The Irrelevance of Capital Structure in Perfect Capital Markets

9
25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 1/9 Page info: *Author: Mathiesen, H. *Document version: 2.2. *Copyright 1997-2014, ViamInvest. Legal notice. Model: The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets 1 Introduction This appendix presents proofs of a modern version of the Modigliani and Miler propositions on the irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets. Note: Footnotes and highlighted text can be clicked for more info. The propositions on capital structure made by Modigliani and Miller (M&M) are among the most important contributions in the theory of corporate finance. The theorems were first stated in the seminal papers [1958, 1963] on the cost of capital, corporate valuation and capital structure. The first versions were very simple. They assumed that debt could be only of the risk-free type, and that all firms belonged to the same risk class. The latter assumption meant that the expected future cash flow in all firms should be perfectly correlated, and only allowed to vary by a scale factor. E.g. CF i,t = a CF j,t , where CF is cash flow in firm i and j, respectively, a is the scale factor, and t count the future periods. These assumptions are certainly unrealistic, but fortunately, later developments in the theory of corporate finance made them redundant. Independent of the capital structure theory Sharpe [1963, 1964] and Treynor [1961] built the first model that could price risky assets on individual terms. This model has now come to be known as the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) . Rubinstien [1973] merged the CAPM model with the original M&M framework on capital structure. This was possible because the M&M framework and the CAPM model are built on almost the exact same assumptions on perfect capital markets. The gain was that the more realistic assumption of risky debt replaced the one of risk-free debt. Equally, the assumption that firms belonging to the same risk class were replaced by the assumption that firms have the same beta b risk. E.g. b i = COV[k i ,k m ]/VAR[k m ], where COV[k i ,k m ] is the covariance between the returns of the asset under valuation (k i ) and the market portfolio (k m ), and VAR[k m ] is the variance of the market portfolio. The equal beta assumption is much less restrictive, because there are indefinitely many and not perfectly correlated future cash flows that produce the same beta. Rubinsteins model represented an important progress, but it could not generalize all of the M&M propositions on capital structure (To be exact, Rubinstein was the first to prove the basic M&M irrelevance theorem using a mean-variance approach, but Stiglitz [1969] had already introduced risky debt by using a state-preference approach. But this was only of theoretical relevance, since the nature of the state preference theory prevent it from being tested empirically). Hsia [1981] generalized the remaining propositions and this progress was also contingent on another and independent discovery in the field of option pricing. This discovery was provided by Black and Scholes [1973] who developed the first option pricing model (OPM) in continuous time. This model is

description

The Irrelevance of Capital Structure in Perfect Capital Markets

Transcript of The Irrelevance of Capital Structure in Perfect Capital Markets

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 1/9

    Page info: *Author: Mathiesen, H.*Document version: 2.2.*Copyright 1997-2014,ViamInvest. Legal notice.

    Model: The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    1 Introduction

    This appendix presents proofs of a modern version of the Modigliani and Miler propositions on the

    irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets. Note: Footnotes and highlighted text can be

    clicked for more info.

    The propositions on capital structure made by Modigliani and Miller (M&M) are among the

    most important contributions in the theory of corporate finance. The theorems were first stated in the

    seminal papers [1958, 1963] on the cost of capital, corporate valuation and capital structure. The first

    versions were very simple. They assumed that debt could be only of the risk-free type, and that all

    firms belonged to the same risk class. The latter assumption meant that the expected future cash flow

    in all firms should be perfectly correlated, and only allowed to vary by a scale factor. E.g. CFi,t =

    aCFj,t, where CF is cash flow in firm i and j, respectively, a is the scale factor, and t count the future

    periods. These assumptions are certainly unrealistic, but fortunately, later developments in the theory of

    corporate finance made them redundant. Independent of the capital structure theory Sharpe [1963,

    1964] and Treynor [1961] built the first model that could price risky assets on individual terms. This

    model has now come to be known as the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Rubinstien [1973]

    merged the CAPM model with the original M&M framework on capital structure. This was possible

    because the M&M framework and the CAPM model are built on almost the exact same assumptions

    on perfect capital markets. The gain was that the more realistic assumption of risky debt replaced the

    one of risk-free debt. Equally, the assumption that firms belonging to the same risk class were replaced

    by the assumption that firms have the same beta b risk. E.g. b i = COV[ki,km]/VAR[km], where

    COV[ki,km] is the covariance between the returns of the asset under valuation (ki) and the market

    portfolio (km), and VAR[km] is the variance of the market portfolio. The equal beta assumption is

    much less restrictive, because there are indefinitely many and not perfectly correlated future cash flows

    that produce the same beta. Rubinsteins model represented an important progress, but it could not

    generalize all of the M&M propositions on capital structure (To be exact, Rubinstein was the first to

    prove the basic M&M irrelevance theorem using a mean-variance approach, but Stiglitz [1969] had

    already introduced risky debt by using a state-preference approach. But this was only of theoretical

    relevance, since the nature of the state preference theory prevent it from being tested empirically).

    Hsia [1981] generalized the remaining propositions and this progress was also contingent on another

    and independent discovery in the field of option pricing. This discovery was provided by Black and

    Scholes [1973] who developed the first option pricing model (OPM) in continuous time. This model is

    http://e.viaminvest.com/default.asphttp://e.viaminvest.com/Copyrights.asphttp://e.viaminvest.com/searchpage.htmhttp://e.viaminvest.com/B14References/ReferencesA.asphttp://e.viaminvest.com/B19Sitemaps/default.asphttp://e.viaminvest.com/A2MonitorSystems/AppA2MonitorSystems/AppBtoA2CAP_model/CAP_Model.asp

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 2/9

    also built on the assumptions of perfect capital markets, so Hsia was able to merge the CAPM, and

    the OPM with the M&M framework on capital structure and thereby generalize the remaining

    propositions. Rubinsteins and Hsias versions are perhaps the most general that have been produced

    so far. The price to be paid for this generalization is that the proofs behind the M&M propositions

    have become considerably more complicated from a mathematical point of view. This text reproduces

    the full Rubinstein argument. The proofs of Hsia arguments are by large omitted but the results will be

    stated. However, both the Rubinstein- and the Hsia argument is proved by a simple and easily

    comprehendible numeric example that illustrates all of the generalized M&M propositions.

    2 Theory

    What Rubinstein generalized, was the most basic of the M&M propositions: The proposition on the

    irrelevance of capital structure.

    Proposition I: The market value of any firm is independent of its capital structure and is given by

    capitalizing its expected return at the rate r appropriate to its class, Modigliani and Miller [1958,

    page 268]. In modern terms, capital structure is irrelevant, and firm value is equal to the present value

    of the free cash flow discounted at the relevant cost of capital.

    Rubinstein used the following assumptions explicitly or implicitly:

    1) Capital markets are perfect

    Markets are frictionless. I.e., there is no transaction cost (Implication: the borrowingrate equals the lending rate), no taxes, and all assets are perfectly divisible and marketable

    (Implication: e.g. human capital is non-existing (it is not divisible and it cant be owned as anasset), and there are no constraining regulations.

    Perfect competition in product and securities markets. Among other things, this imply

    that all producers and consumers are price takers.

    Information efficiency. That is, information is costless, and is received simultaneously

    by all individuals, both corporate insiders and outsiders (this implies no signaling).

    Agents are perfectly rational and use it to maximize there utility

    2) There is no cost to bankruptcy.

    3) Firms issue risky debt and equity, and have the same beta b risk.4) All cash flow streams are perpetuities, and no growth is allowed.

    5) Allowing for proportional corporate tax eases the no-tax assumption above.6) Managers always maximize the shareholders wealth (imply no agency costs).

    7) Homemade leverage is a perfect substitute for corporate leverage. That is, there is nodifference between corporate and personal borrowing (necessary for arbitrage arguments).

    The assumptions above are primarily associated with the original M&M framework. First and

    foremost, in order to apply the CAPM model, the following assumptions are needed.[1]

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 3/9

    8) Investors are risk averse individuals.9) Investors have homogenous expectations (beliefs) about asset returns (Implication: all investors

    perceive identical opportunity sets).10) Asset returns are distributed by the normal distribution.

    11) A risk free asset exists, and investors may borrow or lend unlimited amounts of this asset at aconstant rate: the risk free rate (kf).

    12) There are a definite number of assets and their quantities are fixed over time.

    These were the assumptions. The following proofs draw heavily on Copeland and Weston [1988,

    pages 462-471]. According to the CAPM model, the equilibrium cost of capital for debt (b for

    bonds) and for equity (s for stocks) in any firm is:

    (1)

    (2)

    where,

    E[kb] is the expected cost of capital on bonds.

    E[ks] is the expected cost of capital on stocks.

    kf is the expected return on a risk-free portfolio; that is, a portfolio that yields constant return

    period after period with certainty.

    E[km] is the expected return on the market portfolio.

    bb, or bs is the systematic risk. That is, the risk that cant be diversified away. b measures the size

    of risk contrary to (E[km] - kf) that measures the price of risk.

    COV(kb,km), or COV(ks,km) is the expected covariance in returns between the capital being

    priced and the overall market portfolio.

    VAR(km) is the expected variance of the market portfolio.

    Assuming that there is no growth and that investment equals depreciation (I=Dep), the return on

    equity, ks, of any firm can also be expressed by its accounting definition.

    (3)

    where,

    NOI is net operating income. That is, revenues less variable and fixed cash expenses from

    operations and less deprecations.

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A2MonitorSystems/AppA2MonitorSystems/AppBtoA2CAP_model/CAP_Model.asp

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 4/9

    B is the market value of debt.

    tc is the corporate tax rate.

    SL is the market value of equity in a levered firm.

    Taking the expectation to (3) yields

    (4)

    Substituting (3) into the COV[ks,km] from (2) yields

    (5)

    Substituting (5) into (2) yields

    (6)

    Substituting (6) into (4) yields

    (7)

    E[NOI](1-tc) - E[kb]B(1-tc) =

    (8)

    Making an analog argument for an non-levered firm, where B=0 and SL=VU (VU is the market value

    of an non-levered firm) yields:

    (9)

    Substituting E[NOI](1-tc) from (8) into (9) yields

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 5/9

    =>[2]

    =>[3]

    kf (VL-B) = kf V

    U -kf B(1-tc) VL-B = VU - B(1-tc) V

    L = VU + Btc (10)

    Q.E.D.

    If tc = 0, then firm value is independent of leverage, and proposition 1 is proved to hold.

    Hsia [1981] generalized the rest of the M&M propositions. They will not be proved, only presented.

    Essentially, what Hsia does, is extending the Rubinstein framework by the Black-Scholes OPM

    formula. Then, he uses the fact that the value of equity in a levered firm is identical to the value of a call

    option written on the firm, and that the value of risky debt in a levered firm is the same as the value of

    risk-free debt plus a short put option on the value of the firm. Both options are of the European type,

    and has an exercise price equal to the future value of the risk-free debt, and a maturity equal to the

    maturity of the risk-free debt. The rest of the Hsia argument is purely mathematical[4]

    .

    Proposition II: The required rate of return on equity, or cost of equity (ks), increases with financial

    leverage (B/[B+S]).

    This proposition can be proved by the following formula on the cost of equity:

    (11)

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 6/9

    where,

    N(.) is the cumulative normal probability of the unit normal variate, d1.

    kV is the return on the firms asset.

    T is the maturity time of the firms bonds.

    s is the standard variate of returns on the firms assets.

    D is the future value of the zero coupon bond, or face value.

    Proposition III: The required rate of return on debt or cost of debt (kb) increases with financial

    leverage (B/[B+S]).

    This proposition can be proved by the following formula on the cost of debt:

    (12)

    Proposition IV: In a world without taxes, the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is invariant

    to changes in the capital structure of the firm.

    Proposition 4 can easily be proved by inserting (11) and (12) in the definition for the average cost of

    capital:

    WACC = kb*B/V + ks*S/V, and V = B+S

    = {kf + N(-d1)[kV - kf]V/B}*B/V + { kf + N(d1)[kV - kf]V/S }*S/V

    = kf{(B+S)/V} + [kV - kf]*{ N(-d1) + N(d1)}

    = kf + [kV - kf]*{ 1- N(d1) + N(d1)}

    = kV (kV is the same as r in proposition 1) (13)

    Q.E.D.

    The WACC formula may be generalized to include any number of financial instruments and different

    tax assumptions.

    3 Illustrating the M&M propositions The generalized Modigliani and Miller theorems may seem complicated when looking at the

    mathematics. But fortunately, the propositions are very simple to illustrate in a figure. This is done in

    figure I below.

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 7/9

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 8/9

    Note that all four theorems are fulfilled in figure G. Also very interestingly, the figure version of the

    M&M framework does not require returns to follow the normal distribution. Actually, any underlying

    risk distribution may do! What matters, is that firm cash flow is unrelated to capital structure, and this

    is always so in the perfect M&M world. One might think that the M&M theorems are trivial. But they

    are not. Before the invention of the M&M, framework many corporate treasurers in fact believed that

    leveraging did increase corporate risk. By verbal logic, they argued something like this: If you agree

    that levering up the corporate capital structure makes the remaining equity riskier, and you also agree

    that any junior debt added to the capital structure must, necessarily, be riskier debt carrying a lower

    rating, and a higher interest than on any debt outstanding before the higher leveraging, then you must

    also agree that leveraging does increase corporate risk, thereby decreasing the market value of the

    firm. Propositions 2 and 3 do indeed agree that both the risk of debt and equity increase when

    leverage increases. However, proposition 4 proofs that this does not increase the corporate risk, and

    when this is true, proposition 1 about corporate value must also be valid. The old-fashioned treasurer

    simply forgets to take into account the changing weights.

    Evidence

    Despite all the propositions of the M&M world, when the real world is considered, all firms and

    branches behave as if an optimal capital structure existed. Empirically, branches and firms have

    capital structures that do not change much over time. Another stylized fact is that some firms are

    entirely financed by equity, but no firms are entirely debt financed. Neither of these observations are

    consistent with the M&M propositions. There are several extensions of the M&M capital structure

    theory that may explain the existence of an optimal capital structure. Click here to go to the hypothesis

    exhibition in order to find some of these explanations.

    - Copyright 1997-2014, ViamInvest. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproductionprohibited without permission. Legal notice.

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A0BigPicture/2Hypotheses/Exhi_2CorpGovHypo.asphttp://e.viaminvest.com/Copyrights.asp

  • 25-8-2014 The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp 9/9

    [1] For proof of the CAPM model click here.

    [2] Use the fact that the value of a levered firm, VL, is equal to the value of the firms stocks, SL, plus the value of its

    bonds, B: VL= SL + B SL = VL - B.[3]

    Substituting (E1) into E[kb].

    [4] Proof of the Black-Scholes OPM model may be found in Copeland and Weston [1988, pages 296-299]. In the same

    book [pages 464-469] some of the Hsia proofs may be found.

    http://e.viaminvest.com/A2MonitorSystems/AppA2MonitorSystems/AppBtoA2CAP_model/CAP_Model.asp