist

    understanding of capitalism in decay must encapsulate that process

    106

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    13/39

    whereby the dual nature of labour begins to disintegrate along with the

    contradiction between use and exchange value. In as much as this is the

    case, decay is a positive progressive category to use, because it explains how,

    with the demise of abstract social labour, concrete social labour, orientated

    toward useful needs, eventually dominates productive intercourse between

    people. Below we develop our understanding of the process of decay by

    considering 'money capital' the general form of capital and as such the

    highest manifestation of capital as circulation capital. Specifically, we

    develop an understanding of the contradictions which build up as capital,

    in order to expand value, has to assume particular forms which become

    increasingly alien to it. The alien forms spoken of are fixed capital and

    eventually even its life blood - variable capital. The latter is the real source

    of capitalist decay.

    2.1 CAPITAL'S INTERNAL CONTRADICTIONS: THE PROCESS OF

    DECAY

    Below the word 'decay* refers to the decay of the contradiction within

    labour mentioned above and expresses two meanings, the one negative the

    other positive. On the one hand it refers to a negative decomposition of

    labour's dual nature: negative in the sense that, without communism the

    concrete, use value, need fulfilling character of labour becomes

    decomposed, or, bureaucratised (the example of health care provision

    these past decades being a case in point). On the other hand, it refers to

    the more positive Latin meaning 'decadere', or, literally, 'falling away*; in

    this case it is positive decay and signifies the 'falling away" of the alienating

    character of labour - its value creating abstract side. This, then, is the dual

    meaning of decay emphasised here. To provide a detailed account of this

    process is beyond the scope of this article. At this point I wish no more

    than to intimate how capitalist decay is generated by the contradictioninternal to the capitalist accumulation process.

    A theory of capitalist decay must start from the recognition that capital

    must of necessity accumulate surplus value in order to survive. We know

    from the above that value's substance is abstract labour and that abstract

    labour, the product of the value relation between Capital and Labour, takes

    as its highest material form money capital. Money capital is the highest

    material form because it best reflects capital's essence as being above all

    circulating capital. Hence here we refer to circulation in its widest sense

    covering production, exchange and distribution of value. Capital, in order

    107

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    14/39

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    15/39

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    16/39

    competition to increase the rate of exploitation. This compulsion saw the

    movement toward the creation of a labour process more in keeping with

    capital's value expanding essence. That is, it saw the movement towards a

    labour process occupied by increasingly abstract homogeneous labour; a

    'labour' more adequate to capital because more adaptable to a speedy

    circulation through the labour process.

    The attempt to reduce labour craft fixity and control over the flow of

    production (the latent abstraction of labour in production) leads to the

    simultaneous growth of capital's fixity in the production process, in the

    material form of concentrated machinery (fixed capital). So, the drive to

    accumulate, compels the capitalist system to increase the abstraction of

    labour, but in the process this requires a greater level of fixity on capital's

    part; a fixity which hinders capital's ability to circulate and accumulate!

    This process may increase the mass and rate of profit, but it also heralds a

    vicious spiral of decline for capitalism. Capitalism begins to 'dig its own

    grave' due to the fact that the same process foists upon capital another, all

    consuming, contradiction - an increasingly socialised labour whichthreatens to negate its value form of existence as abstract labour.

    It is this contradiction which is embedded within the heart of capitalism.

    On the one hand, in order to expand, capital has of necessity to reduce the

    fixity of craft type labour and expand the proportions of its form as fixed

    capital. As such capital is compelled to expand in a form which can only

    circulate value in slow seepages over many turnovers. Exactly how many

    turnovers will depend on the size of fixed capital, a particular capital's

    position in the commodity market and capital's ability to control an

    increasingly socialised workforce. On the other hand capital has to reduce

    all the fixity building up within the production process to socially necessary

    abstract labour, by dissolving itself once more into its general money capital

    form. It must do this if value is to circulate and realise the expansionoccurring in the production process. The contradiction is an acute one for

    the capitalist class. As Marx noted:

    13 See appendix concerning the category of socialised labour.

    110

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    17/39

    As long as it is tied up in the process of production, it is incapable

    of circulation, and hence is virtually devalued. As long as it is

    tied up in circulation, it is incapable of production, posits no

    surplus value, is not capital in process.

    As Marx implies in the above quote, and building on what has been

    suggested above, any 'bottle necks' in the production sphere must act as a

    drag on capitalist circulation and, as such, act as an effective devaluation

    of capital.

    This contradiction becomes more critical when one bears in mind two

    interrelated facts which interweave with the above problems for capitalism.

    Firstly, fixed capital is prone to increasing rates ofmoral depreciation of

    the value imparted to commodities due to the intensity of competitive

    accumulation between capitals. Because of this, productive time becomes

    of the essence. This fact intensifies the imperative for production, as

    valorisation process, to occur as smoothly and as quickly as possible.

    Secondly, we have the major obstacle to this endeavour because higher

    levels of fixed capital bring on to the historical stage a higher concentrationof directly socially combined living labour, which, increasingly, through

    emerging economic and political organisation, act as a barrier to capital's

    exploitation of labour and so a barrier to the smooth efficient use of fixed

    capital.

    As the degree of fixed forms of capital develop, both moral depreciation of

    capital and increased socialisation of labour develop the contradictions

    within the capital value relation. Eventually, for the larger dominant

    capitals which emerge in each industry, the atmosphere in the production

    process becomes unconducive to the risking of large amounts of money

    capital in large scale investments of fixed capital. This becomes the case

    whether the investment is by private capitalist or joint stock companies.

    To briefly recapitulate, I have argued that, due to the competitivecompulsion to expand value, capital must increasingly forgo its essential

    14 MECW No 29, op.cit., p 9.

    111

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    18/39

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    19/39

    production can recommence, relatively safe in the knowledge that the

    socialised labour which emerges to negate capitalism, becomes

    transformed and re-atomised via a bureaucratic regulation of labour in both

    an economic and political sense. However even if this solution works, it

    does so only initially, for it is at great cost to capital in general. It allows

    workers institutional links with the state, through which rank and file

    struggle can be channelled to great effect. It also means the beginning of

    a bureaucratic regulation of abstract labour formation which seriously

    restricts the valorisation process. Looking ahead slightly we can say this

    potential negative effect for capital did actualise itself in Britain throughout

    the 1960s and 1970s, when profit rates declined and worker militancy

    became a major problem for the ruling class.

    The potential bureaucratic solution has of course realised itself in the

    historical process. It is what has often been referred to as 'Labourism'.

    Traditionally, one only refers to 'Labourism' as a political phenomenon

    with contradictory 'Left' and 'Right' political manifestations. The

    argument here, however, is that it must be given further recognition as asocio-economic production category which bureaucratically regulates and

    atomises the labour process and in so doing allows the further latent

    abstraction of labour. In section 3 below a preliminary outline is given of

    the historical dialectic of this process in Britain. After which a preliminary

    contribution to a political economy of so called 'Thatcherism' will be given.

    3: THE HISTORY AND DIALECTICS OF CAPITALIST DECAY IN

    BRITAIN

    We become historically dialectic and so more concrete specific by taking

    the above genetical treatment of capitalism and its emergent decaying

    forms and relating them to a specific capitalist entity, in our case Britain.

    With regard to Britain, the further expansion of capital from the late 19thcentury onward served to develop the contradiction within labour to the

    point where it began to decay. That is, capitalist expansion served to

    develop the socialisation of labour in its drive to create every commodity

    on the basis of abstract socially necessary labour. This emergence of

    socialised labour heralded the point of dissolution of commodity fetishism,

    ie, that contradiction within labour between its useful form and its value

    form of existence. Empirically this revealed itself in the labour movement's

    growing clamour for the social regulation of their own labour and

    113

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    20/39

    productive forces. Some of the dominant ideologies workers became

    drawn to, as their capacity to socialise grew, were 'Ricardian Socialism',

    'Municipal Socialism' and 'Syndicalism'. It was through these versions of

    'socialism' that workers began to organise and advance their political

    demands for socialism.

    The grip of an emerging finance capital over and above domestic

    productive capital in Britain also revealed itself in this late 19th century

    early 20th century period. It can be said to mirror the polar grip that

    militancy and socialism was having on dominant sections of the labour

    movement. History shows that finance capital in Britain emerges from the

    fragmented country banking system and quite rapidly (approximately

    between 1870 to 1920) centralises and concentrates its holding of money

    capital in the 'City of London'. Finance capital does this to escape the

    parochial and restrictive connection with industry. At first finance capital's

    predominant form is imperialism, or, corporate finance capital. That is to

    say, finance capital, through the 'City* orients itself as world capital along

    the lines of the fusion of banking and industry outlined by Hilferding, andlater, Lenin. Its other, higher, development - parasitical capital - is held in

    check in this period, by the imperialist mode. More specifically, the

    clearing banks were increasingly drawn into the web of commercial money

    laundering and the short-termist philosophy of merchant banking. Drawn

    in, it should be noted, by the Bank of England and Treasury. Below is an

    attempt to flesh out the process a little more, by, very briefly, itemising,

    firstly, some occurrences which suggest labour's growing strength and

    secondly, some occurrences which suggest capital's waning powers.

    3.1: ASPECTS OF AN EMERGENT COLLECTIVE LABOUR

    MOVEMENT

    In the first two decades of the 20th century independent working classcollectivity reached new heights which have never been attained since.

    Syndicalist ideas of socialism had gripped the most politically advanced

    sections of labour. The main thrust of its practical politics was that trade

    unions were to become the vehicle for achieving socialism and the General

    Strike was to be the main weapon in the trade union arsenal. The militant

    sections of collective labour were concentrated in Coalmining, Docks and

    Railway industries. Throughout this period, especially 1910-14, strike

    waves deepened and often brought whole cities to a standstill. The state

    had increasingly to resort to sending in police and troops in an attempt to

    114

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    21/39

    regain control; this was the case in, for example, Hull, Manchester, Salford,

    Liverpool and Glasgow.

    The period 1910 to 1921 saw the development of worker 'trades councils'

    and 'cooperatives', alongside the development of 'councils of action'

    throughout the country, which were responsible, among other things, for

    the 'Hands Off Soviet Workers' campaign. Also in this period, the

    increasing tendency of trade unions from different sectors of the labour

    process to act together, irrespective of craft division, began to reveal itself.

    As the Minister of Labour lamented in 1920.

    What is called 'class consciousness' is obliterating the distinction

    between those who follow different occupations. 7

    In this period the rank and file workers' movement was still, in large

    measure, autonomous from the rigid policing role of trade union

    bureaucrat, who, particularly during the first world war, was seen as an

    accomplice to state inspired working class oppression. According to the

    British labour historian J. E. Cronin, it was this period when 'technical,

    social and economic processes' were at work combining to internallyhomogenise the working class and cause it to be 'less sharply divided within

    itself. Increases in the numbers of unskilled and semi-skilled workers

    was the objective basis upon which political collectivity began to be formed.

    Within the cities a distinct working class culture was emerging, which

    allowed the point of production struggles to spill over into political struggle.

    Cronin again notes how

    16 For a concise empirical history of the conflict between capital and labour in Britain see

    J. Sheldrake, Industrial Relations and Politics in Britain 1880-1989, Pinter

    Publishers, 1991.

    17 The Minister of Labour 1920 was cited by J. Cronin in his, Labour and Society in

    Britain 1918-1979, p 22, Batsford, 1984.

    18 Ibid., p 27.

    115

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    22/39

    The militancy of 1917-20 transcended the issues of wages, prices

    and dillusion and even war itself. It was, more than any previous

    or subsequent unrest, a mobilisation of the working class as a

    class and of their institutions and neighbourhoods.

    There is a tendency to scoff at such optimism that the working class in

    Britain were acting as a class, on the grounds that this optimism is born ofan 'economistic' outlook. To some degree this may be justified, however,

    this attitude overstates the scepticism. It does so because the holder by and

    large looks at this period of British worker struggle through the distorting

    prism of Stalinism and Labourism and, as such, the hold these categories

    have exerted on worker politics. What we must not forget is that Stalinism

    had not yet developed and Labourism had still to gain a central place in the

    re-atomisation of the growing worker collectivities and had yet to stratify

    them into bourgeois collective bargaining groups.

    Labour history is of course, full of such anecdotal evidence as that supplied

    above. What it has singularly failed to do is place the growing worker's

    movements within a theory of capitalism's decaying forms. The groundwork for the surge in labour collectivity alluded to above had been laid in

    the last quarter of the 19th century. From 1873 to 1896, in the face of

    declining prices, real wage increases were successfully rested from capital.

    In the same period profits went into a spiral of decline.20 Workers began

    to assert their political economy over and above that of capital: increasing

    use value acquisition and needs were to take precedence over surplus value

    creation. In effect the situation was one where workers increased their

    standard of living, whilst capital, unable to cope with an increasingly

    socialised workforce, had to accept the profit losses and begin its flight into

    finance capital.

    Of course there was counter offensives by capital, from the turn of the

    century until 1914 real wages declined, but, one must stress, only at the cost

    19 Ibid., p 31.20 See any number of economic history textbooks for this evidence. For example, A. E.

    Musson, The Growth of British Industry, pp 149-166, Batsford Academic, 1978.

    116

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    23/39

    of inflationary price rises. The latter being no less than the outcome of the

    pitched battle between labour and capital in this period. Objectively the

    battle was being won by labour, empirically this can be gauged by the

    massive decline in fixed capital formation, as capital reverted to its essential

    circulatory form. Feinstein 1points out that in the period 1873-1913

    productivity growth in Britain slowed to an average of 1% per year, whilst

    the USA, Germany and other developed capitalist economies exhibited

    averages of up to 2%. Fixed capital installation was older and less

    advanced, new industries were slower to develop and managerial strategies

    to control labour were lacking. The essential but simple fact was, capital

    was losing control over an increasingly collective labour. Throughout this

    period and until the late 1920s, the ruling class were in disarray, especially

    so when the influence of the Bolshevik revolution made its impact on the

    working class. Bentley captures the atmosphere in the ruling class camp in

    this period when he remarks how

    The socialism which Lloyd George confronted after 1918

    seemed to him something harder and colder...In thecountry hespoke not of socialism but of bolshevism (and) he wrote of 'the

    great struggle which is to come'.22

    Until the Fabian/Labour Party and the TUC could effectively join forces

    with Conservative social chauvinists such as Chamberlain, to ensure a

    bureaucratic atomisation of the emerging socialised working class, it was

    the likes of Syndicalists, such as Tom Mann, who inspired the worker's

    movement politically. As a ruling class counter-weight it was the

    'Anti-Socialist Movement', the 'Economic League' ideologues who

    inspired the capitalist counter-offensives. Up until that watershed in

    British working class formation, the 1926 general strike, the Labour Party

    and TUC, despite the state's careful nurturing, were essentially still on the

    21 See C. H. Feinstein's, "Slowing down and Falling Behind - Industrial Retardation in

    Britain After 1870", in New Directions in Economic and Social History, Vol 2, Anne

    Digby et al (eds), 1992.

    22 M. Bentley, "The Liberal Response To Socialism", in, K. D. Brown, Essays in

    Anti-Labour History, p 49, MacMillan, 1974.

    117

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    24/39

    side lines with respect to any hegemonic control over the working class.

    Therefore, in this period, on the one hand, we had Syndicalism striving to

    breakdown the political divisions between workers. On the other hand, we

    had a Labourism attempting to consolidate its reason for existence by

    working flat out to deepen sectional divisions in the working class and

    deepen the divisions between the British working class and international

    labour via patriotism.

    32: THE RISE OF FINANCE CAPITAL IN BRITAIN

    In this section a brief consideration will be given to the developmental

    tendencies towards a particular variant of finance capital in Britain. The

    1870s to late 1920s was essentially a period of limbo for capitalism in Britain.

    The objective conditions for a transition to socialism were effectively being

    constructed, regardless of any subjective conclusions otherwise reached by

    the actors involved. Finance capital is predicated upon this . That is,

    finance capital emerges when the capitalist mode of production is in the

    netherworld of decay. There are a number of aspects to the way in whichfinance capital in Britain reacted to this transition period, where the

    contradiction within labour was being positively negated by an emerging

    social and collectively conscious labour movement. We note here only

    some of the essential ones.

    As the contradiction developed between, on the one hand greater levels of

    fixed capital formation and intensified moral depreciation of its value

    holding capacity, and on the other hand the negation of commodity

    fetishism, or, the contradiction within labour; the ruling elements within

    capital ensured the easy passage for capital to revert to type, ie, circulation.

    One notes in this respect the general trend away from capital's 'country

    banking' base to the 'City of London* from the 1870s, which quickened to

    a gallop as the century drew to a close. This was achieved primarily througha spate of mergers. By the early 1920s British finance capital had

    consolidated a remote central banking system operating out of the 'City*

    and had taken up full residence in the world of fictitious capital creation

    (secondary share exchanging and short term money market discounting

    etc). 'Over night' almost, the old 'country banking' network which 'lent

    long* and encouraged a 'healthy* fusion with productive capital, had been

    sublated by the growth of parasitic bank branches - the tentacles of finance

    capital and main arteries through which circulatory capital could assert its

    parasitic dominance of productive capital.

    118

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    25/39

    Of course in the 'City* there had always been a number of avenues for capital

    to realise a return. The two basic distinctions of parasitic activity were

    between money market activity, which lent short to domestic productive

    capital and long to foreign Governments and/or high labour intensive, low

    wage, foreign, private industries. Within this configuration however,

    commercial trading in currencies, bonds, secondary share issues and bill

    discounting became ever more dominant. It is this latter faction of capital

    which eventually became the central focal point for a capital reacting to the

    loss of control over its productive base in the UK. The more the

    contradiction within labour became negated and so the collective strength

    of labour grew, the more deeply did this form of capital feel at home in its

    abstract, fictitious world of M-Ml.

    In its imperialist form, finance capital acted as world banker to all

    developing countries. By exporting capital it was able to replenish itself on

    the surplus value of other nation's labour. The problem was that the first

    world war, caused by this imperialist expansion, served, firstly, to bankrupt

    British finance capital (the celebrated foreign earnings of 4 billion by 1914dissolved to nothing); secondly, served to block the flow of capital abroad,

    due to the restrictions imposed on foreign securities during and after the

    war. Such potential for international restrictions on the flow of capital and

    the growing class tensions within Britain, convinced the British ruling class

    that they must attempt to create favourable internal conditions for the

    return of inward capital investment. In other words finance capital had to

    exert short term discipline upon itself by allowing the state to act in its long

    run interests. The state as repository of finance capital's long term interests

    then sought, firstly to contain, then to incorporate and control the labour

    movement. The only lasting way to accomplish this was to firstly, crush the

    syndicalist influence and secondly, foster the growth of reformist elements

    within the Labour movement. From this point on the strategy of Britishfinance capital was to encourage and foster the growth of Labourism within

    the ranks of the Labour movement. No one should doubt that finance

    capital had the necessary institutional links to carry through this policy.

    Apart from the 'Economic League' and organisations like it, one also has

    the multitude of 'Employer Associations', the systematic interlocking of

    directorships which knits the circuit of capital together and sublates it

    under the influences of finance capital. On top of this one also has the

    persona of finance capitalist influence within the state directing planning

    committees, conciliatory procedures and controlling the Treasury Office

    and Bank of England. As John Scott has pointed out, finance capitalists in

    119

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    26/39

    Britain for the past century have been in effect the controlling power elite

    out of a power bloc consisting of large scale industrial capitalists,

    commercial and landed interests.

    No doubt some historians may dispute the historical chronology or other

    particulars of the above. Arguments have raged amongst economic

    historians for years as to how one should characterise this period in British

    economic history. For some it was a period of 'retardation', for others, a

    period of 'restructuring' before the onset of the 'second industrial

    revolution';others still, deny it as a period altogether, claiming it as simply

    part of the natural evolutionary process that all mature 'industrial societies'

    pass through. In this case Britain merely revealed to other nations a glimpse

    of their own de-industrialising future. It would appear that no matter how

    much one pours over the empirical data, there will always be those who will

    dispute your findings. It seems to me that what has been most needed is a

    theoretical basis upon which to investigate/understand the surplus of

    empirical data collected on the economic history of Britain in the period

    1870-1930.In applying Marxist categories this much has become clear: the emergence

    of finance capital occurred in Britain around the 1870s onward; predicated

    upon a temporarily defeated productive capital that could no longer secure

    control over workers to guarantee an efficient rate of accumulation. As the

    decades of the late 19th century gave way to the early 20th century,

    commodity fetishism, based on the contradiction within labour, began to

    break down. Objectively, then, the special interest given this period by

    historians is warranted, for it is the period which heralds the beginnings of

    the negation of capitalism.

    In essence the period can be characterised as that period in British

    capitalism when the two poles of the commodity mode of production were

    becoming wrenched apart. On the one hand, an increasingly organised

    23 See his book, Who Rules Britain?, Polity Press, 1991. M. Useem, The Inner Circle,

    OUP, 1984, also describes how an "inner circle" (finance capitalists) have dictated the

    political agenda.

    120

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    27/39

    labour movement was advancing to assert the preeminence of useful

    production and need; on the other hand, a retreating finance capital was

    holding on to its fetishised value creating world via a parasitic

    'money-go-round' called the 'City of London'. The intensification of this

    contradiction threatened the existence of commodity production. In this

    respect the emergence of Labourism was no accident.

    33: THE EMERGENCE OF LABOURISM

    Labourism can be said to be the development, within a decaying capitalist

    formation, of a new political economic category. Politically it sought to heal

    the rift between finance capital (the value form) with Labour (use value and

    need) via 'corporate compromise' at the level of the State. Specifically,

    Labour was to be given bureaucratically regulated use value provision

    through the construction of the welfare state. This was at great cost to

    capital, but was the only way of establishing the rule of the policemen of the

    labour movement - the TUC and Labour Party Bureaucracy. Alan Fox,

    like the majority of 'industrial relations' experts, views this period as theconsolidation and integration of 'collective bargaining'. Whatever one

    chooses to call it he is surely correct when commenting thus about its

    substantive purpose

    ...when British ruling groups admitted to a recognised foothold

    in decision making such organisations as demonstrated their

    readiness to pursue their ends within established constitutional

    structures, they thereby creatednew allies in the defence of those

    structures.

    The 'new allies' were the Labour Party and the TUC, and 'those structures'

    refer to the growing society wide network of collective bargaining controls

    over labour. Taken as a whole it constitutes Labourism. Industrial

    relations theory never does get to the bottom of 'collective bargaining', aMarxist approach can.

    24 Alan Fox, History and Heritage, George Allen and Unwin, 1985

    121

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    28/39

    Even more important was Labourism's economic/social dimension,

    because this was the basis for collective bargaining. Labourism can be said

    to be a social category which develops out of the decaying forms of

    capitalism. Its fundamental task being to act as a surrogate form of

    abstracting labour in production. As such, it bolstered the ailing value

    form's role in abstracting labour. By this it should be clear that it does not

    make value formation any more efficient, in fact quite the opposite; its chief

    purpose is to prolong the life of an ailing social relation. If we remember,

    the capitalist value form of labour abstraction brings with it an emerging

    socialised labour, this is one reason why Marx could say that capitalism 'digs

    its own grave'. The task of Labourism was to reverse this socialisation of

    labour via bureaucratic rules and procedures both in the labour process

    and wider society and state. In this way capital found the means for a

    reinvestment strategy in Britain from the late 1920s onward. Unlike the

    'Fordist regulation' theory however this process is not evidence of

    capitalism's health, but rather, in line with the argument here, evidence of

    its decay.One can point to many examples of the growth of this social category. One

    notes, as already mentioned above, the growing theory and practice of

    'Industrial Relations'. This fetishistic preoccupation with a 'scientific'

    enquiry into 'employee/employer' relations has an inverse relation with the

    fortunes of capital, ie, as capitalism decays the academic industrial relations

    'industry1 thrives! From as early as 1868 and the Royal Commission on

    Trade Unions, there developed a labourist clique of reformers, full time

    trades union officials, employer associations. The gruesome combination

    of Fabian bureaucracy and right wing social chauvinism, became the

    bedrock upon which a philosophy of consensus industrial relations could

    emerge. The Whitley Committee created in 1916 was the first national

    vehicle for the institutionalisation of Labourism within the labour process.From another angle, one can observe the importance of the merging

    conscious application of labour process strategies in the face of a declining

    commodity fetishism. This was particularly so in areas of industry where

    the reserve army of labour had 'dried up' and an internal bureaucratic

    regulation of the flow of labour to the needs of capital, had become the

    norm. Direct forms of labour control which shadowed the abstraction of

    labour achieved by capitalism, such as 'Taylorism' were introduced (and

    increasingly so after 1931). Along with 'Taylorism' other labour process

    122

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    29/39

    controls became dominant such as 'human relations theory*. This offered

    a more 'responsive autonomy* method of control, according to Friedman.

    Of course at the concrete level of British class struggle the Labourist

    incorporation of the working class was to be a protracted affair. In

    particular, its 'left' face had to be hammered out on the anvil of class

    struggle over many decades. Indeed it was not until the massive waves of

    labour unrest, which swept through Britain from the late 19th century to

    the 1920s, were finally defeated, culminating in the General Strike of 1926,

    that Labourism could take its place with any real success at the head of a

    depoliticised labour movement. In this respect two important

    phenomenon occur; firstly, it was only after 1926 that the Labour Party and

    TUC took firmer root in the social fabric of capitalism. Secondly, the

    successful depoliticisation of the working class heralded the break from the

    gold standard in 1931. As such it heralded a new era of capital and state

    investment on the basis of cheap money. More importantly it heralded the

    decay of a 'universal equivalent form' for capital, this itself the reflection of

    the deeper chasm developing within the form of labour.This strategic retreat of parasitic finance capital was made more palatable

    by the opening of the 'sterling area'; a corridor which insulated sterling from

    the dollar's world hegemonic position as a surrogate universal equivalent

    abstract labour representative. Throughout the 'corridor', parasitic capital

    could repatriate surplus value, generated in the colonies Britain controlled,

    back to the 'City of London' for speculatory purposes. Meanwhile, with

    Labourism in place, the conditions for the 'corporate' side of British finance

    capital to reinvest in the domestic economy had been created. However

    the tension within capitalism to revert to its parasitic form and the ability

    of labour to counteract the bureaucratic mechanisms of Labourism such as

    collective bargaining, has meant that from 1929 to 1979 any moves towards

    the 'corporate' containment of either finance capital and labour couldnever develop. It is this schizophrenia of British finance capital which has

    characterised what in hindsight came to be seen as the consensus years and

    25 A. L. Friedman, Industry and Labour - Class Struggles At Work and Monopoly

    Capitalism, p 69, MacMillan Press, 1977.

    123

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    30/39

    what I have referred to as the labourist bureaucratic control of the labour

    process. The period was to stretch from 1931 to approximately 1973. There

    are those on the left who have described this area as a peculiar kind of half

    hearted attempt at 'Fordist production regimes'. I have argued here that

    this 'Fordism' can be best understood as a social category which emerged

    to contain workers - Labourism. The reason as to why it was such a

    contradictory affair, or, 'half hearted', is wholly to do with the peculiar

    schizophrenic nature of British finance capital. On the one hand it has

    exhibited spasmodically its 'Hilferding type' form (note the corporate

    financial structure of Germany); whilst on the other hand it has been

    systematically pulled awry by its highest parasitic form via speculative

    activity in world money markets. A full appraisal of this must be the subject

    of another work. The point to be stressed here is that Labourism emerged

    to dominance in the late 1920s and became consolidated by the events of

    the post 1945 world order. It eventually began to wane, firstly, under its

    own internal contradictions. The chief contradiction was that working class

    rank and file organisations, bolstered by the promise of full employment,threatened the existence of Labourism. A second contradiction was the

    world capitalist slump, which began to assert itself in the late 1960s - early

    1970s and brought an end to a rate of profit which could afford such a

    compromised value relation. It was out of the ashes of Labourism that so

    called 'Thatcherism' emerged.

    3.4: 'THATCHERISM'

    The waves of growing working class militancy throughout the late 1960s and

    most of the 1970s are evidence of, by this time, an increasingly socialised

    production process facing a capitalist class increasingly bereft of its

    labourist support. Faced with a world slump, the costly bureaucratic

    compromise between labour and capital simply had to be removed. Nomatter the degree of apparent pragmatism at work in this period, the logic

    was clear: Labourism hindered valorisation; could no longer control the

    working class, therefore Labourism had to be removed! However, removed

    under conditions as favourable as was possible to a decaying capitalism.

    The Thatcherite ruling class faction's onslaught post 1979 was no

    'hegemonic victory. In its essence it was a set of pragmatic policies

    designed to carve out a breathing space for capitalism in the hope that, with

    the demise of Stalinism in the East, fortunes may change. In the short term

    the so called Thatcher 'strategy* was simply to break up the bureaucratic

    restrictions on valorisation, whilst also breaking up any socialising

    124

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    31/39

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    32/39

    as 50%. In the capitalist sector gross domestic capital formation fell by

    33% between 1979-83.27 The money form has been used to dissolve the

    bureaucratic association that had ossified into the social fabric in the

    decades of Labourist dominance around the production of needs. This was

    done by imposing 'cash limits' on the public sector; and imposing 'merit

    pay' wage rises, awarded to workers on an individual basis. These

    particular strategies served to break the material basis of Labourism. In

    effect it left the mechanism of control such as collective bargaining in tact,

    but without any context. Basically, collective bargaining has been 'hollowed

    out' - only the framework survives, buttressed by so called 'Human

    Resource Management' goals (we return to this briefly below).

    Secondly, the breaking up of large production units in the name of 'Post

    Fordism' and its derivative 'just-in-time production' occurred. In 1973-4

    there were some 1018 workplaces employing a labour force of over one

    thousand; by 1982-3 this figure had almost halved to 5S9.28 This particular

    strategy, as well as facilitating the break up of socialised labour and allowing

    abetter environment for the intensification of abstracting labour, (tendencytowards the flexible worker, just-in-time production, labour

    surveillance..etc); also served another important purpose. It served to shift

    the burden that unproductive labour was exerting on profitability from the

    stronger capitalist to the weak. Thirdly, a collection of so-called

    'supply-side' policies designed to recommodify the labour process. The

    chief policy being to whip the labour movement back into line by creating

    a large scale reserve army of unemployed. By the early 1980s that arch

    representative of capitalist interests, Nicholas Ridley, could assure his pay

    masters that "the high level of unemployment is evidence of the progress

    we are making". One Employment Act after another has sought to

    27 Ibid.

    28 Business Monitor 1974 and 1985, cited in, A. Callinicos and C. Harman, The Changing

    Working Class,p 57, 1987.

    29 Quote taken from J. Eldridge et al, Industrial Sociology and Economic Crisis,p 32,1991.

    126

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    33/39

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    34/39

    nature. Of course, as Clarke observes, the Utopias of Post-Fordism and

    'flexible specialisation' have no vision and 'serve to rationalise the

    complacent self-satisfaction of a small stratum trying to invent for itself an

    historical role'.31Nevertheless, it is incumbent on Marxists to extract from

    this mishmash the 'rational kernel' within.

    The Thatcherite project to re-commodify workers has had very limited

    success. The main purpose was an impossible one to achieve the

    re-establishment of capitalism in its prime. For all the attempts to control

    labour via the re-imposition of the commodity form in workplace relations,

    there has been little capitalist regeneration of the economy. Capital has

    refused to invest on the scale required and so most of any increase in

    valorisation rates have come solely from the intensification of work. As the

    scale of de-industrialisation suggests, the relations of production stand

    opposed to the forces of production. Without the re-invigoration of the

    value form 'marketisation' of the public sector has been a bureaucratic

    sham. State regulation of such hybrids as British Gas, and the different

    'Water Companies'...etc and 'contracting out' of Health and Educationprovision, has simply lead, contrary to ideology, to greater state regulation

    than ever before. The deregulation of finance capital has further retarded

    any attempts to re-commodify production relations in Britain. In the past

    15 years the pace of the flight of capital away from Britain surprised many.

    With its favoured long term options in Eastern Europe turning sour, its

    parasitic presence can only increase and increase the de-industrialisation

    trend in Britain. As for the changes that have confronted workers in the

    workplace, these too are fraught with long term difficulties for the ruling

    class of Britain. As Gough has explained, the high degree of interrelation

    of abstract workers implied by the fetishised forms of flexible functionalism

    and just-in-time-producing..etc, create the ground upon which the future

    strength of the working class can be built. In the sense that the processintegrates workers across skill boundaries, whilst creating inflexibility for

    capital, especially with the commitment to 'core' worker status. A future

    article will deal with the contradictions of Thatcherism in some detail. The

    task here was to put in place the foundations of an understanding that

    31 Simon Clarke, ibid., p 28

    128

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    35/39

    stretches beyond the particular time period of Thatcherism' and situate it

    within a general theory of the decay of capitalist social relations of

    production in Britain.

    CONCLUSION

    This article has claimed that Marxists up to date have singularly failed toprovide a political economy of what has, for convenience, been called

    Thatcherism'. It was pointed out that 'Post-Fordism' and 'Capitalist

    Decline' theses were inadequate to the task. The former because it was

    merely a Weberian 'ideal-type' concept held together by an eclectic series

    of empirical observations of conjunctural economic and social trends. The

    latter because it was ill-conceived, dealing only with intra capitalist

    struggle as a reason for decline. Nevertheless, as pointed out earlier, the

    concept of capitalist decline held out most promise in our quest to

    understand both 'Labourism' and 'Thatcherism'. As it stood however the

    category of decline had to be strengthened if it was to bear the weight of

    explanation assigned to it. This article has attempted to do this bytransforming it into a category of capitalist decay. The decay, it was argued,

    resided in the contradiction within labour. Specifically, it was pointed out

    that decay referred to the falling away of labour's value form (abstract

    labour), or, rather, its negation into social collective labour. The drive for

    this transition rested with capital's insatiable desire to expand itself. In the

    process of expansion we described how contradictions emerge for capital;

    chiefly, increasing levels of fixed capital in a climate of increasing moral

    depreciation of capital and an increasingly collective and organised labour

    movement. As argued it is at this juncture that capital reverts to type, ie,

    circulation, and finance capital emerges. Labourism, it was argued,

    develops as a social category in capitalist decline, its functions being to

    rescue the labour process for a recalcitrant finance capital by re-atomisingthe socialised worker thus allowing capital to continue the valorisation of

    labour power. It was then argued that this Labourist solution for capitalism

    lasted in Britain from approximately 1931-73. After which time, and due

    mainly to the world slump, it declined rapidly. 'Thatcherism' emerged out

    of the ashes of 'Labourism'. As argued, with 'Labourism' gone any further

    abstraction of labour would lead only to the re-socialisation of labour, this

    was certainly occurring in the militant 1970s. In this respect it was claimed

    that 'Thatcherism' had two suicide missions; on the one hand the break up

    of socialised labour formation, hence of capitalism itself

    (de-industrialisation for the bourgeois mind). On the other hand the

    129

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    36/39

    freeing of parasitic capital from production, to the promise land of the

    promissory bank note - the 'City1 - where it could find short term security

    in speculative money dealing, in the long term hope of a move to the

    ex-Soviet block countries.

    Of course the above strategy has failed and so called 'Thatcherism' lies in

    tatters. The bourgeois class have no all embracing strategies because they

    have no future. Everything achieved by 'Thatcherism' was negative;

    breaking up the forces of production, atomising workers with anti-trade

    union laws and unemployment and bolstering capitalists with the force of

    the state's coercive institutions; and then allowing both classes to fight it

    out, whilst freeing finance capital to hover over the bones. The future can

    only lie with the working class, the problem is they have to seize it by

    redefining once more, for themselves, a common politics.

    APPENDIX

    SOCIALISED LABOUR AND THE VALUE FORM.

    The category socialised labour has a number of attributes which can bedivided, for analytical purposes, into two levels of abstraction from the

    complexities of the capital relation. At a deeper level of abstraction one

    has socialised labours' genetic attributes, which are properties of the inner

    laws of capitals decay, whilst at a more concrete level of abstraction one

    has socialised labours' historical attributes, which are empirically verified

    trends within production and the labour market. Taking the historical

    attributes first, these manifested around the creation of internal labour

    markets and the increasingly relatively autonomous spheres of control in

    production, which the emerging socialised labourer forced capitalists to

    concede. The fact that in later decades, after the consolidation of

    Labourism, these became transformed as mechanisms of control over

    labour is beside the point. Initially they were capitalist concessions whichcost capitalists dearly; raising labour costs, hindering technical change and

    deflating profit rates. The nuts and bolts of the matter are that the dominant

    capitalist enterprises internalise the employment relation: wages, work

    conditions and division of labour are fixed by internal administration,

    influenced by works councils and less by market forces.

    Much has been written about the historical attributes, however little if

    anything has been written in the way of an explanation of the most crucial

    130

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    37/39

    aspect of the emergent socialised labourer - its genetic attributes as a

    category of capitalist decay. This is a little surprising because the process

    is simple enough to understand. One reason why it has been ignored has

    much to do with methodology. When Marxism refrains from treating the

    law of value as if it were some timeless Kantian concept, the genetic

    attributes of socialised labour become central parts of our understanding

    of capitalism.

    In an earlier section of the article it was explained that at the heart of the

    commodity form of production which defines capitalism, there is a

    dialectical contradiction - the contradiction between use value and

    exchange value. The dialectical contradiction revolves around the fact that

    they are opposing substances united in the one body. To add to this we also

    know that, for Marx, the most important commodity form was labour

    power. With this in mind, let us consider the commodity form more closely.

    The commodity form is a unity of opposites: on one side of the contradiction

    there is concrete private labour, on the other side there is abstract social

    labour. As Marx was at pains to stress in Capital, for concrete privatelabour to be socially useful labour requires it take the form of abstract social

    labour. That is, labour must be valorised and exchanged with money

    capital in order that its social usefulness can be validated. The emergence

    of the socialised labourer effectively short circuits this contradiction and in

    so doing offers the potential ground through which the opposing forces of

    the commodity form of production can be abolished and communist social

    relations established. In what sense does the emergent socialised labourer

    short circuit the commodity form of production? Reverting back to the

    contradiction, the following process of negation occurs. From the

    concrete private labour side of the contradiction the socialised labourer

    develops the powers and complexities of concrete labour. From the

    abstract social labour side of the contradiction, the emergent socialisedlabour develops the inherently social attributes of labour. Combined, the

    social labourer extends and develops its productive activity on the basis of

    directly concrete social labour. In so doing the emergent socialised

    labourer's conscious inclination is to exert political pressure which ensures

    the use value need fulfilling aspect of production as a natural right over and

    above valorisation, which is increasingly perceived as a subordinate

    consideration. The vast empirical evidence of strikes, general labour

    unrest, intensifying community struggles and the growing appeal of socialist

    131

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    38/39

    agitation, which occurred on an ever deepening trend from 1870s to

    approximately 1926, provide ample proof of the above.

    In the Gnindrisse Marx was quite specific about how and why the sociallabourer substantiates itself in production on the basis of concrete social

    labour; and how and why the value form becomes increasingly

    subordinated. Marx argued that under capitalism labour time is the

    ultimate source of wealth in the form of value. However capitalism faces

    an unescapable contradiction which eventually brings about its decay. For,

    as capitalism develops, so too does the social productive power of labour.

    So much so that the product of labour bears less and less relation to labour

    time and so value creation. In other words commodities produced are

    substantiated more and more as use values and less and less as aliquots of

    value (Gnindrissep704-706). As labour power is a commodity, then this ishappening to living labour activity itself; the two-fold contradiction within

    labour (Marx's most important discovery) is dissolving.

    Marx is quite clear as to the cause of this tendency toward the negation of

    the commodity form of production - it is the emergence of the socialisedlabourer and its productive potential which outgrows its value form. As

    Marx argues with respect to the role of the emergent socialised labourer,

    in the above mentioned transformation -

    It is neither the direct human labour he himself performs, nor

    the time during which he works, but rather the appropriation of

    his own general productive power, his understanding of nature

    and his mastery over it by virtue of his presence as a social body

    - it is, in a word, the development of the social individual which

    appears as the great foundation stone of production and of

    wealth. The theft of alien labour time, on which the present

    wealth is based, appears as a miserable foundation in face of this

    new one As soon as labour in the direct form has ceased to bethe great wellspring of wealth, labour time ceases and must cease

    to be its measure, and hence exchange value (must cease to be

    the measure) of use value With that, production based on

    exchange value breaks down, and the direct, material production

    process is stripped of the form of penury and antithesis ' (ibidp705-706, my emphasis in bold).

    132

  • 8/14/2019 Theories of Thatcherism by Peter Kennedy

    39/39

    Again the heart of the irreconcilable contradictions of capital when faced

    by the emerging socialised labour is never made more clearer by Marx than

    in the following statement -

    On the one side, then, it (capital) calls to life all the powers of

    science and of nature, as of social combination and of social

    intercourse, in order to make the creation of wealth independent(relatively) of the labour time employed on it. On the other side,

    it wants to use labour time as a measuring rod for the giant social

    forces thereby created, and to confine them within the limits

    required to maintain the already created value as value. Forces

    of production and social relations - two different sides of the

    development of the social individual - appear to capital as mere

    means, and are merely means for it to produce on its limited

    foundation. In fact, however, they are the material conditions

    to blow this foundation sky-h