The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

34
The case for non-discrimination in the international protection of intellectual property Difei Geng y and Kamal Saggi z Department of Economics Vanderbilt University First draft: February 2013 This version: July 2014 Abstract We evaluate the case for non-discrimination in the international protection of intellectual property. If trade is not subject to any frictions then requiring national treatment (NT) in patent protection does not have any consequences for innovation (and welfare) since unfavorable discrimination abroad is fully o/set by favorable discrimination at home. In the presence of trade frictions, however, such international o/setting in patent protection is incomplete and innovation incentives are actually lower under NT. For helpful comments and discussions, we thank seminar audiences at the following venues: Fifth Annual Conference of the International Economics and Finance Society of China (Shanghai; June 2013), Fall DISETTLE Workshop at ECARES, UniversitØ Libre de Bruxelles (Brussels; September 2013), Fall Midwest International Economics Meetings at the University of Michigan (Ann Arbor; October 2013), InsTED Conference at the University of Exeter Business School (Exeter; May 2013), and the University of International Business and Economics (Beijing; June 2013). y E-mail: [email protected]. z E-mail: [email protected]. 1

Transcript of The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Page 1: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

The case for non-discrimination in the internationalprotection of intellectual property�

Difei Gengy and Kamal Saggiz

Department of EconomicsVanderbilt University

First draft: February 2013This version: July 2014

Abstract

We evaluate the case for non-discrimination in the international protectionof intellectual property. If trade is not subject to any frictions then requiringnational treatment (NT) in patent protection does not have any consequences forinnovation (and welfare) since unfavorable discrimination abroad is fully o¤setby favorable discrimination at home. In the presence of trade frictions, however,such international o¤setting in patent protection is incomplete and innovationincentives are actually lower under NT.

�For helpful comments and discussions, we thank seminar audiences at the following venues: FifthAnnual Conference of the International Economics and Finance Society of China (Shanghai; June 2013),Fall DISETTLE Workshop at ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles (Brussels; September 2013), FallMidwest International Economics Meetings at the University of Michigan (Ann Arbor; October 2013),InsTED Conference at the University of Exeter Business School (Exeter; May 2013), and the Universityof International Business and Economics (Beijing; June 2013).

yE-mail: [email protected]: [email protected].

1

Page 2: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

1 Introduction

One of the most important and controversial outcomes of the Uruguay Round of mul-tilateral trade negotiations (1986-95) was the Agreement on the Trade Related Aspectsof Intellectual Property (TRIPS). This far-reaching agreement calls for WTO membersto adopt certain minimum standards of protection for all major types of intellectualproperty such as copyrights, patents, and trademarks.1 For example, TRIPS requiresthat the duration of patent protection granted by all WTO members must be at least20 years. In addition to such harmonization, an equally important aspect of TRIPSis that it requires member countries to adopt certain fundamental principles, such asnon-discrimination in the protection of intellectual property.2 The non-discriminationrequirement in TRIPS manifests itself in two forms: the principle of national treatment(NT) that forbids discrimination between domestic and foreign �rms/nationals withregard to the protection of intellectual property and the most favored nation (MFN)clause that prohibits discrimination between foreign nationals originating from di¤er-ent countries.3 Our primary objective in this paper is to evaluate the case for NT inthe protection of intellectual property. To achieve this objective, we utilize an adaptedversion of the Grossman and Lai (2004) model of endogenous patent protection withongoing innovation.4 While the model focuses on patent policy, the insights it yields arerelevant for other instruments of intellectual property protection such as copyrights andtrademarks.In accordance with Article 3 of TRIPS, Grossman and Lai (2004) focus on non-

discriminatory patent policies in an open economy setting and show two major results.First, countries tend to o¤er too little protection to intellectual property in an openeconomy setting. Second, the harmonization of intellectual property protection across

1See Maskus (2000) for a comprehensive discussion of the economics of intellectual property rightsprotection in the global economy and the international externalities that a multilateral agreement suchas TRIPS attempts to internalize.

2To be sure, the principle of non-discrimination predates TRIPS but historical international intellec-tual property treaties (such as the Paris and Berne Conventions) were not backed by a powerful disputesettlement procedure like the one that is available to WTO members today.

3The NT requirement is speci�ed in Article 3 of TRIPS which says that �Each Member shall accordto the nationals of other Members treatment no less favorable than that it accords to its own nationalswith regard to the protection of intellectual property.�MFN is contained in Article 4 which says that�any advantage, favour, privilege or immunity granted by a Member to the nationals of any othercountry shall be accorded immediately and unconditionally to the nationals of all other Members.�These twin principles of non-discrimination are found in some shape or form in every multilateral tradeagreement of the WTO.

4Their work builds on Nordhaus (1969) who �rst addressed the question of optimal patent policy ina closed economy.

2

Page 3: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

countries is neither necessary nor su¢ cient for achieving e¢ ciency since it does notaddress the underlying problem of under-protection. In the present paper, we buildon their insights by examining the implications of the non-discrimination constraintson national patent policies imposed by NT thereby adding to our understanding of theeconomic consequences of TRIPS.5

Issues surrounding the international protection of intellectual property have mostfrequently been examined in the literature through the lens of North-South modelsof international trade and technology transfer.6 However, such models do not deriveoptimal patent policies: instead they either consider the e¤ects of marginal changes inan exogenously given rate of Southern imitation or examine policies that, on the margin,lower incentives for (endogenous) imitation. Thus, they do not address the implicationsof core TRIPS principles such as NT for equilibrium patent policies and welfare.While non-discrimination in the use of domestic tax instruments such as sales taxes

has received signi�cant attention in the literature, little is known about its e¤ects in therealm of intellectual property protection. Horn (2006) makes the important point thatwhile NT with respect to internal taxes and other such domestic instruments can preventcountries from pursuing legitimate objectives, trade agreements that do not contain sucha clause can be easily subverted by national governments who are invariably inclined tofavor domestic �rms over foreign ones. Thus, according to this view, NT serves as a lineof defense against beggar-thy-neighbor tendencies of individual nations.7

Horn�s (2006) basic query is no less relevant in the realm of intellectual property:when and why does it make sense to constrain national policies in the manner speci�edby NT? To be sure, incentives to pursue beggar-thy-neighbor policies are pervasivein the context of intellectual property.8 After all, a key reason the US and the EU

5In Grossman and Lai (2004) as well as in our model, all innovation is conducted by the privatesector. See Scotchmer (2004) for an analysis of intellectual property treaties in a model where R&D isconducted by both the private and the public sector.

6Much of this literature follows Grossman and Helpman (1991) who provide a comprehensive anduni�ed treatment of the two leading approaches � i.e. the variety expansion model and the qualityladders model. Further building on this work, Helpman (1993) analyzes how a decline in Southernimitation a¤ects global welfare both in the steady state and during the transition path.

7Saggi and Sara (2008) take Horn�s analysis further by studying the role of NT when countries areheterogeneous in market size and/or the quality of goods produced and the mutual agreement over NTis endogenously determined. A recent paper by Horn, Maggi, and Staiger (2010) examines the role ofNT from the perspective of incomplete contracts.

8Lerner (2002) notes that prior to the emergence of major international agreements on intellectualproperty, discrimination against foreign patent applications was quite common during the mid 19thcentury across the world. Discriminatory measures used against foreigners included shorter duration ofpatents, higher fees, shorter extensions, and premature patent expirations. See also Goldstein (2001).

3

Page 4: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

(to a lesser extent) pushed hard for a multilateral agreement on intellectual propertyduring the Uruguay round negotiations was that major developing economies such asBrazil, China, and India were o¤ering little or no intellectual property protection to their�rms, a policy environment that fostered widespread imitation and reverse-engineeringof Western technologies by local �rms in such countries. But does the presence ofsuch beggar-thy-neighbor incentives necessarily provide a rationale for requiring non-discrimination in the protection of intellectual property? Our analysis below shows thatit does not.Our baseline model considers a world comprised of two countries and analyzes the

e¤ects of NT under the assumption that there exist no trade frictions between them.Somewhat expectedly, we �nd that in the absence of a NT requirement, each country�nds it optimal to grant weaker protection to foreign �rms relative to domestic ones.This discrimination arises because governments do not care about the e¤ects of theirpolicies on foreign �rms. However, we show that such discrimination against foreign �rmson the part of both countries does not have any welfare consequences. To understandthe intuition for this surprising result, �rst note that a �rm�s incentive for innovationdepends upon the level of e¤ective global protection available to it under alternativepolicy regimes, where the level of e¤ective global protection is de�ned as the sum ofeach country�s national index of patent protection multiplied by its market size. Thereason NT fails to generate any welfare improvement in our model is that what each�rm gains in terms of protection abroad if discrimination is replaced by NT is exactlyo¤set by what it loses at home so that e¤ective global protection facing �rms remainsunchanged.In section 4, we show that this invariance of innovation incentives and welfare to

NT does not obtain in the presence of trade frictions. When international trade is sub-ject to frictions (such as transportation and communication costs), NT actually lowersinnovation incentives by reducing the e¤ective global protection enjoyed by �rms. Theintuition is that even though trade frictions lower export pro�ts thereby making foreignpatent protection relatively less important for incentivizing innovation in each country,NT calls for each country to provide more of such protection rather than less. Indeed,from the viewpoint of �rms, favorable discrimination granted at home in the absence ofNT more than o¤sets the negative incentive e¤ects of unfavorable discrimination su¤eredabroad. Consumer welfare considerations reinforce the argument in favor of discrimina-tion: trade frictions reduce the volume of trade so that consumer surplus generated byforeign innovations is smaller than that generated by domestic ones.9 Indeed, we show

9The empirical link between the protection of intellectual property and the volume and pattern of

4

Page 5: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

that with any positive level of trade frictions, it is jointly optimal for each country too¤er a relatively lower level of patent protection to foreign �rms, a policy con�gurationprecluded by NT.We also investigate how changes in the level of trade frictions between countries alter

patent protection and the e¤ects of NT. Here we �nd that a reduction in trade frictionsbetween countries lowers each country�s incentive to discriminate against foreigners sincedomestic consumers derive greater bene�ts from foreign innovations when trade frictionsare smaller. Our analysis also shows that di¤erences in market size across countriescan a¤ect incentives for discrimination in rather surprising ways. An important resultin this regard is that if the market size of a country increases relative to the other, itsincentive to discriminate against foreign �rms declines while its level of patent protectionincreases. Intuitively, as a country�s market size increases, its weight in determining thelevel of e¤ective global protection increases as does the bene�t it enjoys from foreigninnovations. Therefore, a larger market has a weaker incentive to discriminate againstforeign nationals, a result that seems to accord quite well with the fact that multilateraldisciplines on intellectual property were pushed strongly by the two largest economies inthe world (EU and the USA) during the Uruguay round. From the perspective of theseeconomies, TRIPS was primarily a means for getting developing countries to acceptdisciplines such as NT and MFN along with an increase in the degree of intellectualproperty protection that they had to extend to innovators.Since an increase in market size asymmetry reduces the degree of discrimination

in the larger market while it raises it in the smaller market, the average degree ofdiscrimination declines in our model as markets become more unequal in size. Foranalogous reasons, the degree of e¤ective global protection increases with market sizeasymmetry. Both of these factors imply that the global welfare loss generated by NTdeclines as markets become more asymmetric in size rather than less. This aspectof our model contrasts sharply with analyses of international trade agreements overconventional policy instruments such as tari¤s and internal taxes since coordination overthese traditional instruments as well as non-discrimination requirements with respect totheir use generally become harder to implement as countries become less similar to eachother � see, for example, Park (2000), Horn (2006), and Sara and Saggi (2008). Insuch models, as a country gets larger (i.e. has more market power) it tends to typicallyincrease its tari¤ or tax but such a change immiserizes the other country. By contrast,in the present context, as the larger country increases its patent protection and lowers

international trade was �rst established by Maskus and Penubarti (2001). See Maskus and Yang (2013)for a more recent investigation of related issues.

5

Page 6: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

its discrimination against foreign �rms, the smaller country�s welfare increases as doesits ability to lower its own protection since innovation incentives of �rms depend onlyon the e¤ective global protection that they receive, and not on its composition acrosscountries. Thus, the type of international spillovers that an international agreementover intellectual property helps internalize are fundamentally di¤erent in character fromthose internalized by trade agreements over tari¤s and other trade policies.10 However,the di¤erent nature of spillovers in the context of patent protection is not the key drivingforce behind our surprising �ndings. Positive international spillovers created by patentprotection only imply that there exists global under-protection of patents. The keyreason discriminatory patent policies dominate NT in the presence of trade frictions isthat such frictions make each country�s innovation relatively less response to foreignpatent protection and by forcing each country to o¤er the same level of protection todomestic and foreign �rms, NT reduces the overall e¤ectiveness of patent protection inencouraging innovation.Our paper echoes an emerging empirical literature that examines how e¤ectively

countries practice non-discriminatory IPR policies during the post-TRIPS era. Rathersurprisingly, existing evidence suggests that even WTO members tend to discriminateagainst foreign innovators in practice. For example, Webster et. al. (2014) �nd that, allelse equal, both European and Japanese patent o¢ ces are more likely to grant patentsto domestic applicants relative to foreign ones. In similar vein, using data for Canada,Mai and Stoyanov (2014) �nd that domestic �rms are substantially more likely to winlitigations with foreign �rms than with Canadian �rms. Consistent with these empirical�ndings, our paper shows that countries indeed have incentives to use discriminatoryIP policies in the absence of NT. More importantly, our paper establishes that theuse of such discriminatory IP policies can be welfare-enhancing relative to NT wheninternational trade is subject to frictions.11

2 Baseline model

To study NT in the international protection of intellectual property, we utilize the openeconomy model of ongoing innovation developed by Grossman and Lai (2004). Before

10Bagwell and Staiger (1999 and 2002) argue that the GATT/WTO principles of MFN and reciprocityhelp achieve e¢ ciency when international trade agreements are motivated by the presence of terms oftrade externalities between countries.11Lai (2007) also examines incentives for discriminatory patent policies in the absence of NT. However,

he only considers a world of free and does not analyze how innovation and welfare di¤er across the twotypes of patent regimes (i.e. discrimination and NT).

6

Page 7: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

describing policy choices, we summarize the underlying economic environment. Theworld consists of two countries: Home (H) and Foreign (F ). Each country has twosectors: a traditional sector that produces a homogeneous good and a modern one thatinvents a variety of di¤erentiated goods through research and development (R&D). Aninvented di¤erentiated good has a �nite life span (�) during which it generates positiveutility for consumers. At the end of its life span, the di¤erentiated good produces zeroutility and exits the market.In both countries, the representative consumer maximizes her lifetime utility

U(t) =

Z 1

t

e��zu(z)dz (1)

where � is the subjective discount rate and u(�) is the instantaneous utility functiongiven by

u(z) = y(z) +

Z n(z)

0

h(x(i; z))di (2)

where y(z) and x(i; z) represent respectively the consumptions of the homogeneous goodand the ith di¤erentiated good at time z and n(z) denotes the measure of di¤erentiatedgoods that are still alive at time z. As in Grossman and Lai (2004), h(:) is assumedto satisfy the following regularity conditions (i) h0 > 0 and h00 < 0; (ii) every varietyof di¤erentiated goods is purchased in equilibrium (i.e. h0(0) = 1); and (iii) optimalmonopoly price of a typical di¤erentiated good is �nite (i.e. �xh00=h0 < 1).Given the preferences in (1) and (2), the representative consumer �rst chooses the

consumption of di¤erentiated goods and then purchases the homogeneous good with theremainder of her income (which is assumed to be positive). There are Mi consumers incountry i, where i = H;F , so thatMi measures country i�s market size for di¤erentiatedgoods.On the production side, di¤erentiated goods are invented by �rms via R&D which

requires a combination of labor (L) and human capital (K). For simplicity, the researchtechnology in country i is assumed to take the Cobb-Douglas form:

�i(z) = Fi[LIi(z); Ki] = A[LIi(z)=ai]�(Ki)

1�� (3)

where �i(z) is the �ow of innovations at time z, A > 0 is a constant, LIi(z) is the laborinput into innovation, ai represents labor productivity, and Ki represents the �xed stockof human capital.12

12Our major results continue to hold when the production function for research has a CES form ofthe type �i(z) = A[�[LIi(z)=ai]

� + (1 � �)K�i ]1=� with � � 0. As is well-known, the Cobb-Douglas

7

Page 8: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

The amount of labor needed to produce one unit of each good (either homogeneousor di¤erentiated) in country i equals ai. The total labor resource in country i, Li, isassumed to be su¢ ciently large so that a positive amount of the homogeneous good isproduced in equilibrium in each country. Labor is mobile between sectors but not acrosscountries. We take the homogeneous good as the numeraire. Since the market for thehomogeneous good is assumed to be perfectly competitive, the wage rate in country isimply equals the marginal product of labor in the traditional sector: i.e. wi = 1=ai.Given the technology speci�ed for innovation in (3), �i(z) + �j(z) newly invented

goods enter country i�s market during each time period z, while a measure of �i(z��)+�j(z��) existing goods die and exit the market. As a result, the growth in the measure ofdi¤erentiated good at a given point in time is

�ni(z) = �i(z)��i(z��)+�j(z)��j(z��).

We focus on the steady state of the world economy where�ni(z) = 0, that is, the measure

of di¤erentiated good in both markets remains constant over time.A di¤erentiated good can be targeted by imitators after being invented. To protect

goods from imitation, the government in each country grants patent rights to inventing�rms. As in Grossman and Lai (2004) patent is assumed to have two dimensions: thelength � and the degree of enforcement ! where ! 2 [0; 1]. While the patent is ine¤ect the patenting �rm charges its optimal monopoly price. Let � be the instantaneousper capita pro�t of a monopoly �rm producing a patented di¤erentiated good so that� = (pm�aw)xm. Also de�ne the index of patent protection as = !(1�e��� )=� where� is the rate of time preference.13 By design, the present value of expected per capitapro�ts from patenting a newly invented good equals �.A patented good, however, is imitated free of cost after the patent expires. Imitation

drives the price of the good to its competitive level so that post imitation pro�ts of aninnovator equal zero. Let T = !(1� e��� )=� be the present value of a 1 dollar �ow overthe entire useful life of a typical patented product.When analyzing optimal patent protection policies in the economic framework de-

scribed above, Grossman and Lai (2004) focus on policies that abide by the non-discrimination principle of NT. As we noted earlier, Article 3 of TRIPS indeed requirescountries to extend equal patent protection to all �rms regardless of their national ori-gin. One of our key objectives, however, is to examine the implications of the constraint

production function obtains when � = 0. Restricting � to be non-positive has two implications. First,the responsiveness of innovation to patent protection decreases as the latter rises. Second, patentprotection policies of di¤erent countries are strategic substitutes for one another. We consider boththese features to be quite realistic.13Positive consumption of good y and perfect intertemporal substitutability of y in consumer prefer-

ences ensure that the interest rate is constant and equal to �.

8

Page 9: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

that NT places on the patent policies of individual nations. To do so, we allow countriesto discriminate between domestic and foreign �rms by formulating and implementingpatent protection levels that depend upon the national origin of �rms. Accordingly, letcountry i extend protection Rii to domestic �rms and

Rij to foreign ones under regime

R, where R = D (discrimination) or NT and ii = ij under NT .Under regime R, a �rm from country i that is successful in innovation earns total

pro�t �MiRii in the home market and �Mj

Rji overseas. The value of a typical innovating

�rm from country i under regime R therefore equals vRi = (MiRii +Mj

Rji)�. Firms

make decisions about their labor inputs for R&D based on the expected total pro�tsthey can earn on the global market. The �rst-order condition determining demand forlabor in country i under regime R where R = D or NT is

vRi@Fi(LIi; Ki)

@LIi= wi

Let Cm and Cc be the instantaneous (per capita) consumer surplus levels undermonopoly and competition respectively, i.e. Cm = h(xm)�pmxm and Cc = h(xc)�pcxc.The discounted surplus over the entire life of a domestic di¤erentiated product enjoyedby a typical consumer in country i equals CmRii + Cc(T � Rii) whereas that derivedfrom a foreign di¤erentiated good is CmRij + Cc(T � Rij).Let �0 denote the welfare derived from goods invented prior to the implementation

of the patent policy. We may then write country i�s national welfare under regime Rwhere R = D or NT , as

WRi = �i0 +

wi�(Li � LRIi) +

Mi�Ri

�[Cm

Rii + Cc(T � Rii)] (4)

+Mi�

Rj

�[Cm

Rij + Cc(T � Rij)] +

��Ri�(Mi

Rii +Mj

Rji)

Similarly, let aggregate world welfare be de�ned simply the sum of national welfare ofeach country:

WWR =Xi

WRi (5)

We proceed by deriving equilibrium policies under discrimination and then imposethe NT constraint on each country to see how it a¤ects equilibrium policies and welfare.It is obvious that the unilateral imposition of NT on a country in our framework canonly make it worse o¤ since a country can always choose not to discriminate in patentprotection if it is welfare-maximizing to do so. But the more subtle issue, and the onethat we address below, is how the simultaneous adoption of NT by both countries a¤ectsmarket outcomes and welfare.

9

Page 10: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

3 E¤ects of NT in the absence of trade frictions

We begin with the scenario where international trade between Home and Foreign is notsubject to any frictions or barriers. An important implication of this assumption is thatfrom a social planner�s view, patent protection abroad is just as valuable to �rms aspatent protection in their domestic market. Later, in section 4 we will see that theintroduction of trade frictions breaks this equivalence which, in turn, has implicationsfor equilibrium policies and welfare under the two regimes.

3.1 Discriminatory patent protection

In what follows, we focus on the non-cooperative Nash equilibrium where each countrysimultaneously and independently determines its domestic and foreign patent protec-tions, treating these protections in the other country as given. The objective of eachgovernment is to maximize national welfare. In particular, we assume interior solutionsfor both the NT and discrimination regimes, meaning that patent protections imple-mented by governments lie strictly between 0 and T . To this end, we need to derive thebest response curves for each country from their welfare levels given in (4).Let us �rst consider the case where countries are free to implement discriminatory

patent policies. Following Grossman and Lai (2004), it turns out to be more intuitive toderive the best response curves of countries by equating each country�s marginal bene�tof extending patent protection to the associated marginal cost, taking the policies of theother country as given.Consider the patent policies of country i. A marginal increase in its domestic pro-

tection ii raises the value of all local �rms. This leads to more R&D investment and agreater variety of di¤erentiated goods invented by such �rms. Each di¤erentiated goodgenerates an discounted per-consumer surplus of Cmii + Cc(T � ii). It follows thatcountry i�s marginal bene�t of raising domestic protection is

Mi

@�Di@ii

[Cmii + Cc(T � ii)] (6)

where @�Di@ii

represents the response of local innovation to the change in domestic patentprotection.One can show that (see appendix)

@�Di@ii

= �iMi

Miii +Mjji

10

Page 11: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

where = �1�� represents the responsiveness of innovation to the value of an innovation

in elasticity form. Plugging this expression into (6), one obtains country i�s marginalbene�t of raising domestic protection

1

�Di M2i

Miii +Mjji[(Cm � Cc)ii + CcT ] (7)

On the other hand, a marginal increase in domestic patent protection allows local�rms to charge monopoly prices for a longer time period. This causes a loss of consumersurplus, which is partially o¤set by the greater monopoly pro�ts accruing to domestic�rms. Since �Di new goods are invented per unit of time, country i�s discounted marginalcost of strengthening domestic patent protection ii equals

Mi�Di (Cc � Cm � �)

�(8)

Equating the marginal bene�t (7) to the marginal cost (8) and rearranging termsgives the �rst order condition determining country i�s patent protection ii to its do-mestic �rms:14

Cc � Cm � � = Mi

Miii +Mjji[(Cm � Cc)ii + CcT ] (9)

Equation (9) describes country i�s best response ii to the degree of patent protectionthat country j extends to country i�s �rms (ji). It is easy to see from (9) that iivaries inversely with ji since Cm � Cc < 0: country i�s protection to its own �rmsdeclines if they receive more protection from country j. The intuition behind this isstraightforward. An increase in ji increases the value of country i�s �rms and therebyencourages them to invest more in R&D activity. Due to diminishing returns in R&D,country i�s marginal bene�t of extending more patent protection to its own �rms is lowerwhen ji is larger. As a result, ii has to fall in order to bring the marginal bene�tback to the level of the marginal cost, namely, Cc � Cm � �. This implies that ii andji are substitutable patent policies.Observe that in the absence of NT, changing country j�s domestic protection (jj)

has no direct e¤ect on country i�s decision regarding its domestic protection (ii). Thisis not the case under NT, since a country cannot choose its domestic and foreign patentpolicies separately.

14The second-order conditions can be shown to hold for both countries.

11

Page 12: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Similarly, the best response curve for country i�s foreign protection, ij, can beobtained as

Cc � Cm = Mi

Miij +Mjjj[(Cm � Cc)ij + CcT ] (10)

It is important to note from the above equation that the marginal cost of strengtheningforeign protection ij is not mitigated by �, because the monopoly pro�ts generatedby extending such patent protection end up accruing to foreign �rms. It follows thata country�s marginal cost of foreign patent protection is always larger than that ofdomestic protection, which is the sole reason for why it has an incentive to implementdiscriminatory patent policies (as shown below). It is also clear from (10) that jj andij are substitutes for each other: if country j increases its domestic patent protection(jj) then country i will �nd it optimal to lower its foreign protection ij.We can show the following:15

Proposition 1: In the absence of NT, each country�s patent policy discriminates infavor of domestic �rms: ��i � �ii � �ij > 0 for i; j = H;F .

Proposition 1 is similar in spirit to the �ndings of Horn (2006) and Saggi and Sara(2008) who focus on NT in the context of tax policies. In particular, they show that ifNT is not binding then each country will tax foreign �rms more because their pro�tsdo not count as part of national welfare. The logic here is the same: discriminatorypatent policies arise naturally from the fact that countries care about pro�ts accruing todomestic �rms but not foreign ones. The key question that follows is whether eliminatingsuch discrimination via NT brings about e¢ ciency gains, which will be addressed in theanalysis below.Firms make R&D decisions based on the duration of patent protection in each country

as well as its market size. The level of e¤ective global protection received by �rms fromcountry i under discriminatory patent policies equals

P �i =Mi�ii +Mj

�ji

where i = H;F . How does the level of e¤ective global protection P �i vary with thenational origin of �rms? We can show the following:

Lemma 1:When countries implement discriminatory patent policies, the e¤ective patentprotection available to �rms is equal across countries: P �i = P

�, i = H;F .

15Proofs of all propositions that are not in the text are provided in the appendix.

12

Page 13: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Lemma 1 implies that the incentives for innovation are the same for �rms in eithercountry, even if one country is relatively more e¢ cient in innovation. Intuitively, whencountry i protects its own �rms more than country j protects its own �rms �as would betrue if the market size of country i is larger �then country i also protects foreign �rmsmore than country j. Indeed, if country i is much larger than country j, it is possible forit to grant better protection to foreign �rms than they receive from their own governmenteven when country i discriminates against foreign �rms. Such international o¤setting ofpatent protection equalizes incentives for innovation across countries.

SinceMH

�HH +MF

�FH =MF

�FF +MH

�HF

it follows thatMi�

�i =Mj�

�j , ��i =�

�j =Mj=Mi

which we state as:

Proposition 2: The relative degree of discrimination (��i =��j) practised by a coun-

try is inversely proportional to its relative market size (Mi=Mj), i = H;F .

As a country�s relative market size increases, its weight in determining the level ofe¤ective global protection increases as does the bene�t it enjoys from foreign innova-tions. Therefore, a larger market has a weaker incentive to discriminate against foreignnationals. As we noted earlier, in typical models of international trade agreements, as acountry gets larger (i.e. has more market power) it tends to typically increase discrim-ination against foreign sellers. By contrast, the opposite happens here and the smallercountry bene�ts from a reduction in discrimination its �rms face abroad as well as anincrease in overall patent protection.

3.2 Patent protection under NT

Now suppose that each country has to choose a non-discriminatory patent protectionlevel that applies to every �rm in the world. A detailed analysis of the NT regime isprovided in Grossman and Lai (2004). Here, we focus on comparing outcomes underNT with those under discrimination. The best response curve for country i under NTcan be written as follows

Cc � Cm � �i� = Mi

Pi(i;j)[(Cm � Cc)i + CcT ] (11)

13

Page 14: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

where Pi(i;j) = Mii + Mjj and �i =�NTi

�NTi +�NTjis the proportion of innovation

that occurs in country i. Given our assumption that the R&D production function isCobb-Douglas in nature, it turns out that �i =

Ki

Ki+Kj, i.e., �i is determined solely by

the relative human capital stocks of countries and is una¤ected by their patent policies.Observe from above that the marginal cost of patent protection in country i under

NT is strictly in between the marginal costs of granting patent protection to domestic�rms and foreign �rms under discrimination:

Cc � Cm � � < Cc � Cm � �i� < Cc � Cm

This inequality follows from the fact that a country only cares about pro�ts of local�rms while NT forces it to treat all �rms symmetrically. As a result, the pro�t of atypical �rm is discounted by �i which increases in its home country�s human capital(Ki). This means that when a large share of the global innovation is carried out by local�rms, the marginal cost of patent protection perceived by a country declines. In general,since NT forces countries into a scenario where the marginal cost of patent protection isa weighted average of the marginal costs associated with the discriminatory protectionlevels accorded to domestic and foreign �rms, intuition suggests that NT might inducecountries to select a level of protection that lies in the interval (ii;ij) �a conjecturewe formally con�rm below.

Proposition 3: (i) Under NT, each country selects a level of patent protection thatexceeds the protection it grants to foreign �rms under discrimination but falls short ofthat which it gives to its domestic �rms: �ij <

NTi < �ii for i; j = H;F . If countries

are symmetric then 2NTi = �ii + �ij for i; j = H;F .

(ii) The e¤ective global protection available to �rms as well as global welfare under NTis the same as that under discrimination: PNT =Mi

NTi +Mj

NTj = P �.

To see more explicitly why welfare under NT is the same as that under discrimination,from (5) we can rewrite world welfare under regime R as

WWR =Xi

�i0 +1

Xi

wi(Li � LRIi)

+CcT

Xi

�Ri Mi �Xi

�Ri PRi

�Cc � Cm � �

�Observe from this that in the absence of NT, world welfare depends only upon the e¤ec-tive protection levels PRi =Mi

Rii +Mj

Rji available to �rms from both countries under

14

Page 15: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

regime R (where R = NT or D) since PRi pins down all the other endogenous vari-ables such as the allocation of resources to R&D (LRIi) and the rates of innovation (�i).But from Proposition 3 we already know that P �i = PNT . As a result, world welfareis invariant to whether or not the underlying patent regime abides by NT.16 There-fore, mandating NT is neither necessary nor su¢ cient for achieving e¢ ciency providedinternational trade is not subject to any frictions.Grossman and Lai (2004) showed that the Nash equilibrium under NT gives rise to

under-protection of intellectual property relative to the socially optimal levels due to thepositive internalities externalities generated by national patent protection policies. Fromthe above analysis, it is not hard to see that the free rider problem that plagues the Nashequilibrium under NT continues to exist even when countries institute discriminatorypatent policies.The welfare neutrality of NT in our model is a rather novel �nding in the context

of the literature on NT. As we noted earlier, models in which NT applies to taxationtypically �nd results favorable to NT. Further, even in the context of patent protection,in a two period model Bond (2005) has shown that, holding constant the level of protec-tion granted to domestic �rms, an increase in the level of patent protection granted toforeign �rms that eliminates discrimination increases global welfare. The driving forcebehind this result is as follows: since each country o¤ers too little protection to foreign�rms, a NT policy that leaves domestic protections unchanged essentially increases over-all patent protection thereby alleviating the ine¢ ciency of aggregate under-protectionin the global economy.While there is under-protection of patent protection in our model as well, what our

analysis highlights is that a move towards increasing patent protection to foreignersdriven by NT does not occur in isolation since each country simultaneously lowers theprotection it grants to domestic �rms. In fact, such changes in patent protection grantedto domestic �rms as a result of NT o¤sets the increased protection granted to foreign�rms so that NT does not alter the e¤ective global protection available to �rms. In thisway, our model is able to separate the impact of NT on welfare from the increase inoverall patent protection that results if NT is interpreted as a policy that brings up thepatent protection granted to foreign nationals holding constant the protection granted

16It is worth emphasizing that our model considers the simultaneous adoption of NT by both coun-tries. One might also be interested in knowing the welfare consequences of a unilateral violation ofNT by a single country. We can show that holding constant the patent protection of one country ata non-discriminatory level, unilateral violation of NT by the other country can indeed lower overallpatent protection and welfare. This implies that the strategic substitutability of patent policies acrosscountries is key to understanding Proposition 3 (ii).

15

Page 16: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

to domestic �rms.

4 NT in the presence of trade frictions

Since the welfare neutrality of NT in the benchmark model is driven by the completeo¤setting of patent protection across countries when discriminatory policies are elimi-nated via NT, it is worth asking whether such international o¤setting also obtains whenfrictions arising from the existence of transportation costs and costs of coordination andcommunication hamper international trade. We now address this issue and show thatwhen trade frictions exist, NT induces incomplete o¤setting of patent protection acrosscountries and actually ends up lowering the e¤ective level of global patent protection.

4.1 Trade frictions and discrimination

Before deriving the e¤ect of trade frictions on the incentives for discrimination in patentprotection, we make three simple observations. First, trade frictions reduce the surplusconsumers derive from foreign goods. Second, by making it costlier for �rms to export,trade frictions lower export pro�ts of �rms (while having no e¤ect on their domesticpro�ts). Third, trade frictions do not a¤ect the consumer surplus derived from goodswhose patents have expired since such goods are imitated and produced locally in eachmarket.Denote the (inverse of) the degree of trade frictions between countries by �, where

0 � � � 1 and � = 1 represents free/costless trade while � = 0 indicates the completeabsence of trade. In the presence of trade frictions, denote the consumer surplus derivedfrom a patented imported good by �Cm while the export pro�ts earned by a �rm by��. This parsimonious formulation of trade frictions (i.e. as being captured by a singleparameter �) is adopted purely for expositional simplicity.17 Our results below hold aslong as both consumer surplus and export pro�ts decrease with trade frictions even ifthey do so at very di¤erent rates.

17Suppose h(x) = �1=" ""�1x

"�1" where " > 1 and � > 0. This utility function yields a constant

elasticity demand curve of the form x(p) = �p�" for each di¤erentiated good. If, in addition, tradebarriers are assumed to be of the ice-berg type, then it is straightforward to show that consumer surplusfrom imports and overseas pro�ts earned by �rms equal �Cm and �� respectively. Lai and Yan (2013)embed this formulation of trade costs in a model of patent protection with �rm heterogeneity and FDIand show that trade liberalization helps alleviate the problem of under-protection in Nash equilibrium.Even in their model, trade frictions lower overseas pro�ts and consumer surplus derived from importedgoods. Thus, allowing for �rm heterogeneity and FDI does not a¤ect the main channel that rendersforeign patent protection less e¤ective than domestic protection in our model.

16

Page 17: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

It is worth noting that in the context of patent protection, a world with prohibitivetrade frictions (� = 0) is not the same as a fully autarkic economy that is shut o¤ fromthe world in every way. In particular, if technology transfer does not depend on trade(i.e. if trade in ideas can occur without trade in goods �see Rivera-Batiz and Romer,1991), then even when there is no trade in goods (i.e. � = 0) a country is free to imitateforeign goods. As a result, one would expect a country to have less incentive to protectintellectual property under � = 0 relative to the autarky case. Indeed it is possibleto show, for example, that patent protection under NT when � = 0 is lower in bothcountries relative to the autarkic level.The key question we address below is: How do trade frictions a¤ect incentives for

discrimination? The overseas pro�t earned by a �rm from country i equals �Mjji� sothat the corresponding �rm value equals

vDi (�) = (Miii + �Mjji)�

As is clear from above, due to the presence of trade frictions (� < 1) patent protectionin export markets (i.e. ji) is relatively less valuable for �rms than protection in theirdomestic markets (i.e. ii).Now consider government i�s decision regarding patent protection. The marginal

cost of extending domestic protection remains unchanged relative to free trade sincetrade frictions do not a¤ect the consumption of domestic goods and thus the pro�t �rmsmake in their domestic markets. A country�s marginal bene�t of domestic protection,however, is di¤erent as trade frictions do a¤ect the value of domestic �rms by reducingtheir export pro�ts and therefore the in�uence of foreign patent protection ji on theirinnovation incentives.The marginal bene�t of extending domestic protection ii equals

1

�Di M2i

Miii + �Mjji[(Cm � Cc)ii + CcT ]

Note that holding constant ji (i.e. the protection domestic �rms get abroad), themarginal bene�t of increasing ii (i.e. the protection to domestic �rms) decreases with�. All else equal, a reduction in trade frictions makes ji a more e¤ective substitute forii due to increased export pro�ts of �rms.Country i�s best response curve for domestic protection ii can be written as

Cc � Cm � � = Mi

Miii + �Mjji[(Cm � Cc)ii + CcT ] (12)

17

Page 18: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Regarding the protection extended to foreign �rms, note that consumers in country ionly derive a surplus of �Cm units from buying a patented foreign good. Since consumersalways buy the good from domestic imitators once the patent expires, the correspondingsurplus post imitation equals Cc. Thus, the marginal cost of raising foreign protectionequals

Mi�Dj (Cc � �Cm)

As is clear, holding constant the rate of innovation, the marginal cost of protectingforeign �rms decreases with trade frictions.Country i�s marginal bene�t of protecting foreign �rms can be written as

1

��Dj M2i

�Miij +Mjjj[(�Cm � Cc)ij + CcT ]

Note that holding constant jj (i.e. the protection foreign �rms get from their owngovernment), the marginal bene�t of increasing ij (i.e. the protection given by countryi to foreign �rms) increases as trade frictions fall.The best response curve for ij is given by

Cc � �Cm = �Mi

�Miij +Mjjj[(�Cm � Cc)ij + CcT ] (13)

Using the above best response curves, we can show the following:

Proposition 4: As trade frictions between countries fall (i.e. � increases), each countryincreases the degree of patent protection granted to foreign �rms �ij(�) while decreas-ing that granted to domestic �rms �ii(�). Furthermore, a reduction in trade frictionsincrease the degree of e¤ective global patent protection in both countries, i.e., @P

�i (�)

@�> 0

where P �i (�) =Mi�ii(�) + �Mj

�ji(�).

We now compare NT and discrimination in the presence of trade frictions. As before,a typical �rm�s value under the NT regime equals

vNTi (�) = (Mii + �Mjj)�

It is important to note that due to the existence of trade frictions, vi will in general bedi¤erent from vj even under NT, which further implies that �rms in di¤erent countriesmay face di¤erent levels of e¤ective patent protection.18

18Recall that when trade is free, all �rms receive the same e¤ective level of global patent protectionunder NT.

18

Page 19: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Under NT, the cost and bene�t of a marginal change in patent protection dependupon the level of trade frictions. As the derivation is similar to before, we simply reportcountry i�s best response curve for i without presenting the details:

Cc � (�i + ��j)Cm � � = Mi�i

Mii + �Mjj[(Cm � Cc)i + CcT ] (14)

+ �Mi�j

�Mii +Mjj[(�Cm � Cc)i + CcT ]

To investigate the e¢ ciency impact of NT, we now introduce the assumption thatcountries are symmetric in all respects (Mi = M , Ki = K and ai = a). This is a usefulsimpli�cation for three reasons. First, it helps isolate the e¤ect of trade frictions onthe international patent regimes. Second, the issue of non-discrimination is as relevant,if not more, in a North-North type setting of relatively similar countries as it is in aNorth-South setting where there are signi�cant di¤erences across countries with respectto market size and human capital. Third, analytical solutions under NT are di¢ cult tocalculate when countries are asymmetric. As a result, in section 4.3, we use numericalexamples to study the case of asymmetry and show that our results do not requirecountries to be symmetric.Denote the symmetric Nash equilibrium level of patent protection under NT by�(�).

Under discrimination, let �d(�) be the patent protection granted by each country todomestic �rms and �f (�) that given to foreign �rms. We can then show the following:

Proposition 5: Suppose countries are symmetric and there exist trade frictions betweenthem (i.e. 0 � � < 1). Then the following hold:(i) The degree of e¤ective global protection received by �rms under NT is lower than thatunder discrimination:

PNT (�) =M(1 + �)�(�) < P �(�) =M(�d(�) + ��f (�))

(ii) The gap between the degree of e¤ective patent protection under discriminationand NT decreases as trade frictions fall (i.e. P �(�)� PNT (�) declines with �).19

When trade frictions exist, from the viewpoint of �rms, protection abroad mattersless for pro�tability than protection at home. As a result, trade frictions make foreignprotection relatively less e¤ective in inducing innovation in each country. However, NT

19The anlaysis for the case of asymmetric countries is a bit more subtle and is presented in Section 5.

19

Page 20: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

forces each country to treat �rms the same even though their innovation incentives re-spond more to domestic protection. As a result, NT blunts the e¤ectiveness of patentprotection for incentivizing innovation so that, in equilibrium, the e¤ective degree ofprotection chosen by countries under NT ends up being lower. This result is importantbecause it shows that while there is under-protection of intellectual property under bothNT and discrimination in our model, this problem is more severe under NT. Thus, some-what paradoxically, in the presence of trade frictions allowing countries to discriminateagainst foreign nationals with respect to patent protection actually leads to strongerinnovation incentives in the global economy.The intuition behind Proposition 5 can also be understood by examining the marginal

bene�t and cost of strengthening patent protection. Suppose that PNT (�) � P �(�). Thenfrom the right-hand sides of (A6) and (A7) in the Appendix, we can see that the marginalbene�t of raising patent protection is larger under discrimination for both countries.Moreover, it exceeds the marginal cost of patent protection so that each country wouldwant to extend its total patent protection. This implies that PNT (�) = P �(�) cannot besustained as a Nash equilibrium. As a result we must have P �(�) > PNT (�).

4.2 Jointly optimal policies under trade frictions

We now consider the problem of choosing jointly (or socially) optimal domestic andforeign patent protection for country i�s �rms (i.e. ii and ji). The jointly optimalpolicies solve

Maxii, ji

WWD(�) where WWD(�) =Xi

WDi (�)

We show in the appendix that

@WWD(�)

@ii� 1�

@WWD(�)

@ji=�Di Mi(1� �)Cc

�> 0 for all 0 < � < 1 (15)

i.e. the net marginal social bene�t of extending domestic patent protection to �rms isstrictly higher than the marginal bene�t of foreign patent protection so long as their existtrade frictions between countries. Using this key relationship, we prove the followingresult:

Proposition 6: In the presence of trade frictions (i.e. 0 < � < 1), social optimality callsfor each country to discriminate against foreign �rms, i.e. wij <

wii for i; j = H;F .

20

20Since under this scheme of jointly optimal protection �rms receive less protection abroad than theydo at home, for any given innovation, foreign consumers begin to enjoy greater surplus (arising from

20

Page 21: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Furthermore, if it is optimal to o¤er �rms less protection in their domestic markets thanthe useful lifetime of products (i.e. wii < T ), then it is optimal to give them no patentprotection in their export markets (i.e. wji = 0).

21

The central point of Proposition 6 is that trade frictions drive a wedge between thesocial value of domestic and foreign patent protections and social optimality calls forassigning a higher priority to domestic protection in each country. In other words, notonly the level of protection but also its composition matters. In contrast, Grossman andLai (2004) show that under free trade e¢ ciency depends on the level of total protectionbut not the compositional feature. In our model, this is easily veri�ed by taking � = 1in (15), so that domestic and foreign protections have equal net bene�t.Proposition 6 shows that, in the realm of patent protection, discriminatory policies

are desirable even when beggar-thy-neighbor incentives are completely missing (as theyare when countries maximize joint welfare). Bond (2005) has shown that it can besocially e¢ cient to internationally discriminate with respect to patent protection if theelasticity of innovation with respect to patent protection di¤ers across countries. Ourresults imply that this is not necessary for discrimination to be desirable since we allowthe elasticity of innovation with respect to patent protection to be the same acrosscountries.22

Comparing the �rst-order conditions determining the Nash equilibrium with thoseunder joint welfare maximization, it is easy to see that the marginal cost of patentprotection under the Nash equilibrium (as perceived by each country) is larger thanthe true social cost while the marginal bene�t of such protection is smaller if e¤ectiveprotection under the two scenarios is the same (i.e. ifMi

wii =Mi

�ii+�Mj

�ji). Thus, in

an interior solution we must haveMi�ii+�Mj

�ji < Mi

wii , i.e. there is under-protection

in Nash equilibrium even in the presence of trade frictions, although the magnitude

local imitation) sooner than domestic ones. Indeed, if markets are unequal in size we can show thatthe degree of jointly optimal protection for �rms in each country is increasing in the relative size of theother country�s market: @wii

@(Mj=Mi)> 0.

21A corner solution for foreign protection might not arise if there exist enforcement costs that areincreasing in the level of patent protection. Under such costly enforcement, foreign protection maybe utilized even if domestic protection does not reach the boundary T . Even so, the rationale fordiscrimination would remain since such enforcement costs would persumably also apply to foreignprotection, and might even be higher than those for domestic protection.22An interesting implication of the presence of trade frictions is that discrimination could be more

desirable for goods that are harder to trade. Speci�cally, in an extreme case where goods are non-tradable (i.e. � = 0), there would be no reason to protect foreign �rms as their innovation incentivesare unresponsive to patent protection granted by countries other than their own. As a result, when� = 0 protecting foreign innovation only delays domestic consumption by the duration of the patentwithout a¤ecting the rate of innovation.

21

Page 22: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

of the externality from foreign protection is reduced. Another interesting observationabout discriminatory patent policies is that while coordination always leads to weakerforeign protection, in an asymmetric Nash equilibrium the North�s foreign protectionmay exceed the South�s domestic protection. This is because the larger country tendsto discriminate less while the smaller country free rides more. Notably, even though theSouth may be "sheltered" by the North, Proposition 6 indicates that this is not justi�edfrom an e¢ ciency point of view.It is also useful to consider the socially optimal protection levels assuming that NT

must be followed. If countries must abide by NT while choosing jointly optimal policies,the common protection level in each country solves:

Maxi, j

WWNT (�) where WWNT (�) =Xi

WNTi (�)

It is straightforward that world welfare cannot be higher under NT as additionalconstraints are imposed on the same maximization problem. Then the natural questionwould be whether NT yields strictly lower world welfare. Proposition 6 implies thatthis is indeed the case as long as there exist interior solutions under NT. The reasonis straightforward: by maintaining the level of total patent protections under NT, e¢ -ciency can be improved by substituting domestic protection for foreign, which necessarilycreates discrimination. Thus we arrive at the following:

Proposition 7: Suppose interior solutions are obtained under NT. Then the impositionof a NT constraint on the social planner lowers welfare: WWNT (�) < WWD(�).

4.3 NT in a North-South setting

In what follows, we discuss how the relative performance of NT and discriminationdepends upon the degree of asymmetry across countries. This issue is important becausewhat made TRIPS negotiations especially di¢ cult was the clash between the views ofdeveloping and developed countries regarding the desirability of multilateral disciplinesin the area of intellectual property. Furthermore, the WTO is comprised of countrieswith markedly di¤erent economies and it is important to know how NT operates insuch an environment. Note that the last section showed that, in the presence of tradefrictions NT is socially less e¢ cient than discrimination, regardless of the degree ofasymmetry across countries. What is interesting to know is whether this is also true ina noncooperative Nash equilibrium when countries are asymmetric in terms of economicfundamentals.

22

Page 23: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

In particular, it seems useful to consider a North-South scenario where one country�s,i.e. North�s, market as well as the stock of human capital is larger than that of the other(i.e. South).23 Suppose Mi > Mj and Ki > Kj. The non-linearity of �rst orderconditions (FOCs) under NT (see (14)) makes it di¢ cult to obtain analytical solutionsunder asymmetry. Nevertheless, we show below that the key driving forces behind NTbeing e¢ ciency-reducing relative to discrimination in a North-South setting remain thesame as those under symmetry. To start, we add up FOCs for both countries under NT.This yields

2Cc � (1 + �)Cm � � = [�i

PNTi (�)[(Cm � Cc)PNTi (�) + (Mi + �Mj)CcT (16)

�(1� �)�Mjj(�)] +�j

PNTj (�)[(Cm � Cc)PNTj (�)

+(Mj + �Mi)CcT � (1� �)�Mii(�)]]

Similarly, adding the two FOCs under discrimination yields

2Cc � (1 + �)Cm � � = [1

2Pi(�)(Cm � Cc)Pi(�) + (Mi + �Mj)CcT (17)

�(1� �)�Mjji(�)] +1

2Pj(�)[(Cm � Cc)Pj(�)

+(Mj + �Mi)CcT � (1� �)�Miij(�)]]

Note that the left hand-side of both equations above can be interpreted as the globalmarginal cost of patent protection, as it is the sum of marginal costs of patent protectionacross countries. Analogously, the right hand-side of both equalities represents the globalmarginal bene�t of patent protection. Observe that the global marginal cost of patentprotection under the two regimes is the same (since the LHS of the two equations is thesame). However, from the perspective of global marginal bene�t of patent protection,NT yields a worse outcome than discrimination due to two reasons. First, when tradefrictions exist, NT forces countries to overuse foreign protection, which other thingsbeing equal, tends to reduce the global marginal bene�t of patent protection. Thisoveruse of foreign protection under NT was the key driving force behind our analysisof the symmetric case. Of course, this mechanism continues to exist under asymmetry.Indeed, observe that the incentive-reducing e¤ects of trade frictions under NT, capturedby the terms (1� �)�Mii(�) and (1� �)�Mjj(�) in (16), are larger than those under

23One may also assume that the North has higher labor productivity (i.e. ai < aj), but this will notchange our analysis in a substantive way.

23

Page 24: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

discrimination, captured by the terms (1 � �)�Mjji(�) and (1 � �)�Mjji(�). This isbecause i(�) > ij(�) and j(�) > ji(�) in equilibrium.24 Intuitively, when countriesconsider raising domestic patent protection under NT, they are more conscious of thenegative incentive e¤ects of trade frictions since the level of foreign protection has toraised by the same amount.The second reason that NT yields a worse outcome than discrimination is that it

leads to unequal e¤ective protection levels across countries. This is a new distortionspeci�c to the North-South scenario, since under symmetry equal protection levels nat-urally arise. Recall that the analysis in section 4.2 shows that a necessary conditionfor global optimality is that countries should receive equal e¤ective protection in theglobal economy, i.e. PWi (�) = P

Wj (�). This result is true regardless of symmetry. In a

North-South setting with trade frictions, in Nash equilibrium the North ends up gettingmore total e¤ective protection than the South. This international disparity, however,tends to be larger under NT relative to discrimination. To see this, observing that �iin (16), which is the weight attached to the North, is greater than that in (17) which is12. Hence, although the North (South) is over-protected (under-protected) under bothregimes in the presence of trade frictions, the problem is more severe under NT.25

It is also worth noting that, as shown in section 2, the above distortions generatedby NT readily disappear when trade fractions vanish. On the one hand, when � = 1

domestic and foreign protections are equally e¤ective so that the incentive-reducingterms in both (16) and (17) drop out. On the other hand, under free trade both countriesreceive equal total e¤ective protection under NT simply by de�nition (i.e. Pi = Pj =

Mii +Mjj), so that the problem of unequal protection also goes away.We conducted numerical simulations to further study NT under asymmetry. We now

brie�y discuss the result of this analysis. For simplicity, consider a constant elasticitydemand function (x = p�" where " = 1:5). With this speci�c demand function it canbe shown that Cm = � � 0:2Cc. Also, let the following values be assigned to the

24We have shown this is true under free trade, that is, NTi (�) > �ij(�) and NTj (�) > �ji(�) when

� = 1. As � falls, both �ij(�) and �ji(�) decrease. Indeed, the marginal bene�t of extending patent

protection to foreigners becomes in�nitesimally small as � approaches zero (see the right hand-side of(13)). This is not true for NTi (�) and NTj (�) since the marginal bene�t of patent protection under NThas a positive lower bound due to the fact that such protection also extends to domestic �rms and partof their innovation incentive stems from domestic pro�ts that remain una¤ected by trade barriers (seethe right hand-side of (14)). Therefore, NTi (�) and NTj (�) cannot be lower than �ij(�) and

�ji(�).

25Our numerical results below show that as the degree of asymmetry between countries increases, thenegative e¤ect of NT becomes smaller. This implies that while the two distortions move in oppositedirections, the overuse of foreign protection may be a more serious problem than the unequal provisionof total patent protection.

24

Page 25: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

fundamental parameters of the model: � = 0:67, = 3, Cc = 5 and T = 20. Let� = 1 without loss of generality. These parameter values ensure interior solutions underdiscrimination and NT and our results are robust to variations in their values. Tonormalize away any level e¤ects, we �x the total world market size (Mi +Mf) and thestock of human capital (Ki +Kf).

Figure 1: Discrimination versus NT when market size di¤ers

Figure 1 shows how the welfare di¤erence between discrimination and NT, i.e. (WWD�WWNT )=WWNT , varies with trade frictions �, given Mi = 10, Mj = 5, Ki = 2 andKj = 1. First note that so long as trade frictions exist (� < 1), discrimination gen-erates strictly higher welfare than NT regardless of the level of such frictions. This isconsistent with our results regarding the negative e¤ects of NT under the presence oftrade frictions. Moreover, as trade frictions fall (i.e. � increases), the welfare di¤erentialbetween the two regimes converges to zero.

Table 1 shows the total e¤ective patent protections across regimes and their rela-tions. First note that the level of patent protection under NT lies in between the twodiscriminatory protections regardless of the level of trade frictions. This veri�es thedistortion of NT caused by excessive use of foreign protection. Moreover, we observethat PNTi > PDi > PDj > PNTj in the presence of trade frictions, indicating that NTindeed aggravates the over-protection (under-protection) problem for the North (South).Furthermore, Table 2 shows the welfare di¤erence between the two patent regimes forindividual countries. Notably, the North is worse-o¤ under NT even if it receives moretotal e¤ective protection than in the discriminatory regime. The reason is exactly be-cause the South is under-innovating due to the lack of e¤ective protection, so that this

25

Page 26: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

generates a larger welfare loss for the North than its gains from higher e¤ective protectionunder NT.

Table1: Equilibrium patent protection in a North-South world

NTi �ii �ij NTj �jj �ji PNTi PDi PNTj PDj� = 0:8 18:29 19:29 15:42 8:76 14:75 5:67 217:98 215:60 190:16 197:16� = 0:9 18:21 19:06 16:22 9:67 13:83 7:55 225:69 224:61 212:31 215:17� = 1 18:20 18:82 16:96 10:40 12:88 9:16 234:05 234:05 234:05 234:05

To see how the welfare gap is a¤ected by the degree of asymmetry, we study the e¤ectsof variations in market size by assuming human capital stock to be equal across countries.In particular, we reduced the gap between MH and MF in the above experiment to 0,�xing their sum (at 20). Also we setKH = KF = 1 and � = 0:75. Figure 2 shows that thewelfare loss from NT is smaller when countries are more asymmetric in terms of marketsize. To understand the intuition behind this result, recall from Proposition 2 that acountry�s incentive for discrimination is inversely related to its market size. Since anincrease in market size asymmetry reduces discrimination in the larger market while itraises it in the smaller market, the average degree of discrimination declines in our modelas markets become more unequal in size. For analogous reasons, the degree of e¤ectiveglobal protection increases with market size asymmetry. Thus, the global welfare lossgenerated by NT declines as markets become more unequal in size. This �nding suggeststhat the NT discipline may be a smaller concern in a North-South setting.

Figure 2: Comparison when market size di¤ers

26

Page 27: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

Finally, we illustrate the e¤ect of asymmetric human capital stocks. To this end, weequalize market size across countries by setting MH =MF = 7:5 and bring KH and KF

closer to 1:5 from 2 and 1 respectively. Again, we see in Figure 3 that NT generatesa smaller welfare loss when human capital stocks are more unequal. The intuition isdi¤erent from that in the case of market asymmetry, however, as we have shown thatrelative capital stock does not a¤ect a country�s tendency for discrimination. To seewhat drives our results, note that Home chooses stronger patent protection under NT(i.e. NTH ) as its human capital stock increases, since it is able to capture a larger shareof global pro�ts that result from innovation. In the meantime, Home �rms will receivemore total protection as its major component is NTH and the increase in NTH is notdiscounted by trade frictions �. As a result, the country with more human capital hasa stronger incentive for innovation under NT, a pattern that promotes innovation andwelfare. This helps explain why welfare under NT is higher when the distribution ofhuman capital stock is more unequal across countries (although welfare under NT is stilllower than that under discrimination).

Figure 3: Welfare di¤erence with asymmetric human capital stocks

5 Conclusion

The TRIPS agreement was controversial from the start. Developing countries foughthard against the inclusion of any multilateral rules on intellectual property, just asmajor developed countries put their considerable weight behind the opposite position. Inaddition to raising intellectual property protection in developing countries, TRIPS made

27

Page 28: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

it illegal for WTO members to discriminate against as well as across foreign nationalsvia the NT and MFN principles respectively.At �rst glance, the inclusion of these principles in TRIPS hardly seems worthy of

comment. After all, the idea of non-discrimination is the very foundation of today�smultilateral trading system. Yet, our analysis has shown that the desirable propertiesof NT in the context of policy instruments that a¤ect trade in goods (or market access)do not extend automatically to the domain of policies that determine the protection ofintellectual property.The key driving force behind our results is that incentives for innovation depend upon

the overall patent protection �rms receive in the global economy and the compositionof such protection matters only when international market access is hampered by tradefrictions. Absent such frictions, NT is inconsequential since what �rms lose abroad isfully compensated by what they gain at home. While we focus mostly on a two-countrysetting, the driving forces behind our analysis carry over to a multi-country scenario.Indeed, one can show the neutrality of NT under free trade holds for any number ofcountries as long as we restrict attention to interior solutions.When access to foreign markets is imperfect, the case for non-discrimination in patent

protection is even weaker. The intuition here is simple as it is undeniable: in the presenceof trade frictions, substituting domestic patent protection for foreign protection a¤ords�rms a higher level of e¤ective patent protection because exports are relatively lesspro�table than domestic sales. Furthermore, consumer welfare considerations reinforcethis argument: trade frictions make foreign innovation relatively less valuable to domesticconsumers in each country by making foreign goods costlier (or reducing the volume oftrade). As a result, in our model, imposing a NT constraint on national governmentsactually reduces welfare in the presence of trade frictions.Finally, it is important to recognize that our �ndings do not necessarily imply that

NT should not have been included as a fundamental principle in TRIPS. Rather, wesee our �ndings as highlighting one potential e¢ ciency cost of NT that arises from thewedge that trade frictions create between the incentive e¤ects of domestic and foreignpatent protection. NT may yield various bene�ts that are not captured by our model,such as lower enforcement and implementation costs, greater consistency across interna-tional trade agreements, and potentially lower costs of international coordination acrosscountries. Inclusion of these potential bene�ts of NT can make it more desirable thandiscrimination.

28

Page 29: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

6 Appendix

6.1 Supporting calculations

Here we show that@�i@ii

= �iMi

Miii +Mjji

Note that @�i@ii

= @�i@vi� @vi

@ii. Hence, @�i

@vi= @�i

@LIi

@LIi@vi

= F iL� @LIi@vi. Di¤erentiating the �rm�s

FOC viF iL = wi w.r.t vi we obtain F iL + viFiLL

@LIi@vi

= 0. This implies @LIi@vi

= � F iLviF iLL

.

Therefore, @�i@vi

= � F i2LviF iLL

= � F i2LviF iLL�i

� �i = vi�i where � � F i2L

F iLL�i. Also note that

@vi@ii

=Mi�. As a result,@�i@ii

= vi�i �Mi� =

�iMi

Miii+Mjji.

6.2 Proof of Proposition 1

We prove Proposition 1 under the more general CES research technology with � � 0.The generalization brings about the essential feature that responsiveness of innovationto patent protection may di¤er across countries, i.e. H 6= F . Taking account of thisfeature, we can modify (9) and (10) as follows

Cc � Cm � � = iMi

Miii +Mjji[(Cm � Cc)ii + CcT ] (A1)

Cc � Cm = jMi

Miij +Mjjj[(Cm � Cc)ij + CcT ] (A2)

where is no longer a constant. We may then add up (A1) for country i and (A2) forcountry j to get

2(Cc � Cm)� � = i

Miii +Mjji[(Cm � Cc)(Miii +Mjji) + (Mi +Mj)CcT ] (A3)

2(Cc � Cm)� � = j

Mjjj +Miij[Cm � Cc)(Mjjj +Miij) + (Mi +Mj)CcT ]. (A4)

It is easy to see that the right-hand sides of (A3) and (A4) are respectively monotonicfunctions of total protectionsMiii+Mjji andMjjj+Miij. And they must also beequal to each other. It follows that we must have Mi

�ii +Mj

�ji =Mi

�ii +Mj

�ji and

i = j = �. Hence (A1) and (A2) immediately imply that �ii >

�ij for i; j = H;F .

29

Page 30: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

6.3 Proof of Proposition 3

We �rst show (ii). Adding up the �rst-order conditions for i and j under NT yields

2(Cc � Cm)� � =

Mii +Mjj[(Cm � Cc)(Mii +Mjj) + (Mi +Mj)CcT ]. (A5)

Comparing (A5) with either (A3) or (A4) yields that i = j = = � and

PNT =MiNTi +Mj

NTj = P �, i; j = H;F

which establishes (ii).Now notice that since Cc � Cm � � < Cc � Cm � �i� < Cc � Cm, we must have

�Mi

P � [(Cm � Cc)�ii + CcT ] <

�Mi

PNT[(Cm � Cc)NTi + CcT ] <

�Mi

P � [(Cm � Cc)�ij + CcT ]

due to the �rst-order conditions for ii, i and ij. This implies

�ii > NTi > �ij, i; j = H;F

which is the desired result.Finally, when countries are symmetric we may focus on the symmetric equilibria such

that �ii = �jj,

�ij =

�ji under discrimination and

NTi = NTj under NT. Then (A3)

and (A5) together imply that

1

(�ii + �ij)[(Cm �Cc)(�ii +�ij) + 2CcT ] =

1

2NTi[(Cm �Cc)2NTi + 2CcT ], i; j = H;F

Monotonicity of both sides ensures that �ii + �ij = 2

NTi . �

6.4 Proof of Proposition 4

We prove this claim under the Cobb-Douglas technology, noting that it is easy to gener-alize under the assumption of CES. Again one can obtain the �rst-order conditions forcountry j by reversing i and j in (12) and (13). It is easy to show that

�ii(�) =CcT

(2 + )(Cc � Cm)� �

�(1 + )� ��(Cc � Cm � �)

(Cc � �Cm)

�and

�ij(�) =CcT

(2 + )(Cc � Cm)� �

�(1 + )(Cc � Cm)� �

(Cc � �Cm)� ��

30

Page 31: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

where � =Mj=Mi. It follows that �ii(�) decreases in � since��(Cc�Cm��)(Cc�yCm) is an increasing

function of �.Similarly, �ij(�) increases in � since

(1+ )(Cc�Cm)��(Cc��Cm) � �

�is an increasing function of

�. Moreover, it can be shown that

P �i (�) =Mi�ii(�) + �Mj

�ji(�) =

CcT

(2 + )(Cc � Cm)� �

�Mi +Mj

�(Cc � Cm)(Cc � �Cm)

�Clearly, since Mj

�(Cc�Cm)(Cc��Cm) is an increasing function of �, P

�i (�) is increasing in �. �

6.5 Proof of Proposition 5

We know that �(�) satis�es the following �rst-order condition:

2Cc�(1+�)Cm�� =

(1 + �)�(�)[(Cm�Cc)(1+�)�(�)+(1+�)CcT�(1��)�Cm�(�)].

(A6)Similarly, �d(�) and

�f (�) respectively satisfy the following �rst order conditions:

Cc � Cm � � =

�d(�) + ��f (�)

[(Cm � Cc)�d(�) + CcT ]

and

Cc � �Cm = �

�d(�) + ��f (�)

[(�Cm � Cc)�f (�) + CcT ]

Adding up the last two equations we obtain

2Cc�(1+�)Cm�� = "

1

�d(�) + ��f (�)

[(Cm � Cc)(�d(�) + ��f (�)) + (1 + �)CcT � (1� �)�Cm�f (�)#

(A7)Moreover, it can be shown that �(�) > �f (�), which further implies that (1 �

�)�Cm�(�) > (1� �)�Cm�f (�).26 Since the right-hand sides of (A6) and (A7) must be

equal, and since both are decreasing functions of d(�) + �f (�) and (1 + �)(�), wemay conclude that

�d(�) + ��f (�) > (1 + �)

�(�)

Multiplying both sides by the common market size M , we get

M(�d(�) + ��f (�)) > M(1 + �)

�(�).

�26Note that �d(�) > �f (�) in any interior equilibrium. Further, if

�f (�) � �(�), then �d(�) >

�f (�) � �(�) and this implies �d(�) + ��f (�) > (1 + �)�(�). One can use the latter inequality to

show that (A6) and (A7) cannot hold simultaneously. As a result, we must have �(�) > �f (�) inequilibrium.

31

Page 32: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

6.6 Proof of Proposition 6

We �rst show that

@WWD(�)

@ii� 1�

@WWD(�)

@ji=�iMi

(1� �)Cc�

> 0 for all � < 1

We have

@WWD(�)

@ii=�iMi

�[

Pi(�)[(Cm�Cc)Pi(�)+(Mi+Mj)CCT�(1��)MjCcji]�(Cc�Cm��)]

(A8)and

1

@WWD(�)

@ji=

�iMi

�[

Pi(�)[(Cm � Cc)Pi(�) + (Mi +Mj)CCT � (1� �)MjCcji]

�(Cc � Cm � �)�(1� �)�

Cc] (A9)

Subtracting the second equation from the �rst yields the desired result.First order conditions (A8) and (A9) simply say that for any country the net marginal

bene�t of domestic protection is higher than that of protection received from abroad. Itfollows that global e¢ ciency requires each country to be protected through its domesticmarket whenever possible. Foreign protection may be needed (which depends on modelparameters such as ) when domestic protection has hit the boundary T . Assumingforeign protection is always interior (i.e. cannot be too large), we have wji <

wii . In

particular, wji = 0 whenever wii is an interior solution.

To show that each country necessarily practices discrimination (i.e. wij < wii), let us

di¤erentiate several cases. First, the conclusion is obvious if both wii and wjj are interior

solutions. Second, when wii = wjj = T discrimination must exist as foreign protection

is not at the same corner. Finally, suppose wii = T and wjj < T , so that wji � 0.Suppose wji > 0 (otherwise we are done). To show that wjj > wji, note that underCES technology with � � 0, we must have P �i (�) � P �j (�) because country i resorts toforeign protection that is more costly. This implies Mi

wii +Mj

wji � Mj

wjj +Mi

wij,

which is reduced to Miwii +Mj

wji �Mj

wjj (as

wij = 0). It follows that we must have

wji < wjj for the inequality to hold.

32

Page 33: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

References

[1] Bagwell, Kyle and R. Staiger. 1999. �An Economic Theory of GATT.�AmericanEconomic Review 89(1), 215-248.

[2] Bagwell, Kyle and R.W. Staiger. 2002. The Economics of the World Trading System.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

[3] Bond, Eric. 2005. �The Economics of International Trade Agreements and DisputeSettlement with Intellectual Property Rights,� in International Public Goods andTransfer of Technology under a Globalized Intellectual Property Regime, eds. KeithE. Maskus and Jerome H. Reichman, New York: Cambridge University Press.

[4] Goldstein, Paul A. 2001. International Copyright: Principles, Law, and Practice.New York: Oxford University Press.

[5] Grossman, Gene M. and Lai, Edwin L. C. 2004. �International Protection of Intel-lectual Property.�American Economic Review 94(5), 1635-653.

[6] Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanan. 1991. Innovation and Growth in theGlobal Economy, Cambridge, MIT press.

[7] Helpman, Elhanan. 1993. �Innovation, Imitation, and Intellectual Property Rights.�Econometrica 61, 1247-1280.

[8] Horn, Henrik. 2006. �National Treatment in the GATT.�American Economic Re-view 96(1), 394-404.

[9] Horn, Henrik, Giovanni, Maggi and Staiger, Robert, W. 2010. �Trade Agreementsas Endogenously Incomplete Contracts.�American Economic Review 100 (1), 394-419.

[10] Lai, Edwin L.-C. 2007. �Theory of International Policy Coordination in Protectionof Ideas,�Chapter 11 in Keith E. Maskus (ed.) Intellectual Property, Growth andTrade: Frontiers of Economics and Globalization, volume 2, 357-389.

[11] Lai, Edwin L.-C. and Yan, Isabel K.M. 2013. �Would Global Patent Protectionbe Too Weak Without International Coordination?�Journal of International Eco-nomics 89 (1), 42-54.

33

Page 34: The case for non-discrimination in the international ...

[12] Lerner, Josh. 2002. �150 years of Patent Protection.�American Economic Review92, 221-25.

[13] Mai, Joseph and Stoyanov, Andrey. 2014. �Home Country Bias in the Legal System:Empirical Evidence from the Intellectual Property Rights Protection in Canada.�Mimeo.

[14] Maskus, Keith E. and Penubarti, Mohan. 1995. �How Trade-Related Are Intellec-tual Property Rights?�Journal of International Economics 39(3-4), 227-248.

[15] Maskus, Keith E. 2000. Intellectual Property Rights in the Global Economy. Wash-ington DC: Institute for International Economics.

[16] Maskus, Keith E. and Yang, Le. 2013. �The Impacts of Post-TRIPS Patent Re-forms on the Structure of Exports.�Discussion paper 13030, Research Institute ofEconomy, Trade and Industry.

[17] Nordhaus, William D. 1969. Invention, Growth and Welfare: A Theoretical Treat-ment of Technological Change. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

[18] Park, Jee-Hyeong. 2000.�International Trade Agreements Between Countries ofAsymmetric Size.�Journal of International Economics 50, 473-95.

[19] Rivera-Batiz, Luis A. and Romer, Paul M. 1991. �Economic Integration and En-dogenous Growth.�Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2), 531-55.

[20] Scotchmer, Suzanne. 2004. �The Political Economy of Intellectual PropertyTreaties.�Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 20(2), 415-37.

[21] Saggi, Kamal and Sara, Nese. 2008. �National Treatment at the WTO: The Roles ofProduct and Country Heterogeneity.�International Economic Review 49(4), 1365-94.

[22] Webster, Elizabeth, Jensen, Paul. H. and Palangkaraya, Alfons. 2014.�Patent Ex-amination Outcomes and the National Treatment Principle.�Rand Journal of Eco-nomics, forthcoming.

[23] World Trade Organization. 2011. World Trade Report 2011: The WTO and Pref-erential Trade Agreements: From Co-Existence to Coherence.

34