THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and...

21
AUTHOR : STEVEN L . SOLNICK, Columbia Universit y TITLE : DEFINING AND MEASURING FEDERALISM IN RUSSIA : A METHODOLOGICAL CRITIQU E THE NATIONAL COUNCI L FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN RESEARC H TITLE WI/ PROGRA M 1755 Massachusetts Avenue, N .W . Washington, D .C . 20036

Transcript of THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and...

Page 1: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

AUTHOR: STEVEN L . SOLNICK, Columbia Universit y

TITLE: DEFINING AND MEASURING FEDERALISM IN RUSSIA :A METHODOLOGICAL CRITIQUE

THE NATIONAL COUNCILFOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN RESEARC H

TITLE WI/ PROGRAM

1755 Massachusetts Avenue, N .W .Washington, D .C. 20036

Page 2: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

PROJECT INFORMATION : 1

CONTRACTOR :

Columbia Universit y

PRINCIPAL INVESTIGATOR :

Steven L . Solnick

COUNCIL CONTRACT NUMBER :

810-0 8

DATE :

May 28, 1 99 6

COPYRIGHT INFORMATION

Individual researchers retain the copyright on work products derived from research funded b yCouncil Contract. The Council and the U.S. Government have the right to duplicate written report sand other materials submitted under Council Contract and to distribute such copies within th eCouncil and U.S. Government for their own use, and to draw upon such reports and materials fo rtheir own studies; but the Council and U.S. Government do not have the right to distribute, o rmake such reports and materials available, outside the Council or U.S. Government without th ewritten consent of the authors, except as may be required under the provisions of the Freedom o fInformation Act 5 U.S.C. 552, or other applicable law .

The work leading to this report was supported in part by contract funds provided by the Nationa l

Council for Soviet and East European Research, made available by the U. S. Department of State under TitleVlll (the Soviet-Eastern European Research and Training Act of 1983, as amended) . The analysis andinterpretations contained in the report are those of the author(s) .

Page 3: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Defining and Measuring Federalism in Russia :

A Methodological Critiqu e

by Steven L . Solnick

Department of Political Scienc e

Columbia Universit y

New York, NY 10027

SLS27 @COLUMBIA .EDU

Submitted to the National Council for Soviet and East European Research

in partial fulfillment of Contract # 810-08

May, 1996

Page 4: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 2

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY '

Assessing the development of center-periphery relations in Russia requires a n

effective definition of "federalism ." To be considered effective, any definition must captur e

the elements of federalism that are central to its appeal in other states, and must als o

facilitate systematic measurement over time .

A federal state is defined as "two levels of government ruling the same land an d

people, each having at least one area of action in which it is guaranteed autonomy ." A

"jurisdictional" conception of federalism focuses on which "areas of action" are in th e

purview of central and regional governments . This critical characteristic of federal system s

fails to be captured by two common approaches to their study : fiscal and constitutional-legal .

Studies of "fiscal federalism" cannot reliably distinguish between omnipresent distributiona l

struggles and more fundamental battles for jurisdictional autonomy . Studies based on

constitutional and legal documents, on the other hand, often conflate powers claimed b y

different levels of government and powers actually exercised by these governments .

A jurisdictional focus requires a direct examination of the division of responsibilitie s

between levels of government, and the degree of policy discord or coordination . The first o f

a series of annual surveys of Russian regional officials was recently completed to begin

tracking the evolution of Russian federalism . Preliminary results of this first survey will be

discussed in subsequent reports to the Council .

'This is the first of three reports from an ongoing research project analyzing and tracing changesin Russian federalism (center/periphery relations), from which additional reports are anticipated throug hJune 30, 1967 . [NCSEER Note]

Page 5: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p .3

Russia represents the world's largest experiment with federal government, at least i n

terms of area. Unlike the Soviet authoritarian state, the quasi-democratic post-Soviet Russia n

regime has exhibited some signs of real devolution of power from the center to the regional level .

To assess whether this devolution of power is significant, observers must begin to think mor e

systematically about the salience of alternative measures of "federalism ." This analysis critiques

two prevailing approaches to measuring "federalism" in Russia: fiscal and legal-constitutional

analyses . I conclude by advocating

a direct study of jurisdictional conflicts .

"Federalism" in Russia : Definition and Significance

According to Riker, a federal state consists of two levels of government ruling the sam e

land and people, each having at least one area of action in which it is guaranteed autonomy . '

Riker draws an important distinction between "centralized" and "peripheralized" federal systems .

In a centralized federal state, most functions are performed by the national authorities ; in a

peripheralized federal state, the federal center is sharply constrained . Riker argues that

centralized federal systems are more likely to survive centrifugal pressures, but are also mor e

likely to see regional autonomy trampled by expanding federal authority . Peripheralized federal

states, on the other hand, are more likely to succumb to regional conflict or even civil war .

Different state structures also have very different distributional consequences : centralized

federalisms are more likely to be able to redistribute resources to poorer subjects, while regiona l

disparities (and, consequently, inter-regional tensions) are likely to be greater in peripheralize d

systems .

Riker's definition emphasizes political and administrative aspects of federalism. In

contemporary Russia, these elements of state structure have been at the heart of the politica l

struggle since the collapse of Communism . In return for their acceptance of the 1992 Federatio n

1 William Riker, Federalism : Origin, Operation, Significance (Boston: Little, Brown and Co ., 1964), esp . p . 11 .See also Riker, "Federalism," in Fred Greenstein and Nelson Polsby, eds ., The Handbook of Political Science, v . 5(Reading, MA : Addison Wesley, 1975) . In this later review article, Riker defines federalism as a division o fjurisdiction between national and regional governments such that each "has some activities over which it has fina ldecisions ."

Page 6: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 4

Treaties, for instance, several republics won special deals : Bashkortostan demanded a specia l

appendix granting it addition control over its foreign trade while Sakha gained additiona l

property rights over natural resources . 2 Since 1992 . other republics and regions have pressed fo r

the right to control appointments or election of sub-national officials (especially in the judicial .

prosecutorial, and media branches, but including the election of regional governors), limit inter -

regional trade, unilaterally adjust tax rates, establish territorial "citizenship," nullify federa l

legislation, and even control the stationing of conscripts drafted from their territory . 3

Riker's definition is not wholly administrative, however . 4 The puzzle posed by Riker' s

theory is why centralization of power in federations leads more often to stable federal system s

and not, ultimately, to the atrophy of sub-national rights and powers . In Riker's theory, political

parties with roots at the local level provide the institutional balance to administrative dominatio n

by the center. In Russia, however, political parties have remained anemic . The survival of

federalism in Russia, therefore, should be associated with 1) limited centralization of politica l

power (an exception to the usual weakness of peripheralized federalisms) ; or 2) consolidation o f

political parties (confirming Riker's theory) 5 ; or 3) the emergence of alternative institutions t o

prevent the "overawing" of regions by the center . 6

Riker's definition of federalism, which I adopt here, neglects several elements o f

federalism that have been the focus of many other avenues of research . Since the emphasis is o n

power and policy — "areas of action" in which levels of government are guaranteed autonom y

2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism . Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i nJeffry Hahn and Theodore Friedgut, eds ., Local Politics in Post-Soviet Russia (Armonk: M.E.Sharpe, 1994), p .247 .

3 Many of these jurisdictional disputes have come to light in the protracted process of drafting constitutions for theconstituent republics, and "charters" for the regions . The process continues as of this writing, with no end in sight .For a useful mid-course overview, see "Analiticheskii obzor konstitutsii respublik vkhodiashchikh v sosta vRossiiskoi Federatsii, " Rossiiskaia federatsiia no .21, 1994 .

4 See Chapter 3 of Federalism .

5 Ways in which local elections might spur the regional development of political parties are considered in Peter C .Ordeshook and Olga Shvetsova, "If Hamilton and Madison Were Merely Lucky, What Hope is There for Russia nFederalism?" manuscript, April 1995 .

6 For example, the role of an independent judiciary as guarantor of states' rights (drawing on the experience o fBritain, Canada and the United States) is developed in Jenna Bednar, William Eskridge, and John Ferejohn, " APolitical Theory of Federalism," manuscript, February I995 . The authors do not extend the argument to Russia ,though much Russian legal analysis of federalism has examined the (still weak) role of the Constitutional Court .

Page 7: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p .5

— this usage pays relatively little heed to formal structures . or to social phenomena. or to

ideologies.7 More significantly, the jurisdictional emphasis has little to say about the role o f

democratic processes or ideology in Russia . Riker, for instance, included the Soviet Union in hi s

list of federalisms, arguing that the mere fact that its federalism fails to prevent tyranny shoul d

not lead to casting it out of the class of federalisms ." 8

Why focus so exclusively on the relationship between levels of governmen t

administration, with so little regard to the nature of those entities? In part, this limited focus i s

dictated by positive theories of federalism, which address the consequences of federal structure .

These contemporary theories link federalism with three systemic outcomes relevant to post -

Soviet Russia : systemic stability, ethnic peace, and economic growth .

The stability and longevity of federal systems was actually Riker's chief focus in hi s

analysis . Two governments seeking to govern the same land and people is the essence of Riker' s

concept of federalism, but it is also the heart of a common definition of revolution . 9 In Riker' s

theory, therefore, the critical ingredient for the emergence of a stable federalism is th e

establishment of a federal "bargain" between national and sub-national leaders over the divisio n

of power. Though Riker sees the federal bargain as a response to external threats, studies o f

state-building in early modern Europe and in empires have revealed negotiated cooptation o f

peripheral groups by the center to be a prevalent route to state (or imperial ) consolidation.10

Federal bargaining, in a real sense, is a modern manifestation of this process, and it represents a

basic approach to state consolidation for post-Soviet Russia .

7 For a broad discussion of the usages of federalism as a concept, see Daniel Elazar, Exploring Federalism(Tuscaloosa, AL: Univ. of Alabama, 1987) .

8 Riker, Federalism, p . 40.

9 This is Charles Tilly's "multiple sovereignty' view of revolutions .

10 An elite cooptation bargaining model for the Soviet space was developed by David Laitin in "The Nationa lUprisings in the Soviet Union," World Politics (October 1991) . For some examples of the negotiated state-makin gin early modern Europe, see James Given, State and Society in Medieval Europe (Ithaca: Cornell University Press,I990) ; or Hendrik Spruyt, The Sovereign State and Its Competitors (Princeton, Princeton University Press, 1994) .For a comparable analysis of Ottoman state-building, see Karen Barkey, From Bandits to Bureaucrats (Ithaca :Cornell University Press, I994)

Page 8: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . . p . 6

Other studies have emphasized the potential role for federal-type solutions to problems of

real or latent ethnic conflict . 11 Despite the spectacular failure of Yugoslav federalism and the

disintegration of the Soviet Union . federal arrangements are still invoked to provide autonom y

for minority groups in multi-national states . As I note above, the multi-national character of th e

Russian Federation provides a primary justification for maintenance of the federal system, a t

least for the ethnic homelands. Since autonomy over a discreet area of social, economic, o r

political life is the objective of such arrangements, the jurisdictional definition derived fro m

Riker again provides an appropriate focus .

Finally, Barry Weingast has recently argued that "market preserving federalism" ca n

stimulate economic growth by combining efficiency-enhancing sub-national competition wit h

central guarantees of property rights and free trade . 12 Weingast's definition also stresses th e

clear delineation of authority to each level of government, with each government autonomous i n

its own sphere. "Market preserving federalism," like Riker's federal bargain, unlinks federalis m

and democracy; the concept has recently been applied to China . 1 3

If we therefore accept a jurisdictional definition of federalism, we may begin to see k

explanations for whether a federal "bargain" is reached, how centralized or symmetrical th e

federation is, and how stable the resulting arrangement proves to be . Before we can begin to

consider causal hypotheses, however, the vexing problem of operationalization must b e

addressed . 1 4

11 See, for instance, Arend Lijphart, Democracy in Plural Societies (New Haven : Yale, 1977) . Note also thediscussion by Daniel Elazar in "International and Comparative Federalism," PS : Political Science and Politics, (June1993) .

12 Barry Weingast, "Constitutions as Governance Structures : The Political Foundations of Secure Markets," Journa lof Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149 no. 1 (1993) : 286-320 .

13 Gabriella Montinola, Yingyi Qian, and Barry Weingast, "Federalism Chinese Style : The Political Basis forEconomic Success in China," World Politics, October 1995 . .

14 I address the relationship between centralization and stability in "Center-Periphery Bargaining in Russia :Assessing Prospects for Federal Stability, " report to the NCSEER, May I996 .

Page 9: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . . p . 7

Measuring" Federalism" in Russi a

The key to the jurisdictional conception of federalism is the degree of centralization .

Peripheralized federations, Riker argues, are not long lived, and excessively centralized one s

cease to be federal . Riker grappled with how to operationalize centralization on several

occasions. Ultimately, he rejected any direct examination of policy making or administrativ e

assignments as "imply[ing] nothing about the basic structure of federalism" since they may

simply be consequences of the particular technologies associated with different policy areas . 1 5

Instead, Riker opted for devising a "measure of disharmony" derived from the coordination o f

party control at both levels of government . 1 6

Unfortunately, in the Russian case, party development has been so anemic that thi s

measure is — for the present at least — virtually useless . Party identification of regiona l

politicians is difficult to ascertain and liable to change at a moment's notice . Regional governors

or republican presidents tend to run their own free-lance political machines, and national

alliances remain highly unstable. Perhaps most vexing, even the national government bears n o

clear party label .

Since Russia is still (despite the Soviet legacy) at a relatively early state of politica l

development, any attempt to measure centralization or peripheralization in the aggregate runs th e

risk of missing important regional variations . Indeed, the geographical variance of center -

regional relations may prove as significant in the long run as the longitudinal variance . Russia

may be evolving into a part-unitary (the Russian oblasts) and part-federal (the ethnic republics )

state that might be neither uniformly centralized nor truly peripheralized . Any useful measure o f

15 Federalism, pp . 127-129 . See also William Riker and Ronald Schaps, "Disharmony in Federal Government," an dWilliam Paul Alexander, "The Measurement of American Federalism," both in Riker, ed . The Development ofAmerican Federalism (Norwell, MA: Kluwer, 1987).

16 Since Riker was proposing that party structure was the primary guarantee of state autonomy, this scheme ran therisk of using an independent variable as a measure of the dependent variable .

Page 10: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 8

federalism must capture not only the aggregate balance of power between center and regions, bu t

also the degree of asymmetry in the federal arrangements .1 7

In the absence of a developed party system (or an established Constitutional Court) .

jurisdictional coordination or conflict has been studied in Russia through two chief approaches :

fiscal federalism and constitutional development . Though each offers useful insights, both ru n

the risk of reification .

Fiscal Federalism

The World Bank and others have attempted to capture Russian federal dynamics throug h

the Russian budget .' 8 Common dependent variables for such analyses include the percentage o f

taxes collected in the region that are spent at the regional level (i .e ., the tax retention rate), the ne t

flow of interbudgetary transfers from the region to the center (i .e ., tax remittances net of retaine d

taxes, subsidies, loans and other subventions from the center), net per capita regional budge t

expenditures, and the share of Federal transfers in the overall budget of each region .

Unfortunately, the Russian budgetary system is in such a state of confusion (compounded by the

high rate of inflation) that these figures seem susceptible to almost infinite manipulation b y

parties wishing to voice a grievance.19

One dominant theme that has clearly emerged from Russian and Western analyses is tha t

the present system is inequitable . According to one study, only 10% of subsidies of regional

budgets from the center goes to territories facing severe environmental or climatic hardships (i .e . ,

to regions where the center should be expected to offset natural disadvantages) . The remaining

90% go to republics like Sakha, Tatarstan and Bashkortostan, whose per capita incomes ar e

17 See "Asymmetries in Russian Federal Bargaining," report to the NCSEER . May 1996 .

18 Christine Wallich, ed . Russia and the Challenge of Fiscal Federalism (Washington, D .C . : The World Bank,1994) . See also the interesting statistical analysis of the I992 Russian state budget by Daniel Triesman ("Th ePolitics of Fiscal Federalism in Post-Soviet Russia ." paper presented to the I995 APSA Annual Meeting) as well a sthe Russian analyses cited below .

19 See, for instance . Philippe LeHouerou, "Decentralization and Fiscal Disparities Among Regions of the RussianFederation," EDP-138, The World Bank, January I994 . The role of inflation in frustrating comparisons isparticularly vexing . A region that concentrated all of its payments in the fourth quarter, for insance, may claim th esame annualized per capita tax payments to Moscow as a region making steady monthy remittances, but would hav eactually paid far less in real terms .

Page 11: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick, "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 9

above the national average. The resulting sense of injustice is captured in one author's rhetorica l

climax : "Why should Ulianovsk oblast' have to pay back one quarter of its legal revenues, if as a

result its per capita budget is two-thirds that of neighboring Tatarstan?" 2 0

It is far from clear, however, who is actually winning and who is losing from Moscow' s

manipulation of fiscal policy . Attempts to sort out the chief beneficiaries of Moscow's larges s

(or weakness) are highly sensitive to the choice of indicator. Consider the tax retention rate :

1992 figures ranged from 38% to 100%, and 1994 figures ranged from 52% to 100% . 21 If we

look instead at the net revenue transfers to the regions (i .e., subsidies and subventions minus ta x

remittances), we get a different set of winners and losers . 22 Yet another picture emerges if on e

considers not just Federal subsidies . but also preferential tax sharing arrangements; in this case 8

territories with per capita regional budgets above the national norm in 1992 emerge as ne t

recipients of Federal subsidies while ten territories with per capita regional budgets below th e

national average emerge as net donors . 23

The variation in fiscal measures of federalism suggests the danger of using any one

measure to capture center-periphery dynamics . Table 1 (see end of paper) shows the top ten

"winners" and "losers" according to a number of measures of fiscal policy in 1992, 1994 an d

1995, as well as the regions most and least dependent on funds from Moscow to finance thei r

regional budgets . Though some relation among these variables is evident, so too are the danger s

of using any single fiscal indicator as the sole guide to federal dynamics .

The relationship among various fiscal measures of federalism is also described in Table 2 ,

which shows the paired correlations between various common indicators . As this table suggests ,

the correlation between various budgetary fiscal indicators (federal share of budget, ne t

20 Oksana Dmitrieva, "Political Games Around the Budget," Moskovskie novosti, no . 28, I993, pp . 8-9 .

21 L . Smirniagin, "The Federation : Processes from Below," Rossiiskie vesti, 26 June I993, p .2 (FBIS-USR-93-090pp17-19) ; Aleksei Lavrov, "Russian Budget Federalism : First Steps, First Results," Segodnia . 7 June I995 (FBIS -SOV-95-125-S) . Lavrov is a deputy to Smirniagin, and these sets of figures are likely to be more comparable tha nmost .

22 L. Smirniagin, "Political Federalism versus Economic Federalism, " Segodniia, 25 June I993 p .2 (FBIS-USR-93 -089 pp54-57 )

23 Dmitrieva, "Political Games Around the Budget"

Page 12: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 1 0

interbudget flow, tax retention rate) is strong and significant, but the measures are far fro m

interchangeable .

For any analysis of federalism, determining who wins and who loses from the budge t

wars is not the same thing as assessing the degree to which the system is federal . Distributional

(or pork-barrel) politics are not the same as jurisdictional politics . Among all the measures o f

fiscal federalism discussed above, the most salient to a study of federalism may be the federa l

share in regional budgets : presumably regions depending on Moscow for only a small share o f

their budgets will be more capable of asserting their independence from the center . 2 4

It is particularly puzzling, therefore, that the federal share of regional budgets seems t o

show no significant correlation with more direct measures of policy assertiveness . Table Two

includes two such policy proxies : deviation of food prices from the federal norm, and regional

differences in the rate of transformation of state enterprises into joint stock companies . Given

federal policy, food prices significantly lower than the national norm probably indicate som e

degree of regional subsidization or price controls, which in turn necessitates certain

(unconstitutional) restraints on trade . Likewise, the pace of enterprises undergoin g

"corporatization" in 1993 in preparation for privatization was often sensitive to the level o f

cooperation between regional and federal authorities . Both measures, therefore, can be used to

suggest the degree of autonomy of regional administrations, but neither is significantly correlated

with fiscal indicators . 2 5

In fact, interpretation of Russian budget figures is almost impossibly difficult if one

attempts to move from basic "winner-loser" judgments to more systemic conclusions about

centralization or peripheralization . To begin with, the consolidated state budget often fails t o

capture the ad hoc pork-barrel agreements between regional authorities and Moscow officials . 2 6

24 For a more complete picture, the measure needs to be combined with regional budget balances .25 LeHouerou ("Decentralization and Fiscal Disparities . . ." p . 17) also found no significant correlation between foo dsubsidies and budget revenues using 1992 budget figures .26 In I992-93, there were at least 32 particular decrees providing fiscal benefits to specific regions . Alexei Lavrov ,a budget specialist in for the President's Analytical Center, complained to me that none of these agreements wer eaccurately reflected in the budget, and that a chief recommendation of the Analytical Center was that all future inter-

Page 13: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 1 1

Further, regions can be granted direct and indirect subsidies through a wide variety o f

instruments, from published government decrees to unpublished decisions issued in the bowel s

of various Moscow ministries . 27 Finally, the regional distribution of expenditures within the

federal budget is not captured by inter-budgetary statistics and remains a mystery even to budge t

analysts within the Presidential administration . 2 8

Even officially published budgetary figures can pose vexing problems of interpretation .

Regional policies financed by regional budgets are not necessarily more autonomous than

regional policies financed by the federal budget (as the current American debate over unfunde d

mandates demonstrates) . Similarly, net flows from the federal to the regional level can sugges t

either a powerful region able to win special subventions . or a poor region in need of heavy

subsidization . 29 Even proxy measures of regional policy — like food subsidies or investmen t

levels — cannot distinguish between regional authorities who are capable of pursuing policies a t

odds with federal objectives, and those sharing the policy goals of the center .

Constitutional Perspectives

Since the 1989-91 "War of Laws" under Mikhail Gorbachev — when all-Union, Union -

republic and local authorities passed legislative and constitutional documents entirely at cross -

purposes — the significance of legal and constitutional maneuvering has been difficult to

unravel . Since 1991, for instance, analysts have focused on the constitutional rights and power s

of subnational units (especially as enumerated in Articles 71-73 of the 1993 Constitution) th e

budgetay transfers be conducted exclusively through formal budgetary channels (interview with author, Novembe rI994) . Lavrov's June 1995 article ("Russian Budgetary Federalism. . .") suggests the practice of "lobbying behind th escenes" continues .

27 According to Lavrov (interview with author, November 1994), there was no comprehensive compilation o fraspriazheniia issued by Federal ministries affecting specific regions .

28 Aleksei Lavrov, "Why subsidized regions voted for the Communists," Rossiiskie vesti, I0 April 1996, p .III .

29 Triesman suggests that political assertiveness is more significant than economic need for explaining 199 2interbudgetary flows ("The Politics of Fiscal Federalism. . .") . LeHouerou, however, found that recipients of highlevels of federal subsidies in I992 had experienced sharp declines in regional budget revenues over the previousyear . ("Decentralization and Fiscal Disparities . . ." p . I6)

Page 14: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . .." p . 1 2

development of an independent judiciary, and the development of republican constitutions an d

regional charters . 3 0

While these approaches illuminate important mechanisms in the overall struggle ove r

federalism . none solves the problem of actually measuring the centralization or peripheralizatio n

of state powers . Article 72 of the Russian Constitution, for instance, enumerates a list of "share d

responsibilities" that -- combined with the exclusively federal powers listed in Article 71 - -

leaves hardly any functions in the clear and exclusive purview of subnational governments . 31 A

federal law to clarify which shared powers reside at the regional level has consistently failed t o

clear the State Duma. Some republics and regions have reacted to this formulation by claimin g

certain exclusive rights in their own constitutions, but it is far from clear which have acted o n

these claims . Many have been using the passage of their own constitutions chiefly as a ste p

toward forcing Moscow to enter into ad hoc negotiations.32 Beginning with Tatarstan in

February 1994, negotiations over conflicting jurisdictional claims have thus far produced thirtee n

extra-constitutional "treaties" delimiting spheres of power . (See Table 3 )

The Constitution of Tuva, for instance, contains 12 distinct contradictions of the Russia n

Constitution, according to Vladimir Suge-Maadyr, Tuva's "ambassador" to the federa l

government in Moscow . 33 The most significant of these include a nullification of the federa l

constitution's guarantee that land would be privatized, and the right to overrule a federal

30 See, for instance, Edward W. Walker, "Designing Center-Region Relations in the new Russia," East EuropeanConstitutional Review, Winter 1995; Erik Hoffmann, "Challenges to Viable Constitutionalism," The Harrima nReview (November 1994) ; Robert Sharlet, "The Prospects for Federalism in Russian Constitutional Politics," Publiu sv .24 n .21 (Spring 1994) ; and Peter C. Ordeshook and Olga Shvetsova, "Russia, Federalism and Political Stability "manuscript, March 1995 .

31 To be more precise, while Article 71 enumerates Federal powers and Article 72 lists shared powers, Article 7 3simply reserves all remaining functions for the subjects of the fedeation . Many legal observers claim, with som emerit, that Article 72 is so encyclopedic that the reserve clause is effectively worthless .

32 The Consitution of Tuva, for instance, contains 12 distinct cotradictions of the Russian Constitution, according t oVladimir Suge-Maadyr, Tuva's "ambassador" to the federal government in Moscow (interview with author ,November 1994) . The most signficant of these included a nullification of the federal constitution's guarantee tha tland would be privatized, and the right to over-rule a federal declaration of a State of Emergency, the right t oappoint their own prosecutor and judges and to veto top military appointments in the republic . Suge-Maadyrblithely explained that these contradictions would be resolved by a "reconciliation commission" along the lines o fthe Tatarstan model . Meanwhile, however, Tuva's "unconsitutional" constitution was fully in force .

33 Interview with the author, Moscow, November I994 .

Page 15: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 1 3

declaration of a State of Emergency, the right to appoint their own prosecutor and judges and t o

veto top military appointments in the republic . Suge-Maadyr calmly asserted that thes e

contradictions would be resolved by a "reconciliation commission" along the lines of the

Tatarstan model . 34 Meanwhile, however, Tuva's "unconstitutional" constitution was fully i n

force .

Even more troublesome than blatant contradictions between Basic Laws at differen t

levels, post-Soviet practice has yet to demonstrate that Constitutional guarantees are — in th e

parlance of positive political economy — "credible ." The 1993 Constitution took the place o f

one that was unilaterally discarded by the president . and the process of drafting the 1993

Constitution was dominated as much by institutional conflict between the executive an d

legislative branches as between subjects of the federation . The September confrontation betwee n

these branches demonstrated the fragility of the Constitutional Court, and few institutiona l

guarantees have been put in place since October 1993 to suggest its performance in any incipien t

federal showdown would be any more forceful . Its 1995 ruling on the constitutionality of the

President's ruling on Chechnya revealed an apparent acceptance of the sweeping powers of th e

Presidency, and showed little indication of an eagerness to actively arbitrate between levels o f

government. 3 5

Finally, just as regions and republics may claim powers that they cannot in fact exercis e

(like the right to name their own prosecutor), some regional administrators may wield powers fa r

greater than any legal document would suggest . The Presidents of Sakha and Kalmykia flirte d

with holding referendums that would extend their terms in office until the end of the century . 3 6

The heads of Sakha and Tiumen' derive considerable power from their right to independentl y

market fixed shares of their regions' considerable resources ; this right was granted b y

34 However eighteen months later, Tuva has yet to receive any Tatarstan-style treaty .

35 Several legislators had challenged the President's right to send troops to Chechnya . While the case was framedmore as a question of legislative-executive powers rather than national-sub-national jurisdiction, the regions exert fa rmore power in the legislative branch that over the Presidency .

36 OMRI Daily Digest, 18 August 1995 .

Page 16: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick, "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . I 4

Presidential decree, not by constitutional principle . 37 Likewise, several governors have sharply

limited the right of producers to ship goods outside their provinces, in direct contradiction of th e

federal constitution . 3 8

Conclusion

These brief illustrations suggest that if we seek to measure the jurisdictional aspect o f

federalism, in line with Riker's definition, there is no substitute for directly examining contro l

over discrete policy areas. Riker's concern that such an approach would be skewed by the

technologies associated with different policy areas can be addressed by working comparativel y

across the federation, examining how the same policy issues are handled in different regions .

We might then be able to directly evaluate whether those regions receiving distributiona l

privileges or claiming greater rights on paper were actually exercising real autonomy from th e

center .

In March 1996, I completed the first round of a survey or regional officials designed t o

measure "federalism" in this direct manner. In collaboration with Russian researchers at the

Russian Political Science Association, 116 employees of regional administrations in 48 region s

were asked about federal and regional roles in personnel appointments, budgetary, tax and trad e

policy, social policy, inter-regional cooperation, and regulation of education, media, an d

commerce. Respondents were also asked about mechanisms for resolving center-periphery

conflicts . The survey will be repeated annually (if possible) to track changes in regiona l

jurisdictional autonomy. Preliminary results of this first survey will be discussed in a subsequen t

report to the Council .

37 Tiumen' was initially granted control over 20% of its oil and gas output (Slider, "Federalism, Discord . . .," p . 251) .Sakha's control over it's gold output was reportedly hiked from 12-15%, and over diamonds from 20-25%, as theresult of a "secret" Yeltsin decree that accompanied tthe June 29 signing of a bilateral treaty between the republi cand Moscow (Reuters Textline, 25 July I995) .

38 Slider cites the case of Voronezh, which limited the export of 35 goods ("Federalism, Discord . . .," p . 251) . Lessblatantly, Ulianovsk oblast' guaranteed its citizens the lowest food prces in the federation by forcing manufacturer son its territory to sell the oblast' administration a share of their output at below-market prices ; these goods were the nbartered for basic foodstuffs, or sold to finance food subsidies . To insure that only Ulianovsk residents benefittedfrom this scheme, subsidized goods were strictly rationed by coupon . (Author's inteview with Gennadii Savinov .permanent representative of the Ulianovsk administration to the Russian President, November 1994) .

Page 17: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick, "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 1 5

Table la: "Winners" and "Losers" in Fiscal Policy, 1992 3 9(Republics in Boldface )

1992 Net Budget Flow 1992 per cap budget

per cap, KRbls) expend. (KRbls )

** "Winners" * *Sakha (83 .6)MagadanTiumen 'Kamchatk aSakhalinKareliaTatarsta nMurmanskBashkortosta nTuva (21 .5 )

Komi (-59)North OssetiaTuvaTatarsta nDagesta n

Irkutsk

KalmykiaKareliaBuriatiaKamchatka (-2 .4)

* *

Tiumen' (64 .9 )Samar aYaroslavl 'Moscow CityNizhnii NovgorodPerm'MagadanBelgoro d

Ul'ianovskKursk (14 .8)

"Losers" * *Chech-Ingush (5 )Stavropo lPenzaTver 'Moscow Ob lKalugaBryanskVoronezhKrasnodarKar.-Cherkessia (9 .8 )

"Sources : I995 figures from Aleksei Lavrov, "Why subsidized regions voted for the Communists," Rossiiskievesti, 10 April I996, p.III ; 1994 figures from Alexei Lavrov, "Russian Budget Federalism : First Steps, FirstResults," Segodnya 7 June I995 (FBIS-SOV-95-125-S) ; 1992 budget flows are from L . Smirniagin, "PoliticalFederalism versus Economic Federalism," Segodniia, 25 June 1993 p .2 (FBIS-USR-93-089 pp54-57) ; I992expenditure levels are from Philippe LeHouerou, "Decentralization and Fiscal Disparities Among Regions of theRussian Federation," EDP-138, The World Bank, January 1994 . 1992 Budget Flow figures are incomplete (missingAdygea, Birobijan, Khakassia, Altai Republic . Karachai-Cherkassia) . 1994 and 95 figures figures omit Chechnya;1995 figures also omit Ingushetia . These tables also omit the 10 Autonomous Okrugs and Birobijan, which tend t obe sparsely populated and are dually subordinated (to neighboring oblasts as well as the federal center) . TheAutonomous Okrugs merit a separate analysis .

Page 18: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . . p . 1 6

Table lb: "Winners" and "Losers " in Fiscal Policy, 199 4(Republics in Boldface )

1994 Tax RetentionRate (percent)

1994 Net Budget Flowto Center (per cap ,

KRbls)

1994 Fed Share ofRegional Budge t (percent

)

** "Winners" **

** Low **

Sakha (100)

Tuva (-991)Karelia

Altai Repu bIngushetia

MagadanBashkortostan

IngushetiaDagestan

Kahnyki aTatarstan

DagestanTuva

Kamchatk aAltai Repub

Kabard .-BalkariaKabard .-Balkaria

North OssetiaKemerovo (82)

Kar.-Cherkessia (-246)

Sakha (1 )BashkortostanSverdloskNizhnii NovgorodSt .Petersburg cit ySamaraKrasnoiars kYaroslavl 'Tatarsta nCheliabinsk (10)

** "Losers" ** ** High * *

Yaroslavl' (52) Moscow City (724) Ingushetia (91 )Ul'ianovsk Samara DagestanSamara Yaroslavl' Altai RepubRyazan St.Petersburg Kalmyki aSt.Petersburg Sverdlosk TuvaPerm' Nizhnii Novgorod Kabardino-Balkari aMoscow Obl Krasnoiarsk North Osseti aNizhnii Novgorod Moscow Obl Karachai-Cherkessi aBelgorod Perm' AdygeaVladimir (60) Cheliabinsk (293) Magadan (54 )Komi (tie )Moscow City (tie)

Page 19: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . ." p . 1 7

Table lc: "Winners" and "Losers " in Fiscal Policy, 199 5(Republics in Boldface )

1995 Tax Retention 1995 Net Budget Flow 1995 Fed Share ofRegional Budge tRate (percent) to Center per cap,

(percent )KRbls)

** "Winners" ** ** Low * *

Sakha (100) Tuva (-1245) Bashkortostan (0.2 )Dagestan Altai Repub St .Petersburg cityBuriatia Kalmykia TatarstanKabardino-Balkaria Dagestan KrasnoiarskTatarstan North Ossetia Nizhnii NovgorodKhakassia Kabardino-Balkaria LipetskTuva Kamchatka SamaraBashkortostan Sakha Sverdlos kKemerovo Mari-El Yaroslavl 'Kamchatka(74) Buriatia (-248) Ryazan

Cheliabinsk (4 )

** "Losers" ** ** High * *

Moscow Obl (51) Moscow City (2817) Tuva (79 )Nizhnii Novgorod Samara Altai Repu bSamara St .Petersburg city KalmykiaYaroslavl' Tomsk DagestanPerm' Yaroslavl' Karachai-Cherkessia

Moscow City Sverdlosk Kabardino-BalkariaSt .Petersburg city Perm' KostromaKalmykia Moscow Obl AdygeaSverdlosk Komi North OssetiaTomsk (57) Krasnoiarsk (1038) Altai Krai (39)

Page 20: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick . "Defining and Measuring Federalism . .. p. 1 8

Table 2 : Bi-Variate Correlation Coefficients for Fiscal Measures ofFederalism40

VariablesFEDBUD95 TAXRET95 NETFLO95 I FEDBUD94

TAXRET94 NETFLO94 NETFLO92

FOOD94Price of 19-good foo d

basket (8/94, Russian Fe d= 100)

.06 .34** - .10

.002 .17 - .22 - .07

RESTRUC93% of enterprises slated fo r

privatization that hadreorganized by 10/93

.06 - .08 - .10

.02 - .11 - .07 .1 5

FEDBUD95Federa1 Share of Regional

Budget (1995 . %)

.47** -.57**

.95** .57** - .58** -.39**

TAXRET95

Share of total 1995 taxesretained by each region

-

I

- .56**

- .49** - .77** - .28** -.30**

- - .56** -.34** .64** .36* *NETFLO95Net Interbudetary Flow t oMoscow (1995 . per cap )

FEDBUD94Federal Share of Regiona 1

Budget (1994 . %)

.57** -.53** -36**

TAXRET94Share of total 1994 taxesretained by each region

- - .34** -.39**

- .38* *NETFLO94Net Interbudetary Flow toMoscow (1994 . per cap)

-NETFLO92Net Interbudetary Flow toMoscow (1992 . per cap)

* Signif at < .05

** Signif at < .0 I

40 Sources : For budget indicators, see notes to Table 1 . Food prices are from Sotsio-ekonomicheskoe polozhenieRossii, lanv .-Sen. 1994 (Roskomstat, I994) . Privatization indicators are from Darrell Slider, "Privatization inRussia's Regions," Post-Soviet Affairs v.I0, n .4 (I994) . Coefficients are Pearsons, 2-tailed .

Page 21: THE NATIONAL COUNCIL FOR SOVIET AND EAST EUROPEAN … · 2 Darrell Slider, "Federalism. Discord and Accommodation : Intergovernmental Affairs in Post-Soviet Russia," i n Jeffry Hahn

Solnick. "Defining and Measuring Federalism . . . p.1 9

Table3:Federation Subjects Signing Bilateral Treaties with theCenter41

Bashkortostan

3 Au ' 94North Osseti aSakha- -

' BuriatiaUdmurtiaKaliningrad obl.

Sverdlovsk obi .Krasnodar krai

30 Jan 96Orenburg obl . 30 Jan 96

3 Komi

20 Mar 96Khabarovsk krai

23 Mar 9529 Jun 95 -11 Jul 9517 Oct 9512 Jan 9612 Jan 96

24 April 96

41 Source : Russian press reports .

* The treaty with Orenburg was preceded by an intergovernmental agreement signed on December 11, 1995, i nadvance of the Duma elections . The agreement was signed by Prime Minsiter Chernomyrdin, whose political base i sin Orenburg .