Thailand Crisis Overload

download Thailand Crisis Overload

of 22

Transcript of Thailand Crisis Overload

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    1/22

    Thailand's Crisis Overload

    Peter Warr

    Southeast Asian Affairs, Volume 2009, pp. 334-354 (Article)

    Published by Institute of Southeast Asian Studies

    For additional information about this article

    Access provided by University of York (7 Sep 2013 06:09 GMT)

    http://muse.jhu.edu/journals/saa/summary/v2009/2009.warr.html

    http://muse.jhu.edu/journals/saa/summary/v2009/2009.warr.htmlhttp://muse.jhu.edu/journals/saa/summary/v2009/2009.warr.html
  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    2/22

    Southeast Asian Affairs 2009

    PETER WARR is John Crawford Professor of Agricultural Economics at the Australian

    National University (ANU). He is also Convener of the Arndt-Corden Division of Econo-

    mics and Director of the National Thai Studies Centre at ANU.

    THAILANDS CRISIS OVERLOAD

    PETER WARR

    Introduction

    Thailand has endured a succession of recent crises: the Asian financial crisisof 199799, originating with the collapse of its own currency and reducing

    investor confidence for the entire decade since; the terrible tsunami of December

    2004; outbreaks of SARS and Avian Influenza; rural drought; an interminable

    insurrection in its southernmost Muslim provinces, producing more than 4,000

    deaths; and growing concern about the consequences for Thailand of global

    climate change. As if all that were not enough, in 2008 an additional double

    crisis overwhelmed the country: a self-inflicted internal political crisis deepening

    social divisions within the country and culminating in the closure of Bangkoks

    international airport in late 2008; and the repercussions of the most serious global

    financial crisis since the Great Depression of the 1930s.

    Thailands immediate prospects are somber, along with the rest of East

    Asia. In contemplating this depressing story it is easy to lose long-term per-

    spective. Despite the serious problems, the quality of everyday life in Thailand

    has continued to improve over several decades and poverty incidence has

    maintained its long-term decline. Thailand has already achieved essentially all

    of its Millennium Development Goals, well ahead of the target date of 2015,

    while most developing countries lag far behind schedule. The current crisis willundoubtedly produce a pronounced economic contraction and some worsening

    of poverty incidence. No one knows how long-lasting this episode of deglobal-

    ization will be, but it will be temporary. It should be seen in the context of

    long term economic improvement which can be expected to continue once the

    global crisis subsides.

    http://bookshop.iseas.edu.sg/
  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    3/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 335

    Accordingly, this chapter turns first to Thailands current twin crises: the

    internal political crisis and the worldwide financial crisis. It then places these

    events in longer term perspective by reviewing Thailands long term economic

    experience and in particular the impact of the last serious economic crisis to affect

    Thailand the Asian financial crisis of 199799. To see what is likely to happen

    as a result of the present contraction it is helpful to look at what happened during

    previous economic downturns.

    The Internal Political Crisis

    Thailands ongoing political conflict is about a challenge to the social dominance

    of the countrys traditional elite the educated Bangkok middle class, including

    the civil service, the military, and the aristocracy. The challenge arose from a

    group of political entrepreneurs who had successfully appealed to the massive

    rural electorate.

    The most important of these political entrepreneurs was Thaksin Shinawatra,

    a clever business tycoon elected Prime Minister by large majorities in 2001 and

    again in 2005. Thaksin was elected by offering populist policies to the rural

    majority. But he was deposed by a military coup in September 2006, allegedly

    because of corruption and because his government was said (by the generals)to be disloyal to the monarchy. Thaksin denied any such disloyalty, but while

    he remained in exile after the coup, a court decision banned him from political

    activity in Thailand and disbanded his Thai Rak Thai political party for alleged

    electoral fraud. In addition, Thaksin was convicted in absentia for misusing his

    powers while Prime Minister in support of his wifes business interests.

    In the subsequent elections of January 2008 the Peoples Power Party

    (PPP), a successor to Thaksins banned Thai Rak Thai, won office with right-

    wing veteran politician Samak Sundaravej as its leader. Opponents of Thaksin

    and his allies were enraged. They now identified themselves by wearing yellow

    shirts, the royal colour, and ironically called themselves the Peoples Alliance for

    Democracy (PAD). They clashed openly and violently with Thaksins supporters,

    now identified at their rallies by red shirts. In late 2008 the PADs protests against

    the PPP government became increasingly strident, justified mainly by the claim

    that Samak and the PPP were mere proxies for the fugitive Thaksin.

    While in office, Samak had continued to host a television cooking programme

    and received payment for doing so. In September, the full bench of the Constitutional

    Court ruled that it was unconstitutional for Samak to maintain his televisioncareer while Prime Minister, and disqualified him from office. The ruling PPP

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    4/22

    336 Peter Warr

    promptly replaced him as Prime Minister with Thaksins brother-in-law, Somchai

    Wongsawat. The PAD were even further enraged.

    On 25 November the PAD occupied Bangkoks Suvarnabhumi International

    Airport, causing its closure and demanding that Somchai step down. The ensuing

    chaos caused great damage to Thailands tourist industry and to commerce dependent

    on air freight. The airport siege ended after eight days, on 2 December, when

    the Constitutional Court voted to disband the three government coalition parties,

    including PPP, again for electoral fraud.

    To the amazement of almost everyone, some former members of the disbanded

    PPP agreed to ally themselves with the opposition Democrat Party, allowing its

    leader Abhisit Vejjajiva to become Prime Minister. The PAD had previously saidit would accept no other premier than Abhisit. They were thus able to claim

    the political outcome as a victory for their tactics and the banning of PPP as a

    vindication of their opposition to the government on the grounds of its electoral

    corruption.

    Behind the political soap opera lies something basic: a dispute about the

    meaning of democracy, or at least the form that democracy should take in Thailand.

    The essence of the PADs objections to Thaksin and his proxies was not just

    that they had acquired power through corrupt electoral practices, a claim that was

    seemingly vindicated by the court decisions against Thai Rak Thai and PPP. More

    fundamentally, it was a challenge to the principle of one-person-one-vote.

    Thaksin had demonstrated a capacity first to enrich himself massively by

    manipulating government telecommunications regulators and then to use this

    wealth to advance himself politically. He was then able to use this new political

    power to enrich himself, his family and his closest supporters, even further. But

    he could not attain political power without mass support. His political discovery

    was to find a way to harness the power of the rural electorate. The secret was to

    promise them handouts at the expense of the public purse and then to deliver onthose promises. He did both of those things. Thaksin remains greatly admired by

    the rural masses, the basis of his political support. These groups recognize the

    economic benefits that Thaksin brought to them while in power and could not

    care less about his alleged corruption or his personal greed.

    Thaksin frightens the traditional elite and is despised by them. Contrary to

    their name, the PAD is essentially a conservative middle class movement who

    desire a return, at least partially, towards Thailands more authoritarian past. They

    perceived the electoral successes of Thaksin, Samak and their allies as having

    demonstrated the failure of electoral democracy because it threatened the dominant

    position of the elite: the army, the civil service and the aristocracy. They have

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    5/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 337

    seen what electoral democracy can deliver and they do not like it. They would

    have opposed Thaksins right to govern whether there had really been electoral

    fraud, as claimed, or not.During their opposition to Samaks government, the PAD leaders demanded

    that Samak step down and two basic changes be made. First, the proportion of

    the Parliament that is elected should be limited to 30 per cent, the rest appointed

    by the elite. Second, they demanded the possibility of a Prime Minister who was

    not an elected member of Parliament. The PAD pointed out that the two most

    respected Prime Ministers of recent decades, Prem Tinsulanonda and Anand

    Panyarachun, were not elected but appointed by the King. The position of the

    PAD was thus a rejection of one-person-one-vote electoral democracy. Beneaththis is a long-standing urban disdain for the competence of the poorly educated

    rural people who elected Thaksin and Samak. Thaksin was seen as the cunning

    politician who had learned how to manipulate them. It is revealing that the PAD

    website includes a statement employing the term low class to describe their red-

    shirted opponents. There is an undeniable social class dimension to the conflict.

    Crudely put, for many of the PAD leaders and supporters, Thaksins rural voters

    were ignorant buffaloes who should not be permitted to determine the leadership

    and direction of the country. That role rightfully belonged to the elite.

    Since Abhisits rise to power the global financial crisis has dominated public

    attention and the underlying domestic political conflict has rightly been sidelined.

    But when new elections are eventually held, Thaksins allies proxies or not

    may well win again. Such is the magnitude of their rural support. Once that

    happens, the crisis resumes. Thailand is groping, sometimes stumbling, towards

    a form of democracy that suits its own circumstances. The underlying conflict is

    deep and will not be resolved easily.

    The Global Financial Crisis

    The financial crisis is proving to be more serious than almost anyone imagined.

    Credit is the lubricant facilitating the operation of the global trading system.

    The supply of credit rests on the existence of trust, especially among financial

    institutions, that debts can and will be honoured. The crisis has destroyed that trust.

    Everyone is afraid of lending, for fear that the borrower will turn out to be unable

    to repay. The global supply of credit has thus evaporated and international trade

    has severely contracted. Export dependent economies such as Thailand are alreadysuffering and the prospects are for worse problems to follow. Deglobalization is

    the latest grim addition to economic jargon. The recent economic forecasts of

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    6/22

    338 Peter Warr

    Asian governments have proven to be uniformly too optimistic and, as we will

    see, Thailand is no exception. As the global crisis deepens there is a continuing

    danger of a protectionist response which could greatly deepen the economic

    contraction, as it did in the 1930s with disastrous consequences.

    The mode of transmission of the crisis to Thailand is primarily not through

    its financial institutions. Fortunately, their direct exposure to the failing U.S. and

    European financial institutions is small. The problem similarly does not arise

    from bottlenecks on the supply side of the Thai economy. The transmission is

    through a contraction in the demand for Thailands output, particularly its exports.

    Along with many of its Southeast Asian neighbours, Thailand has benefited from

    globalization through expansion of its exports. The downside is vulnerability toa contraction in export demand, and this is what has occurred. Export demand

    corresponds to an extraordinary 75 per cent of Thailands output. In January 2009,

    the year-on-year contraction in Thailands exports was 26.5 per cent, accounting

    by itself for a 20 per cent contraction in aggregate demand. Consumption and

    especially private investment demand have also been negatively affected, but

    export demand is the main story.

    Why is the contraction in exports so large? The contractions of GDP in

    the U.S. and Europe are currently of the order of 2 to 4 per cent. How does

    this become a decline in demand for imports from developing countries of up

    to ten times that magnitude? The reason is that the financing of working capital

    in the advanced economies has become very expensive and in some cases it

    is unobtainable. Monetary authorities in the advanced countries are pumping

    funds into the financial system as rapidly as they can, but the deterioration of

    the intermediation function of the financial system means that this does not yet

    translate into availability of credit to business enterprises that need it. Financial

    institutions are afraid to lend to them. Retail and wholesale businesses respond to

    expensive or unobtainable working capital by cutting the size of their inventories.While they attempt to achieve lower levels of inventories their demand for new

    product may contract to zero.

    The bad news is that a radical cut in the desired level of inventories magnifies

    the contraction in the demand for new product. But the good news is that this very

    large inventory component of the contraction of demand is temporary. Inventories

    will not contract to zero. When they have reached their lower desired levels, the

    contraction in the demand for new product will abate. The new level of demand may

    be lower than the previous level, taking into account the lower level of consumer

    and investor spending in the advanced economies, but it will be larger than the

    level temporarily observed during a period of radical inventory downsizing.

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    7/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 339

    What can Thailand do about it? So far as the contraction in export demand

    is concerned, not much; all that can be done is to ride out the storm as well as

    possible. But there is the scope to expand other components of aggregate demand.

    The candidates are: increasing private consumer spending (57 per cent of GDP);

    increasing private investment spending (19 per cent of GDP); reducing import

    spending (75 per cent of GDP); and increasing government spending (24 per cent

    of GDP). Consumers and investors are rattled by the economic news and there is

    limited scope to induce them to spend more in such an uncertain environment.

    Both consumer spending and investment spending are declining, not increasing,

    and there is very little the government can do about it.

    If import demand could be reduced, that would leave more scope for domesticproducers to take up the resulting slack in demand and this is why protection

    is so attractive politically in times of economic downturns. But that would be a

    great mistake. Protectionism is like cocaine. It provides an immediate stimulus,

    but this short-run boost is achieved only at the expense of undermining the

    determinants of long-term economic performance. And is addictive; once rates of

    import protection increase it is very difficult to get rid of them later.

    During the Great Depression of the 1930s increasing protectionism worldwide

    worsened the magnitude of the global contraction. In this, the Congress of the

    United States was an ignominious leader. The Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of

    1930 set in train an increase in global protection that contributed to the depth

    of the Depression and the circumstances leading to World War II. Through its

    Buy American clause inserted into President Obamas current financial bailout

    package, the United States Congress has revealed to the world how little it has

    absorbed from its own history. It is imperative that the rest of the world not follow

    suit and succumb to the temptation to increase protection. Fortunately, the Thai

    government of Abhisit Vejjajiva shows every sign of being a constructive regional

    leader in this respect. Prime Minister Abhisits remarks at the February 2009summit of ASEAN leaders were encouraging in their recognition of the dangers of

    a resort to protectionism. But if the contraction proves to be long-lasting, can

    this resolve be maintained? The question arises as much for Thailand as for any

    other country.

    That leaves government spending. The arithmetic is simple. Export demand

    is three times the size of government spending. If export demand contracts by

    10 per cent, then to make up the slack in aggregate demand, government spending

    has to expand by 30 per cent, and so forth. To make up for a 26 per cent contraction

    in export demand, government spending would need to expand by 78 per cent.

    Nothing like that is possible.

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    8/22

    340 Peter Warr

    There is scope for public debt to be increased and inflation is not currently

    a serious concern. These are not the immediate problems. The problem is the

    logistics of expanding public expenditure so quickly and by such a large amount.There is said to be a portfolio of infrastructure projects waiting on the shelf for

    government approval, but this cannot be sufficient to expand spending enough

    to avert a contraction of output. This is a particular problem in an environment

    where corruption in public spending is a matter of great scrutiny. The same

    issue arises in Indonesia. Public officials are understandably reluctant to expand

    procurement quickly, for fear of making mistakes that could render them liable

    later to criminal charges of corruption or malfeasance.

    The government has announced its intention to expand public spending to

    mitigate the impact of the contraction in aggregate demand resulting from the

    crisis. That is desirable and it will reduce the magnitude of the recession that

    results. But there seems no possibility that it will be sufficient to prevent negative

    economic growth during 2009 and possibly 2010.

    Unfortunately, the governments own economic projections do not convey

    this point because they are based on unduly optimistic assumptions about almost

    all components of aggregate demand, especially export demand. A report from

    the governments economic planning agency, the National Economic and Social

    Development Board (NESDB), released on 23 February 2009, revealed that duringthe fourth quarter of 2008 real GDP had declined by 4.3 per cent, leading to

    growth for the full year of 2008 of 2.6 per cent.1 The report also projects growth

    for 2009 in the major categories of aggregate demand: private consumption

    (2.2 per cent), private investment (3.0 per cent), exports (6.2 per cent) and

    imports (5.4 per cent). The implications of these projections are summarized in

    Table 1.

    Table 1 shows, in column (1), various illustrative target growth rates for real

    GDP constructed by the present author. Columns (2) to (5) show, respectively, the

    real growth rates of private consumption, public investment, exports and imports

    projected by the NESDB. The final column (column (6)) shows the present authors

    calculation of the change in public spending that would be required to achieve

    the target growth rate of GDP (column (1)) given the NESDB assumptions in

    columns (2) to (5). According to these calculations, to achieve zero growth of

    real GDP virtually no expansion of public expenditure would be needed. Growth

    of 5 per cent could be achieved with an expansion of public spending of only

    20 per cent.

    The problem is that almost all of the NESDB assumptions seem overlyoptimistic. Table 2 varies these assumptions in only one respect. The projected

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    9/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 341

    TAB

    LE1

    Thailand:R

    equiredGrowthinGovern

    mentExpendituretoMain

    tainTarget

    GDPGrowthRates(%)with

    ExportGrowthasForeca

    st

    Target

    GDP

    growth

    rate

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    in

    priva

    teconsumpt

    ion

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    in

    priva

    teinves

    tmen

    t

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    inexport

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    in

    import

    Requ

    ire

    dc

    hange

    in

    pu

    blicexpen

    diture

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    0

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    6

    .2

    5

    .4

    0

    .4

    2

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    6

    .2

    5

    .4

    7

    .9

    3

    .5

    2.2

    3

    .0

    6

    .2

    5

    .4

    14

    .2

    5

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    6

    .2

    5

    .4

    20

    .5

    Note:

    Assume

    dGDP

    shares:priva

    teconsump

    tion

    57percen

    t;priva

    teinves

    tmen

    t19percen

    t;exp

    orts

    75percen

    t;imports

    75percen

    t;

    pu

    blic

    expen

    diture

    24percen

    t.

    Source

    :Au

    thorsca

    lcu

    lations,

    base

    do

    npro

    jec

    tions

    from

    Na

    tiona

    lEconom

    ican

    dSoc

    ialDeve

    lopment

    Board

    2009

    .

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    10/22

    342 Peter Warr

    TABLE2

    Thailand:R

    equiredGrowthinGovern

    mentExpendituretoMain

    tainTarget

    GDPGrowthR

    ates(%)withExportGrowthasinJanuary2008to

    January2009

    Target

    GDP

    growth

    rate

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    in

    priva

    teconsumpt

    ion

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    in

    priva

    teinves

    tmen

    t

    Forecas

    tc

    hange

    inexport

    Foreca

    stc

    hange

    in

    import

    Requ

    ire

    dc

    hange

    in

    pu

    blicexpen

    diture

    (1

    )

    (2)

    (3)

    (4)

    (5)

    (6)

    2

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    26

    .5

    5

    .4

    54

    .8

    0

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    26

    .5

    5

    .4

    63

    .1

    2

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    26

    .5

    5

    .4

    71

    .4

    3

    .5

    2.2

    3

    .0

    26

    .5

    5

    .4

    77

    .7

    5

    .0

    2.2

    3

    .0

    26

    .5

    5

    .4

    83

    .9

    Note:A

    ssume

    dGDPs

    hares:as

    inTable

    1.

    Source:

    Au

    thorsca

    lcu

    lations,

    base

    donpro

    jec

    tions

    from

    Na

    tiona

    lEconom

    ican

    dSoc

    ialDeve

    lopment

    Board

    2009

    .

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    11/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 343

    growth rate of exports actually observed between January 2008 and January

    2009, 26.5 per cent, is substituted for the NESDBs projection, 6.2 per cent.

    The impact is dramatic. To achieve zero growth of aggregate demand, an

    impossible expansion of public spending of 63 per cent would be required. To

    keep the decline of real GDP to no more than 2 per cent a 55 per cent expansion

    of public spending would still be needed. These growth rates of public spending

    are not feasible, so if the actual contraction of exports during 2009 turns out

    to be anything like the January 2008 to January 2009 contraction, a large

    contraction in GDP is inevitable. The Thai governments assumptions seem unduly

    optimistic, wrongly implying that it is possible for Thailand to avoid a recession

    during 2009.In any case, maintaining aggregate demand is not the same thing as

    maintaining employment. The export industries releasing employees are more

    labour-intensive than the average, meaning that more workers are laid off per

    million baht of output contraction in these industries than would be the case for

    a uniform contraction of all industries of the same money value. In other words,

    the proportional contraction in formal sector employment resulting from the

    export contraction will be substantially greater than the proportional contraction in

    GDP.2 But public investment tends to be more capital-intensive than the average,

    especially the large infrastructure projects sitting on the governments shelf waiting

    for implementation. One million bahts worth of this kind of spending generates

    far fewer jobs than are lost through a million baht contraction in export demand.

    To maintain employment, the expansion in public investment would thus have to

    be even larger than the above calculations indicate.

    A Longer Term Perspective

    Long Term Growth and the Asian Financial CrisisThailands long-term growth performance is described in Figure 1, showing the

    level of real GDP per capita in each year (vertical bars) and its growth rate (solid

    line) for the period 1951 to 2008. The figure identifies four periods of Thailands

    recent economic history: I Pre-boom (until 1986); II boom (1987 to 1996);

    III crisis (1997 to 1999); and IV recovery (2000 to 2008). Over the period

    1968 to 1986, the average annual growth rate of Thailands real GNP was 6.7 per

    cent (almost 5 per cent per person), compared with an average of 2.4 per cent

    for low and middle-income countries.3 Then, over the decade 1987 to 1996, the

    Thai economy boomed, growing at 9.5 per cent in real terms. Over this decade,

    the Thai economy was the fastest growing in the world.

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    12/22

    344 Peter Warr

    The crisis of 199799 rudely interrupted this boom. The economic damage

    done and the hardship that resulted were both substantial. The crisis eroded

    some of the gains from the economic growth that had been achieved during the

    long period of economic expansion, but it did not erase them. At the low point

    of the crisis in 1998, the level of GDP per capita was almost 14 per cent below

    its level only two years earlier, in 1996. Nevertheless, because of the sustained

    growth that had preceded the crisis, this reduced level of 1998 was still higher

    than it had been only five years before that, in 1993, and was seven times itslevel in 1951.

    Since the crisis, Thailands economic recovery has been moderate. The rate

    of growth of real GDP has been somewhat below its long-term trend rate and

    it was not until 2003 that the level of real GDP per capita had recovered to its

    pre-crisis level of 1996. Foreign direct investment has declined dramatically since

    1998 and private domestic investment has remained sluggish. Despite the slower

    than expected recovery, in 2006 the level of real economic output per person was

    19 per cent above its 1996 pre-crisis level and almost 10 times its level 55 years

    earlier. The average annual rate of growth of real GDP per person over this entire

    period of five-and-a-half decades was 4.2 per cent.

    FIGURE 1

    Thailand: Real GDP Per Capita and Growth of Real GDP Per Capita,

    19512008

    Source: Authors calculations, using data from NESDB, Bangkok.

    0

    20,000

    40,000

    60,000

    80,000

    100,000

    120,000

    140,000

    1951

    1953

    1955

    1957

    1959

    1961

    1963

    1965

    1967

    1969

    1971

    1973

    1975

    1977

    1979

    1981

    1983

    1985

    1987

    1989

    1991

    1993

    1995

    1997

    1999

    2001

    2003

    2005

    2007

    Level of real

    GDP per capita

    15

    10

    5

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    Growth rate

    of real GDP

    per capita

    Level of real GDP per capita at 2003 prices, baht, per year LHS axis

    Growth rate of real GDP per capita at 2003 prices, per cent, per year RHS axis

    II IIII IV

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    13/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 345

    Figure 2 places this experience in a comparative Southeast Asian perspec-

    tive. Data on real GDP are presented for Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia and

    the Philippines. All data are indexed such that GDP per capita in 1970 = 100.Booms occurred in Thailand, Malaysia, and Indonesia from the mid-1980s to

    the mid-1990s, interrupted by the Asian financial crisis. Thailands boom was

    the largest, but most other East Asian countries (except the Philippines) were

    not far behind.

    As Figure 2 shows, in 199799 serious contractions occurred in Thailand,

    Malaysia and Indonesia. Relative to 1996, Thailands initial contraction was the

    most severe. Along with Indonesia, its contraction also lasted the longest. The

    199799 crisis in all three of these countries was the collapse of the export

    oriented investment booms they had shared over the preceding decade.4 For all

    these countries, the crisis erased a fraction of the gains experienced during the

    preceding boom, but definitely not all of those gains. The Philippines had not

    experienced the boom and the Asian crisis had little discernable impact.

    FIGURE 2

    Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand:

    Real GDP Per Capita, 19602008(Indexed to 1970 = 100)

    Note: Real GDP per capita is calculated using US$ at constant 2000 prices.

    Source: Calculated from World Bank, World Development Indicators, various issues.

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    1960

    1962

    1964

    1966

    1968

    1970

    1972

    1974

    1976

    1978

    1980

    1982

    1984

    1986

    1988

    1990

    1992

    1994

    1996

    1998

    2000

    2002

    2004

    2006

    Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Thailand

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    14/22

    346 Peter Warr

    Why has Thailands recovery been so slow? The crisis was a contraction

    in aggregate demand, rather than a contraction in productive capacity. Labour

    and capital were underutilized because there was insufficient demand for Thai

    output. Where did this contraction in demand come from? Table 3 shows that

    it came from private investment demand. The upper section of the table shows

    the composition of expenditure on GDP in Thailand during the pre-crisis boom

    TABLE 3

    Thailand, Indonesia and Malaysia: Contributions to Expenditure on GDP,

    19872007

    Country/Period Consumption Investment Government Net exports Total

    Thailand

    Pre-crisis(198796)

    Crisis(199799)

    Post-crisis(200007)

    54.8

    54.0

    57.6

    38.9

    27.0

    26.0

    9.9

    10.5

    11.3

    5.0

    8.5

    5.3

    100

    100

    100

    Indonesia

    Pre-crisis(198796)

    Crisis(199799)

    Post-crisis(200007)

    55.0

    65.0

    62.1

    27.8

    24.5

    23.7

    9.1

    6.5

    7.7

    0.4

    5.0

    6.6

    100

    100

    100

    Malaysia

    Pre-crisis(198796)

    Crisis(199799)

    Post-crisis

    (200007)

    48.8

    43.5

    46.1

    37.2

    35.0

    23.0

    12.8

    10.5

    12.6

    1.2

    11.5

    18.3

    100

    100

    100

    Source: Authors calculations, using data from World Bank, World Development Indicators,various issues.

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    15/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 347

    (1987 to 1996), the crisis (1997 to 1999) and the post-crisis recovery period

    (2000 to 2007). During the crisis, the share of investment in GDP collapsed by

    13 percentage points. Investor confidence was severely damaged by the events

    surrounding the crisis and during the post-crisis recovery period, this share did

    not recover sufficiently to restore Thailands long-term rate of growth.

    This problem of reduced investor confidence following the Asian financial

    crisis was not unique to Thailand. Table 3 shows similar calculations for two other

    crisis-affected Southeast Asian economies, Indonesia and Malaysia. The pattern is

    similar. Finally, Figure 3 shows annual data on the share of investment in GDP

    in five crisis-affected East Asian economies: Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia, the

    Philippines, and Korea. Although the contraction of private investment in Thailand

    is at least as large as any other (Malaysia is similar), the figure shows that the

    problem of sluggish post-crisis recovery of investment was shared by several

    East Asian economies. It would not seem appropriate to look for country-specific

    causes. The decline of investor confidence was region-wide, at least among the

    countries seriously affected by the crisis. The crisis showed the possibility that

    investors could be bankrupted by macroeconomic events over which they have

    FIGURE 3

    East Asia: Investment Shares of GDP, 19932007

    Source: Authors calculations, using data from World Bank, World Development Indicators,various issues.

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    Thailand Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Korea

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    16/22

    348 Peter Warr

    no control and where they have little or no forewarning. The main point is that

    a collapse of private investment was the means by which the crisis impacted

    on each of these countries and that once investor confidence had been damagedrestoring it was a difficult and slow process.

    Poverty Incidence and Inequality

    Is economic growth really so important? Do the poor actually benefit from it, or

    only the rich? If it is the latter, does a contraction in growth really matter? The

    following discussion draws upon the official poverty estimates produced by the

    Thai governments National Economic and Social Development Board (NESDB),

    which, like all other available poverty estimates, are based upon the household

    incomes collected in the National Statistical Offices Socio-Economic Survey

    (SES) household survey data. Despite their imperfections, these are the only data

    available covering a long time period. These survey data have been collected

    since 1962. The early data were based on small samples, but their reliability has

    improved steadily, and since 1988 the raw data have been available in electronic

    form. A difficulty in comparing these data over time is that the poverty line has

    been revised several times, changing upwards the real purchasing power that it

    represents. Figure 4 summarizes the authors attempts to compile a long-term serieson poverty incidence, based on a consistent poverty line one held constant in

    real purchasing power from 1962 to 2007.

    Figure 4 focuses on the familiar headcount measure of poverty incidence:

    the percentage of a particular population whose household incomes per person

    fall below the poverty line. Until recently, the SES data were classified according

    to residential location in the categories municipal areas, sanitary districts, and

    villages. These correspond to inner urban (historical urban boundaries), outer urban

    (newly established urban areas), and rural areas, respectively. Poverty incidence

    is highest in the rural areas, followed by outer urban, and lowest in the inner

    urban areas. When these data are recalculated in terms of the share of each of

    these residential areas in the total number of poor people and then the share of

    the total population, as in the last two rows of the table, respectively, a striking

    point emerges. In 2006, rural areas accounted for 86 per cent of the total number

    of poor people but only 64 per cent of the total population.

    Figure 4 also shows the Gini coefficient of inequality. This index potentially

    takes values between zero and one, with higher values indicating greater inequality.

    The index for Thailand rose significantly over the 45 years shown. Combinedwith the reduction in absolute poverty, which occurred at the same time, this

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    17/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 349

    means that the real incomes of the poor increased with economic growth, but the

    incomes of the rich increased even faster. The data reveal a considerable decline in

    poverty incidence up to 1996, a moderate increase to 1998, and a further increase

    over the following two years. Over the eight years from 1988 to 1996, measured

    poverty incidence declined by an enormous 21.4 per cent of the population, anaverage rate of decline in poverty incidence of 2.7 percentage points per year.

    FIGURE 4

    Thailand: Poverty Incidence and Inequality, 19622007

    Notes: Poverty incidence means the number of poor within a reference population groupexpressed as a proportion of the total population of that group. The headcount measure ofaggregate poverty incidence is the percentage of the total population whose incomes fallbelow a poverty line held constant over time in real terms; rural poverty is the percentage of

    the rural population whose incomes fall below a poverty line held constant over time in realterms, and so forth. Poverty share means the number of poor within a reference populationgroup expressed as a proportion of the total number of poor within the whole population.Population share means the population of a reference group expressed as a proportion of thetotal population of that group. The data shown are identical to data published by the NationalEconomic and Social Development Board (NESDB) for the years 1988 to 2006, except thatthe published data for Municipal Areas and Sanitary Districts have been aggregated to anurban category using their respective population shares in the total for urban areas (the sumof the two) as weights. The data for the earlier years have been spliced together with thisseries from published sources so that the resulting series matches the NESDB series for theyear 1988. In accordance with the practice of the Thai government statisticians, both povertyincidence and inequality are based on incomes rather than expenditures in these data. Highervalues of the Gini coefficient indicate greater inequality.

    Source: Authors calculations, using data provided by the NESDB, Bangkok.

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    90

    100

    1962

    1969

    1975

    1981

    1986

    1988

    1990

    1992

    1994

    1996

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2004

    2006

    2007

    Povertyincidence(%)

    0.00

    0.10

    0.20

    0.30

    0.40

    0.50

    0.60

    0.70

    Ginicoefficient

    Total Rural Urban Gini

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    18/22

    350 Peter Warr

    That is, each year, on average 2.7 per cent of the population moved from incomes

    below the poverty line to incomes above it. Over the ensuing two years ending in

    1998 poverty incidence increased by 1.5 per cent of the population. Alternatively,

    over the eight years ending in 1996 the absolute number of persons in poverty

    declined by 11.1 million (from 17.9 to 6.8 million); over the following two years

    the number increased by 1 million (from 6.8 to 7.9 million). Thus, according to

    the official data, measured in terms of absolute numbers of people in poverty, the

    crisis reversed 9 per cent of the poverty reduction that had occurred during the

    eight-year period of economic boom immediately preceding the crisis.

    Poverty Reduction and Economic Growth

    What caused the long-term decline in poverty incidence? It is obvious that over

    the long term, sustained economic growth is a necessary condition for large-

    scale poverty alleviation. No amount of redistribution could turn a poor country

    into a rich one. Long term improvements in education have undoubtedly been

    important, but despite the limitations of the underlying SES data, a reasonably

    clear statistical picture also emerges on the short-term relationship between

    poverty reductions and the rate of economic growth. The data are summarized

    in Figure 5, which plots the relationship between changes in poverty incidence,calculated from the data used in Figure 4, above, and the real rate of growth of

    GDP over the corresponding period.

    Periods of more rapid economic growth were associated with more rapid

    reductions in the level of absolute poverty incidence. Moderately rapid growth

    from 1962 to 1981 coincided with steadily declining poverty incidence. Reduced

    growth in Thailand caused by the world recession in the early to mid-1980s

    coincided with worsening poverty incidence in the years 1981 to 1986. Then,

    Thailands economic boom of the late 1980s and early 1990s coincided with

    dramatically reduced poverty incidence. Finally, the contraction following the crisis

    of 199799 led to increased poverty incidence. The recovery since the crisis has

    been associated with significant poverty reduction. Economic growth matters for

    the poor, as well as the rich.

    As shown in Figure 5, the correlation between these two variables is

    unmistakable. However, one pair of observations is a clear outlier the data

    point corresponding to the period 199698, which captures the major impact of

    the Asian financial crisis. It should be noted that poverty data are not available for

    the years 1997 to 1999. The correlation between poverty reduction and growth,based on data for the periods before and after the crisis period, would predict

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    19/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 351

    that a large decline in GDP such as one that occurred during the crisis period

    would produce a larger decline in poverty incidence than the one that actually

    occurred. This point is examined more systematically in Table 4 and Figure 6.

    Table 4 reports two regressions on the relationship between the rate of change

    of poverty incidence (negative values mean a decline in poverty incidence), the

    dependent variable, and the rate of GDP growth over the corresponding period, the

    independent variable. The first regression includes all data points. The estimated

    coefficient is negative as expected (the faster the growth, the greater the poverty

    reduction) and significant at the 5 per cent level.

    The second regression equation is the same except that the data point for

    the Asian financial crisis period, 199698, is omitted. The estimated coefficient

    is somewhat larger and again significant at the 5 per cent level. This second

    equation is then used to predict the change in poverty incidence that would be

    expected to result from the reduction in real GDP observed in the crisis. The

    results are summarized in Figure 6. An annual rate of GDP growth of 6.5 per

    cent (the one that actually occurred) would be expected to result in an annualincrease in poverty incidence of 4.52 per cent. The 95 per cent confidence interval

    FIGURE 5

    Thailand: Poverty Incidence and Economic Growth, 19622007

    Source: Authors calculations using poverty data as in Figure 4 and GDP data from NESDB,Bangkok.

    8.00

    6.00

    4.00

    2.00

    0.00

    2.00

    4.00

    6.00

    8.00

    10.00

    12.00

    196269

    196975

    197581

    198186

    198688

    198890

    199092

    199294

    199496

    199698

    19982000

    200002

    200204

    200406

    200607

    Percent

    Annual GDP growth Annual change in poverty incidence

    Asian financial

    crisis

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    20/22

    352 Peter Warr

    TABLE 4

    Thailand: Poverty Growth Regressions

    Independent variable Coefficient t-statistic p-value

    1. Dependent variable dP; all observations

    Intercept 0.247 0.35 0.729Real GDP growth 0.346 3.01 0.011

    R2= 0.430;adjR 2= 0.383; F= 9.07;p= 0.0108

    2. Dependent variable dP; all observations except 199698.

    Intercept 0.960 0.85 0.416Real GDP growth 0.548 2.90 0.014

    R2= 0.433;adjR 2= 0.381; F= 8.40;p= 0.0145

    Note: Regression equation: dP = a + by, where dP is the annual rate of change of povertyincidence between data points,yis the average annual rate of growth of real GDP betweendata points anda andb are the estimated coefficients.

    Source: Authors calculations, using data from the NESDB, Bangkok.

    FIGURE 6Thailand: The Growth/Poverty Nexus and the Asian Financial Crisis

    Source: Authors calculations, using data as in Table 4 and Figure 5.

    76543

    2101234567

    10 5 0 5 10 15

    Annual GDP Growth (%)

    Crisis: predicted,

    95% confidence

    interval

    Crisis: actual

    AnnualChangeinPoverty

    In

    cidence(%)

    around this prediction is [2.92, 6.12], meaning that given the estimated regression

    equation we can be 95 per cent confident that the level of poverty incidence thatwould result from a growth rate of real GDP of 6.5 per cent will lie within the

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    21/22

    Thailands Crisis Overload 353

    range of 2.92 to 6.12 per cent. However, the observed annual increase in poverty

    incidence (Crisis: actual in the figure) was only 0.8 per cent, well outside this

    95 per cent confidence interval. Poverty did not increase nearly as much as would

    be predicted on the basis of the contraction in real GDP.

    Several hypotheses can be advanced for this seeming anomaly. One is that

    the dramatic depreciation of the baht that immediately followed the crisis raised

    the prices of exported commodities, including most major agricultural goods.

    This benefited the rural poor but harmed the urban poor. The net effect may have

    been a reduction in poverty incidence. Another hypothesis, supported by extensive

    anecdotal evidence, is that Thai people assisted one another to an unusual extent

    during the crisis. Urban workers, laid off from construction and manufacturingemployment returned to their extended family base in the provinces. There they

    were absorbed into the business activities of the extended family and the loss of

    household income (on which the poverty calculations are based) was much less

    than would have otherwise occurred.

    Conclusion: Thailands Twin Crises

    The conclusion seems inescapable that hard economic times lie ahead for the Thai

    people. Two crises will continue to bite: the countrys unresolved internal politicalconflict and the global financial crisis. Political conflict will resurface when elections

    are next called. The precise form this conflict will take is unpredictable but it too

    may have adverse economic consequences. Regrettably, Thailands rival political

    support groups have learned that holding the public to ransom by occupying public

    facilities like airports is an effective tactic. There may be more of it.

    Both export demand and private investment will be negatively affected by

    the global financial crisis. The economy will contract during 2009, possibly by

    4 to 5 per cent. Expanded public spending will moderate the contraction that

    would otherwise have occurred but there is no possibility that it could expand

    sufficiently to prevent a contraction of aggregate output. The Thai economy is

    resilient and the central bank has ample international reserves to ride out a crisis.

    The country is as well-placed as any to emerge from the current crisis rapidly

    when global economic conditions improve. Regrettably, no one knows how soon

    that will happen.

    Changes in poverty incidence are sensitive to the rate of growth and poverty

    incidence will be impacted by the coming economic slowdown.5 Nevertheless, an

    examination of the experience of the Asian financial crisis of 199799 shows thatpoverty incidence did not increase nearly as much during that period as would

  • 7/29/2019 Thailand Crisis Overload

    22/22

    354 Peter Warr

    have been predicted from the statistical relationship between poverty incidence

    and economic growth. Thai people assisted one another to an unusual extent

    during this period and this moderated the increase in poverty incidence that wouldotherwise have occurred. If the impact of the global financial crisis proves to be

    as pronounced as is feared, this shock-absorber capacity of Thai society may

    be called upon again.

    Notes

    The research assistance of Razib Tuhin is gratefully acknowledged. The author is responsible

    for all defects.

    1 The sectoral composition of this reported 2.6 per cent annual growth was agriculture

    5.1 per cent, industry 3.4 per cent and services 1.2 per cent. The unusually high

    reported growth in agriculture arose from reported agricultural growth of 8.6 per cent

    and 9.6 per cent in the second and third quarters, respectively. These data warrant

    closer examination.2 This is presumably why a contraction in exports from China is causing a decline in

    total employment within China even though reported GDP growth is still 6 per cent.

    Chinas export industries are highly labour-intensive.3 World Bank, WorldDevelopmentReport1998 (New York: Oxford University Press,

    1998).4 Peter Warr, ed., Boom, Bust and Beyond, in Thailand Beyond the Crisis (London:

    Routledge, 2005), pp. 365.5 World Bank, Thailand Economic Monitor, December 2008, World Bank Office,

    Bangkok, available at .

    http://www.worldbank.or.th/http://www.worldbank.or.th/