The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361...

50
Housing Policy Debate Volume 8, Issue 2 359 © Fannie Mae Foundation 1997. All Rights Reserved. The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities Anthony Downs The Brookings Institution Abstract This article describes the population forces that caused U.S. metropolitan areas to grow rapidly after 1940 but caused falling population in many large older cities. It shows why the basic processes that generated the spatial growth and development of American metropolitan areas have also under- mined the fiscal strength of many older central cities and inner-ring suburbs. By concentrating low-income households in inner-core neighborhoods, these processes create undesirable conditions that motivate economically viable households and firms to move to surrounding suburbs and not move back. Three strategies have been suggested for improving these conditions: major structural reform of metropolitan institutions, limited reform of big-city governments, and community development of inner-core areas. The first is the most capable of changing the dynamics causing decline, but it lacks political support because it would require the majority of metropolitan residents to sacrifice some benefits they gain from existing arrangements. Keywords: Development/revitalization; Urban planning; Populations Introduction This article presents a brief historical perspective and a policy overview concerning the current decline of many American big cities and inner-ring suburbs. It emphasizes the challenge of attracting middle-class households to live in those communities. 1 A basic perspective on changes in metropolitan structures Population trends can best be understood if American cities are viewed as continuous dynamic social processes occurring in 1 The term core area as used in this article refers to the central city and the inner-ring suburbs of a metropolitan area. Inner-ring suburbs are those legally separate communities immediately adjacent to, and contiguous with, the central city of a metropolitan area. Outer-ring suburbs are those legally separate communities on the outer periphery of the metropolitan area, usually not adjacent to or contiguous with the central city, and often some distance away from that city.

Transcript of The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361...

Page 1: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 359Housing Policy Debate • Volume 8, Issue 2 359© Fannie Mae Foundation 1997. All Rights Reserved.

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities

Anthony DownsThe Brookings Institution

Abstract

This article describes the population forces that caused U.S. metropolitanareas to grow rapidly after 1940 but caused falling population in many largeolder cities. It shows why the basic processes that generated the spatialgrowth and development of American metropolitan areas have also under-mined the fiscal strength of many older central cities and inner-ring suburbs.By concentrating low-income households in inner-core neighborhoods, theseprocesses create undesirable conditions that motivate economically viablehouseholds and firms to move to surrounding suburbs and not move back.

Three strategies have been suggested for improving these conditions: majorstructural reform of metropolitan institutions, limited reform of big-citygovernments, and community development of inner-core areas. The first is themost capable of changing the dynamics causing decline, but it lacks politicalsupport because it would require the majority of metropolitan residents tosacrifice some benefits they gain from existing arrangements.

Keywords: Development/revitalization; Urban planning; Populations

Introduction

This article presents a brief historical perspective and a policyoverview concerning the current decline of many American bigcities and inner-ring suburbs. It emphasizes the challenge ofattracting middle-class households to live in those communities.1

A basic perspective on changes in metropolitanstructures

Population trends can best be understood if American cities areviewed as continuous dynamic social processes occurring in

1 The term core area as used in this article refers to the central city and theinner-ring suburbs of a metropolitan area. Inner-ring suburbs are those legallyseparate communities immediately adjacent to, and contiguous with, thecentral city of a metropolitan area. Outer-ring suburbs are those legallyseparate communities on the outer periphery of the metropolitan area, usuallynot adjacent to or contiguous with the central city, and often some distanceaway from that city.

Page 2: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

360 Anthony Downs

defined locations, not as locations or places per se. At any givenmoment, describing a city is analogous to taking a snapshot ofmany ongoing and constantly changing flows of people, goods,and services. This is particularly true because of the highrates of household mobility in the United States. About 16 to17 percent of Americans move each year, including more than30 percent of renters and around 10 percent of homeowners(Downs 1981, chap. 3; U.S. Bureau of the Census 1996 [Statisti-cal Abstract]). About three-fifths of those movers remain in thesame county, many in the same city.

Private firms are also quite mobile. Each year, many new firmsare born and many existing ones die. In addition, existingfirms often move from one place to another or establish newbranches, thereby reallocating their overall resources in space.Thus, in any particular neighborhood, the local population andeconomy can remain the same or grow only if at least as manynewcomers move in (or are born there, net of local deaths) asinitial residents and firms move out. So every city is really thelocus of constant movements of people and firms into, out of,around, and within its boundaries.

Historically, many American cities have been the locations for—and provided the means of—achieving upward mobility over timefor large populations arriving from elsewhere with few economicresources, and sometimes with relatively few social and humanresources. These influxes have come both from abroad and fromrural parts of the United States at different times. Certainneighborhoods have performed the vital function of helping thesepeople improve their social and economic status and move tobetter locations. This function is still crucial in most U.S. metro-politan areas. From 1990 through 1995, 29 percent of net U.S.population growth stemmed from net immigration from abroad—not counting illegal immigration (U.S. Bureau of the Census1996 [Statistical Abstract]).

Viewing cities dynamically has several crucial implications.First, it is impossible to eliminate poverty from large metropoli-tan areas, each of which will always contain many poor people aslong as it continues receiving poor immigrants.

Second, large metropolitan areas necessarily contain thousandsof low-quality dwelling units—“slum dwellings”—needed tohouse many of their poor households, unless the public sectorspends huge sums on housing subsidies for the very poor. If poorhouseholds are required to pay fully for their own upkeep, manycannot afford to occupy dwellings that are of “decent quality” by

Page 3: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361

middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households mustlive in what are considered substandard dwellings, unless thepublic sector provides large housing subsidies for them. Mostsocieties cannot afford the subsidies needed to house all theirlow-income households at middle-class standards. Even theUnited States—which might be able to afford that outcome—hasnever chosen to do so. Thus, slums perform the absolutely essen-tial social function of providing housing that many poor peoplecan afford.

Third, at least some concentrated-poverty neighborhoods arenecessary functional parts of every large metropolitan area. Noteveryone succeeds in rising in social and economic status. At anygiven moment, a large metropolitan area contains thousands ofhouseholds still at the bottom of the socioeconomic ladder be-cause they have not yet moved up. Moreover, newly arrivingimmigrants tend to enter a metropolitan area through a fewspecific neighborhoods—those where housing is less costly orwhere they can find others of their own ethnic group. Theseneighborhoods contain disproportionate concentrations of rela-tively poor households. As households that entered at the bottomof the ladder move up, they tend to move to other neighborhoodswith higher average incomes and status. In fact, many affluentimmigrants, often from Asia, move directly to the suburbs. Thisprocess leaves urban entrepôt neighborhoods with long-termabove-average percentages of very low income and low-statushouseholds. No doubt, this condition makes it harder for personsliving in those areas to improve their lots. Yet such concentrated-poverty areas are essential to the overall functioning of themetropolitan area. Over time, the particular neighborhoodsserving this function often change, especially when the largestimmigration flows shift from one ethnic group to another.

This conclusion does not mean that all concentrated-povertyneighborhoods in cities are necessary parts of the upward mobil-ity process. More than one type of concentrated-poverty areaexists in every large city. Many neighborhoods contain mostlypoor people who have not recently immigrated and have fewprospects for improving their situations. These concentrated-poverty areas are often socially and economically isolated fromfruitful opportunities for upward mobility and plagued by nega-tive conditions stemming from poverty; they are dysfunctionalenclaves of the so-called underclass.2 It would therefore be

2 For a discussion of the underclass, see Jencks and Peterson (1991). For adiscussion of the process by which destitute households get “left behind” insuch areas when better-off households move out, see Wilson (1987).

Page 4: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

362 Anthony Downs

desirable to transform them radically into a less destructivecondition.

Unfortunately, the three implications presented above are rarelystated publicly by elected officials or city planners. Politicalpressures make it impossible for officials to admit these truths.If they did, residents of the areas concerned would claim thattheir right to live better lives was being ignored or abandoned.

The dynamics of changes in total population and inpopulation composition in declining cities from 1950to 1980

Introduction

Among the 189 U.S. cities with 1990 populations over 105,000,53 lost population in the 1980s. Together, they contained18.5 million residents in 1990, 16.5 percent fewer than in 1950.Tables 1, 2, and 3 provide some basic data on these 53 decliningcities, their metropolitan areas, and their suburbs from 1950 tothe 1990s. Fifteen lost more than 20 percent of their populationbetween 1950 and 1990, including 13 that lost population in allfour decades. These 15 acutely declining cities have presumablyexperienced the biggest net outflows of middle-class households(U.S. Bureau of the Census 1995 [Statistical Abstract]).

It is useful to divide the population changes in declining citiessince 1950 into two sets: those occurring from 1950 to 1980 andthose subsequent to 1980. In both eras, what happened in each ofthese cities should be viewed within the context of the overallmovement of population within its metropolitan area, includingimmigration.

Initial population conditions in 1950

From 1941 to 1945, millions of households moved into thesemetropolitan areas to work in war production. Yet virtually nonew housing had been constructed in the United States duringeither the 1930s, because of the Great Depression, or the 1940s,because of the war. By 1950, much of the housing in these citieswas old and severely overcrowded. Overcrowding was particu-larly acute in neighborhoods occupied by African Americans.They had been confined to a small number of older areas by

Page 5: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 363

Tab

le 1

. P

op

ula

tio

n C

ha

ng

es f

rom

195

0 to

199

2 in

All

53

La

rge

U.S

. Cit

ies

Th

at

Dec

lin

ed i

n P

op

ula

tio

nfr

om

198

0 to

199

0

Tota

l Cit

y P

opu

lati

on o

n A

pril

1(T

hou

san

ds)

% C

han

ge in

Pop

ula

tion

Cit

yR

egio

n19

5019

60 1

970

198

0 1

990

1992

1950

–60

1960

–70

1970

–80

1980

–90

1990

–92

Akr

on, O

HM

W27

529

027

523

722

322

45.

45–5

.17

–13.

82–5

.91

0.45

Atl

anta

, GA

S33

148

749

542

539

439

547

.13

1.64

–14.

14–7

.29

0.25

Bal

tim

ore,

MD

S95

093

990

578

773

672

6–1

.16

–3.6

2–1

3.04

–6.4

8–1

.36

Bea

um

ont,

TX

SW

9411

911

811

811

411

526

.60

–0.8

40.

00–3

.39

0.88

Bir

min

gham

, AL

S32

634

130

128

426

626

54.

60–1

1.73

–5.6

5–6

.34

–0.3

8B

ridg

epor

t, C

TN

E15

915

715

714

314

213

7–1

.26

0.00

–8.9

2–0

.70

–3.5

2B

uff

alo,

NY

NE

580

533

463

358

328

323

–8.1

0–1

3.13

–22.

68–8

.38

–1.5

2C

edar

Rap

ids,

IA

MW

7292

111

110

109

112

27.7

820

.65

–0.9

0–0

.91

2.75

Ch

atta

noo

ga, T

NS

131

130

120

170

152

153

–0.7

6–7

.69

41.6

7–1

0.59

0.66

Ch

icag

o, I

LM

W3,

621

3,55

03,

369

3,00

52,

784

2,76

8–1

.96

–5.1

0–1

0.80

–7.3

5–0

.57

Cin

cin

nat

i, O

HM

W50

450

345

438

536

436

4–0

.20

–9.7

4–1

5.20

–5.4

50.

00C

leve

lan

d, O

HM

W91

587

675

157

450

650

3–4

.26

–14.

27–2

3.57

–11.

85–0

.59

Day

ton

, OH

MW

244

262

243

194

182

183

7.38

–7.2

5–2

0.16

–6.1

90.

55D

enve

r, C

OW

416

494

515

493

468

484

18.7

54.

25–4

.27

–5.0

73.

42D

etro

it, M

IM

W1,

850

1,67

01,

514

1,20

31,

028

1,01

2–9

.73

–9.3

4–2

0.54

–14.

55–1

.56

Eri

e, P

AN

E13

113

812

911

910

910

95.

34–6

.52

–7.7

5–8

.40

0.00

Eva

nsv

ille

, IN

MW

129

149

139

130

126

128

15.5

0–6

.71

–6.4

7–3

.08

1.59

Fli

nt,

MI

MW

163

197

193

160

141

139

20.8

6–2

.03

–17.

10–1

1.88

–1.4

2F

t. L

aude

rdal

e, F

LS

3684

140

153

149

149

133.

3366

.67

9.29

–2.6

10.

00G

ary,

IN

MW

134

178

175

152

117

117

32.8

4–1

.69

–13.

14–2

3.03

0.00

Hon

olu

lu, H

IW

248

294

325

365

365

371

18.5

510

.54

12.3

10.

001.

64Ja

ckso

n, M

SS

9814

415

420

319

719

646

.94

6.94

31.8

2–2

.96

–0.5

1K

ansa

s C

ity,

KS

MW

130

122

168

161

150

147

–6.1

537

.70

–4.1

7–6

.83

–2.0

0K

ansa

s C

ity,

MO

MW

457

476

507

448

435

432

4.16

6.51

–11.

64–2

.90

–0.6

9K

nox

vill

e, T

NS

125

112

175

175

165

167

–10.

4056

.25

0.00

–5.7

11.

21L

ansi

ng,

MI

MW

9210

813

113

012

712

717

.39

21.3

0–0

.76

–2.3

10.

00L

ouis

vill

e, K

YS

369

391

362

299

269

271

5.96

–7.4

2–1

7.40

–10.

030.

74M

acon

, GA

S70

7012

211

710

710

70.

0074

.29

–4.1

0–8

.55

0.00

Mem

phis

, TN

S39

649

862

464

661

061

025

.76

25.3

03.

53–5

.57

0.00

Met

airi

e, L

AS

NA

NA

136

164

149

NA

NA

N

A20

.59

–9.1

5

N

A

Page 6: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

364 Anthony DownsT

able

1.

Po

pu

lati

on

Ch

an

ges

fro

m 1

950

to 1

992

in A

ll 5

3 L

arg

e U

.S. C

itie

s T

ha

t D

ecli

ned

in

Po

pu

lati

on

fro

m 1

980

to 1

990

(con

tin

ued

)

Tota

l Cit

y P

opu

lati

on o

n A

pril

1(T

hou

san

ds)

% C

han

ge in

Pop

ula

tion

Cit

yR

egio

n19

5019

60 1

970

198

0 1

990

1992

1950

–60

1960

–70

1970

–80

1980

–90

1990

–92

Mil

wau

kee,

WI

MW

637

741

717

636

628

617

16.3

3–3

.24

–11.

30–1

.26

–1.7

5M

inn

eapo

lis,

MN

MW

522

483

434

371

368

363

–7.4

7–1

0.14

–14.

52–0

.81

–1.3

6M

obil

e, A

LS

129

203

190

200

196

202

57.3

6–6

.40

5.26

–2.0

03.

06N

ew O

rlea

ns,

LA

S57

062

859

355

849

749

010

.18

–5.5

7–5

.90

–10.

93–1

.41

New

ark,

NJ

NE

439

405

382

329

275

268

–7.7

4–5

.68

–13.

87–1

6.41

–2.5

5N

orfo

lk, V

AS

214

306

308

267

261

254

42.9

90.

65–1

3.31

–2.2

5–2

.68

Peo

ria,

IL

MW

112

103

127

124

114

114

–8.0

423

.30

–2.3

6–8

.06

0.00

Ph

ilad

elph

ia, P

AN

E2,

071

2,00

31,

949

1,68

81,

586

1,55

3–3

.28

–2.7

0–1

3.39

–6.0

4–2

.08

Pit

tsbu

rgh

, PA

NE

677

604

520

424

370

367

–10.

78–1

3.91

–18.

46–1

2.74

–0.8

1R

ich

mon

d, V

AS

230

220

249

219

203

202

–4.3

513

.18

–12.

05–7

.31

–0.4

9R

och

este

r, N

YN

E33

231

929

524

223

223

4–3

.92

–7.5

2–1

7.97

–4.1

30.

86R

ockf

ord,

IL

MW

9312

714

714

013

914

236

.56

15.7

5–4

.76

–0.7

12.

16S

alt

Lak

e C

ity,

UT

W18

218

917

616

316

016

63.

85–6

.88

–7.3

9–1

.84

3.75

Sav

ann

ah, G

AS

120

149

118

142

138

139

24.1

7–2

0.81

20.3

4–2

.82

0.72

Sh

reve

port

, LA

S12

716

418

220

619

919

729

.13

10.9

813

.19

–3.4

0–1

.01

Sou

th B

end,

IN

MW

116

132

126

110

106

106

13.7

9–4

.55

–12.

70–3

.64

0.00

St.

Lou

is, M

OM

W85

775

062

245

339

738

4–1

2.49

–17.

07–2

7.17

–12.

36–3

.27

St.

Pet

ersb

urg

, FL

S97

181

216

239

239

235

86.6

019

.34

10.6

50.

00–1

.67

Syr

acu

se, N

YN

E22

121

619

717

016

416

3–2

.26

–8.8

0–1

3.71

–3.5

3–0

.61

Tole

do, O

HM

W30

431

838

335

533

332

94.

6120

.44

–7.3

1–6

.20

–1.2

0W

arre

n, M

IM

W1

8917

916

114

514

28,

800.

0010

1.12

–10.

06–9

.94

–2.0

7W

ash

ingt

on, D

CS

802

764

757

638

607

585

–4.7

4–0

.92

–15.

72–4

.86

–3.6

2Yo

nke

rs, N

YN

E15

319

120

419

518

818

624

.84

6.81

–4.4

1–3

.59

–1.0

6

Tot

al p

opu

lati

on22

,052

22,6

8922

,342

19,9

3818

,557

18,2

722.

89–1

.53

–10.

76–6

.93

–1.5

4N

um

ber

of c

itie

s52

5253

5353

52P

erce

nt

chan

ge in

adj

ust

ed t

otal

pop

ula

tion

:To

tal a

dju

sted

to

sam

e n

um

ber

of c

itie

s (5

2)22

,052

22,6

8922

,206

19,7

7418

,408

18,2

722.

89–2

.13

–10.

95–6

.91

–0.7

4N

um

eric

al c

han

ge in

adj

ust

ed t

otal

pop

ula

tion

(00

0)s:

637

(483

)(2

,432

)(1

,366

)(1

36)

Not

e : I

nc l

ude

s on

ly c

itie

s w

ith

mor

e th

an 1

00,0

00 r

esid

ents

in

199

0. M

W =

Mid

wes

t; N

E =

Nor

thea

st;

S =

Sou

th;

W =

Wes

t; N

A =

not

ava

ilab

le.

Page 7: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 365T

able

2. P

op

ula

tio

n C

ha

ng

es f

rom

195

0 to

199

4 in

Met

rop

oli

tan

Are

as

wit

h C

entr

al

Cit

ies

Th

at

Dec

lin

edin

Po

pu

lati

on

fro

m 1

980

to 1

990

Tota

l Met

ropo

lita

n A

rea

Pop

ula

tion

on

Apr

il 1

(Th

ousa

nds

)%

Ch

ange

in P

opu

lati

on

1950

1950

Met

ropo

lita

n A

rea

Ori

gin

alE

stim

ated

1960

197

0 1

980

199

019

9419

50–6

019

60–7

019

70–8

019

80–9

019

90–9

4

Akr

on, O

H41

0.0

482.

860

5.0

679.

066

0.0

658.

067

7.0

25.3

112

.23

–2.8

0–0

.30

2.89

Atl

anta

, GA

671.

872

7.1

1,01

7.2

1,39

0.0

2,23

3.0

2,96

0.0

3,33

1.0

39.9

036

.65

60.6

532

.56

12.5

3B

alti

mor

e, M

D1,

337.

41,

467.

81,

804.

02,

071.

02,

199.

02,

383.

02,

458.

022

.91

14.8

06.

188.

373.

15B

eau

mon

t, T

X19

5.1

235.

630

6.0

316.

037

3.0

361.

037

3.0

29.8

83.

2718

.04

–3.2

23.

32B

irm

ingh

am, A

L55

8.9

657.

574

7.0

767.

081

5.0

840.

087

2.0

13.6

12.

686.

263.

073.

81B

ridg

epor

t, C

T25

8.1

273.

335

0.0

402.

043

9.0

444.

0N

A28

.06

14.8

69.

201.

14N

AB

uff

alo,

NY

1,08

9.2

1,08

9.2

1,30

7.0

1,34

9.0

1,24

3.0

1,18

9.0

1,18

9.0

20.0

03.

21–7

.86

–4.3

40.

00C

edar

Rap

ids,

IA

104.

310

4.3

136.

9N

AN

AN

AN

A31

.26

NA

NA

NA

NA

Ch

atta

noo

ga, T

N24

6.5

295.

934

0.0

371.

041

8.0

424.

043

9.0

14.9

09.

1212

.67

1.44

3.54

Ch

icag

o, I

L5,

495.

45,

179.

86,

221.

06,

979.

07,

246.

07,

411.

07,

668.

020

.10

12.1

83.

832.

283.

47C

inci

nn

ati,

OH

904.

41,

070.

01,

268.

01,

385.

01,

468.

01,

526.

01,

581.

018

.50

9.23

5.99

3.95

3.60

Cle

vela

nd,

OH

1,46

5.5

1,55

7.0

1,90

9.0

2,06

4.0

2,27

8.0

2,20

2.0

2,22

2.0

22.6

18.

1210

.37

–3.3

40.

91D

ayto

n, O

H45

7.3

542.

972

7.0

850.

094

2.0

951.

095

6.0

33.9

116

.92

10.8

20.

960.

53D

enve

r, C

O56

3.8

615.

993

5.0

1,22

8.0

1,42

9.0

1,62

3.0

1,79

6.0

51.8

131

.34

16.3

713

.58

10.6

6D

etro

it, M

I3,

016.

23,

167.

63,

950.

04,

435.

04,

388.

04,

267.

04,

307.

024

.70

12.2

8–1

.06

–2.7

60.

94E

rie,

PA

219.

421

9.6

251.

026

4.0

280.

027

6.0

280.

014

.30

5.18

6.06

–1.4

31.

45E

van

svil

le, I

N16

0.4

260.

727

2.0

285.

027

6.0

279.

028

7.0

4.33

4.78

–3.1

61.

092.

87F

lin

t, M

I27

1.0

309.

042

8.0

497.

045

0.0

430.

043

3.0

38.5

116

.12

–9.4

6–4

.44

0.70

Ft.

Lau

derd

ale,

FL

NA

83.9

334.

062

0.0

1,01

8.0

1,25

6.0

1,38

3.0

298.

0985

.63

64.1

923

.38

10.1

1G

ary,

IN

NA

408.

557

4.0

633.

064

3.0

605.

062

0.0

40.5

110

.28

1.58

–5.9

12.

48H

onol

ulu

, HI

353.

035

2.9

500.

463

1.0

763.

083

6.0

874.

041

.80

26.1

020

.92

9.57

4.55

Jack

son

, MS

142.

216

7.9

221.

025

9.0

362.

039

5.0

412.

031

.63

17.1

939

.77

9.12

4.30

Kan

sas

Cit

y, K

S —

Th

is c

ity

is in

clu

ded

in t

he

Kan

sas

Cit

y, M

O, m

etro

poli

tan

are

a. —

Kan

sas

Cit

y, M

O81

4.4

869.

11,

109.

01,

274.

01,

449.

01,

583.

01,

647.

027

.60

14.8

813

.74

9.25

4.04

Kn

oxvi

lle,

TN

337.

134

5.2

377.

040

9.0

546.

058

6.0

631.

09.

218.

4933

.50

7.33

7.68

Lan

sin

g, M

I17

2.9

279.

434

2.0

424.

042

0.0

433.

043

6.0

22.4

123

.98

–0.9

43.

100.

69L

ouis

vill

e, K

Y57

6.9

599.

875

4.0

867.

095

4.0

949.

098

1.0

25.7

114

.99

10.0

3–0

.52

3.37

Mac

on, G

A13

5.0

147.

519

7.0

227.

027

3.0

291.

030

7.0

33.5

615

.23

20.2

66.

595.

50M

emph

is, T

N48

2.4

559.

272

7.0

834.

093

9.0

1,00

7.0

1,05

6.0

30.0

114

.72

12.5

97.

244.

87M

etai

rie,

LA

—T

his

cit

y is

incl

ude

d in

th

e N

ew O

rlea

ns

met

ropo

lita

n a

rea.

Page 8: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

366 Anthony Downs

Tab

le 2

. Po

pu

lati

on

Ch

an

ges

fro

m 1

950

to 1

994

in M

etro

po

lita

n A

rea

s w

ith

Cen

tra

l C

itie

s T

ha

t D

ecli

ned

in P

op

ula

tio

n f

rom

198

0 to

199

0 (

con

tin

ued

)

Tota

l Met

ropo

lita

n A

rea

Pop

ula

tion

on

Apr

il 1

(Th

ousa

nds

)%

Ch

ange

in P

opu

lati

on

1950

1950

Met

ropo

lita

n A

rea

Ori

gin

alE

stim

ated

1960

197

0 1

980

199

019

9419

50–6

019

60–7

019

70–8

019

80–9

019

90–9

4

Mil

wau

kee,

WI

871.

01,

024.

81,

279.

01,

404.

01,

397.

01,

452.

01,

456.

024

.80

9.77

–0.5

03.

940.

28M

inn

eapo

lis,

MN

1,11

6.5

1,24

0.7

1,59

8.0

1,96

5.0

2,19

8.0

2,53

9.0

2,68

8.0

28.8

022

.97

11.8

615

.51

5.87

Mob

ile,

AL

231.

126

6.9

363.

037

7.0

444.

047

7.0

512.

036

.01

3.86

17.7

77.

437.

34N

ew O

rlea

ns,

LA

685.

471

5.8

907.

01,

046.

01,

304.

01,

285.

01,

309.

026

.71

15.3

324

.67

–1.4

61.

87N

ewar

k, N

JN

A1,

593.

91,

833.

02,

057.

01,

964.

01,

919.

01,

934.

015

.00

12.2

2–4

.52

–2.2

90.

78N

orfo

lk, V

A44

6.2

484.

962

9.0

733.

01,

201.

01,

445.

01,

529.

029

.72

16.5

363

.85

20.3

25.

81P

eori

a, I

L25

0.5

271.

431

3.0

342.

036

6.0

339.

034

4.0

15.3

39.

277.

02–7

.38

1.47

Ph

ilad

elph

ia, P

A3,

671.

03,

671.

04,

343.

04,

824.

04,

781.

04,

922.

04,

949.

018

.31

11.0

8–0

.89

2.95

0.55

Pit

tsbu

rgh

, PA

2,21

3.2

2,21

3.2

2,40

5.0

2,40

1.0

2,57

1.0

2,39

5.0

2,40

2.0

8.67

–0.1

77.

08–6

.85

0.29

Ric

hm

ond,

VA

328.

136

7.0

457.

054

2.0

761.

086

6.0

917.

024

.52

18.6

040

.41

13.8

05.

89R

och

este

r, N

Y48

7.6

665.

880

1.0

962.

01,

031.

01,

062.

01,

090.

020

.31

20.1

07.

173.

012.

64R

ockf

ord,

IL

152.

416

7.0

230.

027

2.0

326.

033

0.0

347.

037

.72

18.2

619

.85

1.23

5.15

Sal

t L

ake

Cit

y, U

T27

4.9

413.

457

6.0

705.

091

0.0

1,07

2.0

1,17

8.0

39.3

322

.40

29.0

817

.80

9.89

Sav

ann

ah, G

A15

1.5

151.

518

8.3

N

A23

1.0

258.

027

6.0

24.2

9

NA

N

A11

.69

6.98

Sh

reve

port

, LA

216.

727

0.2

321.

033

4.0

377.

037

6.0

378.

018

.80

4.05

12.8

7–0

.27

0.53

Sou

th B

end,

IN

205.

123

2.8

271.

028

0.0

242.

024

7.0

255.

016

.41

3.32

–13.

572.

073.

24S

t. L

ouis

, MO

1,68

1.3

1,78

9.6

2,14

4.0

2,41

1.0

2,41

4.0

2,49

2.0

2,53

6.0

19.8

012

.45

0.12

3.23

1.77

St.

Pet

ersb

urg

, FL

409.

142

8.5

809.

01,

089.

01,

614.

02,

068.

02,

157.

088

.80

34.6

148

.21

28.1

34.

30S

yrac

use

, NY

314.

746

5.3

564.

063

6.0

723.

074

2.0

754.

021

.21

12.7

713

.68

2.63

1.62

Tole

do, O

H39

5.6

601.

069

5.0

763.

061

7.0

614.

061

4.0

15.6

49.

78–1

9.13

–0.4

90.

00W

arre

n, M

IT

his

cit

y is

incl

ude

d in

th

e D

etro

it, M

I, m

etro

poli

tan

are

a.W

ash

ingt

on, D

C1,

404.

11,

534.

02,

097.

02,

910.

03,

478.

04,

223.

04,

474.

036

.70

38.7

719

.52

21.4

25.

94Yo

nke

rs, N

YT

his

cit

y is

incl

ude

d in

th

e N

ew Y

ork

Cit

y m

etro

poli

tan

are

a.

Tot

alp

opu

lati

on35

,945

40,6

3850

,533

57,5

6363

,454

67,2

8869

,315

Per

cen

t ch

ange

in a

dju

sted

tot

al p

opu

lati

on:

Nu

mbe

r of

are

as52

.049

4949

4949

5124

.33

14.6

49.

836.

043.

01To

tal a

dju

sted

to s

ame

nu

mbe

r35

,840

.340

,533

.850

,395

.957

,772

.763

,454

.067

,288

.069

,315

.0N

um

eric

al c

han

ge in

adj

ust

ed t

otal

pop

ula

tion

:of

are

as (

48)

9,86

2.1

7,37

6.7

5,68

1.4

3,83

4.0

2,02

7.0

Not

e: I

ncl

ude

s on

ly m

etro

poli

tan

are

as w

ith

cen

tral

cit

ies

con

tain

ing

mor

e th

an 1

00,0

00 r

esid

ents

in

199

0. N

A =

not

ava

ilab

le.

Page 9: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 367

Tab

le 3

. Su

bu

rba

n P

op

ula

tio

n C

ha

ng

es f

rom

195

0 to

199

0 in

Met

rop

oli

tan

Are

as

wit

h C

entr

al

Cit

ies

Th

at

Dec

lin

edin

Po

pu

lati

on

fro

m 1

980

to 1

990

Tota

l Su

burb

an P

opu

lati

on o

n A

pril

1(T

hou

san

ds)

% C

han

ge in

Pop

ula

tion

Met

ropo

lita

n A

rea

1950

Est

imat

ed19

60 1

970

198

0 1

990

1950

–60

1960

–70

1970

–80

1980

–90

Akr

on, O

H20

831

540

442

343

551

.59

28.2

54.

702.

84A

tlan

ta, G

A39

653

089

51,

808

2,56

633

.86

68.8

010

2.01

41.9

2B

alti

mor

e, M

D51

886

51,

166

1,41

21,

647

67.0

534

.80

21.1

016

.64

Bea

um

ont,

TX

142

187

198

255

247

32.0

65.

8828

.79

–3.1

4B

irm

ingh

am, A

L33

240

646

653

157

422

.47

14.7

813

.95

8.10

Bri

dgep

ort,

CT

114

193

245

296

302

68.8

526

.94

20.8

22.

03B

uff

alo,

NY

509

774

886

885

861

52.0

014

.47

–0.1

1–2

.71

Ced

ar R

apid

s, I

A—

——

——

NA

——

——

—–—

——

— N

A —

——

——

Ch

atta

noo

ga, T

N16

521

025

124

827

227

.35

19.5

2–1

.20

9.68

Ch

icag

o, I

L1,

559

2,67

13,

610

4,24

14,

627

71.3

535

.16

17.4

89.

10C

inci

nn

ati,

OH

566

765

931

1,08

31,

162

35.1

621

.70

16.3

37.

29C

leve

lan

d, O

H64

21,

033

1,31

31,

704

1,69

660

.90

27.1

129

.78

–0.4

7D

ayto

n, O

H29

946

560

774

876

955

.57

30.5

423

.23

2.81

Den

ver,

CO

200

441

713

936

1,15

512

0.61

61.6

831

.28

23.4

0D

etro

it, M

I1,

318

2,28

02,

921

3,18

53,

239

73.0

428

.11

9.04

1.70

Eri

e, P

A89

113

135

161

167

27.5

419

.47

19.2

63.

73E

van

svil

le, I

N13

212

314

614

615

3–6

.61

18.7

00.

004.

79F

lin

t, M

I14

623

130

429

028

958

.22

31.6

0–4

.61

–0.3

4F

t. L

aude

rdal

e, F

L48

250

480

865

1,10

742

1.92

92.0

080

.21

27.9

8G

ary,

IN

275

396

458

491

488

44.2

615

.66

7.21

–0.6

1H

onol

ulu

, HI

105

206

306

398

471

96.7

648

.26

30.0

718

.34

Jack

son

, MS

7077

105

159

198

10.1

636

.36

51.4

324

.53

Kan

sas

Cit

y, K

S –

––P

art

of a

not

her

cit

y’s

met

ropo

lita

n a

rea

–––

–––

Par

t of

an

oth

er c

ity’

s m

etro

poli

tan

are

a ––

–K

ansa

s C

ity,

MO

412

633

767

1,00

11,

148

53.6

021

.17

30.5

114

.69

Kn

oxvi

lle,

TN

220

265

234

371

421

20.3

5–1

1.70

58.5

513

.48

Lan

sin

g, M

I18

723

429

329

030

624

.87

25.2

1–1

.02

5.52

Lou

isvi

lle,

KY

231

363

505

655

680

57.2

839

.12

29.7

03.

82M

acon

, GA

7812

710

515

618

463

.87

–17.

3248

.57

17.9

5M

emph

is, T

N16

322

921

029

339

740

.32

–8.3

039

.52

35.4

9

Page 10: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

368 Anthony Downs

Tab

le 3

. Su

bu

rba

n P

op

ula

tio

n C

ha

ng

es f

rom

195

0 to

199

0 in

Met

rop

oli

tan

Are

as

wit

h C

entr

al

Cit

ies

Th

at

Dec

lin

edin

Po

pu

lati

on

fro

m 1

980

to 1

990

(co

nti

nu

ed)

Tota

l Su

burb

an P

opu

lati

on o

n A

pril

1(T

hou

san

ds)

% C

han

ge in

Pop

ula

tion

Met

ropo

lita

n A

rea

1950

Est

imat

ed19

60 1

970

198

0 1

990

1950

–60

1960

–70

1970

–80

1980

–90

Met

airi

e, L

A –

––P

art

of a

not

her

cit

y’s

met

ropo

lita

n a

rea

–––

–––

Par

t of

an

oth

er c

ity’

s m

etro

poli

tan

are

a ––

–M

ilw

auke

e, W

I38

853

868

776

182

438

.73

27.7

010

.77

8.28

Min

nea

poli

s, M

N71

91,

115

1,53

11,

827

2,17

155

.14

37.3

119

.33

18.8

3M

obil

e, A

L13

816

018

724

428

116

.03

16.8

830

.48

15.1

6N

ew O

rlea

ns,

LA

146

279

453

746

788

91.3

662

.37

64.6

85.

63N

ewar

k, N

J1,

155

1,42

81,

675

1,63

51,

644

23.6

517

.30

–2.3

90.

55N

orfo

lk, V

A27

132

342

593

41,

184

19.2

331

.58

119.

7626

.77

Peo

ria,

IL

159

210

215

242

225

31.7

42.

3812

.56

–7.0

2P

hil

adel

phia

, PA

1,60

02,

340

2,87

53,

093

3,33

646

.25

22.8

67.

587.

86P

itts

burg

h, P

A1,

536

1,80

11,

881

2,14

72,

025

17.2

44.

4414

.14

–5.6

8R

ich

mon

d, V

A13

723

729

354

266

372

.99

23.6

384

.98

22.3

2R

och

este

r, N

Y33

448

266

778

983

044

.40

38.3

818

.29

5.20

Roc

kfor

d, I

L74

103

125

186

191

39.1

921

.36

48.8

02.

69S

alt

Lak

e C

ity,

UT

231

387

529

747

912

67.2

436

.69

41.2

122

.09

Sav

ann

ah, G

A32

3964

8912

024

.76

63.2

338

.74

34.8

3S

hre

vepo

rt, L

A14

315

715

217

117

79.

64–3

.18

12.5

03.

51S

outh

Ben

d, I

N11

713

915

413

214

119

.01

10.7

9–1

4.29

6.82

St.

Lou

is, M

O93

31,

394

1,78

91,

961

2,09

549

.47

28.3

49.

616.

83S

t. P

eter

sbu

rg, F

L33

262

887

31,

375

1,82

989

.44

39.0

157

.50

33.0

2S

yrac

use

, NY

244

348

439

553

578

42.4

526

.15

25.9

74.

52To

ledo

, OH

297

377

380

262

281

26.9

40.

80–3

1.05

7.25

War

ren

, MI

–––

Par

t of

an

oth

er c

ity’

s m

etro

poli

tan

are

a ––

–––

–P

art

of a

not

her

cit

y’s

met

ropo

lita

n a

rea

–––

Was

hin

gton

, DC

732

1,33

32,

153

2,84

03,

616

82.1

061

.52

31.9

127

.32

Yon

kers

, NY

–––

Par

t of

an

oth

er c

ity’

s m

etro

poli

tan

are

a ––

–––

–P

art

of a

not

her

cit

y’s

met

ropo

lita

n a

rea

–––

Tot

al p

opu

lati

on18

,838

28,2

0136

,201

44,3

0749

,472

49.7

028

.37

22.3

911

.66

Nu

mbe

r of

are

as48

4848

4848

4848

4848

Nu

mer

ical

ch

ange

in t

otal

su

burb

an p

opu

lati

on:

9,36

38,

000

8,10

65,

165

Not

e: I

ncl

ude

s on

ly m

etro

poli

tan

are

as w

ith

cen

tral

cit

ies

con

tain

ing

mor

e th

an 1

00,0

00 r

esid

ents

in

199

0. N

A =

not

ava

ilab

le.

Page 11: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 369

racially restrictive covenants prohibiting occupancy by non-whites in most newer parts of these cities and their suburbs.Hundreds of thousands of African-American households movedinto these neighborhoods from 1941 to 1945 to aid in war produc-tion and from 1945 to 1950 because mechanization displacedthem from southern cotton harvesting. In 1948, the U.S. Su-preme Court ruled that racially restrictive covenants were notlegally enforceable. Almost immediately, severely overcrowdedblack households began moving out of the “ghettos” where theyhad been confined and into surrounding neighborhoods.

The triple population “explosion” from 1950 to 1980

The decades from 1950 to 1980 were characterized by threemajor flows of population into large metropolitan areas. The firstconsisted of low-income African Americans migrating into majorU.S. metropolitan areas, as noted above. This flow reached itspeak in the 1950s but remained high in the 1960s (Farley andAllen 1987).

The second flow was a large-scale movement of white youngpeople out of rural areas throughout the Northeast, South, andMidwest. They entered metropolitan areas seeking better eco-nomic opportunities than were available in their initial farm-oriented communities.

The third flow was a virtual explosion of births throughout thenation to more than 4.0 million per year in the so-called babyboom period, from the mid-1950s to the early 1960s. Since thedeath rate did not rise in this period, the rate of natural increaseshot upward, especially among African Americans and Hispanics(U.S. Bureau of the Census 1996 [Statistical Abstract]).

These three major population flows hugely expanded the totalpopulations of the nation’s major metropolitan areas from 1950through 1980. Figure 1 shows the gains by decade from 1950 to1990 in the combined population of the 49 U.S. metropolitanareas with central cities that lost population from 1980 to1990.3 The biggest gain both absolutely and in percentage terms(24.3 percent) occurred in the 1950s, with subsequent decadesexperiencing gains that declined in both absolute and relativesize. In these metropolitan areas as wholes, the number of

3 Although 53 cities containing more than 100,000 residents in 1990 lostresidents from 1980 to 1990, they were located in only 49 metropolitan areasbecause some of the cities were suburbs in those areas.

Page 12: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

370 Anthony Downs

Fig

ure

1. S

ub

urb

an

an

d C

ity

Po

pu

lati

on

Ch

an

ges

fro

m 1

950

to 1

990

in 4

9 M

etro

po

lita

n A

rea

s w

ith

Cen

tra

l C

itie

sT

ha

t D

ecli

ned

in

Po

pu

lati

on

fro

m 1

980

to 1

990

Mil

lion

s of

Per

sons

Cit

ies

lost

in a

ll d

ecad

esaf

ter

1960

.

–4

1950

s

1960

s

1970

s

1980

s

–20

24

68

10

gain

ed in

tot

al p

opul

atio

n in

all

dec

ades

.

Yet

all 4

9 m

etro

are

as c

ombi

ned

also

but

gain

s gr

adua

lly

slow

ed.

Sub

urbs

gai

ned

in a

ll d

ecad

es

Page 13: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 371

middle-class households increased tremendously from 1950 to1990. Any losses of middle-class households within their centralcities therefore occurred because of changes in the spatial distri-bution of households within these areas.

Other factors influencing spatial settlement patterns from1950 to 1980

One key factor was a sizable increase in the average real in-comes of most households from 1950 to 1973. The median incomeof families in constant dollars rose 96.6 percent in those 23years, or about 2.9 percent per year compounded—comparedwith an overall increase of only 7.1 percent in the 23 years from1970 to 1993, or 0.3 percent per year compounded (U.S. Bureauof the Census various years [Statistical Abstract]). This riseintensified the desire of many households to occupy bigger homeson larger lots. Higher real incomes also enabled more householdsto purchase and use private automobiles.4 At the same time,major networks of high-speed expressways, including the inter-state highway system, were built in all U.S. metropolitan areas.

These trends made possible a gigantic peripheral expansion ofthe territory within these metropolitan areas occupied by built-up settlements, including residences, shopping centers, indus-trial districts, office parks, and other places of employment.Millions of new housing units and other urban structures werecreated on vacant land around the edges of these metropolitanareas, which therefore expanded in all possible directions. Thesenew peripheral settlements had much lower average gross densi-ties (persons per square mile) than the older settlements aroundwhich they were constructed. This caused a peripheral popula-tion explosion in the total number of persons residing in thesuburbs of these metropolitan areas. By the mid-1950s, the totalsuburban population of these metropolitan areas combined hadsurpassed their total central-city population, which declined ineach decade after 1960.

By the mid-1960s, the immense boom in housing and otherconstruction that built these burgeoning suburbs had created farmore dwelling units in each metropolitan area since 1950 thanadditional households that had moved or been formed there, inspite of huge population increases (table 4). This outcome is

4 The number of motor vehicles registered per 100 U.S. residents increasedfrom 32.2 in 1950 to 63.2 in 1980 (Motor Vehicle Manufacturers Association1991; U.S. Bureau of the Census 1996 [Statistical Abstract]).

Page 14: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

372 Anthony Downs

Table 4. Average Annual Housing Increases in Metropolitan Areas

Added Surplus of HousingNew Housing Households Units over

Decade Starts per Year per Year Added Households

1950s 1,596,522 1,016,400 580,1221960s 1,646,333 1,060,200 586,1331970s 2,129,600 1,737,500 392,100

Note: Figures include the average number of new housing units started each year(including new mobile homes), the average number of new households added each year,and the surplus of new units over added households. Some of the surpluses wereabsorbed by losses of existing housing, but a large fraction made net additions to theusable inventory, gradually overcoming the shortages that initially existed in 1950.

evidenced by the appearance of abandoned housing units inmany older parts of central cities after about 1965. Abandon-ment can usually occur only if even the most destitute house-holds have somewhere else to live. Thanks to this massivebuilding of new housing units, the initial overcrowded conditionsin these central cities were no longer necessary.5 So withinexisting central cities as well as in new suburbs, households ofall income groups spread out at much lower densities than in1950.

Thus, it was almost inevitable, and surely desirable, that most ofthese central cities experienced some declines in population from1950 to the mid-1960s. These declines were not necessarily amark of urban decay but resulted from the elimination of initialovercrowding and a shift to lower residential densities associatedwith higher household incomes, lower movement costs, greaterhousehold mobility, and massive new housing construction.

The impact of racial discrimination and segregation

The spatial arrangement of households within these metropoli-tan areas was decisively influenced by racial segregation anddiscrimination by whites against nonwhites, especially AfricanAmericans. Although many African-American households movedinto these metropolitan areas from 1950 to 1965, three factorsprevented them from occupying newly constructed housing onthe fringes.

5 This was not true in all large cities. New York City in particular did notexperience large-scale new rental housing construction within the city becauseof continued stringent rent controls. New York City also gained many low-income immigrants from abroad, whose arrival offset outflows of middle-classhouseholds to the surrounding suburbs, where the latter occupied the manynew suburban homes built in the 1950s and especially the 1960s and 1970s.

Page 15: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 373

One factor was the maintenance of high quality standards fornew housing by almost all legal jurisdictions. Such standardsprevented newly arrived poor households from constructing theirown inexpensive but low-quality housing—shacks—on vacantperipheral land, as occurred in migrations of poor people tourban areas in most of the rest of the world. In addition, manysuburban exclusionary laws prohibited manufactured housing,minimized the amount of land available for multifamily housing,and prohibited small detached single-family units. Consequently,most new housing was too costly for poor households to occupy.

The second factor was the almost universal prevalence of racialdiscrimination by white real estate agents, mortgage lenders,and homeowners against occupancy of housing in all-white areasby black households—with one exception. The exception wasblack occupancy in all-white neighborhoods immediately adjoin-ing enclaves already occupied mainly by blacks. The strongexpansion pressures of the overcrowded African-American popu-lations built up in racially restricted neighborhoods by 1950could not be resisted by owner-occupants or landlords in adjacentall-white blocks. Therefore, after racially restrictive covenantswere outlawed, most all-black areas rapidly expanded into ad-joining initially all-white neighborhoods through a process ofmassive racial transition (Massey and Denton 1993). No stableintegration resulted because many whites would not remain in,and most would not move into, neighborhoods occupied by morethan about one-third African Americans.6 Consequently, oncemany African Americans had moved into a mainly white area, allother whites refused to move in, and the normal process of about16 percent neighborhood turnover per year then involved onlyAfrican Americans moving in.7 That soon converted the entireneighborhood to almost wholly African-American occupancy.

Except in these neighborhoods adjacent to all-black areas, racialdiscrimination by whites prevented black households from enter-ing mainly white areas in any significant numbers. Those fewAfrican Americans who tried to move in found it hard to locateunits that were available to them or financing for those units.

6 A 1976 survey in Detroit showed that, once a neighborhood contained36 percent black residents, 57 percent of white survey respondents would feeluncomfortable living there, 41 percent would try to move out if they alreadylived there, and 73 percent would be unwilling to move in if they were notliving there (Massey and Denton 1993).

7 For discussions of this “automatic resegregation” process and the overallprocess of massive neighborhood racial transition, see Schelling (1971) andDowns (1981, chap. 7).

Page 16: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

374 Anthony Downs

And if they did move in, they were often threatened with vio-lence or greeted with such hostility that most soon departed.This behavior by the white population in effect eliminated anypossibility of relieving the expansion pressure of all-black inner-city neighborhoods by having additional African-Americanhouseholds move into the same new suburban housing develop-ments then being occupied by whites.

The third factor was a “natural” tendency of newly arrivingAfrican Americans to move into neighborhoods where they al-ready had relatives or friends, rather than into areas occupiedmainly by whites. This tendency has been observed throughoutthe world among new urban residents of all ethnic groups.

The resulting out-movement of middle-class whites

The process of massive neighborhood racial transition describedabove contributed to a huge movement of white middle-classhouseholds out of central cities. As the African-American popula-tions of these metropolitan areas continued to grow, throughboth natural increase and further in-migration, African Ameri-cans displaced whites in ever-larger parts of these central cities,and of many inner-ring suburbs. These displaced white house-holds were by no means all members of the middle class; manywere working class or poor. But they included many middle-classhouseholds, too. Some would have chosen to move to the suburbsfor reasons other than racial displacement, as discussed furtherbelow. There can be no doubt, however, that the rapid expansionof segregated African-American neighborhoods motivated manythousands of white households who had lived in those sameareas to move out of central cities.8

This process is clearly reflected in population data (figure 2).From 1960 to 1970, the African-American population of the52 cities that lost population in the 1980s soared by 623,600, or10 percent, whereas the nonblack population fell by 1.107

8 “Although whites were still highly resistant to racial integration in housing,withdrawal to the suburbs provided a more attractive alternative to thedefense of threatened neighborhoods and led to a prevalence of flight overfight among whites in racially changing areas. The combination of rapid whitesuburbanization and extensive black in-migration led to an unprecedentedincrease in the physical size of the ghetto during the 1950s and 1960s…. In afew short years, the population of vast areas of Chicago’s south and west sidesbecame virtually all black, as occurred on Cleveland’s east side, Philadelphia’snorth and west sides, and in most of central city Newark, Detroit, Baltimore,and Washington, D.C.” (Massey and Denton 1993, 45–46).

Page 17: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 375

Fig

ure

2. P

op

ula

tio

n C

ha

ng

es b

y R

aci

al

Gro

up

in

52

Dec

lin

ing

Cit

ies,

196

0 to

199

0

Wh

ite

loss

es g

reat

ly e

xcee

ded

blac

k ga

ins

in t

he

1960

s an

d19

70s;

bot

h g

rou

ps s

how

edlo

sses

in t

he

1980

s.

PO

PU

LA

TIO

N L

OS

SE

SP

OP

UL

AT

ION

GA

INS

–13,

960

1970

s

1980

s

–3–2

–1M

illi

ons

of P

erso

ns

Non

blac

ks

Bla

cks

Tota

l

01

1960

s

Page 18: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

376 Anthony Downs

million, or 6.7 percent.9 In the 1970s, the ethnic displacementprocess slowed down, but the loss of whites accelerated. TheAfrican-American population of all 52 cities rose by 486,900, or7.1 percent, whereas the nonblack population fell by 2.919million, or 19.1 percent—even though the Hispanic population ofthese cities, here included as part of the nonblack population,increased somewhat. In the 1980s, the black population of thesecities fell by 13,960, or 0.2 percent, whereas the nonblack popu-lation continued declining by 1.352 million, or 10.9 percent.10

The above population data lead to two clear conclusions.First, from 1950 to 1980, a major cause of the loss of whitemiddle-class households in these central cities was physicaldisplacement by the numerical and spatial expansion of theAfrican-American population. True, that displacement was alsomade possible by large-scale construction of suburban housingoccurring at the same time. But whites withdrew from cities intothe new suburban housing partly because racial segregation insuburbs prevented the rapidly growing black populations incentral cities from expanding into surrounding suburbs. Thus,the displacement of white households from central cities byblacks occurred under metropolitan housing market conditionsdominated by the racial discrimination and segregation practicesof whites.

The second conclusion is that the large-scale out-movement ofwhites from central cities was not caused solely by such racialdisplacement. This is shown by the fact that nonblack populationlosses in these central cities greatly exceeded African-Americanpopulation gains, often by a factor of two, three, or more (seefigure 2). Clearly, some forces other than the spatial expansionof the African-American population within these cities were alsocausing nonblacks—mostly non-Hispanic whites—to move to thesuburbs in large numbers.

9 Figure 2 includes data for 52 such cities; data for Metairie, LA, a suburb ofNew Orleans, are not available for earlier years, so this city has been excludedfrom these calculations. Some of the black population data are for the category“nonwhite,” as used by the Census Bureau in earlier years. The category“nonblack” includes other minority groups, such as Hispanics and Asians, so itis not equivalent to the non-Hispanic white population, but it is used here toillustrate a basic point, for which it is sufficiently accurate.

10 Data from tables on large-city population are from the U.S. Bureau of theCensus (various years [Statistical Abstract]).

Page 19: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 377

Nonracial causes of white outflows from these cities

Several alternative causes of such movements—not mutuallyexclusive—have been suggested by various observers, as follows(some were discussed earlier):

Mainly exogenous or technological factors

1. Rising real incomes among all groups of householdsfrom 1950 to 1973, and among middle- and upper-incomehouseholds after 1973, caused many households to move outof older homes and neighborhoods in central cities in orderto enjoy more spacious and modern dwellings and neighbor-hood designs in newly built suburbs.

2. Increased use of motor vehicles within cities with streetsbuilt in earlier eras intensified traffic congestion and ineffi-ciencies of movement. This led many business firms to moveto less congested suburban locations, where they could alsooperate on larger sites with more efficient one-floor layouts.Many employees of such firms then found it convenient tolive in the suburbs near their relocated jobs.

3. Improved highways linking central cities and outlyingsuburbs, heavily financed with federal funds, plus increasedownership and use of private automotive vehicles, made iteasier for households to live in the suburbs and remainemployed in central cities. It also became easier for manybusiness firms to relocate from high-density central-citylocations to lower-density suburban locations where theycould use more efficient physical layouts. (This cause waspartly a result of public policies, too.)

Results of public policies

1. The home-purchase financing arrangements offered, withfederal help, by savings and loans and banks to householdsmoving into the suburbs were superior to those available forhouseholds wishing to stay in the city and rehabilitate olderunits or build new ones there.

2. Hundreds of thousands of households and businesses weredisplaced from locations in central cities by federally fi-nanced urban renewal and highway construction programs.Many displaced persons and firms discovered that it was

Page 20: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

378 Anthony Downs

easier and more efficient to move to suburban locations—often along the same highways—than to remain in thecentral city.11

3. As large central cities struggled to cope with increasingdemands for public services, they often raised their propertytax rates above those found in surrounding suburbs lessburdened with significant fractions of poor households. Thisincreased the incentives for some households and businessfirms to move to suburbs with lower tax rates.

Social factors

1. As the percentages of minority-group households withincentral cities increased, the fractions of central-city publicschool enrollments composed of children from minority-group homes rose even faster, partly because of higher birthrates among major minority groups than among whites. Butonce many white households found their children attendingschools with more than 25 to 33 percent minority students—especially more than 50 percent—they decided to move tosuburbs where schools remained almost entirely populatedby white students. This movement was greatly acceleratedin cities where courts ordered widespread busing of studentsto achieve more racially balanced enrollments.

2. Rising crime rates within many parts of large central citiescreated an atmosphere of fear and uncertainty about thesafety and security of remaining residents of these cities.12

This atmosphere was—and still is—aggravated by constantemphasis in the mass media on lurid reports of violent localcrimes in daily newspapers and TV broadcasts and littlenote of the positive aspects of city life. Consequently, manyhouseholds moved to suburban locations to escape big-cityinsecurities.

11 For an analysis of the impact of urban renewal and highway clearance oncities, see the National Commission on Urban Problems (1969, chap. 6). Themagnitude of displacement can be judged partly from the following quotationfrom that report: “By the end of 1967, no less than 1.1 million dwelling unitsin the urban renewal areas of the country had been identified as needingeither demolition (760,000 units) or rehabilitation (350,000 units)…. 404,000[demolitions] … had already been carried out” (p. 160).

12 For data on crimes in cities, see Downs (1994) and DiIulio (1992). For ageneral discussion of the history of crime rates in cities, see Wilson andHerrnstein (1985).

Page 21: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 379

It is not possible here to evaluate how much each of these forcescontributed to large-scale withdrawal of the white populationfrom these cities, beyond that clearly associated with spatialdisplacement by black population expansion. However, all thesehypotheses can be incorporated into a broader explanation ofmetropolitan-area dynamics, explained below.

How the American metropolitan growth processsystematically redistributes viable households andfirms and taxable resources away from central cities

Some basic aspects of all metropolitan-area growth processes

Almost every U.S. metropolitan area has been founded on ariver, ocean, lake, or other transportation mode transfer pointand has expanded outward from that origin as its population hasgrown. This means that the central point at first contained thehighest concentration of economic activities and jobs. Moreover,transportation networks are initially constructed to converge onthat point of origin, making it more widely accessible than mostother points in the same metropolitan area.

The resulting established agglomeration of facilities in andaround the central business district initially creates monopolisticlocational advantages for that core. These advantages cannot befully duplicated at outlying locations, at least in the short run,because no one location has such an accessible site as theestablished core area, or such an agglomeration of facilities andactivities.

As a metropolitan area’s total population grows, its settledportions must expand outward from the center unless its averagepopulation density continuously rises. The density almost neverrises enough to preclude outward peripheral expansion. Whentransportation was costly and inefficient, the center maintainedhigh density because it was so hard to move to far-out locations.But the development of inexpensive automotive transportationchanged that situation radically.

In fact, all urban areas throughout the world expand outwardmore than upward because it is nearly always cheaper to buildon vacant land than to tear down existing structures and replacethem with higher-density structures. Since transportationhas steadily become more efficient over time, this inside-outexpansion has been further encouraged by technological change.

Page 22: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

380 Anthony Downs

Improved transportation and communications technologiesreduce the monopolistic cost advantage of locating close to thecore, thereby stimulating outward movement and peripheraldevelopment. Increasing central densities rather than growingoutward would also go against the historical tide of rising realincomes—which generate desires for more space per householdand therefore lower densities.13

As population continues to grow and the built-up area expands,outlying centers of jobs and retail activity grow up in addition tothe original downtown. This development is further encouragedby improved transportation and communications and by risingreal incomes.

Some crucial and nearly unique aspects of the Americanmetropolitan growth process

A crucial, nearly universal, but not inevitable aspect of Americanperipheral growth was the division of the edges of metropolitanareas into many small legal jurisdictions separate from theoriginal central city. That division resulted from political andlegal decisions made by state legislators, local citizens, and localpoliticians. Other governance arrangements concerning land usecould have been adopted—as in other developed nations—butwere not.

Fragmented government involved creation of legally separatesuburbs, instead of growth within a single legal jurisdiction—though the latter has happened in a few U.S. metropolitan areaswhere the central city can annex surrounding communities(Rusk 1993). The development of separate suburbs occurred forseveral reasons. Builders creating new peripheral subdivisionsoften wanted to control the rules governing their operations inways different from those prevailing in the dominant city. Resi-dents of areas lying outside the central city’s original boundariesoften wanted to distance themselves from the problems of the

13 Real incomes have historically risen over long periods in the United Statesfor nearly all social groups in all segments of the overall income distribution.However, this was not true throughout the period covered by this analysis—1950 to 1990. From 1950 to 1973, real household incomes rose rapidly fornearly all such groups, as noted later in the text. From 1973 to 1990, realhousehold incomes rose for the upper quintiles in the overall distribution butdeclined for the lower quintiles. This produced a very slow net increase for thedistribution as a whole. However, during the 1950s and 1960s, when some ofthe largest population movements affecting declining cities took place, realincomes were rising for nearly all groups. See Levy (1987, chap. 4).

Page 23: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 381

city by creating separate jurisdictions in which they could con-trol densities and tax rates. Local residents often wanted toestablish higher building, economic, and social standards thanthey thought were possible under the rules of the central city, sothey incorporated separately and adopted more stringent—andbetter-enforced—housing codes and rules.

Another key feature of American metropolitan growth concernsthe high quality standards required for new housing and otherconstruction, as noted earlier. In the United States, local regula-tions in peripheral communities—and even central ones—almostuniversally prevent the creation of new very low cost housingunits, such as the shacks built in barrios in less developed na-tions. The resulting high-quality new structures are inherentlymore modern and up-to-date than older ones, so they attracthouseholds and firms with relatively high incomes. Moreover,only households with incomes in the upper two-thirds of theincome distribution can afford to occupy such new dwelling unitswithout large public subsidies.

Maintaining high quality standards in new-growth areas has adual impact on the spatial distribution of households. First, itcauses a disproportionate concentration of affluent households innew-growth suburbs. Second, it leads to a disproportionateconcentration of poor households in the central city and olderinner-ring suburbs where deterioration and obsolescence havereduced the quality—and hence the costs—of older housing.

This situation also results in differential de facto housing qualitystandards within each metropolitan area. Inside much of thecentral city and other older parts of the core, standards of hous-ing quality are not maintained among existing units at the highlevel legally required for newly built units. Such a lowering ofstandards is necessary to push the actual cost of occupancy downto where low-income households can afford it. If housing codeswere stringently enforced at high quality levels, thousands ofhouseholds would be thrown out on the streets. Moreover, citybudgets for code enforcement have often been cut back so greatlythat strict enforcement could not be achieved even if it weredesired. And many cities did not—and do not—have enoughfunds for rehabilitating those deteriorated units that the citygovernment has taken over through tax delinquencies or aban-donment. In contrast, high quality standards are maintained forall new housing built, most of which is located at the suburbanperiphery. This de facto dual set of housing quality standards israrely recognized explicitly because it would seem undemocratic

Page 24: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

382 Anthony Downs

to admit that lower quality standards are maintained in poorerneighborhoods.

Thus, the disproportionate concentration of poor householdswithin central cities arises from the fundamental institutionalstructure of U.S. metropolitan areas and of their growth pro-cesses. This structure may seem to be natural or a result of free-market forces, but it is neither. In fact, other structures prevailin most of the world (Downs 1969). In very poor nations, the poorbuild their own brand-new units of very low quality and locatethem at all distances from the center, even on the new-growthperiphery. In many other developed nations, especially in West-ern Europe, national governments have subsidized much higherfractions of all new units, permitting poor households to live innew units also on the periphery. This has been true during muchof the post–World War II period in Sweden, France, West Ger-many, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom. So the Ameri-can pattern is unusual.

That pattern has come to be called “suburban sprawl,” and it hasdominated American metropolitan growth for the past 50 years.Sprawl is really a particular form of suburbanization with sev-eral characteristics that differentiate it from other conceivableforms of suburbanization:14

1. It has no limits on the outward expansion of additionalurban settlements.

2. It divides legal control over land uses, property taxes, andlocal services among many different bodies, each controllinga relatively small area, with no single body having anyresponsibility for the entire area.

3. It involves “leapfrog” settlements, in which some new sub-divisions are located far from the edges of already–built-upareas.

4. There is no centralized control or planning over how thearea develops.

5. Land ownership is relatively fragmented.

6. Different land uses are spatially segregated into separateneighborhoods.

14 This definition of suburban sprawl was taken largely from the remarks ofHenry Richmond at the conference “Alternatives to Sprawl” held at theBrookings Institution in May 1995 (see Richmond 1996).

Page 25: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 383

7. There is no unified or centralized allocation of public fiscalresources.

8. There is extensive strip commercial development alongmajor suburban arteries.

Why American metropolitan growth disproportionatelyconcentrates poverty in core areas

The dominant growth pattern of American metropolitan areassets in motion a major process of spatial resource reallocationthat drains fiscal and human resources from older core areasand weakens the ability of governments there to provide keyservices.15

As an American metropolitan area’s population grows larger, theabsolute number of low-income and poor households within itrises. This occurs because since 1969 the poor (as defined byfederal standards) have formed a relatively constant proportionof the nation’s total population, ranging from 11.4 to 15.2 per-cent in different parts of the general business cycle (U.S. Bureauof the Census 1996 [Statistical Abstract]). Yet the percentage ofall poor households in the metropolitan area that live in the corearea normally increases because of the concentration processdescribed above. In that case, the absolute number of poor house-holds in the core area must rise as the area grows. But the localgovernments serving the core area normally have fixed bound-aries. Moreover, the average population density usually declinesover time for reasons already discussed, plus local resistance tohigher densities. Therefore, increases in the absolute number ofpoor households living in the core usually result in a risingpercentage of poor households in the total population of that corearea.

From 1980 to 1990, this chain of events caused both absolutelyand relatively larger concentrations of very poor householdswithin the core areas of most large metropolitan areas. In 1990,there were about 10 million persons living in census tracts where40 percent or more of the total population was poor—twice asmany as lived in such tracts in 1980 (Jargowsky and Bane 1991;Kasarda 1993; Mincy and Wiener 1993). About 7.5 million ofthese people lived in central cities, where they constituted about10 percent of the total central-city population. However, they

15 This process was described and analyzed at length by Bradbury, Downs, andSmall (1982).

Page 26: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

384 Anthony Downs

were concentrated disproportionately in a small number ofvery large cities. New York, Chicago, Detroit, Los Angeles, andPhiladelphia combined contained 2.13 million persons living inextreme-poverty census tracts, or about 28 percent of all suchresidents of central cities in 1990, compared with 20.8 percent ofthe nation’s total central-city population.16

The problem of increasing concentrations of very poor house-holds within the core area is aggravated by the differentialability of various firms, households, and other resources to move.Financial capital, most jobs, economically viable firms, andnonpoor households are resources that can freely flow betweenthe core and outlying locations. Therefore, they seek the loca-tions most favorable to their welfare. These resources not onlygenerate economic activity where they are located, but also forma taxable base there. If they move to outlying areas, they bothcreate a large economic and taxable base in those areas andreduce the economic and taxable bases available to the govern-ments responsible for the core (Ladd 1993).

In contrast, poor households, capital sunk in physical structures,and government institutions cannot move freely in and out ofthe core because of (1) the immobility of existing physical capi-tal, (2) fragmented governance structures, and (3) exclusionaryzoning by governments outside the core. The first of these im-pediments is inherent; the second and third are nonmarketfactors created by deliberate public policies.

Negative consequences of the concentration of poverty withincore areas

The result of higher and higher concentrations of poverty withinthe core area is rising social and technical obsolescence in thatarea, compared with the newer settlements on the outer periph-ery. Social obsolescence includes poor-quality public schools,badly trained school graduates, and high crime rates and secu-rity costs. Another manifestation of social obsolescence is theincreasing ineffectiveness of various public bureaucracies sup-posedly created to help people cope with poverty, includingpublic schools, welfare systems, public housing agencies,police, city administrators, and health care systems. Thesebureaucracies are basically monopolies, so their members—like

16 Data on central-city extreme-poverty tract populations are from Kasarda(1993). Data on central-city populations for the entire nation were obtainedby the author by telephone in 1990 from Don Starsinik of the U.S. CensusBureau.

Page 27: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 385

all monopolists—come to focus on maintaining their own powersat the expense of the welfare of their clients. The behavior ofthese bureaucracies tends to reinforce the dependence of theirclients rather than liberate their clients’ capabilities (Kretzmannand McKnight 1993).17 Technical obsolescence includes con-gested streets, obsolete electrical wiring and communicationssystems, decaying and obsolete water and sewer systems, anddeteriorated structures poorly designed for rehabilitation intomodern status.

As a metropolitan area grows larger, its core area’s intrinsiclocational advantages become heavily—often completely—offsetby increasing costs from rising social and technical obsolescence.As a result, more and more financial capital, viable firms, andnonpoor households move out of the central core and into theouter periphery. They remove viable resources with them, leav-ing the core area with lower taxable resources and higher percapita service requirements (Pack 1994).

This process is aggravated by presumed or de facto desiresamong many white households for segregation from AfricanAmericans. Since the percentage of poor persons is much higheramong African Americans and Hispanics than among Asians ornon-Hispanic whites, the concentration of poverty describedabove is often accompanied by a concentration of minority-grouphouseholds in high-poverty areas. This accelerates the with-drawal of nonpoor white households into peripheral areas andincreases their desire to erect barriers against the entry ofminority-group households into their suburban communities.

The racial aspects of concentrated poverty are likely to becomemuch worse because of future changes in the American popula-tion. Between 1995 and 2020, the total U.S. population will riseby 60 million persons, of whom 47 million, or 79 percent, will beAfrican Americans, Hispanics, and Asians.18 The first two ofthese groups are now spatially concentrated in central cities andhave much higher fractions of poverty than either non-Hispanicwhites or Asians. Thus, future demographic changes will inten-sify the concentration of poverty within the core portions ofmetropolitan areas—and spread it outward from there—unlessthe nation succeeds in notably improving the average lot ofAfrican Americans and Hispanics. Such increased concentration

17 This view is based on the earlier work of Ivan Illich, such as Toward aHistory of Needs (Illich 1980).

18 These estimates are from the middle-series projections in Current Popula-tion Reports (U.S. Bureau of the Census various years).

Page 28: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

386 Anthony Downs

is likely even though greater numbers of nonpoor members ofthese minority groups have recently been moving from centralcities into suburbs.

The resulting self-aggravating downward spiral of core-areafiscal and social viability

The departure of many viable firms and nonpoor householdsfrom the core area creates a self-aggravating downward spiral infiscal, economic, and social strength there. The percentage ofnonviable firms and poor households rises, and the amount offinancial capital willing to invest there declines. Since poorhouseholds generate more costly needs for social services percapita than nonpoor households—including police, fire fighting,education, and other social services—this change in the composi-tion of the core-area population raises the per capita cost ofdelivering adequate services to that population (Pack 1994). Atthe same time, the departure of many financially viable firmsand households reduces the per capita tax base of the govern-ments serving the core area, thereby decreasing their ability topay for these increasingly costly social services.

In contrast, the movement of many nonpoor households andviable firms from the core area into the suburban peripheryincreases the overall economic viability of many communities onthat periphery, partly by raising their per capita tax bases inrelation to those of the core area. In essence, both financialcapital and human resources flow in a continuously acceleratingprocess from the core area, with its high costs and severe prob-lems, into the suburban periphery, with its lower costs andlesser problems.

This process of spatial resource reallocation creates anever-greater inequality of opportunities among residents ofconcentrated-poverty core areas and certain low-resource sub-urbs on the one hand and residents of high-resource suburbs onthe other. Thus, the growth process created by the structure ofAmerican metropolitan areas is fundamentally inequitable andunjust. It inherently reduces the welfare of many poor house-holds to benefit nonpoor ones.

Differential impacts on metropolitan suburbs

However, the results of this process are not uniformly beneficialto suburbs, because the process has several quite varied impacts

Page 29: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 387

on suburbs with different characteristics.19 Many older inner-ring suburbs find themselves experiencing the same self-aggravating downward spiral as the central city itself. Theschools in these suburbs become loaded with children from verypoor homes, local crime rates rise, many middle-income house-holds and viable businesses withdraw to farther-out suburbs,and the local governments concerned become fiscally strapped.Farther out, many low-commercial-tax-base suburbs with grow-ing populations also become fiscally strapped, but for a differentreason. Many young households with children are moving intothese communities, partly in flight from the core area. Educatingtheir children imposes high tax costs on these suburbs, but thesuburbs have very few commercial or industrial properties towhich to shift those tax burdens. Consequently, their residentialtax rates soar, and local citizens resist further improvements inschool quality or other public services (Orfield 1997).

In contrast to these fiscally strapped suburbs are the high-commercial-tax-base suburbs in economically favored quarters.Almost every metropolitan area has one suburban corridor orquarter currently capturing most new commercial and industrialactivity.20 This “favored quarter” is also usually the location ofthe highest-quality and highest-price executive homes. That factis by no means a coincidence, since the executives living thereusually determine where their firms will locate. In Atlanta, thisis the north-northeast quarter; in Minneapolis, the southeastquarter; in Chicago, the west-northwest quarter; and so on.These rapidly growing suburbs have such high commercial taxbases that they can raise spending on schools and other publicservices while limiting residential tax rates. They also tend tocapture disproportionate shares of overall metropolitan-areapublic spending on such items as roads, schools, and sewersystems.

19 This analysis of types of suburbs has been taken from the work of MyronOrfield, a member of the Minnesota State Legislature. His book Metropolitics(Orfield 1997) has just been published by the Brookings Institution and theLincoln Institute of Land Policy.

20 I am indebted to Christopher Leinberger of Robert Charles Lesser Associ-ates for the concept of the favored quarter (Leinberger 1995). This idea alsohas its roots in the work of Homer Hoyt (1939), an economist with the FederalHousing Administration during the 1930s. Hoyt found that high-incomehousing could radiate from the core in one wedge—often from the corner of thecentral business district that contained the financial services industry. Hoyt’stheory was based on the movement of high-rent districts in 142 Americancities in 1900, 1915, and 1936.

Page 30: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

388 Anthony Downs

The absence of incentives for key actors in this process tocounteract its negative results

Although the serious negative impacts of this process on societycan be perceived when the process is viewed as a whole, noimportant actors in either the public or private sector are moti-vated to react to these overall consequences. Each is faced withincentives that are based on its serving the welfare of only asmall, parochial part of the entire area. Therefore, it remains inthe interest of all groups that enjoy mobility to continue with-drawing from the core area, further weakening its viability.21

In fact, certain characteristics of sprawl aggravate this processmore than would occur with other forms of suburbanization.Unlike suburbanization within limited boundaries, as now prac-ticed in Oregon, sprawl encourages firms and households tomove far out from the core areas of the metropolitan region(Downs 1994, chap. 1; Richmond 1995). Because the new jobs areso far from inner-city areas that workers there neither hearabout such jobs nor would be able to travel to them if they heardabout them, inner-city unemployment worsens.

This separation also encourages residents of outlying suburbanareas to believe that their welfare is totally independent of thewelfare of inner-city neighborhoods and residents. Such a mis-conception makes many suburbanites unwilling to devote anytax resources to inner-city problems.22

Unlike peripheral growth within some type of overarching fiscalstructure, growth in sprawl totally separates the fiscal resourcesof the new suburban areas from those of the older core areas.The core areas then slowly decline in relation to the serviceneeds of the growing concentration of poor people there.

Unlike growth in the immediate vicinity of already–built-upareas, sprawl requires building more costly infrastructures—especially longer trunk lines—to service a given amount of popu-lation because new growth leapfrogs to sites far from existinginfrastructure services. The infrastructure costs raise the total

21 Myron Orfield has proposed a political coalition strategy discussed later inthis article that could be used to counteract some aspects of this outward flowprocess. However, such a strategy would have to be initiated by a politicalentrepreneur and would have uncertain prospects of success.

22 For a discussion of why suburbanites’ welfare is still closely linked to theability of central cities to perform their social functions, see Downs (1994,chap. 4).

Page 31: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 389

costs of providing urban living to a population, reducing re-sources for improving the lot of the poorest residents, most ofwhom remain in areas not served by this new infrastructure(Burchell et al. 1992).

Major obstacles within declining cities to reversingpast middle-class outflows

Mayors and other officials in declining American cities, and mostresidents thereof, would dearly love to reverse the systematicoutflows of viable resources described above. Within decliningcities themselves, however, four major obstacles to achieving thisgoal must be overcome before the overall processes of resourcewithdrawal can be effectively addressed. These obstacles arehigh rates of crime and insecurity, poor-quality public schools,white resistance to living in racially mixed neighborhoods, andineffective public bureaucracies.

High rates of crime and insecurity

Crime rates in concentrated-poverty neighborhoods are muchhigher than in middle- and upper-income neighborhoods. This istrue of both crimes reported to the police and crimes reported insurveys of neighborhood residents. And crime rates in primarilyAfrican-American neighborhoods are somewhat higher than inprimarily white neighborhoods, other things being equal (Jencks1991; Kelling 1993; see also Wilson and Herrnstein 1985). Thesefacts are widely known among middle-class households of allethnic groups. As a result, households seeking to escape fromcrime and personal insecurity—including many African-American households—move away from neighborhoods withconcentrated poverty as rapidly as possible (Rosenbaum 1991).

True, reported crime rates have recently fallen somewhat inmany large declining cities and risen in many nearby suburbs.Nevertheless, crime rates in big cities—especially in very poorneighborhoods—remain much higher than in most middle-income suburbs.23

23 It is not within the scope of this article to analyze in detail why crime rateshave fallen recently in some big cities. Possible causes include smaller agecohorts of city teenagers, more intensive community policing and other lawenforcement efforts, and the incarceration of larger numbers of criminals. Forone comprehensive view, see Kelling and Coles (1996).

Page 32: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

390 Anthony Downs

Fear of crime is also closely related to middle-class antipathy tobig-city public schools. Children attending those schools areoften physically threatened or bullied by their classmates orlocal gangs, and subject to being shot or stabbed at school or ontheir way to and from school. Fear of crime is also related towhite reluctance to live in racially mixed neighborhoods becausemany whites associate high crime rates with the presence oflarge numbers of black or Hispanic households.

Fear of crime is therefore probably the biggest obstacle to at-tracting middle-class households back into declining cities orretaining those that are there now. But fear of crime in cities isjust as powerful among minority-group households (Rosenbaum1991) and is a major reason why so many have moved out of thecities since 1980.

I do not know what effective steps can be undertaken to reducecrime. One possibility is deliberately deconcentrating poorhouseholds by enabling many of them to move to scattered dwell-ings in outlying suburban communities.24 That might reducecrime rates in big-city neighborhoods by decreasing the concen-tration of poverty there. But this “moving to opportunity” strat-egy is certain to encounter huge resistance from residents of theoutlying suburban communities. Moreover, such a strategywould require large-scale public subsidies to enable poor house-holds to occupy relatively costly suburban dwellings. In thepresent climate of federal funding cutbacks, that ingredientseems extremely unlikely.

Perhaps more community policing and other big-city strategiescould reduce crime in concentrated-poverty areas. Promisingprogress in reducing crime rates has recently been achieved inNew York City by focusing police efforts on maintaining publicorder, not just on arresting criminals (Kelling and Coles 1996).However, in at least some such areas, the proportion of localresidents who habitually use drugs reaches 20 to 35 percent,especially because of crack addiction. It seems extremely difficultto greatly reduce drug-related crimes where a significant propor-tion of the clientele for local drug dealers consists of local resi-dents themselves.25

24 For detailed discussion of this strategy, see Downs (1973). The basic argu-ments advanced in that book remain relevant in the 1990s. This strategy isalso the basis of the Gautreaux decision and the Moving to Opportunityprogram initiated by the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Developmentin 1993.

25 The estimate that as many as 20 to 35 percent of the residents of someconcentrated-poverty neighborhoods are habitual drug users comes from field

Page 33: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 391

Poor-quality public schools

In general, big-city public school systems provide much lowerquality educations for their students than suburban publicschool systems. This conclusion is supported by higher dropoutrates, lower test scores, lower college placement rates, andgreater social disorders in most big-city public school systems.This outcome does not result primarily from lower spending perpupil; some big-city school systems spend far more per pupilthan surrounding suburban school systems or city parochialsystems that produce much better results. There appear to bethree major causes for the poor performance of big-city publicschools.

The first is the concentration in these schools of students fromextremely poor and distressed households in which children arenot exposed to positive reinforcements for their education.26 Thisdrawback probably cannot be overcome without a major decon-centration of poverty in certain neighborhoods within decliningcities.

The second cause is existing regulations that require publicschools to “mainstream” children suffering from various distur-bances or handicaps (i.e., to place them in regular classes withnonhandicapped students) and prevent those schools from expel-ling disruptive students. Requiring the mainstreaming of a smallminority of students whose presence in classrooms disruptsthe education of the vast majority is a foolish and inefficientpractice unfair to the majority of students. If public schools areto compete effectively with each other and with private schools,they must be able to operate under rules conducive to goodeducational practices. That may require establishing specialschools for disruptive students and providing separate trainingfor severely handicapped students.

The third cause is that most big-city public schools are monopo-listic bureaucracies dominated by a combination of teachers’unions and school administrators (Chubb and Moe 1990). In alleras, monopolistic bureaucracies of all types become controlled

workers in a specific Baltimore neighborhood I visited in 1996. Over30 percent of the babies born to mothers living in that neighborhood wereaddicted at birth. The specific identity of the neighborhood is not revealedhere to avoid placing those field workers in an unfavorable light from theviewpoint of the local residents with whom they work every day.

26 For a discussion of the impact of concentrated poverty on big-city education,see Orfield (1985).

Page 34: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

392 Anthony Downs

by the interests of the bureaucrats themselves rather than theinterests of their clients. In nearly all other phases of life,Americans encourage competition as the most effective way toelicit maximum performance and maximum attention to theneeds and desires of clients and customers. A similar approachneeds to be taken in regard to big-city public schools. Describingexactly how that should be done—whether through charterschools, vouchers, competition with private schools, or othermeans—is not within the scope of this article.

The fact that good educations can be provided to poor minority-group children living in concentrated-poverty areas has beenproved by the superior performance of hundreds of Catholicparochial schools serving such areas in declining cities. More-over, those parochial schools operate with per-student spendingmuch lower than that of nearby, ineffective public schools. True,parochial schools elicit stronger parental support and participa-tion than most public schools, since parents must pay at leastsomething to enroll their children. And parochial schools canexercise disciplines and expulsions not possible under presentpublic school regulations. But parochial schools at leastdemonstrate that concentrated poverty need not lead to pooreducation.27

Changing the structure of most big-city public school systemswill not be easy because unionized teachers form a large andwell-organized voting bloc within every declining city. They cangenerate immense political pressure resisting any changes thatupset their present dominance. Teachers’ unions have almostuniversally opposed using vouchers (especially those applicablein private schools), adopting merit pay for teachers, or fundingcharter or other alternative schools with public money—alltactics that would increase competitive pressure on publicschools and their teachers to perform better. But without majorchanges in existing big-city school systems, the tremendousinequality of educational experiences that now handicaps mil-lions of children living in declining cities will continue to make amockery of the American value of equal educational opportunity.

27 Caroline Minter Hoxby (1996) calculated that making a $1,000 per-pupilvoucher available on a means-tested basis to all U.S. students and permittingthat voucher to be used in private schools—including parochial schools—wouldsubstantially improve the student achievement levels of both private schoolstudents and the remaining public school students by motivating publicschools to become more competitive with private schools (80 percent of whichare Catholic). This voucher would attract about 4 percent more students toprivate schools than go there now (raising their overall share from 10 percentto 14 percent) because private schools now deliver higher student achievementlevels than public schools, on average.

Page 35: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 393

White resistance to living in racially mixed neighborhoods

White resistance to living in racially mixed areas—and to send-ing children to predominantly minority schools—is a majorobstacle to attracting white middle-class families back intodeclining cities or retaining those now living there. Yet the vastmajority of middle-class households living in American suburbstoday are non-Hispanic whites. Research done in 1976 byReynolds Farley showed that most white households werewilling to live in neighborhoods with a significant fraction ofblacks or other minorities—but only if that fraction was wellbelow 50 percent. And only about one-fourth of white householdswould move into a neighborhood containing 33 percent blackhouseholds (Farley et al. 1978). Similar surveys conducted byFarley and William H. Frey in 1992 indicated that less than halfof the 636 households interviewed would “feel uncomfortable” ina neighborhood containing 33 percent African-American resi-dents. Nevertheless, only 41 percent were willing to move intosuch a neighborhood, and only 27 percent were willing to moveinto a neighborhood containing 60 percent African-Americanresidents (compared with only 16 percent of white respondents inthe 1976 survey) (Farley and Frey 1994).

Yet in the 53 declining cities combined, the overall proportion ofminority-group residents in 1990 was 50.2 percent, and theoverall proportion of African-American residents was 39.4 per-cent. Nineteen of these cities have predominantly minoritypopulations, and 13 have predominantly African-Americanpopulations. Even more important, the public school systems inthese cities are overwhelmingly attended by minority students.In the 23 of these cities for which 1990 data were available, theaverage proportion of minority students was 61.8 percent, and6 cities had more than 85 percent minority students (NationalCenter for Education Statistics 1992). Such dominance of publicschool enrollments by minority students is typical in most largeAmerican cities, not just those with declining populations.

It might appear to be a logical goal for any of these cities toattract white middle-class households back into the city, bothbecause there are so many more white middle-class householdsin the suburbs and because the arrival of such households mightcreate a more even ethnic balance within many of these cities. Ofcourse, few—if any—public officials would publicly avow such agoal, because they would immediately be accused of being racist.And even if city officials adopted such a goal implicitly, theywould have a hard time achieving it unless they focused on

Page 36: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

394 Anthony Downs

attracting white middle-class households into primarily whiteneighborhoods within their cities. Even in such neighborhoods,the dominance of public schools there by minority-group stu-dents might discourage white middle-class households withchildren from moving in.

This analysis implies three conclusions. First, white middle-classhouseholds are likely to move into, or remain in, declining citiesin significant numbers only if they can live in predominantlywhite neighborhoods. Most declining cities still have some sec-tions that are predominantly white. Second, the white middle-class households most likely to live in declining cities are thosewith no school-age children: “empty nesters,” elderly households,singles, gays, or young married households without children.28

Third, white middle-class households with school-age childrenare not likely to move into declining cities, even into primarilywhite neighborhoods, unless those neighborhoods are servedeither by relatively inexpensive private schools or by publicschools with ethnically balanced enrollments like those found insome so-called magnet schools.

From the viewpoint of declining cities and of American societygenerally, it would be desirable if white middle-class householdswere not prejudiced against moving into neighborhoods withsubstantial proportions of African-American or other minorityresidents and did not mind sending their children to predomi-nantly minority schools. But it would be highly unrealistic tosuppose that this is now the case. Nor do I know of any cogentmeans of changing existing white racial and ethnic attitudes onthese subjects. Therefore, this obstacle to attracting middle-classhouseholds into declining cities is likely to remain formidable.

Ineffective public bureaucracies

Big-city governments are run by individual agencies that inher-ently become bureaucratic because of their sheer size, their lackof competition, and the nonmarketable nature of many of theiroutputs (Downs 1967). As noted above concerning public schoolsystems, monopolistic bureaucracies almost inevitably shift theirbehavior to best serve those who run them rather than theirclients or customers. That helps explain such anomalies aspublic housing authorities keeping thousands of units vacantdespite long waiting lists of applicants, or public schools that can

28 Note that two other articles in this issue of Housing Policy Debate, Lang,Hughes, and Danielsen (1997) and Moss (1997), reach this same conclusion.

Page 37: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 395

be opened only when determined by members of their janitors’union—regardless of what their principals want. City govern-ments are notorious for imposing complex rules and regulationson businesses that want to expand or locate within the city, oftenmotivating those businesses to move elsewhere. City buildingcodes often require obsolete technical ingredients or processes toprotect the jobs of plasterers, plumbers, or other tradespeoplewhose unions exercise powerful political influence (AdvisoryCommission on Regulatory Barriers to Affordable Housing 1991,chap. 3).

Several tactics could increase the effectiveness of many suchagencies. One is privatizing some or all of their functions, or atleast introducing some competition from the private sector forportions of their activities. Another is leadership from the mayoror city council designed to review and reform existing proceduresfrom the viewpoints of the clients or customers, such as busi-nesses considering expansion or relocation. A third is pressurefrom organized business interests within the city who want tohelp maintain the city’s tax base so that their taxes do not riseas other firms move out.

There is no simple or permanent remedy for ineffective perfor-mance by city bureaucracies. But progress can surely be madethrough vigorous leadership and sustained pressure from privateinterests within the city. Therefore, this obstacle is more suscep-tible to improvement than the other three.29

Conclusions

Prospects for overcoming three of these four obstacles to attract-ing more middle-class households into declining cities seembleak. Therefore, declining cities cannot realistically count onany significant near-future increases in their middle-class popu-lations (of any ethnic group) as major means of improving theirsituations. Even retaining the middle-class households thatalready live there will be difficult. It will require an all-out as-sault on crime, a major reform of the cities’ public school sys-tems, and continuous pressure on other municipal bureaucracies

29 An innovative public-private partnership in Washington, DC recentlyresulted in establishment of the George Washington University Center forExcellence in Municipal Management, which will help develop the leadershipcapacity and management skills of the District of Columbia governmentworkforce. The DC business community has provided private funding for theCenter and is an equal partner in the effort with the university and theDistrict government.

Page 38: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

396 Anthony Downs

to improve their services to their true clients and customers.Whether the elected officials in these cities have the energy, theguts, the willpower, and the persistence to undertake thesepolicy initiatives with diminishing fiscal resources remainsto be seen.

How could the systematic outflow of viable resourcesfrom declining cities be stopped, counteracted, orslowed?

What strategies might be adopted to alter this dynamic processor at least ameliorate its results? There are at least three funda-mental approaches: major structural change, reform of big-citygovernment behavior, and community development.

Major structural change

This approach involves trying to alter the basic structure of thegrowth process in American metropolitan areas. In its full-blownform, the structural changes it pursues include the following:

1. Counteracting the fragmentation of governmental controlover land uses. The most logical way to do this would be byadopting a single metropolitan-area-wide government thatreplaced all existing local governments.30 However, thattactic has no political support from either suburban or cityresidents or officials; hence it will never happen in mostmetropolitan areas. A more feasible approach is having thestate government require all existing local governments toprepare comprehensive land use plans using a standardizedplanning process that pursues common goals set by thestate. Then the state creates an overarching body to coordi-nate these individual plans—a body that has substantialpowers to pressure local governments into revising theirplans. This body can be regionwide (as in the Twin Citiesarea of Minnesota) or statewide (as in Oregon). Theimportance of this body is enhanced further if it also hasoperational control over all regional sewer, water, andtransportation systems (as in the Twin Cities and Portland).

30 Unified metropolitan government is the solution suggested by David Rusk(1993). However, I believe this arrangement does not have enough politicalsupport to be adopted in many more American metropolitan areas than thefew that have already adopted it, for reasons stated in the text.

Page 39: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 397

2. Creating some method for all cities in a metropolitan area toshare in all the taxable resources therein. To counteract thelosses of central-city and inner-ring suburban taxable re-sources that arise from the constant out-movement of firmsand households, there must be some mechanism for all citiesto tap into all taxable resources, no matter where they arelocated within the region. The most comprehensive existingexample is the property-tax-base-sharing scheme employedin the Twin Cities area of Minnesota. But even that schemeinvolves only further increases in commercial real estateproperties. A broader scheme would place at least someportion of real estate assessed values and sales taxes into apool to be shared among all communities by some basicformula related to population, poverty levels, or otherfactors.

3. Placing limits on the outward spatial expansion of newdevelopment. To keep new job growth within a reasonablecommuting distance from inner-city neighborhoods, and tolimit excessive costs of creating trunk lines to far-out subdi-visions, a metropolitan region could adopt an “urban growthboundary” within which most, or all, future developmentwithin a planning period must be located. This tactic alsohas the advantage of reducing the rate at which peripheralopen space is swallowed up by further urban development—a goal that probably has widespread suburban support.Urban growth boundaries have been used most cogently inOregon. However, this tactic also requires preventing newurban developments from arising immediately outside themetropolitan area by adopting statewide bans on new ruraldevelopment except at very low densities.31

4. Requiring all suburbs to zone a certain proportion of theirdevelopable land for affordable housing—including multi-family units—and creating incentives and penalties de-signed to encourage those communities to remove otherregulatory barriers to such housing.32

5. Developing means of helping low-income householdsfrom inner-city neighborhoods move into housing in

31 The Oregon experience is evaluated by Knaap and Nelson (1992). Also seeLang and Hornburg (1997) and Abbott (1997) for a discussion of the politicsbehind the urban growth boundary in Portland, OR.

32 An earlier analysis of inclusionary zoning that is still relevant is that byMallach (1984). For an update and comparison on inclusionary housing inCalifornia and New Jersey, see Calavita, Grimes, and Mallach (1997).

Page 40: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

398 Anthony Downs

middle-income suburban communities they otherwise couldnot afford. This could be done by converting public housingassistance into portable vouchers, using existing federalhousing vouchers, requiring inclusionary zoning for a cer-tain number of affordable units in every new suburbansubdivision, or creating special state taxes, such as a realestate transfer tax with receipts devoted to subsidizing suchhousing. This tactic has been successfully demonstrated inthe Chicago area for 20 years in the Gautreaux decisionprocess, though only at a relatively small scale per year.33

6. Creating private, nonprofit regionwide organizations to helpenforce existing laws against racial discrimination in hous-ing and lending markets. These organizations can usetesters and bring lawsuits against real estate agents, lend-ers, and homeowners who engage in illegal discrimination.They can also help minority home seekers find financing forhome purchases.

7. Creating private, nonprofit job information and placementcenters located in or near inner-city areas with high unem-ployment rates, but also closely linked to major suburbanfirms. Such centers could provide information about avail-able jobs to inner-city residents and screen potential appli-cants for suburban employers.

8. Providing subsidized transportation for inner-city workersemployed in suburban jobs to assist them in reaching jobs atscattered or far-out locations.34

9. Continuing and expanding so-called enterprise or empower-ment zones within distressed portions of central cities andinner-ring suburbs. Tax incentives and other aids would beprovided to firms that located in these zones and furnishednew jobs to residents thereof.

One look at these elements indicates how radically their com-bined adoption would change the existing metropolitan growthprocess. A crucial part of such change would be creating institu-tions responsible for the operation of the metropolitan area as a

33 For an evaluation of the Gautreaux project, see Rosenbaum (1991).

34 Hughes and Sternberg (1992) link such transportation subsidies to the jobplacement centers described in the preceding point, as well as to the provisionof day-care centers in inner-city neighborhoods for mothers who work outsidetheir homes.

Page 41: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 399

whole, not just for the prosperity of one small part. The basicidea is not to eliminate local governments, but to place themwithin some broader framework with two key traits: (1) desig-nating certain persons as responsible for the combined outcomesof all local government decisions in the metropolitan area and(2) equipping those persons with sufficient power and authorityto achieve effective results.

Unfortunately, even such radical reforms would not necessarilyeliminate the four major obstacles to returning the middle classto the declining cities discussed above. Hence, these structuralreforms can be regarded as necessary but not sufficient remediesto the problems of declining cities.

The structural change approach is popular with intellectualsbecause they regard revising the underlying structure as essen-tial to reversing its results. I have advocated this approachmyself in New Visions for Metropolitan America (Downs 1994).But it is unpopular with most metropolitan citizens because theybenefit notably from the current structure. That is also true ofnearly all existing politicians, city and suburban. So this ap-proach is mostly untried and has had little impact on the realworld.

Modified version of structural change

Myron Orfield (1997) has both proposed and helped achieve amodified version of the structural change approach in the TwinCities metropolitan area in Minnesota. He believes that thesame approach could be followed in other major metropolitanareas with declining central cities. He advocates forming apolitical coalition in the state legislature among representativesof three areas: the declining central city, inner-ring suburbs alsoexperiencing decline, and outer-ring suburbs with very lowcommercial property tax bases and high populations of school-age children.

If representatives of these three areas form a majority in thestate’s legislature, they could pass state laws creating a tax-base-sharing plan for all communities within the entire metro-politan area. The plan would place some portion of all futureincreases in commercial and industrial assessed property valuesinto a pool to be shared by all communities within the metropoli-tan area by means of a standard formula. Most commercial andindustrial properties are concentrated in a single corridor or

Page 42: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

400 Anthony Downs

quarter within each metropolitan area, so communities in therest of the area do not now benefit much from the area’s eco-nomic and population growth, insofar as their tax bases areconcerned. Under this arrangement, they would share in at leastsome of the fiscal growth of the favored quarter.

Traditional local fiscal arrangements involve fragmentation oftaxable property resources among communities solely in accor-dance with where those properties are located. Orfield has shownthat tax-base sharing could produce a much more equitabledistribution of fiscal resources among metropolitan-area commu-nities than the present system. It is also fairer, because thecommercial and industrial facilities now concentrated in thefavored quarter are usually patronized or staffed by many per-sons living in other communities, which must bear the publiccosts of housing those persons (such as school costs) withoutbenefiting from the taxes generated by the shopping or jobs thosepersons support. Of course, those communities in the favoredquarter vehemently oppose this strategy, since it forces them toshare the added assessed values they gain from growth. But theycan be outvoted in the state legislature by representatives ofcommunities that would be net gainers from tax-base sharing.

For such a coalition to be formed, however, some political entre-preneur must first marshal enough statistical evidence to con-vince representatives of the potentially gaining communities tostop regarding each other as enemies and start working to-gether. That is an especially difficult transition for representa-tives from the central city and those from the suburbs, who nowregard themselves as having very few common interests. Oncesuch a political coalition has been formed and has successfullypassed tax-base sharing of the type described above, it could alsoinitiate other elements of the metropolitanwide structuralchange strategy described earlier.

Orfield’s proposed strategy has the huge political advantage ofchanging the support base for structural reform from a minorityof citizens and politicians within a metropolitan area—those inthe central city and especially in inner-city distressed areas—into a majority by bringing in those in suburbs suffering fromfiscal difficulties. He has conducted statistical analyses of condi-tions in several large metropolitan areas proving that communi-ties containing a majority of both residents and state legislatorswould benefit from this approach; hence, it is not just applicablein Minnesota.

Page 43: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 401

Reform of big-city government behavior

A second basic approach is ignoring the regional nature of theproblem and focusing on dismantling or radically reforming thepublic bureaucracies within declining cities. This strategy isadvocated by the Cato Institute and other proponents of slashingbig-city tax rates and local government payrolls.35 There isundoubtedly merit in this approach because most big cities docontain dysfunctional bureaucracies that need reform or replace-ment, as noted earlier. Their behavior often constitutes a seriousobstacle to the attraction or retention of viable business in de-clining cities.

However, the main political advantage of this approach is that itdoes not upset the nonpoor majority—mostly suburban resi-dents—who believe they benefit from the present structure ofregional inequalities, since this remedy costs them nothing. Itdoes not require them to pay higher taxes to help big-city govern-ments or to accept more low-income neighbors or to make anyother apparent sacrifices. Therefore, this city government reformstrategy readily gains their political approval. That is one reasonmany conservatives in particular advocate this strategy as analternative to what they view as costly and most likely ineffec-tive government spending programs—to which they would haveto contribute.

This approach has three weaknesses. It does little to offset thesocial and technical obsolescence of central-city and inner-suburban neighborhoods. Also, it does not stop the outflow ofresources into the surrounding periphery. Finally, it does notreduce the gross inequalities of public sector resources emanat-ing from the growth process.

Community development

A third approach stresses the resources intrinsic to concentrated-poverty areas, such as their central locations, the untapped ener-gies and talents of their residents, and the possible collectiveresults of community efforts. This is the approach of the commu-nity development movement. The most recent version is set forth inthe handbook Building Communities from the Inside Out by JohnP. Kretzmann and John L. McKnight of Northwestern University

35 This viewpoint is advanced by Moore and Stansel (1993). However, thestatistical analysis underlying their conclusions is seriously flawed, as pointedout in detail by Downs (1994, app. B).

Page 44: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

402 Anthony Downs

(Kretzmann and McKnight 1993). They advocate emphasizing thepositive characteristics of each community and its individual andgroup residents rather than emphasizing problems and needs.However, other advocates of the community development ap-proach call for significant additional public expenditures in low-income neighborhoods financed by the federal governmentinstead of just relying on self-help or “bootstrap” improvements.

The self-help-oriented community development approach alsohas the political advantage of not upsetting the majority ofmetropolitan-area residents, since it does not require them tocontribute much, if anything, of their own resources to helpingsolve core-area problems. Perhaps there are some locationaladvantages of inner-city sites for which purely profit-orientedbusiness firms may find it worthwhile to endure the insecuritiesand other disadvantages of such sites. This is the contention thatProfessor Michael Porter of the Harvard Business School iscurrently advancing (Porter 1997). However, the version of thecommunity development approach based on major additionalpublic spending in core areas would require contributions fromsuburbanites and others because such spending would have to befinanced by higher taxes on people living elsewhere.

Like the preceding strategy, this approach has the weakness of notoffsetting the outflow of resources from the core. It also downplaysthe destructive behavior of many residents in concentrated-povertyareas, such as male sexual hostility toward women, evasion of theresponsibilities of parenthood, and disregard of personal andproperty rights. Furthermore, experience shows that effectivecommunity development rarely occurs without at least some helpfrom outside catalysts, such as the Enterprise Foundation, oroutside resource contributors, such as the Local InitiativesSupport Corporation. Moreover, this approach has great diffi-culty in reaching a sufficient scale to affect conditions in morethan one or a few distressed neighborhoods within a city. And itspractitioners—in spite of heroic and time-consuming efforts—canrarely pull together enough economic resources to affect allaspects of life even in those few neighborhoods, in contrast tofocusing on housing alone, schools alone, or some other singleaspect.

The need for multiple remedies undertaken simultaneously

The extremely brief summaries and critiques of the threemajor approaches set forth above hardly do justice to either theintentions or the reasonable expectations of their advocates.

Page 45: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 403

Moreover, the presentation is admittedly biased in favor of thestructural change approach that I happen to favor. However,more detailed consideration of the advantages and drawbacks ofthese approaches is not within the scope of this article.

In reality, none of these approaches can work alone. All three areprobably necessary to make real progress in improving life inconcentrated-poverty areas. The process of decline cannot bereversed if outlying areas can freely drain resources from thecore without sharing their tax bases. Core cities cannot workwell if dysfunctional public bureaucracies are not dismantled orreformed. And community development cannot work well with-out some outside economic resources from the periphery to aidlocal residents in poor areas.

Which approach, if any, is most likely to be adopted?

Unfortunately, the vested interests of the majority ofmetropolitan-area residents, and of nearly all public officials,would be upset by such a combined strategy because it wouldreduce their ability to gain benefits from the present institu-tional structure and growth process.

Even adopting the structural change approach alone would upsetthe politically dominant majority. It would require members ofthat majority to contribute resources to attack inner-city prob-lems, and it would rearrange the power structure in each metro-politan area. Moreover, if the structural change approach wereto be carried out to its fullest extent, it would require significantfederal funding of affordable housing subsidies and major aid toinner-city neighborhoods. But the likelihood of such federalassistance seems remote in this era of federal budget cuts andthe devolution of federal policy making to state and local govern-ments. Thus, the structural change approach appears very un-likely to be tried soon in any significant number of metropolitanareas containing declining cities.

This pessimistic conclusion need not apply to the version ofthe structural change approach advocated by Myron Orfield,however. In those metropolitan areas where representatives inthe state legislature from the central city, fiscally distressedinner-ring suburbs, and fiscally distressed outer-ring suburbscombined form a majority of all legislators, a coalition couldbe formed to adopt tax-base sharing and other regional

Page 46: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

404 Anthony Downs

arrangements—assuming the governor does not veto such laws.36

The biggest difficulty with this approach is that it requires astrong, well-informed, persuasive, and incredibly persistentpolitical entrepreneur to overcome the entrenched hostilitybetween central-city and suburban legislators in most states.

Adopting only the approach of reforming big-city public bureau-cracies would upset most of the incumbent officials who controland manage those entrenched institutions. True, they are only asmall part of each city electorate. But they wield disproportion-ate political power because of their control of these institutionsand the benefits these institutions can confer on others, theirhigh degree of organization, and the intensity of their interest incity policies relative to the apathy of most big-city citizens.Political competition against incumbent officials from conserva-tive mayoral candidates might nevertheless generate this ap-proach in a few declining cities, as it has in Jersey City, NJ. Butthat is not likely to happen on a large scale.

That leaves the community development approach as the mostlikely to occur, because it would arouse the least opposition frompowerful vested interests. But the community developmentapproach itself usually requires initial catalysts and seed moneyfrom outside the neighborhoods involved. Also, it can reach onlya very limited scale and comprehensiveness within any one city.These limitations make it a weak instrument even for improvingconditions within concentrated-poverty neighborhoods. And itdoes almost nothing to stop the long-range outflow of resourcesfrom declining cities generated by the American metropolitan-area growth process.

Conclusions

In modern democracies, the majority of citizens and public offi-cials are willing to sacrifice their own immediate advantagesonly if they believe that some crisis threatens the continuation ofthose advantages. The decline of cities and inner suburbs wherepoverty is concentrated has not yet created a sufficiently visibleor severe crisis to stimulate residents of outer-ring suburbs totake effective action. It appears that only after our society has

36 The governor of Minnesota has twice vetoed changes in the Twin Cities tax-base-sharing program passed by the state legislature that would increase thepercentage of new commercial and industrial assessed values from eachcommunity put into the pool and shared throughout the metropolitan area orotherwise strengthen the ability of the entire process to equalize fiscal re-sources throughout the area.

Page 47: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 405

moved much farther toward even higher fractions of poorlyeducated, untrained, unskilled, and often dangerous low-incomeresidents will the sense of crisis become really acute. That mightcreate majority political support for an approach to counteract-ing urban decline that would actually work. The only other waysupport could be generated would be through the formation of amajority political coalition in certain state legislatures withjurisdiction over entire metropolitan areas. Meanwhile, it iswishful thinking to believe middle-class households of any ethnicgroups now residing in suburbs will return to declining cities inlarge numbers. Hence their resources will not offset continuationof the systematic outflow of resources from those cities alreadybuilt into the metropolitan-area growth process.

Author

Anthony Downs is a Senior Fellow in Economic Studies at The BrookingsInstitution.

The views stated in this article are solely those of the author and not necessar-ily those of The Brookings Institution, its trustees, or other staff members.

References

Abbott, Carl. 1997. The Portland Region: Where City and Suburbs Talk toEach Other—and Often Agree. Housing Policy Debate 8(1):11–51.

Advisory Commission on Regulatory Barriers to Affordable Housing. 1991.“Not in My Back Yard”: Removing Barriers to Affordable Housing.Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development.

Bradbury, Katharine L., Anthony Downs, and Kenneth Small. 1982. UrbanDecline and the Future of American Cities. Washington, DC: BrookingsInstitution.

Burchell, Robert W., et al. 1992. Impact Assessment of the New Jersey InterimState Development and Redevelopment Plan, Report II: Research Findings.New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University, Center for Urban Policy Research.

Calavita, Nico, Kenneth Grimes, and Alan Mallach. 1997. Inclusionary Hous-ing in California and New Jersey: A Comparative Analysis. Housing PolicyDebate 8(1):109–42.

Chubb, John E., and Terry M. Moe. 1990. Politics, Markets, and America’sSchools. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

DiIulio, John D., Jr. 1992. Crime. In Setting National Priorities: What CanGovernment Do? ed. Henry J. Aaron and Charles L. Schultze, 101–5.Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Page 48: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

406 Anthony Downs

Downs, Anthony. 1967. Inside Bureaucracy. Boston: Little, Brown.

Downs, Anthony. 1969. Housing the Urban Poor: The Economics of VariousStrategies. American Economic Review 56(4):646–51.

Downs, Anthony. 1973. Opening Up the Suburbs: An Urban Strategy forAmerica. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

Downs, Anthony. 1981. Neighborhoods and Urban Development. Washington,DC: Brookings Institution.

Downs, Anthony. 1994. New Visions for Metropolitan America. Washington,DC: Brookings Institution and Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Farley, Reynolds, and Walter R. Allen. 1987. The Color Line and the Quality ofLife in America. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Farley, Reynolds, and William H. Frey. 1994. Changes in the Segregation ofWhites from Blacks during the 1980s: Small Steps toward a More IntegratedSociety. American Sociological Review 59(1):23–45.

Farley, Reynolds, Howard Schuman, Suzanne Bianchi, Diane Colasanto, andShirley Hatchett. 1978. “Chocolate City, Vanilla Suburbs”: Will the Trendtoward Racially Separate Communities Continue? Social Science Research7:319–44.

Hoxby, Caroline Minter. 1996. The Effects of Private School Vouchers. InHolding Schools Accountable: Performance-Based Reform in Education, ed.Helen F. Ladd, 177–208. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Hoyt, Homer. 1939. The Structure and Growth of Residential Neighborhoods inAmerican Cities. Washington, DC: Federal Housing Administration, U.S.Government Printing Office.

Hughes, Mark Alan, and Julie E. Sternberg. 1992. The New MetropolitanReality: Where the Rubber Meets the Road in Antipoverty Policy. Washington,DC: Urban Institute.

Illich, Ivan. 1980. Toward a History of Needs. New York: Bantam.

Jargowsky, Paul A., and Mary Jo Bane. 1991. Ghetto Poverty in the UnitedStates: 1970–1980. In The Urban Underclass, ed. Christopher Jencks and PaulA. Peterson, 251–70. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Jencks, Christopher. 1991. Is the American Underclass Growing? In TheUrban Underclass, ed. Christopher Jencks and Paul A. Peterson, 28–100.Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Jencks, Christopher, and Paul E. Peterson, eds. 1991. The Urban Underclass.Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.

Kasarda, John D. 1993. Inner-City Concentrated Poverty and NeighborhoodDistress: 1970 to 1990. Housing Policy Debate 4(3):253–302.

Kelling, George. 1993. Measuring What Matters: A New Way of Thinkingabout Crime and Public Order. City Journal 2(2):21–33.

Page 49: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 407

Kelling, George, and Catherine M. Coles. 1996. Fixing Broken Windows. NewYork: Free Press.

Knaap, Gerrit, and Arthur C. Nelson. 1992. The Regulated Landscape: Lessonson State Land Use Planning from Oregon. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute ofLand Policy.

Kretzmann, John P., and John L. McKnight. 1993. Building Communities fromthe Inside Out. Chicago: Acta.

Lang, Robert E., and Steven P. Hornburg. 1997. Planning Portland Style:Pitfalls and Possibilities. Housing Policy Debate 8(1):1–10.

Lang, Robert E., James W. Hughes, and Karen A. Danielsen. 1997. Targetingthe Suburban Urbanites: Marketing Central-City Housing. Housing PolicyDebate 8(2):437–70.

Ladd, Helen F. 1993. Fiscal Consequences for U.S. Central Cities of theChanging Urban Form. In Urban Change in the United States and WesternEurope, ed. Anita A. Summers, Paul C. Cheshire, and Lanfranco Senn, 327–70.Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press.

Leinberger, Christopher B. 1995. The Changing Location of Development andInvestment Opportunities. Urban Land 54(5):31–36.

Levy, Frank. 1987. Dollars and Dreams: The Changing American IncomeDistribution. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Mallach, Alan. 1984. Inclusionary Housing Programs: Policies and Practices.New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University, Center for Urban Policy Research.

Massey, Douglas S., and Nancy A. Denton. 1993. American Apartheid: Segre-gation and the Making of the Underclass. Cambridge, MA: Harvard UniversityPress.

Mincy, Ronald B., and Susan J. Wiener. 1993. The Underclass in the 1980s:Changing Concept, Constant Reality. Washington, DC: Urban Institute.

Moore, Stephen, and Dean Stansel. 1993. The Myth of America’s UnderfundedCities. Policy Analysis No. 188. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.

Moss, Mitchell. 1997. Reinventing the Central City as a Place to Live andWork. Housing Policy Debate 8(2):471–90.

Motor Vehicle Manufacturers Association. 1991. Motor Vehicle Facts andFigures ’90. Detroit.

National Center for Education Statistics. 1992. Digest of Educational Statis-tics 1992. NCES 92-097. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Education.

National Commission on Urban Problems. 1969. Building the American City:The Report of the National Commission on Urban Problems. New York:Praeger.

Orfield, Gary. 1985. Ghettoization and Its Consequences. In The New UrbanReality, ed. Paul E. Peterson, 174–76. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Page 50: The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities€¦ · The Challenge of Our Declining Big Cities 361 middle-class standards. Therefore, many poor households must live in what are considered

408 Anthony Downs

Orfield, Myron. 1997. Metropolitics. Washington, DC: Brookings Institutionand Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Pack, Janet Rothenberg. 1994. The Impacts of Concentrated Urban Poverty onCity Government Expenditures. Impact paper. University of Pennsylvania,Wharton School Real Estate Center.

Porter, Michael. 1997. New Strategies for Inner-City Economic Development.Economic Development Quarterly 11(1):11–27.

Richmond, Henry R. 1995. Regionalism: Chicago as an American Region.Portland, OR: MacArthur Foundation.

Richmond, Henry. 1996. Remarks. In Alternatives to Sprawl, ed. DwightYoung. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

Rosenbaum, James E. 1991. Black Pioneers: Do Their Moves to the SuburbsIncrease Economic Opportunity for Mothers and Children? Housing PolicyDebate 2(4):1179–213.

Rusk, David. 1993. Cities without Suburbs. Washington, DC: Woodrow WilsonCenter Press.

Schelling, Thomas C. 1971. Dynamic Models of Segregation. Journal ofMathematical Sociology 1:143–86.

U.S. Bureau of the Census. Various years. Current Population Reports.P-25-1104. Washington, DC.

U.S. Bureau of the Census. Various years. Statistical Abstract of the UnitedStates. Washington, DC.

Wilson, James Q., and Richard J. Herrnstein. 1985. Crime and Human Nature.New York: Simon and Schuster.

Wilson, William Julius. 1987. The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, theUnderclass, and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.