The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

52
The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross- Country Evidence from Within the Firm Francine Lafontaine Jagadeesh Sivadasan Ross School of Business, University of Michigan AEA Meetings, Jan 2007 (Updated Jan 2009)

description

The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm. Francine Lafontaine Jagadeesh Sivadasan Ross School of Business, University of Michigan AEA Meetings, Jan 2007 (Updated Jan 2009). Introduction. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

Page 1: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

Francine LafontaineJagadeesh Sivadasan

Ross School of Business, University of Michigan

AEA Meetings, Jan 2007 (Updated Jan 2009)

Page 2: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

2

Introduction

Goal: Assess the effects of regulations that create rigidities in the labor market

Important and controversial question: a number of papers have considered the effects of such regulations at the macro level (e.g. Botero et al (2004), Lazear (1990))

We focus on the very micro level, using data from a single fast-food chain with operations in more than 40 countries around the world: most importantly, we quantify the effect of the regulations on firm

labor adjustment decisions also examine effect on extent of operations

Page 3: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

3

Introduction

Important advantages of our empirical setting: Fundamentally same production technology Same output (as close as can get) Labor intensive - labor issues really matter We have very detailed data: weekly revenues and

costs information for each outlet outside the US (more than 2500 of them, over 4 years, in 43 countries)

Page 4: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

4

Introduction

Important advantages of our empirical setting: The high frequency of our data has two main

advantages: Gets around problems with annual data, which can hide

a lot of within year turnover (Hamermesh and Pfann (1996))

Allows us to adopt estimation strategies with lots of controls (i.e. fixed effects at the outlet, outlet-year, or outlet-year-season)

Page 5: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

5

Introduction

We focus on questions that are particularly suited to our data Companion paper – addresses the effect of regulation

on productivity and labor demand In some sense, more direct place to look for effects But in reality, theory ambiguous on these effects,

whereas clear predictions on hysteresis and effect on responsiveness to output changes

And our data – labor costs, not labor levels => potential biases due to “poor” measure of wages

Page 6: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

6

Introduction – Preview of Results

We find strong evidence that in countries with more rigid labor laws: Outlets’ choices of labor levels are less responsive,

from period to period, to changes in revenues, and there is more hysteresis in labor levels, that is labor in

one period is more related to previous period labor We also find some evidence that in such

countries: the Company enters later and operates fewer outlets

-- and uses “local” franchising more as well

Page 7: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

7

Organization of this Talk

Basic Model and Predictions A Note on Dynamics Data and Definition of Variables Results for Labor Adjustment – Botero & GCS Key Identification Issues

Contrasting with Materials Adjustment Results IV Results

Results on Company’s Extent of Operations Conclusions

Page 8: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

8

Basic Model

Draws on Heckman and Pagés (2003), who drew on Holt, Modigliani, Muth and Simon (1960)

Given our weekly data, we take capital as given (or contributing to the Hicks neutral productivity term), and write a 2 input Cobb-Douglas production process with labor and materials

where Yt is the quantity of output produced by the firm in period t, Lt is labor, and Mt represents materials used

tttt MLY

Page 9: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

9

Basic Model

Assume iso-elastic demand curve:

where Pt is the price per unit output in period t, represents demand shifters and is the price elasticity of demand

The firm’s profit to be maximized is

where Wt is the wage rate faced by the firm in period t, and St is the per unit cost of materials

ttttttt MSLWQP

/1tt QP

Page 10: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

10

Basic Model

Each week, manager chooses labor and materials so FOCs for these are binding

Assume horizontal labor and materials supply in each local market (each outlet buys little, and even as a group they are a tiny part of the market)=> obtain optimal labor and materials demand function

in terms of the primitives (prices, demand & production function parameters)

=> can write total labor and material cost equations conditional on output

Page 11: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

11

Basic Model

These input demand equations are

where we use bt to denote log(WtLt) and ft to mean log(StMt), and

These equations then describe equilibrium input costs in the absence of adjustment costs

' log t*t rb

t*

t rf ' log

.1

1 'and1

1 '

Page 12: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

12

Basic Model

Now suppose that there are costs to adjusting labor. First, let the cost of being off the static optimum be quadratic in log labor

where o > 0. Second, suppose that the cost of changing labor levels from one period to the next are given by

where we expect a to be positive and increasing in the rigidity of labor regulations

2*o )( tt

ot bbc

21a )( tt

at bbc

Page 13: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

13

Basic Model

Each outlet minimizes the sum of these costs. This yields optimal labor choice

where outlet i is in country j, and

The optimal labor cost equation above can be rewritten as

1,*)-(1 ti

jit

jit bbb

')log-1()-1( 1, jti

jit

jit brb

.o

ja

jaj

Page 14: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

14

Basic Model

Taking, as a first approximation,

we get the following econometric specification for the labor costs of outlet i in country j at time t:

where τ j is the index of labor regulation, and is stands for store, store-year, or store-season-year fixed effects.

itistij

bitj

rtiit

jti

jit

jit

brbr

aabaaraab

1,1,

101,1010 'log)1()()1(

jj aa 10

Page 15: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

15

Basic Model

In this regression, we expect r to be negative and b to be positive.

In other words, our simple model yields two principal implications that we bring to data: Labor costs should be less responsive to changes in revenues

in countries where regulations are more stringent Labor costs at time t should be more dependent on labor costs

at time t-1 in countries with more stringent laws (hysteresis) These predictions are intuitive, and the latter has been

tested in a number of studies of the effect of regulation on labor demand (see survey in Heckman and Pagés, 2004).

Page 16: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

16

Note on Dynamics

Our two testable implications are derived from a very simple model Heckman and Pagés (2004) express concern that the labor hysteresis

prediction may not arise in a more general dynamic model We solved a more general dynamic stochastic programming model:

Two state variables are current productivity and last period labor. We solve numerically for four scenarios: with both symmetric (quadratic) and asymmetric (i.e. severance pay

only) adjustment costs. and for iid as well as persistent demand /productivity shocks processes

Page 17: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

17

Note on Dynamics To approximate our actual data, using optimal policy functions, we ran regressions

on simulated behavior of 75 outlets for 104 periods across 45 regimes Zero adjustment costs Symmetric quadratic

adjustment costs Asymmetric linear

adjustment costs Fixed (lump-sum)

adjustment costs IID

shocks Persistent

shocks IID

shocks Persistent

shocks IID

shocks Persistent

shocks IID

shocks Persistent

shocks Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.0000 0.0006*** 0.657*** 0.574*** 0.874*** 0.251*** 0.117*** 0.146*** [0.0001] [0.0001] [0.039] [0.015] [0.043] [0.017] [0.008] [0.008] Log (Revenue) 0.984*** 0.984*** 0.198*** 0.264*** 0.190*** 0.288*** 0.398*** 0.677*** [0.0001] [0.0002] [0.022] [0.018] [0.030] [0.020] [0.026] [0.023] Adj. cost X Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.0001 -0.0004 1.130*** 0.690*** 1.856*** 0.398*** 0.253*** 0.421*** [0.0002] [0.0003] [0.151] [0.090] [0.104] [0.032] [0.020] [0.031] Adj. cost X Log (Revenue) -0.0001 0.0001 -0.540*** -0.602*** -0.885*** -1.083*** -1.344*** -0.971*** [0.0004] [0.0006] [0.111] [0.089] [0.118] [0.073] [0.067] [0.089] Constant -1.529*** -1.528*** -0.555*** -0.688*** -0.181** -1.267*** -1.470*** -1.337*** [0.0001] [0.0002] [0.072] [0.022] [0.072] [0.023] [0.021] [0.005] Fixed Effects Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Outlet-year-

season Observations 351000 351000 351000 351000 351000 351000 351000 351000 Adjusted R-squared 0.999 0.999 0.801 0.932 0.782 0.929 0.852 0.90 Number of clusters 45 45 45 45 45 45 45 45

Page 18: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

18

The Data

Mostly from internal firm records Cover over 2500 outlets in more than 40 countries

worldwide, weekly from 2000 to 2003 Data on

Revenues per week Total labor costs per week Total materials costs per week Number of items (standardized notion of output)

Page 19: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

19

The Data

We measure the rigidity of the labor regulations in each country using the Botero et al (2004) index (see appendix in paper for details) Main advantage – computed similarly across

countries Main disadvantage – laws may not be enforced as

strongly everywhere

We verify our results using an index of hiring and firing flexibility from the Global Competitiveness Survey (2002) of business executives

Page 20: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

20

Index of labor regulation (Botero, et al)

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9Z

MB

HK

G

USA

UG

Y

SGP

IRL

AU

S

BO

L

TH

A

KO

R

LK

A

HR

V

BE

L

VN

M

DO

M

PO

L

UK

R

NO

R

NL

D

FRA

KA

Z

RU

S

Page 21: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

21

ArgentinaAustralia

Austria BelgiumBulgaria

Bolivia

Brazil

Canada

SwitzerlandChile

China

Colombia

Czech Republic

Germany

DenmarkDominican Republic

Ecuador

SpainFinland France

Great Britain

Greece

Hong Kong

Croatia

Hungary

Indonesia

India

Ireland

Israel

Italy

Jamaica

Jordan

Japan

South KoreaSri Lanka

Lithuania

Latvia

Morocco

Mexico

Malaysia

NetherlandsNorway

New Zealand

Panama

Peru Philippines

Poland

PortugalRussian Federation

Singapore

Slovakia

Slovenia Sweden

Thailand

Tunisia

Turkey

Taiwan

Ukraine

United States

Venezuela

Vietnam

South Africa

Zimbabwe

0.2

.4.6

.8In

dex

of l

abo

r re

gul

atio

n (

Bot

ero

, et a

l)

.2 .4 .6 .8 1Hiring/firing inflexibility (2002, Global Competitiveness Report)

Fitted (OLS) Fitted (GLS, Root-N weight)

Page 22: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

22

Panel Characteristics (baseline sample)

Year Number of observations

Number of outlets

Number of countries

2000 80,429 1,721 39 2001 85,113 1,828 37 2002 74,201 2,147 38 2003 82,305 1,938 37 Total 322,048 2,526 43

Page 23: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

23

Descriptive StatisticsPanel B: Summary statistics (variables in logs) Variable N Mean SD P25 Median P75 Min Max

Log (Labor cost) 322,048 7.19 0.85 6.71 7.27 7.78 -5.05 10.25 Log (Revenue) 322,048 8.84 0.69 8.46 8.90 9.32 2.85 11.50 Log (Material cost) 318,749 7.72 0.66 7.37 7.78 8.16 -4.87 10.94 Panel C: Summary statistics (variables in levels) Variable N Mean SD P25 Median P75 Min Max

Labor cost 322,048 1,798.57 1,391.21 819.84 1,434.39 2,390.97 0.01 28,219 Revenue 322,048 8,485.44 5,329.17 4,730.58 7,332.80 11,156.53 17.30 98,668 Material cost 318,749 2,706.78 1,626.86 1,590.36 2,394.45 3,481.43 0.01 56,580 Index of labor regulation 322,048 0.00 0.16 -0.15 0.03 0.16 -0.25 0.42

Page 24: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

24

0.2

.4.6

.81

.2 .4 .6 .8Index of labor regulation (Botero, et al)

Correlation between changes in labor cost and revenue

Fitted (GLS, Root-N weight)

Correlation between changes in material cost and revenue

Fitted (GLS, Root-N weight)

0.2

.4.6

.81

.2 .4 .6 .8 1Hiring/firing inflexibility (2002, Global Competitiveness Report)

Correlation between changes in labor cost and revenue

Fitted (GLS, Root-N weight)

Correlation between changes in material cost and revenue

Fitted (GLS, Root-N weight)

Correlation between changes in input costs and revenue

Page 25: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

25

Table 4: Baseline Results

(4) (5) (6) Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.501*** 0.348*** 0.203*** [0.049] [0.036] [0.033] Log (Revenue) 0.341*** 0.360*** 0.391*** [0.040] [0.035] [0.036] Regulation X Log (Lagged labor cost) 1.013*** 0.909*** 0.687*** [0.291] [0.223] [0.203] Regulation X Log (Revenue) -0.570*** -0.488*** -0.414*** [0.144] [0.101] [0.106] Constant 0.623*** 1.550*** 2.305*** [0.227] [0.310] [0.358]

Fixed Effects Outlet Outlet-year Outlet-year-

season

Observations 322,048 322,048 322,048 Adjusted R-squared 0.945 0.952 0.959 Number of clusters 43 43 43

Page 26: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

26

Table 4: Baseline Results

Effect of a one standard deviation (0.85) increase in Log (Lagged Labor) in percentage terms

At Regulation = mean (0.00) 42.59 29.58 17.26

At Regulation = mean + sd (= 0.16) 56.36 41.94 26.60

Impact of increase in Regulation 13.78 12.36 9.34

Effect of a one standard deviation (0.69) increase in Log (Revenue) in percentage terms

At Regulation = mean (0.00) 23.53 24.84 26.98

At Regulation = mean + sd (= 0.16) 17.24 19.45 22.41

Impact of increase in Regulation -6.29 -5.39 -4.57

Page 27: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

27

Table 5: GCS Index Results

(1) (2) (3) Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.530*** 0.371*** 0.220*** [0.053] [0.041] [0.034] Log (Revenue) 0.355*** 0.383*** 0.418*** [0.041] [0.036] [0.038] Inflexibility X Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.988*** 0.914*** 0.710*** [0.332] [0.291] [0.235] Inflexibility X Log (Revenue) -0.734*** -0.714*** -0.629** [0.221] [0.217] [0.262] Constant 0.244 1.136*** 1.909*** [0.240] [0.316] [0.363]

Fixed Effects Outlet Outlet-year Outlet-

year-season

Observations 338,660 338,660 338,660 Adjusted R-squared 0.948 0.955 0.961 Number of clusters 48 48 48

Page 28: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

28

Table 5: GCS Index Results

Effect of a one standard deviation (0.85) increase in Log (Lagged Labor) in percentage terms

At Inflexibility = mean (0.00) 45.05 31.53 18.70

At Inflexibility = mean + sd (= 0.13) 55.97 41.63 26.55

Impact of increase in Inflexibility 10.92 10.10 7.85

Effect of a one standard deviation (0.69) increase in Log (Revenue) in percentage terms

At Inflexibility = mean (0.00) 24.50 26.43 28.84

At Inflexibility = mean + sd (= 0.13) 17.91 20.02 23.20

Impact of increase in Inflexibility -6.58 -6.40 -5.64

Page 29: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

29

Key Identification Issues

As per our model above, the error term is:

Thus the error term includes omitted supply-side parameter it (output elasticity with respect to labor) and demand side parameter it (elasticity of demand)

Our store or store-year-season fixed effects control implicitly for the differences in τ j across countries, and for these supply and demand parameters insofar as they are fixed within a store or store-year or store-year-season

itit

jit aae

1

1log)1( 10

Page 30: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

30

Key Identification Issues

Unanticipated demand and productivity shocks can also add to the error term if labor is set early, then a high (low) demand shock shows up as

too little (much) labor conditional on output Since we are interested in the coefficient on lagged labor

or revenue interacted with regulation, a bias arises only when: the omitted demand and supply parameters vary within store-

year-seasons, and are correlated with lagged labor/revenue in a different way across different regulation regimes

prediction errors (with regard to demand and productivity shocks) are correlated with levels of regulation

Page 31: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

31

Key Identification Issues

We address these potential identification issues in two different ways: using the material demand equation as a control with instrumental variables

The material demand equation is a good control because: omitted demand and supply parameters are the same for the material

as for the labor demand equation prediction error also would bias the material demand specification in a

similar way IV approach

draws from traditional approaches in the literature (Blundell and Bond 1998)

uses lagged endogenous variables that are uncorrelated with unpredicted component of current demand and productivity shocks

we have more instruments than endogenous variables, so we can perform an overidentification test – good results!

Page 32: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

32

Table 6: Material Costs Results (Botero et al. Index)

(4) (5) (6) Log (Lagged materials cost) 0.159*** 0.112*** 0.033* [0.038] [0.036] [0.019] Log (Revenue) 0.852*** 0.901*** 0.942*** [0.027] [0.020] [0.008] Regulation X Log (Lagged materials cost) -0.211 -0.168 -0.089 [0.201] [0.197] [0.125] Regulation X Log (Revenue) -0.020 -0.004 -0.075* [0.138] [0.093] [0.043] Constant -1.032*** -1.102*** -0.856*** [0.084] [0.127] [0.132]

Fixed Effects Outlet Outlet-year Outlet-

year-season

Observations 362,711 362,711 362,711 Adjusted R-squared 0.947 0.953 0.960 Number of clusters 43 43 43

Page 33: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

33

Table 6: Material Costs Results (Botero et al. Index)

Effect of a one standard deviation (0.66) increase in Log (Lagged Materials cost)

At Regulation = mean (0.00) 10.49 7.39 2.18

At Regulation = mean + sd (=0.16) 8.27 5.62 1.24

Impact of increase in Regulation -2.23 -1.77 -0.94

Effect of a one standard deviation (0.69) increase in Log (Revenue)

At Regulation = mean (0.00) 58.79 62.17 65.00

At Regulation = mean + sd (=0.16) 58.57 62.12 64.17

Impact of increase in Regulation -0.22 -0.04 -0.83

Page 34: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

34

Table 7: Robustness check: OECD Sample and Interaction Terms (1)

OECD (2) (3) (4) (5)

Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.174*** 1.709*** -0.052 0.204 0.165 [0.030] [0.325] [0.063] [0.333] [0.176] Log (Revenue) 0.461*** -1.085*** 0.639*** 0.726*** 0.645*** [0.036] [0.276] [0.065] [0.205] [0.171] Regulation X Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.428*** 0.331** 0.380* 0.687** 0.700*** [0.141] [0.161] [0.200] [0.299] [0.238] Regulation X Log (Revenue) -0.354* -0.069 -0.225 -0.584*** -0.543*** [0.183] [0.108] [0.152] [0.152] [0.141] GDP X Log (Lagged labor cost) -0.158***

[0.033]

GDP X Log (Revenue) 0.156***

[0.030]

Entry barriers X Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.081***

[0.021]

Entry barriers X Log (Revenue) -0.078***

[0.025]

Wage flexibility X Log (Lagged labor cost) -0.0002

[0.064]

Wage flexibility X Log (Revenue) -0.063

[0.038]

Labor relations X Log (Lagged labor cost) 0.008 [0.040] Labor relations X Log (Revenue) -0.053 [0.032]

Fixed effects Outlet-year-season

Outlet-year-

season

Outlet-year-

season

Outlet-year-

season

Outlet-year-

season

Constant 1.996*** 2.197*** 2.273*** 2.238*** 2.291*** [0.314] [0.321] [0.296] [0.344] [0.321] Observations 236,291 322,048 265,842 321,569 321,569

Page 35: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

35

Table 8: Robustness check: DID comparison of top and bottom decile of change in Index of Inflexibility between 2002 and 2004

LABOR MATERIALS (1) (2) (3) (4)

Log (Lagged input cost) 0.570*** 0.358*** 0.157*** 0.055*** [0.032] [0.057] [0.022] [0.016] Log (Revenue) 0.152*** 0.198*** 0.897*** 0.918*** [0.038] [0.053] [0.023] [0.021] Year 2003 -0.474* -0.138 [0.280] [0.122] Year 2003 X Log (Lagged input cost) -0.328*** -0.233*** -0.034 0.008 [0.040] [0.059] [0.023] [0.018] Year 2003 X Log (Revenue) 0.321*** 0.328*** 0.048* 0.032 [0.037] [0.067] [0.025] [0.022] DInf_p90 X Year 2003 1.435*** 1.107*** [0.494] [0.164] DInf_p90 X Log (Lagged input cost) -0.143 -0.179 0.104*** 0.103*** [0.112] [0.191] [0.037] [0.033] DInf_p90 X Log (Revenue) 0.196 0.083 -0.091** 0.009 [0.171] [0.202] [0.045] [0.044] DInf_p90 X Year 2003 X Log (Lagged input cost) 0.519*** 0.432** 0.001 -0.077* [0.127] [0.198] [0.053] [0.044] DInf_p90 X Year 2003 X Log (Revenue) -0.634*** -0.722*** -0.125** -0.078 [0.105] [0.211] [0.057] [0.060] DGDPGR X Year 2003 15.56** 9.037*** [6.029] [1.803] DGDPGR X Log (Lagged input cost) -1.970*** -0.480 1.555*** 1.061*** [0.660] [1.073] [0.303] [0.256] DGDPGR X Log (Revenue) 1.403 0.341 -1.110*** -0.135 [1.378] [1.654] [0.350] [0.320] DGDPGR X Year 2003 X Log (Lagged input cost) 1.881** 0.647 -2.257*** -2.088*** [0.857] [1.101] [0.360] [0.304] DGDPGR X Year 2003 X Log (Revenue) -3.569*** -4.088** 0.806** 0.181 [0.823] [1.780] [0.362] [0.375] Constant 1.233*** 1.968*** -1.250*** -0.941*** [0.288] [0.252] [0.132] [0.086]

Fixed effects Outlet Outlet- Outlet Outlet-

Page 36: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

36

Table 8: Robustness check: Case study of labor reform in South Korea (1996-98)

BEFORE-AFTERLABOR MATERIALS

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Log (Lagged input cost) 0.765***0.270*

** 0.332*** 0.122***[0.049] [0.058] [0.039] [0.024]

Log (Revenue) 0.206***0.160*

** 0.717*** 0.822***[0.034] [0.041] [0.034] [0.026]

POST_REFORM X Log (Lagged input cost)

-0.404**

*

-0.129*

* -0.024 -0.018

[0.053][0.064

] [0.044] [0.029]

POST_REFORM X Log (Revenue)0.335**

*0.574*

** 0.033 0.040

[0.043][0.049

] [0.037] [0.035]D_KOREA X Log (Lagged input cost)

D_KOREA X Log (Revenue)

D_KOREA X POST_REFORM X Log (Lagged input cost)

D_KOREA X POST_REFORM X Log (Revenue)

Constant -0.1270.515*

**-

1.242***-

0.710***[0.096] [0.145] [0.100] [0.137]

Fixed Effects OutletOutlet-

year-season

OutletOutlet-

year-season

Observations 15,071 15,071 15,099 15,099 Adjusted R-squared 0.854 0.894 0.944 0.963Number of clusters 152 152 152 152

Page 37: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

37

Table 8: Robustness check: Case study of labor reform in South Korea (1996-98)

DIFFERENCE-IN-DIFFERENCES LABOR MATERIALS

(5) (6) (7) (8) Log (Lagged input cost) 0.272*** 0.084*** 0.074*** 0.023*** [0.021] [0.016] [0.009] [0.007] Log (Revenue) 0.460*** 0.549*** 0.958*** 0.965*** [0.013] [0.013] [0.009] [0.010]

POST_REFORM X Log (Lagged input cost) 0.190*** 0.090*** 0.054*** 0.018

[0.015] [0.021] [0.014] [0.012]

POST_REFORM X Log (Revenue) -0.167*** -0.152*** -0.043*** 0.005

[0.013] [0.014] [0.012] [0.013] D_KOREA X Log (Lagged input cost) 0.493*** 0.186*** 0.257*** 0.099*** [0.054] [0.060] [0.040] [0.024] D_KOREA X Log (Revenue) -0.254*** -0.389*** -0.241*** -0.143*** [0.036] [0.043] [0.035] [0.028]

D_KOREA X POST_REFORM X Log (Lagged input cost) -0.594*** -0.219*** -0.078* -0.036

[0.055] [0.067] [0.046] [0.031]

D_KOREA X POST_REFORM X Log (Revenue) 0.502*** 0.726*** 0.075* 0.035

[0.045] [0.050] [0.038] [0.038] Constant 1.156*** 2.158*** -1.453*** -1.153*** [0.105] [0.085] [0.053] [0.053]

Fixed Effects Outlet Outlet-

year-season

Outlet Outlet-

year-season

Observations 71,273 71,273 71,200 71,200 Adjusted R-squared 0.977 0.984 0.971 0.980 Number of clusters 592 592 592 592

Page 38: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

38

Impulse response functions based on VAR analysis

Page 39: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

39

Implied Rigidity Estimates

The underlying structural parameters and are not simultaneously identified.

However is identified Model implies following relationship between optimal

adjustment and actual adjustment of labor

More regulation => higher => greater dampening of adjustment

o a

jj aa 10

j

Page 40: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

Estimate of a0 Estimate of a1 Dampening factor estimate

Regulation Change

P25 P75 (percent)

Panel 1: Using results from Column 6 of Table 4 Coefficient on Log (Lagged labor cost): 0.203 Coefficient on Regulation X Lagged labor cost: 0.687 0.900 0.687 23.7 1 - Coefficient on Log (Revenue): 0.609 - (Coefficient on Regulation X Revenue): 0.414 0.453 0.325 28.3

Average of above: 0.406 Average of above: 0.550 0.677 0.506 25.2

Panel 2: Using results from Column 1 of Table 7 – OECD only Coefficient on Log (Lagged labor cost): 0.174 Coefficient on Regulation X Lagged labor cost: 0.428 0.890 0.749 15.9 1 - Coefficient on Log (Revenue): 0.539 - (Coefficient on Regulation X Revenue): 0.354 0.514 0.397 22.7

Average of above: 0.356 Average of above: 0.391 0.702 0.573 18.4

40

Table 11: Estimates of Dampening Factor

(change in labor costs in the absence of adjustment costs / actual change in labor costs)

Page 41: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

41

A Look at the Firm’s Expansion

If more rigid labor regulations imply that individual outlets cannot adjust labor as much as they otherwise would, then all else the same, outlets in these markets will be less profitable.

This suggests the firm should Enter later Expand less rapidly Franchise more ?

in highly regulated markets

Page 42: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

42

Labor Regulation and International Expansion: Time to Entry

Whole Sample Country = Observation(end of 2001)

Log(GDP/capita in USD) -0.31** -0.22** -0.32** -0.22**[0.07] [0.08] [0.07] [0.08]

Log(Population) -0.19** -0.11 -0.18* -0.10[0.07] [0.06] [0.07] [0.07]

Log(Distance to USA in kms)

0.28[0.19]

0.26[0.18]

0.24[0.21]

0.23[0.19]

Regulation (Botero et al) 1.10* 1.14*[0.44] [0.45]

Regulation (GCS) -0.45 -0.44[0.65] [0.70]

Constant 5.09* 3.80* 5.36* 3.95*[2.01] [1.61] [2.14] [1.72]

Observations 6906 8111 34 40R-squared 0.42 0.23 0.45 0.24

Number of Clusters 37 43

Page 43: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

43

Labor Regulation and International Expansion: Number of Outlets

Whole Sample Country = Observation(end of 2001)

Log(GDP in USD) 0.59** 0.57** 0.51** 0.50**[0.13] [0.12] [0.18] [0.16]

Log(Population) 0.63** 0.54** 0.58** 0.53**[0.17] [0.15] [0.20] [0.18]

Log(Distance to USA in kms)

-0.45+ [0.26]

-0.40[0.27]

-0.38[0.32]

-0.30[0.32]

Regulation (Botero et al) -2.02* -2.60*[0.83] [1.07]

Regulation (GCS) -0.37 -1.99[1.47] [2.01]

Constant -8.25* -7.54** -7.10 -6.83+[3.56] [2.81] [4.64] [3.51]

Observations 7423 8628 38 44R-squared 0.41 0.38 0.34 0.30

Number of clusters 41 47

Page 44: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

44

Labor Regulation and International Expansion: Use of Franchising

Whole Sample Country = Observation(end of 2002)

Log(GDP in USD) 0.15 0.12 0.18 0.14[0.06]* [0.05]* [0.06]* [0.05]**

Log(Population) -0.001 -0.01 0.03 0.01[0.06] [0.04] [0.06] [0.04]

Log(Distance to USA in kms)

-0.19[0.06]**

-0.28[0.07]**

-0.17[0.08]*

-0.27[0.08]**

Regulation (Botero) 0.12 0.37[0.37] [0.38]

Regulation (GCS) 0.82 0.91[0.40]+ [0.40]*

Constant 0.59 1.43 -0.35 0.76[1.53] [1.12] [1.68] [1.30]

Observations 2852 3372 29 33R-squared 0.35 0.29 0.38 0.34

Number of clusters 30 36 29 33

Page 45: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

45

Conclusion

Using weekly data from outlets of a multinational fast-food chain, we have shown evidence of a statistically and economically important effect of labor regulations on labor decisions at the micro level

To our knowledge this is the first time that effects of such policies are documented in a cross-country context at such a micro level

Page 46: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

46

Conclusion

Specifically, using our most conservative estimates, we find that an increase of one standard deviation in the labor regulation rigidity index reduces the response of labor cost to a one standard

deviation increase in output (revenue) by about 4.4 percentage points (from 26.4 per cent to 22.0 percent)

increases the response of labor cost to a one standard deviation increase in lagged labor cost by about 9.6 percentage points (from 17.0 per cent to 26.6 per cent)

Page 47: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

47

Conclusion

We have also shown that results are similar whether we use the Botero et al.

index, or an alternative measure of labor regulation from the Global Competitiveness Survey

The effects do not hold for material costs, confirming that they are not spurious – the increased rigidity in labor is not driven by omitted variables that are also likely to affect other variable costs

The effects are even stronger when we estimate using an IV approach

Page 48: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

48

Conclusion

Consistent with the impact on adjustment behavior, we also find that the Company delayed entry, and operates fewer outlets and its partners rely on franchising more

in countries with more rigid labor laws

Page 49: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

49

Conclusion So we have shown that labor levels are more

persistent in countries that enact more rigid labor laws, an effect these policies are meant to achieve

However, increases (responses to positive shocks) as well as decreases in labor levels are affected

Consistent with our earlier findings that outlet level labor demand was lower in more heavily regulated markets, our results on timing of entry and level of operations of the Company across markets suggest that easing these laws would increase employment and output in this industry

Page 50: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

50

Other paper (Lafontaine and Sivadasan, “Within-firm Labor Productivity across Countries: A case study): Quantifying the Labor Demand effect

We find coefficients for regulation of about -0.4 => an increase in labor regulation (Botero Index)

from its 25th percentile to its 75th percentile value reduces labor per outlet by 0. 4 * 0.31 = 12%

Alternatively, a one standard deviation increase in the labor regulation rigidity index leads to a reduction in conditional labor demand of 6.4 per cent

Page 51: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

51

Interpreting the Expansion Effects

From column 1 (part a): an increase in labor regulation by one standard deviation increases the time to entry by 1.7 years on a mean of 8.9 years (so not quite 20% increase)

From column 1 (part b): a one standard deviation increase in the index of labor regulation reduces the number of stores by about 3.2 relative to a mean of 12.06 outlets (a >25% reduction)

Page 52: The Microeconomic Implications of Labor Regulations: Cross-Country Evidence from Within the Firm

52

Interpreting the Expansion Effects

We also find some evidence that the franchisor and its partners rely on franchising more the more highly regulated the labor market is

Our analyses here are based on more limited information, however, and we have yet to verify robustness