Th Euro Crisis

42
Index 1. Introduction 2. The Origins of Cooperation in Europe 3. The European Monetary System 4. The Maastricht Treaty 5. The ERM crisis of 1992 6. Conditions for a Successful Currency Union 7. Reasons for Monetary Unification 8. Further Macroeconomic Benefits and Costs 9. The Euro Crisis 10. The Road Towards Recovery 11. Room for Improvement 12. The Underlying Crisis: External Imbalances 13. Solutions 14. Conclusions References Appendix: figures and tables

description

Final dissertation of a BSc in Economics

Transcript of Th Euro Crisis

  • Index

    1. Introduction

    2. The Origins of Cooperation in Europe

    3. The European Monetary System

    4. The Maastricht Treaty

    5. The ERM crisis of 1992

    6. Conditions for a Successful Currency Union

    7. Reasons for Monetary Unification

    8. Further Macroeconomic Benefits and Costs

    9. The Euro Crisis

    10. The Road Towards Recovery

    11. Room for Improvement

    12. The Underlying Crisis: External Imbalances

    13. Solutions

    14. Conclusions

    References

    Appendix: figures and tables

  • 2

    1. Introduction

    The European Union as we know it today is the result of a long and

    complicated process whose origins can be traced back to the years immediately

    following the Second World War. The process that culminated in 2002 with the

    introduction of a single currency has lately been at the centre of political debate in

    all Member States, especially since the outbreak of the financial crisis of 2008. The

    system, already proven vulnerable in the early Nineties, besides not yielding all of

    the benefits forecast by its founding fathers, is now standing accused of having

    actually aggravated the crisis acting as to spread it across Europe in the form of a

    sovereign debt crisis.

    A look to the origins and the high hopes that propelled a process spanning

    over more than half of the previous century can provide a good starting point for a

    discussion of the weaknesses and the strengths of the European Union and its role

    in the 2010 crisis. Furthermore, based on similar experiences such as the Gold

    Standard it is possible to individuate the main areas of improvement by comparing

    how the same issues have impacted the other scenarios and what approaches were

    adopted to address those issues.

  • 3

    2. The Origins of Cooperation in Europe

    In an effort to prevent the outbreak of another conflict, six European

    countries started to cooperate as early as 1950, following a plan designed by the

    French Foreign Minister Robert Schuman. Germany, France, Italy, Luxembourg,

    Belgium, and the Netherlands joined forces in 1951 in the European Coal and Steel

    Community (ECSC), thus coordinating their heavy industries. This early cooperation

    evolved into the European Economic Community and the European Atomic Energy

    Community (Euratom), as stated by the Treaty of Rome of 1957. Leaving aside the

    latter, which dealt specifically with issues related to the development of Europes

    nuclear industries, the main idea behind the former was to create a common

    market, which could allow the free movement of persons, goods, services, and

    capital. This was to be achieved through the establishment of a customs union (Art.

    3 of the Maastricht Treaty), the commitment of Member States to a common

    agricultural policy, and the end of state intervention in the form of restrictive

    agreements and aids that would interfere with the principle of free competition.

    While the first regulations on the common agricultural policy entered into

    force in 1962, it would take much longer for the idea of a common currency to be

    applied: in particular, the first steps in that direction were taken in 1970, when the

    Council appointed a committee of experts to propose ways of achieving economic

    and monetary union. The report submitted by the experts the Werner Report

    consisted of three steps to achieve free movement of capital, fixed exchange rates

    and possibly a single currency by 1980. Starting the following year, Member States

    were to coordinate their economic policies, especially their budgetary ones, with a

    view to reducing excessive fluctuation of exchange rates. The achievement of this

    task, conceived relying on fixed exchange rates against the dollar, was put at stake

    when the US decided to float the dollar in 1971, leading to an appreciation of the

  • 4

    Deutschmark. In an attempt to counteract these rising divergences, 1972 saw the

    implementation of the so-called snake in the tunnel system1, which allowed for

    the currencies to fluctuate in narrow bands (+/- 1.25%) with respect to each other,

    and in wider ones, provided for by the Smithsonian Agreement, with respect to the

    US dollar. However, this newly-designed plan was aborted the following year due to

    aggravating international macroeconomic conditions rising oil prices in particular

    which forced some countries to abandon the parity against the US dollar.2

    1 "Phase 2: the European Monetary System", 2010. 24 Jun. 2014 2 In the meanwhile, despite the initial failures, more European countries decided to join the

    European Coal and Steel Community, whose members increased to nine in 1973 - when

    Denmark, the United Kingdom, and Ireland joined -, and even further in 1981, with the arrival

    of Greece, and in 1986, with Spain and Portugal. "Europa - The history of the European

    Union", 2009. 28 Jun. 2014

  • 5

    3. The European Monetary System

    A new attempt at coordinating macroeconomic policies was made in 1979,

    with the establishment of the European Monetary System. The EMS included all

    member countries currencies, except for the pound sterling. At the core of this

    agreement there was the Exchange Rate Mechanism: a weighted average of the

    Member States bilateral exchange rate indices made up a parity grid, to which

    was associated a newly created basket currency, called European Currency Unit.

    Bilateral exchange rates were allowed to fluctuate by 2.25% of the parity, with the

    exception of the Italian Lira and the Spanish Peseta, which were allowed to vary by

    as much as 6%. This second attempt, in which participating countries agreed to give

    up some of their monetary autonomy, was more successful than the first one3:

    exchange rates could now be changed only by mutual agreement of the interested

    countries and the Commission, a fact that witnessed the emerging consensus

    among in Europe on the importance of achieving price stability. There are, however,

    controversial opinions regarding the causality links between the gradual

    convergence of inflation rates among European countries and the establishment of

    the European Monetary System. Eichengreen (1992) regressed CPI inflation data on

    money growth, GDP growth, and inflation over preceding years for EMS and non-

    EMS countries spanning from 1979 through 1990. The results showed very weak

    significance, implying that EMS membership seemed to be meaningless for lowering

    inflation4. Some argue5 that the context of general disinflation prevailing in Europe

    at that time played a major role, allowing the system to survive - despite several

    realignments - until 1992. In particular, it has been suggested that, starting in the

    mid-Seventies, European countries committed to a monetarist approach to

    3 See appendix, figure 1. 4 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 6. 5 Hodson, 2010, p. 161.

  • 6

    macroeconomic policies, focusing on the pursuit of low inflation by restricting

    money supply growth, and in this context adhering to the ERM was seen as a

    further way of achieving their goals6.

    Anyway, whatever the underlying causes, the perceived success of the EMS

    in the Eighties pushed the European Council to establish the Committee for the

    Study of Economic and Monetary Union, which submitted a report in 1989 (the

    Delors report) calling for a three-stage process to achieve a monetary union with

    free mobility of capital, fully integrated financial markets, irrevocably fixed

    exchange rates and irreversible convertibility of currencies, with a possible adoption

    of a single currency in place of the various national currencies7. Under the first

    stage, invoked also by the Single European Act of 1987, starting from 1990, the

    internal market was completed, and restrictions on capital mobility were removed.

    Furthermore, all Community currencies were included in the ERM under common

    rules. The following stage required Member States to draft a new treaty, which

    would provide a number of parameters aiming to:

    coordinate macroeconomic policies between states;

    set medium-term economic objectives and rules on the size of annual

    budget deficits;

    create the European System of Central Banks.

    The new treaty envisaged by the Delors report was the Treaty on the European

    Union, also known as the Maastricht Treaty, signed in 1991.

    6 Hodson, 2010, p. 161. 7 Delors, 1989.

  • 7

    4. The Maastricht Treaty

    The Treaty comprises a series of amendments to the previous international

    agreements, thus pulling together the European Coal and Steel Community, the

    European Economic Community, and the Euratom to form the European Union,

    which is based on three pillars: the European Communities, the common foreign

    and security policy, and police and judicial cooperation in criminal matters. The

    provisions of the Treaty limit the authority of Member States, who assign specific

    areas of competence to Community Institutions, sharing their sovereignty. The

    Treaty also defines the role of European Institutions, such as the Parliament, the

    Council, the Commission, the Court of Justice and the Court of Auditors, their term

    and their relationship with each other, expanding the role of the European

    Parliament and defining the procedures to be followed for the adoption and the

    implementation of EU law. In matters of economic and monetary union, the

    stepwise process originally outlined in the Delors report was defined in much the

    same way, with the significant addition of the amendments to the original treaties

    that were needed in order to make the provisions in the second and third stage

    binding on Member States.

    The final goal was the adoption of a single currency for all adhering countries,

    and it was to be achieved through three stages, spanning throughout the Nineties:

    1. liberalisation of capital movements towards the realization of a common

    market, coordinating economic policies the process had begun in 1990,

    and it should have reached completion by 1994 and the granting of

    political independence to national central banks (Art. 108);

    2. from 1994 to 1998, the establishment of the European Monetary Institute

    which, together with the Council, had to report to the Commission on the

    progress made in the fulfilment by the Member States of their obligations

  • 8

    regarding the achievement of economic and monetary union(Art. 109 j), i.e.

    the fulfilment of the so-called Maastricht convergence criteria outlined in

    the same article. The critical values were defined in Protocol 12 annexed to

    the Treaty and in the Stability and Growth Pact, approved in 1997.

    Table n. 1: The Maastricht convergence criteria

    Price stability Measured by the harmonized consumer

    price inflation rate, it shouldnt be

    more than 1.5% above the value of the

    three best performing Member States

    Sound public finances The government deficit as a percentage

    of GDP shouldnt exceed the value of

    3%

    Sustainable public finances The government debt shouldnt exceed

    60% of GDP

    Durability of convergence The long-term interest rate should be

    no more than 2% above the value of

    the three best performing Member

    States in terms of price stability

    Exchange rate stability Participation in the ERM for at least

    two consecutive years without severe

    deviations from the central rate.

    Source: Hodson, 2010

  • 9

    Furthermore, according to article 109 f of the Treaty, the European

    Monetary Institute had the following tasks:

    strengthen co-operation between the national central banks;

    strengthen the co-ordination of the monetary policies of the

    Member States, with the aim of ensuring price stability;

    monitor the functioning of the European Monetary System;

    hold consultations concerning issues falling within the competence

    of the national central banks and affecting the stability of financial

    institutions and markets;

    take over the tasks of the European Monetary Co-operation Fund,

    which shall be dissolved; the modalities of dissolution are laid down

    in the Statute of the EMI;

    facilitate the use of the ECU and oversee its development, including

    the smooth functioning of the ECU clearing system.

    3. By 1999, the EMI had to be liquidated while the newborn European Central

    Bank took over its functions (Art. 109 l). By that time, exchange rates had to

    be irrevocably fixed.

  • 10

    5. The ERM crisis of 1992

    The newly drafted system was hit the following year by a severe exchange

    rate crisis which put at stake its very existence, despite the commitment of the

    Member States. The first step towards European Monetary Union, i.e. the removal

    of barriers to capital mobility in order to arrive at a common market, was

    implemented starting from 1990. This was a significant difference with respect to

    the EMS of the previous decade. As Eichengreen (1992) underlines, the EMS back

    then was a hybrid of fixed and flexible exchange rates. Since the 1980s, exchange-

    rate stability and low inflation let countries benefit from effects usually deriving

    from fixed exchange rates. Periodic realignments (fifteen of them took place

    between 1979 and 19928) would take care of asymmetric shocks and issues related

    to competitiveness. This, however, was only made possible by the presence of

    restrictions on capital movements, which sheltered the central banks reserves

    against speculative attacks provoked by anticipations of a realignment.9 The

    difference became more clear with the unification of Germany.

    Massive public investments in Eastern Germany put inflationary pressures

    on the Deutschmark, forcing the Bundesbank to increase interest rates. With no

    capital controls, the other EMS countries were forced to import higher German

    rates, which worsened the position of those who were facing a recession: such was

    the case of the United Kingdom, of Spain, of Italy, whose fundamentals displayed

    falling economic growth and rising public debt, and of France, where

    unemployment figures were rising. The situation deteriorated further in 1992 when

    Denmark rejected the Maastricht Treaty, and polls claimed France was going to

    follow. Investors began to speculate on devaluations in the weaker countries, in

    particular the United Kingdom, Italy, Spain and France. Capital started flowing out

    8 Montiel, 2009, p. 447. 9 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 8.

  • 11

    from those countries and into Germany. Choosing to sacrifice external equilibrium

    (the parity with the Deutschmark) in favour of internal economic objectives, the

    United Kingdom, Spain, and Italy dropped out of the ERM in 1992. France was able

    to face the speculative pressures without retreating, but those resulted in wide

    exchange rate fluctuations (+/- 15%)10. Only after some years of economic recovery,

    marked by large margins of fluctuation, most countries were able to meet the

    Maastricht criteria in order to proceed towards monetary unification11. Despite

    these difficulties, in 1998 the Council examined the fundamentals of the Member

    States: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy,

    Luxembourg, The Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom

    were deemed to have fulfilled the Maastricht requirements; only Greece was not.

    The inclusion of Italy and Belgium was a controversial one, since their public debt

    was exceeding 100% of GDP12. Despite qualifying, Sweden, Denmark, and the

    United Kingdom decided not to join the EMU in 1999.

    Thus, only eleven of the fifteen original countries participated initially to the

    EMU in 1999. Their currencies were irrevocably locked with fixed exchange rates.

    Following the plan, the ECB took the place of the EMI and started to dictate

    monetary policy for the European Union. On January 1st, 1999 the Euro became the

    official unit of account, but it only started circulating, alongside national currencies,

    in 200213.

    10 Montiel, 2009, p. 449. 11 Hodson, 2010, p. 163. 12 Montiel, 2009, p. 449. 13 See appendix, figures 1, 2, 3.

  • 12

    6. Conditions for a Successful Currency Union

    Before running an ex post analysis of the costs and benefits of the EU, it is

    useful to understand whether, based on the theory, such a union could have been

    feasible in present-day Europe, and what conditions could have made it better. It

    has already been noted that the preconditions required by the Maastricht Treaty

    werent met by all of the founding members of the European Monetary Union. In

    the early Nineties, some even suggested the EMU should start only with a subset of

    EC members, namely the only seven who could plausibly satisfy all the convergence

    criteria by 199714. However, according to Eichengreen (1992), this option was

    rejected as the benefits from the adoption of a single currency tend to increase the

    more countries participate; rather than starting with a smaller union, EC members

    chose to extend the waiting period until more of them came closer to meeting the

    requirements.

    Besides the convergence criteria, other prerequisites affecting the overall

    benefits and costs of monetary unification are necessary for a successful currency

    union. De Grauwe (2012 a) develops a critique of the theory of optimum currency

    areas testing the views held by the European Commission in the Nineties.

    The first point of such critique concerns the relevance of differences among

    countries trade structure and what will this imply in the case of demand shocks.

    The Commission held the view that most demand shocks would impact different

    countries in similar ways because the removal of barriers and the completion of the

    single market would lead to a similar structure of trade across the Euro zone. Since

    trade between industrial European nations is to a great extent intra-industry trade,

    a higher degree of trade integration will cause less asymmetric shocks, and more

    symmetry in the movements of output and employment for countries in the union.

    14 Namely, the Netherlands, France, the United Kingdom, Spain, Luxembourg, Germany, Denmark, and Portugal. See Eichengreen, 1992, p. 52-55.

  • 13

    The higher the degree of industry similarity between Member States, the better the

    effect of a monetary union, which will then tend to make income and employment

    more correlated between countries involved. This relationship would be reversed if

    Europe were to move away from industrial similarity towards regional

    specialization. This second scenario finds support in data from the early Nineties,

    which show that the correlation of disturbances - both in the case of temporary and

    permanent ones - of Economic Community countries with those of Germany is

    rather low. The findings suggest that shocks in Europe are relatively idiosyncratic15,

    making the case against the adoption of a single currency. However, later studies

    revealed that as economic integration in Europe increased, the business cycles of

    European countries became more correlated16. The issue remained controversial

    until the outbreak of the current crisis, which forced the European policymakers to

    intervene, only to realize that a unique remedy wasnt going to work for the whole

    union, especially if the countries who gained the most from unification werent

    willing to make some sacrifices to help those in need17.

    Another point at issue concerns the fact that countries who decide to join a

    currency union automatically give up some of their powers. Adopting a single

    currency in common with other states implies losing control over monetary policy

    and exchange rate policy. States are left free to decide only on matters concerning

    their budgetary and fiscal policies which, some argue, may become a further

    source of asymmetric disturbances18. Therefore, in case of shocks, the mechanisms

    to restore equilibrium rely on labour mobility, wage-price adjustments, inter-

    regional flows of capital be it private or public , and fiscal transfers19. A

    successful currency union should then rely on:

    15 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 14. 16 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 27. 17 Eichengreen, 2010, De Grauwe, 2012 b, De Grauwe and Sngas, 2003. 18 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 31. 19 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 16.

  • 14

    high labour market flexibility. Drawing comparisons from the United States

    labour market, De Grauwe (2012 a) and Eichengreen (1992) suggest that this

    is not the case for an EU consisting of 15 countries, and even less so for the

    present-day EU-27.

    the presence of a system of fiscal transfers to provide relief in case of

    asymmetric shocks, both for real and financial shocks, as is the case in the

    United States20. Completing the monetary union with a budgetary one

    lowers dramatically its costs. This, however, implies the need for a stronger

    political union, which is lacking in Europe.

    Based on the above criteria, De Grauwe (2012 a) claims the EU doesnt

    constitute a successful currency union. This is partly due to the heterogeneity of

    each countrys position, which doesnt allow to draw a unique scheme benefiting

    all. Data suggests that only a subset of EU countries could form an optimal currency

    area, including Germany, the Benelux countries, Austria, and France. Enlarging the

    union any further may result in economic costs exceeding the advantages for

    participants.

    20 Eichengreen, 1992, De Grauwe, 2012 a.

  • 15

    7. Reasons for Monetary Unification

    Despite all the unfavourable forecasts and several doubts regarding the

    possibility of building a successful union, European legislators still opted for

    monetary integration in Europe, displaying a surprisingly strong willingness to

    follow the predetermined path, and being mainly concerned with the following

    three objectives21:

    the elimination of exchange rate uncertainty aiming at increasing intra-

    European trade;

    enhancing Europes role in the world monetary system;

    making the cost of managing the Common Agricultural Policy affordable.

    How did the European Union perform with respect to the achievement of the above

    goals?

    7.1 Eliminating exchange rate uncertainty

    The first objective should benefit consumers at the microeconomic level,

    lowering the costs deriving from exchanging one currency into another, while at the

    same time it should help trade and international investments, getting rid of the

    deadweight loss represented by the transaction costs22 and of the exchange rate

    risk23. The European Commission provided an estimation of the direct gains in its

    1990 report One Market, One Money: an evaluation of the potential benefits and

    costs of forming an economic and monetary union. The yearly estimates of the

    entity of such savings range between 13 and 20 billion Euros; put in relative terms,

    it amounts to 0.25 to 0.50% of the Community GDP24. Nowadays the figures would

    probably be even smaller due to a wider use of electronic payments, which bypass

    21 Montiel, 2009, p. 446. 22 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 55. 23 Eichengreen, 1992. 24 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 55.

  • 16

    the currency conversion issue. Furthermore, the evidence for an increase in intra-

    European trade or investment is scanty: despite the obvious welfare gains from the

    elimination of the exchange rate uncertainty and the minimization of the inflation

    risk25, the use of different currencies need not pose a limit to the trade of goods or

    services, as there already exist other means of hedging the exchange rate risk, such

    as currency diversification, or forward markets26.

    Nonetheless, the elimination of transaction costs brings about also

    intangible benefits, such as price transparency. Consumers are supposed to be

    facilitated in the comparison of prices since now these are all expressed in the same

    currency. This should increase competition, resulting in prices converging to the

    lowest value within the Community, and benefits for the consumers. However, as

    De Grauwe (2012 a) points out, price discrimination is widely practiced in the

    European Union, since most consumers are unlikely to move to a different country

    to take advantage of lower prices there. Furthermore, data show that price

    convergence - occurring in the early 1990 - disappeared since the launch of the Euro

    zone27.

    7.2 Enhancing Europes role in the world monetary system

    The 1990 EC Commission report One Market, One Money makes a point of

    demonstrating the impact on growth of the elimination of the exchange rate risk. In

    the minds of the European legislators, who were conducting the analysis on a

    neoclassical growth model, lower or no exchange rate risk should decrease the

    systemic risk, which in turn will lower the real interest rate and shift the economy to

    25 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 58. 26 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 8. 27 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 56, 57.

  • 17

    a new equilibrium level, resulting in an accumulation of capital and a transitional

    increase in the growth rate, reaching higher output and capital per worker28.

    However, when confronted with data, this theory does not seem to hold.

    Comparing the growth rate in the Euro area before and after 1999, one finds little

    to no evidence of positive effects of the Euro on growth. On the other hand, there is

    also little evidence that the adoption of the Euro caused a slowdown in the growth,

    confirming the principle of monetary neutrality in the long run29. This mismatch

    between theoretical predictions and actual outcomes is probably due to the fact

    that the elimination of exchange rate risk did not bring about significant decreases

    in the real interest rate, with the exception of Ireland, Spain, Portugal, and Greece.

    Ireland, Spain, and Greece actually saw a temporary acceleration of growth, as

    predicted by the theory.30

    7.3 Making the cost of managing the Common Agricultural Policy affordable

    The Common Agricultural Policy was implemented starting in 1962, giving

    Member States joint control over the food production. European farmers were

    granted the same, fixed price for their produce. Of course, the prices were fixed in

    terms of domestic currency, so insofar as exchange rates were not fixed, there was

    an incentive for markets to speculate on the price of commodities, shipping them

    from one country to another and disrupting efforts to maintain an orderly

    market.31 Fixing exchange rates prevented speculation from happening while

    granting food safety for the citizens of the Union and decent earnings for farmers32.

    28 EC Commission, 1990, p. 78-81. 29 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 65. 30 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 65. 31 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 9. 32 "The history of the CAP - Agriculture and rural development." 2012. 29 Jun. 2014

  • 18

    8. Further Macroeconomic Benefits and Costs

    Whether the objectives listed above have been fully attained or not, joining

    the European Monetary Union implied several other consequences. Among the

    gains, even if their effect is disputed, countries who entered the Union, besides

    becoming part of a stronger international political entity, could efficiently and

    effectively curb inflation, while maintaining some exchange rate discipline, as

    shown by the EMS in the Eighties. Even more so when the soft pegs of the EMS

    were replaced by the fixed exchange rates provided for under the Maastricht

    Treaty: once monetary unification was achieved, in order to take full advantage of

    its positive effects, participating countries had to commit credibly to it. This implies

    that, as Eichengreen (2010) notices, neither the Maastricht Treaty nor its later

    updates - i.e. the Treaties signed in Amsterdam (1997), Nice (2001), and Lisbon

    (2007) - consider an exit procedure for a country willing to drop out of the

    European Union. European leaders needed their efforts to appear credible and

    permanent, whereas including clauses of that kind might have severe destabilizing

    effects: it would end up paving the way for self-fulfilling crises if markets were to

    start betting on a countrys exit33.

    Therefore, joining the European Monetary Union meant that sovereign

    countries had to give up permanently their exchange rate and monetary policies,

    which became a matter of competence of the ECB. Furthermore, having to respect

    the Maastricht criteria and the Stability and Growth Pact implied also a limited

    scope of action in matters of fiscal policy. The European Central Bank was instituted

    with the specific task of maintaining price stability, and not as a lender of last

    resort34. This concept was embedded in the Stability and Growth Pact as well as in

    the Maastricht criteria, in order to prevent single Member States from running

    33 Eichengreen, 2010, p. 17. 34 Maastricht Treaty, Art. 105.

  • 19

    overly expansionary fiscal policies and then pressing the ECB to buy their national

    debt. Once the monetary union was in force, the bad behaviour of one of the

    members would take its toll on the rest of them. If indebted states were to ask the

    ECB to bail them out, and if the ECB actually did so, then the remaining countries

    would end up having to repay somebody elses debts in the form of inflation, or in

    the form of a higher tax burden, or with higher interest rates35. State sovereignty in

    matter of fiscal policy was further reduced in 2011 with the approval of the so-

    called Fiscal Compact, a treaty imposing tighter budget constraints and sanctions

    for countries that do not respect the Maastricht criteria36. Trapped within such

    narrow bounds, individual states have very little room for action left in case of

    asymmetric shocks which nonetheless may still occur. As seen earlier, the only

    adjustment mechanisms in place rely on the adjustment of prices and wages, the

    mobility of labour, capital flows, and fiscal transfers37.

    With regard to the first channel, problems arise from the fact that, due to a

    number of factors encompassing differences in the taxation of labour and high

    unionization of workers, wages in Europe are rather rigid and slow to adjust38. At

    the same time, the presence of a number of barriers like language and cultural

    differences, or differences in legal systems e. g. in case of mandatory licences or

    permits, or the lack of harmonization of the school systems , slow down the

    mobility of labour, which was already traditionally low within single states,

    especially in the southern periphery of the European Union39. The result was the

    deterioration of these countries competitive position as measured by the

    increase in the relative unit labour costs of southern Member States compared to

    35 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 28. 36 "Six-pack? Two-pack? Fiscal compact? A short guide to the new EU fiscal governance", 2012. 29 Jun. 2014 37 Eichengreen, 1992, De Grauwe, 2012 a. 38 Eichengreen, 1992, De Grauwe, 2012 a. 39 Eichengreen, 1992.

  • 20

    core countries 40. As De Grauwe (2012 b) shows, it would take a series of internal

    devaluations, coming at a great cost in terms of lost output and employment in

    countries such as Greece, Ireland, Spain, Italy, and Portugal. The same author went

    even further, claiming that internal devaluations in the PIIGS countries are less

    costly when the surplus countries are willing to allow for internal revaluations. (De

    Grauwe, 2012 b; see also appendix, figures 4, 6, and table 2)41

    Thus, ruling the first two mechanisms out of the picture, it must be kept in

    mind that the unification of financial markets allows free mobility of capital across

    the union. However, some devaluation risk will always be present to discourage

    capital inflows towards countries experiencing recessionary dynamics42. This

    became particularly evident during the Euro crisis that hit the European Union in

    2010-201143.

    40 De Grauwe, 2012 a. 41 The same conclusion, on a theoretical level, is reached by Eggertson and Krugman, 2012. 42 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 24, 25. 43 De Grauwe, 2010.

  • 21

    9. The Euro Crisis

    The downturn that hit the Euro zone in 2010 is often referred to as a debt

    crisis. However, the overall level of debt in the EU as a percentage of GDP wasnt

    even nearly as high as the debt in the United States: the value of the general

    government consolidated debt for the US in 2010 was approaching 95%, about ten

    percentage points above the aggregate level of the EU with 16 Members44.

    Nonetheless, it is the Euro zone that was severely hit by the crisis, which soon

    became the main topic of political debate and began raising questions regarding the

    opportunity for some countries to continue to take part in it.

    The overall low level of debt for the EU as a whole actually hides huge

    differences in each countrys level of debt45. Nonetheless, except for Greece, the

    overall trend in the years before 2008 in compliance with the convergence criteria

    , was that of a decrease of public debt. However, after the economic downturn of

    2008, the scenario worsened dramatically: on one hand, national budgets came

    under strain because, as the recession set in, the decline in government tax

    revenues was faced by an increase in the expenditure on social programs to ease

    the recovery; on the other hand, public governments were often called in to

    guarantee solvency for private debtors, and did so by issuing national debt46.

    This was the situation in 2010, when Dubai unexpectedly postponed the

    repayment of its bonds. The event caught the markets and the rating agencies

    completely off-guard. Consequently, investors became extremely sensitive to the

    risk of default on sovereign debt. Rating agencies were quick to look for more

    potential culprits, downgrading Greek bonds first, and then those of several other

    southern European countries. This ended up amplifying the destabilizing effects of

    44 See appendix, figure 7. 45 See appendix, figure 8. 46 De Grauwe, 2010.

  • 22

    financial markets, where investors started to look for adequate compensation in

    terms of higher interest rates for what was suddenly perceived as a huge risk47. The

    countries with the highest level of debt were penalized with huge interest charges

    while capital fled into less indebted countries, such as Germany. These states, who

    became known as virtuous countries, took advantage of the situation, which

    allowed them to borrow lots of capital on the markets at very convenient rates. In

    the meanwhile, the cost of servicing the debt became unbearable for southern

    European countries, and intervention was called for at the European and

    international level in order to restore equilibrium.

    47 De Grauwe, 2010; see appendix, figures 5 and 9.

  • 23

    10. The Road Towards Recovery

    The crisis could have been stopped soon after its eruption by bailing out

    Greece48. As a matter of fact, the divergence in the interest rates on long term

    government bonds did indeed start to decrease in 2012, when the ECB

    implemented its OMT Outright Monetary Transactions program, pledging to buy

    unlimited amounts of European sovereign debt in order to reassure the markets49.

    It took two years, however, for the ECB to intervene, mainly due to disagreements

    among Eurozone governments on the right actions to be taken50. A quick

    intervention was needed in order to give markets a form of reassurance with regard

    to the solvency of a Member State, thus preventing the contagion to other

    countries in similar positions. In addition to this, falling prices of bonds could have

    severely hurt banks, who were recovering from the 2008 downturn by exploiting

    the high rates on long-term government bonds. Moreover, De Grauwe (2010)

    further argued that delayed intervention in Greece would have protracted the rise

    in the yield of government bonds, a fact that translated into huge costs for the

    servicing of the debt. Pressed by the markets, the governments would be forced to

    enact extraordinary measures, contracting fiscal policies, leading to deflationary

    pressures51 and risk pulling down the EU in a deeper recession following the

    dynamics of the Fisher paradox52. The previous prediction turned out to be rather

    accurate: the ECBs procrastination, which was protracted even further due to the

    political disagreement of governments on the matter, reduced the effect of the

    authorities reassurances and the credibility of the intervention itself, not only

    falling short of the goal of stopping the crisis, but even worsening it. In the end, it

    48 De Grauwe, 2010. 49 De Grauwe, 2014, see also appendix, figure 5. 50 De Grauwe, 2014. 51 De Grauwe, 2010. 52 See appendix, figures 11 and 12.

  • 24

    created an asymmetric adjustment mechanism, in which most of the burden was

    carried by the debtor nations, who have been imposed a strict rule of austerity

    without any compensating stimulus by the creditor nations53. As predicted, this

    resulted in deflationary pressures for debtor countries, that can be seen from the

    change in the relative unit labour costs: they were soaring for debtor countries until

    2008-2009, testifying a worsening of their competitive position, and then started

    dropping, more severely for Ireland, Greece, and Spain. These dynamics havent

    been observed for creditor countries, where relative unit labour costs remained

    almost constant for the period in line with the average from 1970 to 201054.

    Despite these harsh remedies, there is no evidence that they will actually be

    effective in improving countries ability to repay their debts; on the contrary, the

    position of debtor countries actually worsened55. Data suggests that the stronger

    the austerity program, the heavier its toll on a countrys GDP, and therefore on the

    debt-to-GDP ratio56. In such a recessionary scenario, for their position to become

    sustainable, countries such as Italy, Greece, Portugal, Ireland, and Spain would have

    to significantly increase their exports, while at the same time keeping on growing: a

    nearly impossible target, especially given the impossibility of exploiting exchange

    rate devaluations.

    53 De Grauwe, 2012 b and 2014, Eggertson, 2012. 54 De Grauwe, 2012 b; see appendix, figure 6. 55 This follows closely the Fisher paradox, as reported also by Eggertson and Krugman, 2012. 56 De Grauwe, 2014. See appendix, figures 10 and 11.

  • 25

    11. Room for Improvement

    The crisis merely exposed the structural weaknesses that policymakers had

    neglected to recognize and correct while still in time to do so. They have been

    warned about the need to foster coordination of fiscal policies across the union, a

    concept that was warmly suggested by the Maastricht treaty, but, as Eichengreen

    forecast in 1992 and later observed , lacked substantial implementation57.

    Besides the problems that have been examined so far which can be

    summarized by admitting that the Euro-15 does not constitute an optimal currency

    area , the Euro crisis was fuelled by two design failures, which concern mainly two

    points58.

    1. The monetary union is fully centralized, while macroeconomic policies are

    conducted at the national level. When business cycles, which are not constrained by

    the single monetary policy, generate periods of recession in a region, then

    monetary policy has no way of intervening on that specific area. In this kind of

    setting, having only one policy interest rate for the whole union may even aggravate

    cyclic booms and recessions. Without a supranational fiscal authority that could

    compensate for local asymmetric shocks, prices and wage adjustments, together

    with labour migrations, have proven insufficient to take care of the job59.

    2. The lack of safety nets and, more importantly, the absence of a budgetary union

    to support the monetary union. This implies that crises like the one of 2010 are

    likely to occur again because Member States issue debt in a currency they have no

    57 Eichengreen, 1992, and 2010, p. 19. 58 De Grauwe, 2012 a, and 2014. 59 De Grauwe and Sngas, 2003.

  • 26

    direct control over60. Even more so considering the design of the ECB: given its

    complete autonomy from the governments, they have no power to force it to

    provide liquidity, even during a crisis. Therefore, the EU currently sees in force a

    primacy of the Central Bank over the governments - unlike in the United States61.

    This translates into the supremacy of non-elected officials at the ECB, who decide

    upon the fate of democratically elected governments by deciding whether to act as

    a lender of last resort or not62.

    60 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p.114, and 2012 b. 61 Eichengreen, 1992, p. 45. 62 De Grauwe, 2014.

  • 27

    12. The Underlying Crisis: external imbalances

    Eurostat data for the period immediately preceding the 2010 crisis suggests

    the Euro zone countries were far from being in balance even back then63. The

    problem of external imbalances in the Balance of Payments of Member States has

    been underestimated for a while, and even the Maastricht Treaty didnt consider

    the issue as one worth worrying about, unless it concerned countries who meant to

    join the EU. The official stance on the problem, however, almost completely

    disregarded individual countries Balance of Payments while focusing on the

    balance of payments of the union as a whole which, indeed, was in equilibrium.

    Nevertheless, according to a recent analysis64, a misalignment of internal real

    exchange rates, coupled with the lower interest rates in force right after the

    introduction of the Euro, allowed peripheral countries to obtain cheap credit to

    finance their private and public deficits. This caused capital to flow out of PIIGS

    countries, who exhibited increasingly negative Balances of Payments, and into

    centre-European countries, who ended up funding the formers BoP deficits. This is

    supported also by data on the values of TARGET2 balances, i.e. the balances of the

    Euro area interbank payment system, representing the claims and the liabilities of

    the National Central Banks to the ECB. For the period going from 2007 to 2011,

    these show plenty of liquidity accumulating in central European countries, flowing

    in from southern peripheral ones65.

    63 See appendix, figure 12. 64 Mayer, Mbert, and Weistroffer, 2011; Mayer and Bttcher, 2011. 65 See appendix, figure 13.

  • 28

    13. Solutions

    Krugman (2012), De Grauwe (2012 b), Eichengreen (2010), among others66,

    seem to agree that the only way out of a similar situation involves a collaboration

    between debtor and creditor countries. The first step in this direction would be an

    increase in spending by the creditor countries, so as to turn their BoP surplus into a

    deficit. An additional option yielding similar outcomes would imply an internal

    devaluation by debtor countries in order to boost exports. As a result of the first

    two steps, creditor countries would have to cope with some more inflation and the

    creation of excessive reserve money, as deficit countries obtain central bank

    money from the ECB to fund their balance of payment deficits.67 These solutions,

    however, are not being implemented in a symmetric way; instead, lots of pressure

    is put on debtor countries, who feel left out from the decision process68. For

    example, debtor countries in most cases have indeed undergone a process of

    internal devaluation, bearing huge social costs, while surplus countries did not allow

    any significant internal revaluation69.

    This problem is a direct legacy of the Euro crisis. To prevent situations of

    stalemate such as the one right after the Greek debt downgrading, the ECB and the

    Commission have been assigned wider powers and responsibilities the latter can

    now impose changes in taxation and budgetary policies, and should monitor and

    correct macroeconomic imbalances in the framework of the Macroeconomic

    Imbalance Procedure -, but these came without greater accountability70. The

    European Central Banks and the Commissions decisions can affect the lives of

    millions of European citizens, who in turn do not have a say on the matter, and thus

    66 See also Mayer, Mbert, and Weistroffer, 2011, and Mayer and Bttcher, 2011. 67 Mayer and Bttcher, 2011. 68 De Grauwe, 2012 b, and 2014. 69 De Grauwe, 2012 b. 70 De Grauwe, 2014.

  • 29

    feel excluded from the decision making process while being forced to bear its social

    and economic consequences71.

    71 De Grauwe, 2014.

  • 30

    14. Conclusions

    In an analysis of the then newly drafted Maastricht Treaty, Eichengreen

    (1992) expressed his doubts with regard to the possibility of building a currency

    union in Europe. Already back then, data suggested it was not the case of an

    optimal currency area, and nowadays it appears that he might not have been

    wrong. It has been noted how many of the problems he forecast actually showed up

    recently. His and De Grauwes (2014) comments on the Treaty leave very few things

    unsaid. The two suggested European policymakers to work on fixing a number of

    mistakes by directly modifying the Maastricht Treaty, and in particular:

    allocate more clearly responsibility for exchange-rate policy and facilitate

    policy coordination at G7 summits. In the years preceding the crisis,

    European political leaders would meet in Brussels to discuss common

    policies which they wouldnt implement in their own countries, caring more

    about internal consensus than about the health of the European economy72.

    Like during the Great Depression, indebted countries (Germany and Austria

    then; Italy, Portugal, Greece, and also the US now) were in such position also

    because of the policies adopted by countries experiencing a surplus (the US

    and France in the 1930s, China and Germany nowadays)73. Adjustment

    would be easier, faster, and less painful in terms of shocks to output and

    unemployment for debtors if creditors adopted expansionary fiscal

    policies74. Since the latest crisis, the Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure

    has been set up, monitoring a number of macroeconomic variables such as

    current account balances, competitiveness measures, house prices, and

    72 Eichengreen, 1992. 73 Eighengreen, 1994. 74 Eichengreen, 2010.

  • 31

    bank credit. However, there is still more to be done: the need to prove to

    markets the credibility of the commitment to the Union might force

    Members to issue eurobonds75. Such an issue of debt would make

    participating countries jointly liable. At the same time, though, it would

    bring about moral hazard issues; it is therefore understandable that this

    proposal has met stiff resistance.76

    Safeguard the political independence of the ECB, but at the same time keep

    in mind that the impossibility for governments to influence its actions has

    proven a triggering issue in the latest crisis77. One of the key features of the

    Gold Standard, which some claim to be the reason of its initial success, was

    the independence of the banking sector from political powers; besides this,

    and strictly following from it, that regime also featured a strong role played

    by the Bank of England78, which has been matched only in recent years by

    the ECB. However, its recent policy developments, and especially forcing

    austerity upon the sinners79, are a mere replication of the mistakes made

    in the previous century, which led to the Great Depression80.

    Set up a more extensive system of regional coinsurance to help absorb

    asymmetric shocks. Another parallel can be drawn with the Gold Standard

    on this field. Actually, both downturns highlighted the importance of lenders

    of last resort in order to act quickly on impending dangers. This kind of

    institutions hadnt been properly designed also during the Gold Standard

    75 De Grauwe, 2012 b. 76 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p.125. 77 De Grauwe, 2014. 78 Eichengreen, 2010. 79 De Grauwe, 2014. 80 Eichengreen, 1994, 2002, and 2010.

  • 32

    era, condemning Austria to a harsh recession.81 In 2010, when Greece was in

    need of financial help, the European Union wasnt able to provide any.

    Therefore, Greece had to ask the IMF for relief, sparking debate on whether

    the IMF should intervene on what was considered as an internal matter. To

    respond to such emergencies, the European Financial Stabilization

    Mechanism (EFSM) and the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) were

    established82.

    The solutions to the problems brought up by the Euro crisis are being

    implemented, but the healing process is far from being a straightforward one. On

    one side, the implementation of these political measures is at odds with the

    principle of subsidiarity, i.e. it impacts the sovereignty of Member States because it

    requires a redefinition of community versus state competencies83. On the other

    hand, the crisis has shown that single Member States arent that willing to sacrifice

    their economic interest for the sake of the European Union84. This last observation

    is, by all means, the biggest issue for the European Union: the absence of a strong

    political union, and the lack of a firm idea of commitment to a common cause85.

    Without a stronger political union which cannot be achieved only by

    strengthening the bureaucratic union the Euro will remain nothing but a currency

    without a country, and that makes the Euro zone unsustainable in the long run.86

    81 Eichengreen, 2000, and 2010. 82 "Financial assistance in EU Member States - European ..." 2012. 29 Jun. 2014

    83 Eichengreen, 1992. 84 De Grauwe, 2014. 85 De Grauwe, 2012 a, p. 132. 86 De Grauwe, 2014.

  • 33

    References

    De Grauwe Paul, Sngas Marc-Alexandre. Monetary Policy in EMU when the

    Transmission is Asymmetric and Uncertain. [S. l.], 2003.

    De Grauwe Paul, Crisis in the eurozone and how to deal with it in Centre for Europ.

    Policy Studies, 204, 2010.

    De Grauwe Paul, Economics of Monetary Union. Oxford, University Press, 2012,

    (Ninth ed). Print.

    De Grauwe Paul, In search of symmetry in the Eurozone in Centre for Europ. Policy

    Studies, 268, 2012.

    De Grauwe Paul, Chi governa lEuro?, Festival dellEconomia di Trento, Universit

    degli Studi di Trento, Palazzo Geremia, 31 May 2014. Lecture.

    Delors Jacques, Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European

    Community, 1989.

    EC Commission, One Market, One Money, in European Economy, 44, 1990.

    Eggertsson Gauti B., Krugman Paul, Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A

    Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach, in The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127.3, pp.

    1469-1513, 2012.

  • 34

    Eichengreen Barry J., Should the Maastricht Treaty be saved?. Princeton,

    International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University,

    1992. Print.

    Eichengreen Barry J., Gabbie d'oro: il gold standard e la grande depressione: 1919-

    1939. Roma Bari, Laterza; Milano, Cariplo, 1994. Print.

    Eichengreen Barry J., Temin Peter, The Gold Standard and the Great Depression in

    Contemporary European History, Cambridge (United Kingdom), University Press,

    2000, pp. 183 207. Print.

    Eichengreen Barry J., Still fettered after all these years (NBER Working Paper 9276),

    Cambridge (Massachussetts), National Bureau of Economic Research, 2002. Print.

    Eichengreen Barry J., Temin Peter, Fetters of gold and paper (NBER Working Paper

    16202), Cambridge (Massachussetts), National Bureau of Economic Research, 2010.

    Print.

    Hodson Dermot, Economic and Monetary Union: an experiment in new modes of EU

    policy-making in Policy-making in the European Union, Oxford (United Kingdom),

    University Press, 2010, pp. 158 179. Print.

    Mayer Thomas, Bttcher Barbara, Eurolands hidden balance-of-payments crisis in

    EU Monitor, 88, Deutsche Bank Research, 2011.

  • 35

    Mayer Thomas, Mbert Jochen, Weistroffer Christian, Macroeconomic imbalances

    and the Eurosystem, in Deutsche Bank Global Economic Perspectives, 8, 2011, pp.

    35 41.

    Montiel Peter, International macroeconomics. Chichester (United Kingdom), Wiley-

    Blackwell, 2009. Print.

    "Europa - The history of the European Union", 2009. 28 Jun. 2014

    "Phase 2: the European Monetary System", 2010. 24 Jun. 2014

    "Financial assistance in EU Member States", 2012. 29 Jun. 2014

    "The history of the CAP - Agriculture and rural development", 2012. 29 Jun. 2014

    "Six-pack? Two-pack? Fiscal compact? A short guide to the new EU fiscal

    governance", 2012. 29 Jun. 2014

  • 36

    Appendix: figures and tables

    Figure 1: CPI inflation in the Eurozone. (Source: Montiel, 2009, p. 450)

    Figure 2: long-term interest rate (government bond yield). (Source: Montiel, 2009, p. 450)

  • 37

    Figure 3: Public debt. (Source: Montiel, 2009, p. 451)

    Figure 4: Relative unit labour costs for PIIGS countries. (Source: De Grauwe, 2012 b)

  • 38

    Table 2: Internal devaluation in PIIGS countries. (Source: De Grauwe, 2012 b)

    Figure 5: (Source: De Grauwe, 2014)

  • 39

    Figure 6: Relative unit labour costs in core European countries. (Source: De Grauwe, 2012 b)

    Figure 7: General government consolidated gross debt as a percentage of GDP. (Source: European Commission, AMECO)

  • 40

    Figure 8: General government consolidated gross debt as a percentage of GDP. (Source: European Commission, AMECO)

    Figure 9: Interest rate spread over German bonds. (Source: OECD.stat)

  • 41

    Figure 10: The Fisher mechanism. (Source: De Grauwe, 2014)

    Figure 11: The Fisher mechanism. (Source: De Grauwe, 2014)

  • 42

    Figure 12: Current account balances in EU. (Source: De Grauwe, 2014)

    Figure 13: Target 2 balances of NCBs, in EUR billions. (Source: ECB Monthly bulletin, Oct. 2011, p. 36)