STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT...

47
STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE IN RESIDENCY PROGRAMS By Dr. Jimmy Schwarzkopf Research Fellow & Partner STKI [email protected] Dr. Schwarzkopf has worked during the last 30 years in all areas of Computer Information Services. IT Analyst as META Group Israeli Research Manager and was named a META Group Research Fellow. As an academic researcher in Entrepreneurship Sciences has published and presented in the Academy of Management and Babson Conferences. As a consultant in Arthur Andersen Consulting (USA), Booz Allen (USA) and Kesselman & Kesselman. As a systems professional in SCS Computers and the R&D Unit of the Israel Defense Forces. As a sales and marketing professional in Digital Equipment Corporation. Teaching in the MIS department at Ben Gurion University and the Computer School of the IDF. Entrepreneur founding two companies in the IT arena: store and forward mail and office information systems. Dr. Schwarzkopf received BSE and MSE degrees (Systems Engineering) from the University of Central Florida. Got his MSIA (Management Information Systems) and ABD (PhD Program) in Systems Science (received (twice) the William Larimer Mellon Scholarship/Award) from Carnegie Mellon University. His doctorate (Management/ Entrepreneurship) he got from Case Western Reserve University. Paper: STKI 132 November 2005

Transcript of STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT...

Page 1: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND

EXECUTIVE IN RESIDENCY PROGRAMS

By

Dr. Jimmy Schwarzkopf Research Fellow & Partner

STKI [email protected]

Dr. Schwarzkopf has worked during the last 30 years in all areas of Computer Information Services. IT Analyst as META Group Israeli Research Manager and was named a META Group Research Fellow. As an academic researcher in Entrepreneurship Sciences has published and presented in the Academy of Management and Babson Conferences. As a consultant in Arthur Andersen Consulting (USA), Booz Allen (USA) and Kesselman & Kesselman. As a systems professional in SCS Computers and the R&D Unit of the Israel Defense Forces. As a sales and marketing professional in Digital Equipment Corporation. Teaching in the MIS department at Ben Gurion University and the Computer Schoolof the IDF. Entrepreneur founding two companies in the IT arena: store and forward mail and office informationsystems.

Dr. Schwarzkopf received BSE and MSE degrees (Systems Engineering) from the University of Central Florida. Got his MSIA (Management Information Systems) and ABD (PhD Program) in Systems Science (received (twice) the WilliamLarimer Mellon Scholarship/Award) from Carnegie Mellon University. His doctorate (Management/ Entrepreneurship)he got from Case Western Reserve University.

Paper: STKI 132 November 2005

Page 2: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

2

STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND

EXECUTIVE IN RESIDENCY PROGRAMS

ABSTRACT

What constitutes venture capital and what constitutes angel financing is a natural

question. In the time period after the bubble burst in 2000 it became easy to differentiate: 1. Angel investors: usually “high status” individuals, former successful

technology entrepreneurs who use their financial wealth, which financed birth and initial growth of ventures.

2. Venture capital (VC): independently managed, dedicated pools of capital that focus on equity-linked investments in privately held, high growth companies needing mid stage financing. Startup/seed financing were usually not acceptable VC funding phases, because of the greater risks involved.

The growth in “Startup/Seed Financing” by VCs (almost 100% in Israel during FY 2004 alone), shows that Israeli VCs contrary to their Silicon Valley counterparts are interested in participating earlier in the venture’s life.

In the post Google IPO era, since 2004, Israeli VC partnerships are eagerly pursuing “good” startup/seed ventures, by using a combination of new programs like the “Entrepreneur/Executive in Residency (EIR)” programs among others. No academic papers that analyze these phenomena or even describe it have been found. On the other hand, newspapers and VC magazines have mentioned and described the work of EIRs in the VC industry in Israel.

The purpose of this paper is to conceptualize the characteristics of and relationships between: “VC partners” and the “Entrepreneurs” who received financing in the startup/seed phases. This will allow comparison between many types of VC-Entrepreneur relationships in startup/seed stage ventures and shed light on the nascent entrepreneurs and the EIR programs in particular. We believe that knowledge concerning this type of program will help VCs in other countries by either encouraging them to adopt this practice or to abandon it. The question of how VC equity financing will evolve over the next decade and how it will work with startup/seed ventures is a particularly critical one.

Page 3: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

3

TABLE OF CONTENTS Abstract ..................................................................................................................................... 2 Introduction ............................................................................................................................... 4 Discovery, Innovation and Entrepreneurship ......................................................................... 13 The Conceptual Model ............................................................................................................ 18 Variables ................................................................................................................................. 19 Research Questions ................................................................................................................. 34 References ............................................................................................................................... 37 List of Figures

Figure 1: Amount Raised by Israeli High Tech Companies ($M) ............................... 7 Figure 2: Capital Raised by Israeli Seed Companies ($M) .......................................... 8 Figure 3: Number of Israeli High-Tech Companies by Sector and Stage (2/05) ......... 9 Figure 4: The Conceptual Model ............................................................................... 19

Page 4: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

4

INTRODUCTION Venture capital has proven to be one of the most capital efficient mechanisms for

building high-tech companies and job creation in Israel. Since 1995, the Israeli economy has

experienced an inflow of $43 billion ($16 billion through VC investments, $20 billion in

proceeds from these ventures and $7 billion from VC backed IPO’s) (IVA 2005 Yearbook).

A combination of regional advantages and historical accidents conspired to produce

in Israel the second greatest (after Silicon Valley) "Science Park" in the world. In terms of

recent patents per capita, Israel stands third after USA and Japan (Trajtenberg, 2001). During

the last three decades, Israel has shown dramatic growth in technological startups and is one

of the world’s largest recipients of venture capital financing. By virtue of Israel’s

entrepreneurial culture and close ties to America, Israeli startups have a strong presence in

the United States. Check any technological start-up in the USA, and odds are that one of its

competitors is an Israeli company (Bednarz, 2005). More Israeli companies are listed on

NASDAQ than those of any other country outside North America- 70 out of 340 foreign

listings (Canada has 80). Israeli start-ups have raised more than $5.2 billion in initial public

offerings on NASDAQ in the last 5 years. This continued growth is directly related to the

number of serial entrepreneurs getting back in the industry (IVC Research Center Surveys).

The size of the venture capital pool available for early-stage (both startup/seed and R&D

stages) financing has grown in only two countries: USA has $3.65 billion and Israel has $.55

billion, while the rest of the world together has less than $.4 billion (Acs & Audretsch; 2003)

Venture money is not long-term money. The concept is to invest in an idea or new

technology, create a company and as soon as it reaches a sufficient size and credibility sell it

to a corporation or to the public-equity markets. Venture capitals’ niche exists because of the

Page 5: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

5

structure and rules of capital markets (Zider, 1998). Banks will only finance a new business

to the extent that there are hard assets against which to secure the debt. Most startup/seed

ventures have few hard assets. Usury laws limit the interest banks can charge on loans and

the risks inherent in startup/seed ventures justify higher rates than allowed by law. Usually,

in return for financing one to five years of a company’s start-up, venture capitalists expect a

ten-fold return of capital. Combined with the preferred position and stock options this is a

very high cost on capital. This equity investment is like a loan with a 60%+ annual

compound interest rate that cannot be prepaid (Zider, 1998).

Venture capital fills the void between personal sources of funds for innovation

(usually provided by friends and family of the entrepreneur, government programs or

corporate venture funds) or angel financing (former successful technology entrepreneurs that

use their financial wealth) and later-stage traditional sources of merchant capital available to

ongoing enterprises.

The VC industry has three “clients” it needs to satisfy in order to succeed. The fund

is required to: 1) provide a sufficient return on capital in order to attract investment from

individuals and private equity funds, 2) attractive returns for its own participants, 3)upside

potential to the “right” entrepreneurs in order to attract “ideas that will generate high returns”

(Zider, 1998). The challenge for a VC is to earn consistently a superior return on investment

in inherently risky business ventures. Institutions and individuals invest in a VC fund based

on its track record, confidence in the VC partners themselves and the entrepreneurs the VC

finances.

Investment behavior by Israeli technological investors can be divided into five eras:

Genesis (up to 1987), post-market crash (1987-1995), post-Netscape IPO (1995-2000), post-

Page 6: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

6

bubble (2000-2004) and post-Google IPO (post 2004). In a short description of the VC

behavior during these eras we have:

1. GENESIS (up to 1987): Investors usually invested in spillovers from corporations and in a few garage entrepreneurs with revolutionary ideas. In Silicon Valley we had Intel and Apple among others. In Israel, we had Scitex, Elscint, Elta and Elbit among others. The Israeli government interfered in 1985, by passing the law for the Encouragement of Industrial R&D Investments. Israel high-tech exports grew from a mere $422 million in 1969 (in 1987 dollars) to $3,316 million in 1987 (Toren, 1990).

2. POST-MARKET CRASH (1987-1995): The VC industry in Silicon Valley shifted its investment focus away from startups/seed firms, in favor of mature ventures (that is, development finance) and leveraged buyouts and buyins. The Israeli Government, in 1991, decided to play a role in the development of Israeli venture capital markets in two ways:

a. Funded several technological incubators where novice entrepreneurs would get a supportive framework (grants, infrastructure and guidance) in order to translate ideas into their own companies. 700 companies started in the incubators and in the year 2000: 200 were still there, 250 had closed, 200 got VC investment and 50 where on their own (Trajtenberg, 2001).

b. The Israeli Government financed hybrid (public/private) venture capital funds to leverage private capital from foreign investors (Trajtenberg, 2001). Yozma Fund (as it was named) took equity stakes in 10 US style venture operations (the program included equity guarantees and tax breaks). When the program was declared successful (catalyzing the establishment of the VC industry), it was privatized and sold. (OECD, 2003).

The VC industry in Israel was ready for the new era.

3. POST-NETSCAPE IPO (1995-2000): The VC industry, in Silicon Valley as

in Israel, now focused on ventures in the new ICT (communications/ software/ internet) areas. In Silicon Valley, VC investment in startup/seed ventures grew from 0.64% of total investment in Q1/1995 to over 9.17% in Q3/1999 (Moneytree Survey). The VC industry in Israel matured. From the $3,092 million invested in Israeli High Tech Industries in 2000, over 40% was from Israeli VC firms (see figure 1). Startup/seed investment, in Israel, crossed the 17% of total investment in 2000 (Moneytree Survey).

Page 7: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

7

FIGURE 1: Amount Raised by Israeli High Tech Companies ($M)

4. POST-BUBBLE (2000-2004): During the post-bubble era, VCs needed success stories in order to gain back confidence from investors. This forced most technology VCs to avoid startup/seed ventures where technologies are uncertain and market needs are unknown. Also, the structure of VC partnerships used to be inappropriate for startup/seed investments. Investments (startup/seed stage more than others) are usually very time consuming to negotiate and monitor. The typical venture capitalist constrained by governance and regulatory considerations could typically be responsible for no more than a dozen investments. VCs consequentially were unwilling to invest in very young firms that only required small investments but the same amount of monitoring and involvement (Gompers & Lerner, 2003). The VC industry everywhere was hurting. Israeli VCs raised $3,711 million in 2000 and $-174 million in 2002 (reflecting $221 million refunded by the funds that year). Israeli VC investment in startup/seed ventures also plummeted in 2002 (figure 2) to 4% of total (IVC Research Center Annual Report). In Silicon Valley, startup/seed investment fell to 0.31% of total in 2Q2002 (Moneytree Survey). Most of the amount that VCs were willing to invest was channeled to more mature ventures. The Israeli government again interfered with several startup/seed programs in 2002.

a. TNUFA: Grants for preparation of business plans and patent proposals.

b. HEZNEK: The program invests in startup/seed ventures together with a VC fund (50% and up to $1.1million) in exchange for non-voting rights shares. The investing VC has the option of buying-out the government’s share at any time within the first 7 years.

Page 8: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

8

This program helped keep a minimum positive amount of startup/seed investment

by reducing risk for the VC fund. See figure 2.

FIGURE 2: Capital Raised by Israeli Seed Companies ($M)

5. POST-GOOGLE IPO (after 2004): The VC industry understood that they are in a cyclical industry with cycles shorter than those of other merchant capital suppliers. Israeli VC funds also saw the importance of a portfolio with a significant amount of startup/seed ventures. In 2004, Israeli VCs invested 11% of the total in startup/seed ventures (IVC annual report 2005). In contrast, Silicon Valley VCs are shunning away from startup/seed ventures and they invested only 0.1% of total during 1h/2005 (Moneytree Survey).

Page 9: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

9

FIGURE 3: Number of Israeli High-Tech Companies by Sector and Stage (2/05)

Technology VCs were always looking for good technology-managers in particular

industries (see figure 3) so that they can invest part of the fund in startup/seed stage ventures

(Zider, 1998). Industry investment composition suggests that venture capitalists specialize in

industries in which the monitoring and information evaluations are important and in which at

least one of the partners has the required knowledge (Acs & Audretsch, 2003). VCs (post

bubble) focused mainly on the middle part of the classic industry S-curve. They avoided both

the startup/seeds, when technologies are uncertain and market needs are unknown, and the

later stages, when competitive shakeouts and consolidations are inevitable and growth rates

slow dramatically (Zider, 1998). In this research, we will only look at one of these industries:

the Information and Communication Technology (ICT) industry (figure 3: IT & Enterprise

Page 10: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

10

Software, Communication and Internet categories) and concentrate on what is happening in

the post-Google IPO era.

To a venture capitalist of the 21st century, the crown jewels of a hot new tech venture

are not the closely guarded software codes but the talented people who can quickly transform

the technology into a revenue-generating product that leads the venture to a blockbuster IPO

or a lucrative acquisition. These stars, dubbed simply “the talent” are not young and restless

Gen Xers slaving away in garages: they are people who, in one way or another, have been

around long enough to earn a few stripes (Warner, 1998). As Georges Doriot said in the

1940s –“Always consider investing in a grade A man with a grade B idea. Never invest in a

grade B man with a grade A idea”- (quoted in Bruton, Fried & Hisrich, 1997: 41). It is

clearly the “entrepreneurial team- VC partner” teams that will often separate the “winners”

from the “losers” in startup/seed startups. The small number of good, experienced

technology-managers in the ICT industry (who can deal with uncertainty, high growth and

high risk) who also have a “new” idea for a venture means that the supply of startup/seed

ventures, that would qualify for VC funds, are few and far between (Jacobius, 2004). VC

emphasis on serial entrepreneurs does have some repercussions that are not necessarily

positive (IVC 5/2005). It clearly does not give sufficient opportunities to first-time

entrepreneurs who have a hard time finding a VC that believes in their ability to execute the

business plan. The VC partners have come with the Entrepreneur/Executive in Residency

(EIR) programs in order to enlist both (ideas and people) separately (asynchronously).

Many Israeli VCs have created these Entrepreneur/Executive in Residence (EIR)

programs in order to optimize their own search for the next startup, which they hope may be

a new company that the EIR forms or joins during their tenure at the VC.

Page 11: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

11

“Entrepreneur/Executive in Residence (EIR)” is a position found mostly in Israeli VC

partnerships interested in the ICT start-up industry. The EIR concept has been around for a

while. Competition for talent has grown feverish, so most Israeli VC ventures are relying on

it, more and more (IVC 5/2005).

People chosen for the EIR programs have usually been involved in a number of

startups, and more often than not, have succeeded by taking their companies public or have

been acquired. Whatever the case may be, they are looked upon as having “high status” in

their particular field of knowledge. In other words, an EIR is a person who has an

outstanding record of accomplishment as either an executive or technologist and who joins a

VC partnership as an interim step to his next venture. The EIR program is designed to

provide these entrepreneurs, seeking their next business venture, with the network, resources

and tools to identify emerging market segments and business opportunities. The EIR program

also gives the entrepreneur special and unique experience by participating and learning many

venture capital activities.

“Entrepreneur/Executive in Residence (EIR)” programs have many functions within a

VC. In some VCs, EIRs act as consultants who specialize in particular industries and can

lend significant value in terms of screening entrepreneurs who pitch to VCs for startup/seed

financing. In other cases, EIRs do more than consulting with the VC venture organizations.

EIRs actually “incubate” an idea, while getting a salary and/or support of researchers for

market studies (in order to validate a technological idea), from the VC. Eventually he/she

will form their own company, or join a team which the VC will fund. Israeli VCs are eagerly

pursuing “good” startup/seed ventures, where they can double or triple their startup valuation

from one round of financing to the next. The question of how equity financing will evolve

Page 12: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

12

over the next decade is a particularly critical one given the entrance of VC funds (with EIR

programs) into very early, even pre-birth stage of ventures. This stage was populated

previously only by “angel” investors.

This latter function, the start of new ventures by EIR programs is the subject of this

study. I will study both types of EIRs (those that come up with the idea and those that join a

team that came up with the idea). The EIR will get a small amount of funding (from the VC)

categorized as “pre-seed” (this “pre-seed” financing could be an actual investment or it could

be the funding of research) to create a commercially viable business in the ICT industry in

Israel.

This study might, at a future point in time, also compare startup/seed investment

programs by VCs in Israel with those in other places, especially Silicon Valley.

The venture’s success is based on many factors. One of these factors is the VC-

Entrepreneur relationship. This relationship is based on the particular VC fund culture, the

VC partner and the entrepreneur’s background and so will greatly influence the venture’s

success.

What this research will be looking for is the relationships in a startup/seed venture

between the VC partner and the entrepreneurial team. Sweat equity (non-financial

investment) is an integral component in the relationship between VC partners and

entrepreneurs. VCs assume that an EIR program will optimize the relationship and in doing

so maximize profits. The VCs with EIR programs want to participate in the initial stage of a

venture and supply funds for the innovation stage (startup/seed).

These Entrepreneur/Executive in Residence programs are based on the need of the

VCs to predict through differences in individuals the how, why and where of their new

Page 13: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

13

successful innovative venture. What VCs expect from their EIRs is the chance to invest in a

company’s startup/seeds, when the stock is the cheapest and the potential for big returns the

greatest. EIRs also allow the VC to enter the food chain at an earlier stage. Venture capital

executives assert that the companies that come from an EIR program will sell for more

(Jacobius, 2004) when it comes time for the venture capitalist to exit the deal (venture). No

prior research has examined the effects of the post Google IPO reactions on VC investments

and their decision on how or why to enter startup/seed stage ventures. No research has yet

tracked results of companies that have come out of EIR programs or to explain what factors

influence the degree of success of an EIR relationship (no academic papers that dealt in the

subject were found, only references in the VC professional literature).

This research will look at the ICT “startup/seed” startups in Israel; look at results

coming from “high status” entrepreneurs in the Entrepreneur/Executive in Residence (EIR)

programs versus equally “high status” entrepreneurs that are not in EIR programs. VC

partners and their ventures’ entrepreneurs plus some first time entrepreneurs (that received

startup/seed investments, from VC funds), will be interviewed. Allowing comparisons

between many types of VC-Entrepreneur relationships and the results of these varied

relationships, can shed light on startup/seed investments and the EIR programs in particular.

I believe that knowledge about this type of program will help VCs, by encouraging them to

adopt this practice if it enhances the end result, or to abandon it if it makes no difference.

DISCOVERY, INNOVATION AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP

The literature on entrepreneurship can be classified into two schools of thought

(Thornton, 1999). The supply side school, focuses on the availability of suitable individuals

to occupy entrepreneurial roles and the “demand side” school, which focuses on the number

Page 14: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

14

and nature of the entrepreneurial roles that need to be filled. The Entrepreneur/Executive in

Residence programs basically requires us to look at both sides and in doing so find a model

that combines both.

The literature on the demand side of entrepreneurship suggests a number of ways to

examine where entrepreneurs are needed, relationships with VCs, the management theories

that describe the organizations/ventures, and the context of organizational funding. From this

perspective, demand side researchers have studied new ventures by organizational

hierarchies (Freeman, 1986), activity of the professions (Wholley et al, 1993), policies of

nation states (Doboin & Doud, 1997), development of markets (White, 1981; King & Levine,

1993) and advent of new technological change (Shane, 1996). These studies focus on the

number and nature of the entrepreneurial roles that need to be filled.

Supply side research, which focuses on the availability of suitable individuals to

occupy entrepreneurial roles tries to predict through differences in individuals the how, why

and where of new ventures. Supply side approaches have examined attributes of culture

(Weber, 1998; Shane, 1993), and social class and ethnic groups (Aldrich & Waldinger,

1990). The idea that psychological traits alone account for entrepreneurship has been largely

abandoned (Thornton, 1999) but we still know that special types of individuals create

opportunities and VCs need an adequate supply of them. Clearly, the founding of a venture

may be dependent on the individual entrepreneur (as supply-side analysis suggests) (Shaver

& Scott, 1991), but it is also clear that an individual cannot mobilize without an

infrastructure (as demand-side analysis suggests).

In EIR programs, venture capitalists buy into the ability of the entrepreneur to

discover opportunities from technological changes leading to new processes, products,

Page 15: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

15

markets or ways of organizing them, while the entrepreneur buys into the VC’s ability to

provide the capital and infrastructure he needs. This shows that a hybrid (supply/demand)

theory is needed when explaining the EIR programs.

Entrepreneurship and Economic Theories

EIR programs are about discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities. Unfortunately,

most research on entrepreneurship investigates the entrepreneurial process after opportunities

have been discovered (Shane, 2000). In order to explain EIR we need to look at theories of

opportunities based on market theories from the various schools of economics.

Neoclassical economics assumes that markets are composed of maximizing agents

whose decisions about prices clear markets. Researchers in this field ignore the existence of

entrepreneurs, stating that people will discover the same opportunities in any given

technological change (Khilstrom & Laffont, 1979). This makes it not relevant for the EIR

trend research.

Psychological theories define entrepreneurship as a function of “stable’

characteristics possessed by some people and not others: need for achievement (McClelland,

1961), willingness to bear risk (Brockhaus & Horowitz, 1986), self efficacy (Chen, et.

al.1998) and internal locus of control, tolerance and ambiguity (Begley & Boyd, 1987). In

other words, they assume that attributes of people rather than information about opportunities

determine who becomes an entrepreneur. This process depends on people’s ability and

willingness to take action. Research by this school focusing on the discovery process finds

that discovery depends on relative differences between people and in their willingness to

search for and identify opportunity (Shane & Venkataraman, 2000), also in the superior

information processing ability, search techniques or scanning behavior that makes some

Page 16: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

16

people more able or willing to discover opportunity (Shaver & Scott, 1991). Most modern

researchers are skeptical of born “DNA-based” high tech entrepreneur theories. Israeli VC

funds do not use psychological testing techniques in order to find EIRs but they do talk about

“born” entrepreneurs.

The Austrians, on the other hand, assert that markets are composed of people that

possess different information (Hayek, 1945) and that the discovery of opportunity cannot be

understood through mechanical computation because any given individual cannot identify all

possible opportunities (Kirzner, 1973). Differences in information lead people to see

different value in a given good or service and offer different prices to obtain or sell it. In

other words, by buying or selling goods or services in response to the discovery of price

misalignments, an individual can earn entrepreneurial profits or incur entrepreneurial losses.

The most important part of Austrian economics (Kirzner, 1985), needed in order to explain

the EIR programs, is that possession of information (based on career choices and experience)

that is appropriate to a particular opportunity leads to opportunity discovery. Nobody is more

likely than anyone else (at birth) to become an entrepreneur. Individual differences and

experiences in an individual’s life path affect the way people exploit opportunities, while

ignoring attributes of the opportunities themselves. Different people will discover different

opportunities in a given technological change because they possess different prior knowledge

(Venkataraman, 1997).

Newer research shows that some inventors failed to recognize the commercial value

of their own inventions. A small amount of technological change might generate a large

amount of economic output because entrepreneurs can discover a large number of

Page 17: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

17

opportunities in which to exploit the technology (or vice versa: large amount of technology

change can produce small amounts of output) (Shane, 2000).

The EIR programs are based on the assumption that entrepreneurs discover

opportunities, not because they where born with special attributes (e.g., unusual perceptive

ability) that makes them able to recognize opportunities, but because career experiences and

the prior knowledge gained makes people better able to discover certain opportunities than

others (Shane, 2000). Another assumption is that entrepreneurship cannot be explained solely

by reference to factors external to individuals, like competition or the entrepreneur’s prior

founding experience (Singh & Lumsden, 1990), although prior founding experience is

considered important in the EIR programs.

Sources of prior knowledge that lead to opportunity discovery are idiosyncratic,

resulting from work experience, personal events and university education (Venkataraman,

1997). EIRs will be able to discover opportunities in sectors that they know well rather than

in sectors that are hot (Shane, 2000). We hope to research if when evaluating opportunities,

entrepreneurs use only the ones they identify themselves or EIRs can use information about

new opportunities by also evaluating and understanding proposals from other entrepreneurs,

that reach the aligned VC firm.

We will research the factors (if any) of the long term effects of military training

(social and technological) in the EIR and VC partner relationship. We will suggest that social

skills and willingness to take risks by some Israeli youth during their military service (elite

combat and/or technological units) will influence their post-military careers as civilian

entrepreneurs. The early age (usually 20) when Israelis receive managerial responsibilities

Page 18: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

18

(officer rank) and the continued reserve duty (in some cases up to age 60) determine social

capital and trust between members of the same background.

Research on the relationship between the EIR, the VC partner and the firm is

contradictory. On one hand it states that entrepreneurial differences may imprint the

development of new organizations even before they are founded (Shane, 2000); on the other

hand, research shows that organizations are programmed only during venture infancy, not

before birth (Stinchcombe, 1965). We suggest that the VC partner-EIR relationship influence

and define the venture even before the “idea” for the venture is established.

THE CONCEPTUAL MODEL The ability to predict venture performance based on observable initial factors is an art

and the following model does not try to climb such a high mountain. However, the central

argument of the EIR program and the following model (figure 4) is that the ability of a

venture to get funding, its survival and its success are fundamentally shaped by the pre-entry

experiences of their founders (Klepper, 2001; 2002; Carrol et al, 1996) and by features and

trust of the VC-entrepreneurial team relationship.

Startup/seed investments in Israel are becoming very attractive, and VC funds are

investing double the amount they invested in previous years. VCs are now constantly looking

at the startup/seed investment market. This study will try to model (see Fig: 4) the

relationships between different types of entrepreneurs and the VC partners in those

startup/seed ventures. The model will also try to explain if “Entrepreneur/Executive in

Residence (EIR)” programs, which many VCs are using today, affect the marginal funding

and survival probability, as well as the likelihood for a high performance venture.

Page 19: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

19

FIGURE 4: The Conceptual Model

VARIABLES

Dependent Variable

Empirically defining venture success is problematic (Solymossy, 2000). This study

uses a multidimensional framework for defining success for the entrepreneur, the venture and

the VC partner. In the EIR program, the VC partner and the EIR commit to each other at the

beginning of the relationship and align their goals at that point.

There is an ongoing discussion about suitable indicators of new venture performance

(Brush & Vanderwerf, 1992; Wiklund, 1998). Measures have ranged from subjective self-

assessment to quantified and reasonably objective measures of economic performance

(Sexton, et al., 1997). Usually, broad measures reflecting multiple aspects of both growth and

Page 20: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

20

economic performance are preferable (Wiklund, 1998). The venture capital-backed firm has

a very limited financial history during the elapsed time between birth and next step financing.

There are several options that the research can follow during the qualitative phase

of this study:

1. Following Cooper, et al., (1994), new venture performance can be classified into three mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive categories: failure, marginal survival and high performance.

2. Following Dahlqvist, Davidson, Wiklund (2000) and Solymossy (2000)

new venture performance can be measured by sales growth, employment growth and profitability.

3. Subjective self-assessment of difference at two points: at venture birth

(how easy it was to get funding) or ability to get next phase investment. The dependent variable in this model preferably will always be, if available, the

increase in valuation of the venture. The key argument is that ”high status” entrepreneurs in

EIR programs facilitated by a good and extensive relationship with the VC partner can

produce better returns in a venture than other entrepreneurs of equal “high status” standing.

Independent Variables

Entrepreneurial research shows increasingly that the individual “high status”

entrepreneur is at the cornerstone of the development of new opportunities and the founding

process (Busenitz & Barney, 1997; Shane & Venkataraman, 2000). Even the VC literature is

drawing attention to the centrality of this “high status” entrepreneur and the founding team

(Bygrave & Timmons, 1992) and the quality of the founding entrepreneur in the funding

decision (Zacharis, Meyer & Castro, 1999). In this study entrepreneurs can attain “High

Status” by any of three ways:

1. Technological Prior Knowledge (TPK),

Page 21: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

21

2. Managerial Prior Knowledge (MPK)

3. Served the IDF (Israel Defense Forces) in the Computer Units or as a Combat Officer.

In contrast, using other research on technological entrepreneurship we can show that

it involves agency on the part of many actors, well beyond just the “high status”

entrepreneurs themselves, it is path dependent and embedded in the technological system

developed (Garaud & Karnoe, 2003). In other words, the relationships and backgrounds of

both the VC partner and the entrepreneur in what we can call “Israeli Start-up Scene”.

The Israeli Start-up Scene

In this study, the scene of the “Israeli Start-up Valley” will be investigated by

comparing backgrounds of both VC partners and entrepreneurs plus their relationships, in

other words their social capital. The Information and Communication Technology (ICT)

entrepreneur, in Israel, is the modern-day “pioneer”, roaming new technology frontiers much

the same as earlier Israelis (late nineteen century) dried swamps and built roads and

kibbutzim. As modern-day pioneers, they are especially responsive to risky ventures that

have the potential for great rewards. Israeli society acknowledges the successful

entrepreneurs who have taken aggressive professional and technical risks (the garage

tinkerers who created successful companies) as heroes and attaches little, if any, stigma to

trying and failing in a new venture. Leaving a venture to work for another and eventually

returning even to the same venture is rewarded (Ariav & Goodman, 1994).

Research suggests that government promotion of ICT, high levels of private sector

R&D investment and an education system that produces ICT-literate graduates are the most

important factors in ICT industry success (Watson & Myers, 2001). Many people have

Page 22: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

22

attributed the success of Israel’s ICT industries primarily to the influence of institutions of

higher education (Technion and Weitzman Institute) and the high technological environments

(weapon systems developed in Israel or in partnership with American contractors) in the

defense forces (Cummings, 2005). From previous research, we know that universities can

influence the rate at which ventures are founded by making equity investments and giving

professor-inventors a share of royalties (Digregorio & Shane, 2003).

The technological prowess of the Israeli military is a catalyst for entrepreneurship. A

disproportionate number of Israeli veterans begin their own businesses often in highly

competitive technical fields. A lack of resources means soldiers have to be precise, outwit

their enemies with greater skill and regard themselves, as team members of a smaller force,

more personally accountable for their actions – all elements inherent in making a business

thrive (Cummings, 2005). The roles of government (military research) and the natural

environment (no natural resources) of Israel cannot be underestimated. The relocation of

efforts from military research (mid 1990s) into civilian research brought defense R&D

technologies/management knowledge into the private market.

The members of this technological society (entrepreneurs and VC partners) are a

strongly homogeneous group: male, alumni of the IDF (Israeli Defense Forces) computer

units (or officers in elite combat units) and engineers/computer scientists by education.

Although they may have gone to US universities for graduate degrees or later worked in

Silicon Valley, they return in order to create their next venture in Israel (Cummings, 2005).

Israeli ICT ventures and VC funds collaborate with one another in formal and

informal ways, developing alliances, contracting for services, or simply sharing information.

Employees of different ventures mix frequently in reserve duty (military), local business and

Page 23: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

23

social gatherings. Along with sharing the same type of risks, the entrepreneurs also share a

camaraderie unsurpassed almost anywhere else in the ICT industry (except maybe for Silicon

Valley). Even engineers and scientists who work at competing ventures during the workday

remain close friends off the job. The young engineers and programmers meet at popular

social establishments or in reserve military duty to share high-tech "war stories." These

discussions enable the individuals to share industry gossip as well as facilitate employment

searches in other ventures (Cummings, 2005).

Some structural analysts have found that social networks have similar properties in

different countries. This type of social capital was first identified in Silicon Valley (Saxenian,

1994) where in forums based on relationships that are easily formed and maintained,

technical and market information is exchanged, business contacts are established and new

enterprises are conceived. Entrepreneurial capital like this also promotes the diffusion of

intangible technological capabilities and understandings (Saxenian, 1994).

EIR role in the VC prior to start of the venture. Not all entrepreneurs have a

previously well-defined concept to the point where it is ripe for investment. Some do not

have a concept at all. EIRs will be at different points in their future ventures. The conditions

of the EIR in the VC premises and his other obligations with the partners will no doubt

influence the concept, the relationship and the attention given by the partners (not just in the

business environment but on other important issues). The only other research study found

about VC and Entrepreneur having a commitment of employment for the latter (Hoffman &

Blakey, 1987) showed how it affected positively in the earlier stages of the relationship.

Entrepreneur’s “previous knowledge”. The identification of opportunities has been

recognized as one of the most important abilities of successful entrepreneurs (Ardichvili,

Page 24: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

24

Cardozo & Ray, 2003). Opportunity identification may be related to, among other factors,

entrepreneurial alertness (Kirzner, 1973), prior knowledge (Shane, 2000), social networks

(Singh, Hills, Hybels, & Lumpkin, 1999), entrepreneurial cognition (Baron, 1998) and

potential financial reward (Schumpeter, 1976).

Prior knowledge, which refers to an individual’s distinctive information about a

particular subject matter, may be the result of work experience (Evans & Leighton, 1989;

Cooper, Gimeno & Wo, 1994), university education (Gimeno, Folta, Cooper & Wo, 1997) or

other means (Shane, 2000). It may be accumulated through experimental learning and/or

through second-hand experience. As individuals become knowledgeable at a particular task

through experience, they become increasingly efficient; they learn to focus attention

primarily on the key dimensions; the ones that contribute most variance to the outcome of

decisions (Choo & Trotman, 1991). Individuals with more knowledge appear to think in a

more intuitive way in similar situations.

In conclusion, research in this area shows that higher levels of prior knowledge are

associated with the identification of a greater number of innovative opportunities. The study

will quantify the entrepreneur’s “previous knowledge” in each of the following areas:

technology knowledge, network development, software development, hardware

development, educational achievements, market knowledge, customers’ needs and problems,

industry trends, management experience, VC relations, prior founding, management

education, top management, project management, financial management and general

management.

Sources of “high status” of the entrepreneur. Starting a new venture is fraught

with difficulties that are particularly severe for inexperienced entrepreneurs. Founding

Page 25: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

25

propensity is a factor that varies over an individual’s life course. Unlike psychological traits,

careers are dynamic. Careers are a series of choices that individuals make based on the

opportunities available to them (Shane & Khurana, 2001). Which opportunities are available

to each individual is a function of where they are in the social structure and how they got

there (Shane & Khurana, 2001).

The biggest opportunity that an entrepreneur can get is becoming a member of the

EIR program in a first tier VC partnership: the VCs transfer legitimacy to the entrepreneur in

their portfolio (Fried & Hisrich, 1995). Entrepreneurs who possess greater legitimacy can

more easily obtain necessary resources than those who do not exhibit certain legitimating

characteristics (Hannan & Freeman, 1989).

Entrepreneurs require information, capital, skills and labor to get funding for a

venture. While they hold some of these resources themselves, they often complement their

resources by accessing their contacts (Aldrich & Waldinger, 1990; Hansen, 1995; Cooper,

Folta & Woo, 1995). The contacts that lead to successful outcomes are part of their social

capital and a key component of entrepreneurial networks (Burt, 1992). Social capital is the

set of tangible or virtual resources that accrue to entrepreneurs through the social structure,

facilitating the attainment of their goals (Lin, 1998; Portes, 1998). By this, they include

contacts that help them get things done. When the entrepreneur’s contacts contribute to their

entrepreneurial goals, these social contacts are their social capital (Burt, 1992). These

relations extend across professional networks, reaching friends and colleagues from earlier

jobs.

“High status” entrepreneurs’ networks span relations to organizations, clusters of

firms, as well as to other people that help them set up the venture (Hansen, 1995). Linking

Page 26: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

26

“high status” entrepreneur’s career experience to the startup founding success is important

for the EIR model in this study. An entrepreneur’s career experiences show that they

influence venture founding by mitigating the liability of newness (Stinchcombe, 1965), they

confer status (Blau & Duncan, 1967), they affect capabilities and skills of individuals

(Becker, 1975) and finally they shape the resource networks of the entrepreneur (Burt, 1992;

Granovetter, 1974).

“High status” entrepreneurs’ prior founding experience will provide external

constituents with positive evidence that the entrepreneur has successfully completed the

difficult process of adapting to the role of venture founder and has developed the skills

necessary to found and manage an organization (Shane & Khurana, 2001). Their prior

experience in gathering resources enhances the strength of those relationships as well

(Aldrich & Waldinger 1990).

An entrepreneur in Israel achieves “high status” by a combination of many different

factors. The first, a must, has to be previous entrepreneurial activity that includes previous

venture founding. Second, he could have worked in the market as a customer (in the IDF

computer units) or supplier (in software development), possessing information not publicly

available about the ICT technology in question. Alternatively - a third factor – he could have

served as an officer in an extremely prestigious combat unit (fighter pilot, commando and

other elite forces) where his managerial skills shined while working in teams.

High status entrepreneurs will be more likely to found firms than entrepreneurs of

low status because their status will generate the necessary legitimacy to motivate potential

investors, employees and other stakeholders to reallocate resources to the new venture. Their

status gives the stakeholders more confidence in the ideas they are proposing and makes

Page 27: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

27

them more likely to attribute high value to those ideas (Shane & Khurana, 2001). In the case

of an invention, evaluators will rely on the status of the inventor in making decisions about

the opportunity (Merton, 1973).

Mediating Variables

Some VC funds will target startup projects because the returns from successful

startup/seed investments can be several times higher than later-stage investments. Even

though the potential for higher returns is generally recognized, no more than a low

percentage of venture capital funds portfolio focuses primarily on such investments, mostly

because successfully managing the risks of startup/seed investments demand more from the

investment team than the traditional monitoring approach used for later stage investments

(Roberts & Tempest, 1998). When the new venture obtains financing from the VCs to aid in

its development (Mason & Harrison, 1996) it requires greater care and investment discipline,

and implementation of programs, like the EIR, that create an opportunity in this newly-

served investment segment.

Once an investment is made, the investment is illiquid, and its success is highly

dependent on a small group of managers/entrepreneurs in the venture (Fried & Hisrich,

1994). It is in the interests of both entrepreneurs and VC fund partners to do everything

possible to ensure that their operating venture succeeds; they effectively become active

collaborators.

Post investment activities. Involvement can take place across the whole spectrum

of managerial activity, from strategic planning to operational matters. VCs can be vigorous

and influential board members and play a significant part in shaping operating strategies

(Rosenstein, et al., 1993). Mainly because of time constraints, VCs tend not to become over-

Page 28: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

28

involved in day-to-day operations unless major problems arise; assistance most frequently

given includes help in raising additional funds, strategic planning and management

recruitment (Gorman & Sahlman, 1989). Paradoxically, a more intense level of involvement

by VCs does not necessarily mean that ventures will necessarily operate any better than

where there is only a limited involvement (Macmillan et al., 1989).

The perceptions of the relationship (non-financial involvement sweat equity).

Significant information asymmetries allow entrepreneurs to engage in opportunistic behavior

after an investment is made (Sahlman, 1998), making it all the more important that the initial

decision to invest be one based on trust and “influenced by the VC partner and entrepreneur

forecasted relationship”.

The dynamic ownership and working arrangements surrounding the VC-E

relationship inherent in new ventures always influence the outcome (Arthurs & Busenitz,

2003). VC contribution to the VC-E relationship is not solely financial (Busenitz, 1999). In

addition to providing risk capital, in exchange for partial ownership of the venture, Israeli

VCs are typically active investors. They seek to add value through their interaction with and

advice for the managers of the entrepreneurial venture (Macmillian, Kulow & Khoylian,

1989; Bygrave & Timmons, 1992), as well as through their monitoring and reorganizing of

the companies in which they participate (Sapienza & Gupta, 1994). Efforts to explain this

intriguing VC-E relationship have relied on agency theory (Sahlman, 1990; Sapienza and

Gupta, 1994; Barney et al., 1989) and stewardship theory (Fox & Hamilton, 1994; Davis, et

al., 1997; Arthurs & Busenitz, 2003).

Agency theory prescribes actions that focus on the protection of the investment of the

principal (VC) against the “harmful” behaviors of the agent (entrepreneur) (Jensen &

Page 29: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

29

Meckling, 1976). This principal-agent relationship arises when the entrepreneur engages the

VC for funding of a new venture (Amit et al., 1990; Sahlman, 1990). This theory assumes

that both the agent and principal are self-interested and bounded rational (Eisenhard, 1989),

forcing the enactment of proper incentives and controls to align their goals. Bounded

rationality gives rise to information asymmetry between the parties (Amit, et al., 1990;

MacIntosh, 1994; Amit, et al., 1998; Bohren, 1998).

For example:

1. The entrepreneur may attempt to “oversell” the merits and viability of the venture (Levy & Lazarovitch-Porat, 1995) in order to get more favorable financing terms (Amit et al., 1998).

2. May claim to have more knowledge about a particular technology than is true (Arthurs & Busenitz, 2003).

3. The entrepreneur may use VC funds to purchase excessive perquisites (Arthurs & Busenitz, 2003).

It appears that the agency theory is most applicable, in explaining behavior,

immediately prior to the initial investment. Especially if the investment VCs make in a new

venture is with an entrepreneur unknown to the VC’s partners. When there is goal

incongruence between the two, agency theory is useful. Recent research has not studied the

relevance of agency theory in explaining the type of relationship that EIR programs represent

(Kelly & Hay, 2001; Landstrom, 1992; Van Osnabrugge, 2000). At issue is the idea of goal

congruence between VC and entrepreneur that should exist in EIR relationships. When there

is congruence between the VC and the entrepreneur (Arthurs & Busenitz, 2003), like in the

EIR program (by design), agency theory could be silent or at least not very important.

Agency theory does not account for the trust developed by the EIR program and the

VC involvement as a form of collaboration to grow the venture. Trust plays a key role in the

Page 30: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

30

willingness of the VC partner and the EIR entrepreneur to share knowledge and work

together. In the EIR program the idea is to obtain better goal alignment between principal and

agent through choosing the right “high status” entrepreneur and then offer compensation

initiatives and partial ownership schemes (Bohren, 1998). Trust is a process where the actors

regularly test each other’s integrity, moving from small, discrete exchanges of limited risk to

more open-ended investment deals that subject the parties to substantial risk (Lazerson &

Lorenzoni, 1999). This process should take place during the first part of the EIR program.

My qualitative research will show if in investments done with EIR programs “trust” is

implicit in the relationship and if agency theory is relevant.

Stewardship theory, on the other hand, characterizes human beings as having higher-

order needs for self-esteem, self-actualization, growth, achievement and affiliation (Arthurs

& Busenitz, 2003). It is concerned with identifying the situations in which the interests of the

principal (VC) and the steward (entrepreneur) are aligned (Arthurs & Busenitz, 2003). The

EIR program fits this theory perfectly. The principal and the steward commit to each other at

the beginning and align their goals at that point where many potential points for latent

conflict are solved, before they arise. In an EIR program venture the VC’s business advice

and counseling will be taken in a fair manner based on mutual stewardship trust and not

wrongly received as in other VC-E relationships (Busenitz et al., 1999; Korsgaard et al.,

1995).

Perceptions of the “trust” relationship between VC partner and entrepreneur.

Lewiki & Bunker (1995, 1996) propose a typology of trust in professional relationships

based on the notion of trust as residing within the individuals and being an iterative process

as knowledge of the other person grows. The three trust types are briefly defined as follows:

Page 31: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

31

1. Calculus-based Trust: is the trust that exists between individuals in the early stages of a relationship. Basically the economic calculation of the value of maintaining the relationship relative to the costs of severing it.

2. Knowledge-based Trust: is the trust that exists between two individuals that know each other well enough for the parties to have a history of interaction that allows each to make predictions about the other.

3. Identification-based Trust: is the trust that exists because the parties effectively understand and appreciate the other’s wants to such an extend that each can effectively act for the other.

During the empirical part of the study the idea is to prove that EIR programs help

bring the VC/entrepreneur relationship toward the identification-based trust phase (and at

least having the knowledge-based trust phase).

Non-financial (sweat) investments. A non-trivial difference between EIR program

ventures and others is the fact that the non-financial investments of time, energy and sweat

equity that entrepreneurs make usually before the VCs arrive, are done simultaneously by

both the VC and the entrepreneur in the EIR program. The more psychological ownership

both sides have in the venture, the more likely it is that both will offer larger amounts of

sweat equity to the venture. This is in contrast to valuing pre-seed ventures less due to the

VC-E agency costs (Jensen & Mecklig, 1976).

A VC partner plays a number of roles in the VC-E relationship, they find money,

operating services, networking, image, moral support, general business knowledge and

discipline (Vance & Hisrich, 1995). VCs are sometimes called consultants, with financial

interests, because of their individual expertise, experience and willingness to give advice.

They are usually in contact with the top management of the venture in order to formulate and

adhere to their business strategy. VCs provide networking in order to locate service

providers, law firms, marketing consultants, other outsiders (especially those with financial

Page 32: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

32

interests) like other investors or banks and sometimes even customers. VCs’ image usually

transfers to their portfolio companies, enhancing their standing with customers and future

employees (Vance & Hisrich, 1995).

VCs used to provide their entrepreneurs with the minimum of cash required (Gorman

& Sahlman, 1989) in order to get the venture going. This unwillingness of the VCs to invest

in growth strategies affected the startup/seed ventures in that some of them yielded returns

that were adequate (living dead) but not stunning (Bygrave & Timmons, 1991). The research

will see if this behavior changes when the VCs use the EIR program and trust more the

entrepreneurs.

Sweat equity (non-financial investment) is an integral component in the relationship

between the VC partners and the entrepreneurs. The average time a lead VC spends with a

venture averages about thirteen (13) hours a month and a non-lead VC spends less than five

(5) hours average (Vance & Hisrich, 1995). Another study (Cable & Shane, 1997) shows

VCs visiting their portfolio ventures an average of nineteen (19) times per year and spending

one hundred (100) hours (direct contact or phone) with each venture. VC partners are usually

responsible for nine (9) ventures and sit on at least five (5) other boards. Thus, each non-

financial investment made in one venture cannot be made in others. VC partners sometimes

refrain from providing the best non-financial investment in one firm; they diversify risks by

diffusing time and tacit knowledge between multiple ventures (Sahlman, 1990). Again, the

empirical research will find how this differs with EIR program ventures.

Moderating Variables

I will use three moderating variables:

1. existence of angel investors,

Page 33: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

33

2. type of technology and date

3. gender.

Angel investors. There is little systematic research on the amount of angel

investment in ICT industries in Israel. How has the entry of venture capital into startup/seed

investment (in mass) during the last 5 years influenced the decisions of the wealthy

entrepreneurs it created (will they return to the market as VC partners, EIRs, entrepreneurs or

angel investors?). This variable will moderate for the existence of private angel investors in

the investment syndicate of the venture.

Technological system developed by the venture. During specific dates, certain ICT

submarkets were more successful than other submarkets. The model will be controlled with

variables on technology (submarkets of the ICT industry) and the dates of the venture. In

some eras, ICT markets have been in a rollercoaster. The market context at start-up is likely

to affect the subsequent performance of the venture. Different technologies gather higher

valuations in certain years, sometimes disconnected from the real value of the technologies

involved. Valuations are based on the “mind-share” of the markets, because of the limited

financial history of the new ventures. Adding variables about ICT market results will control

the dependent variable

Gender of the VC partner and gender of the entrepreneur. The members of the

Israeli entrepreneurial relationship (entrepreneurs and VC partners) are a strongly

homogenous group. Bygrave & Timmons (1992) suggested that entrepreneurs’ pre-existing

personal relations with venture capitalists enhanced the development and sustaining of

cooperative relationships. Roberts (1991) found that networking with people who had prior

relationships with venture capitalists, enhanced the development of cooperative venture

Page 34: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

34

capital relationships. Preliminary work along these lines has found that social capital does not

operate in the same ways for women and minorities as it does for white men (Burt, 1998;

Burt, 2000). Extending this line of work on the inequality among groups of potential

entrepreneurs is warranted in order to check access to VC financing and other resources.

An explanation for gender differences, in career development, through different

societal expectations for men and women is that it leads to divergence in work preferences

(Harriman, 1985). These experiences are seen as constricting career choices, compromising

career potential (Gottfredson, 1981) and influencing women’s beliefs, attitudes and self-

conceptions that ultimately affect their work interests and choices (Farmer, 1997). Some

studies of choices involving the start-up of a venture support this perspective (Brush,1992;

Buttner and Moore,1997; Carter, 1997), but others provide evidence that the entrepreneurial

career choice is gender blind (Fagerson, 1993). Adding this variable, to the model, will test

to see which point is more plausible.

RESEARCH QUESTIONS

Research Aim

To answer the question of how equity financing will evolve over the next decade

given the entrance of VC (venture capital) funds (with EIR [entrepreneur in residency]

programs) into very early, even pre-birth stage of ventures (investment stage previously

reserved for “angel” investors).

Research Goals

This study will try to shed light on factors that are changing the equity financing

markets by having VC firms enter early in a venture’s life. Who should be the dominant

figure in new pre-seed ventures (VC firms or angel investors)? What happened to the angel

Page 35: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

35

investor? Is he joining VC firms in a new way (EIR programs)? How do they interact? What

has changed?

Research Questions

1. To what extend are VC funds “crowding out” the angel investor?

2. Is the percentage of VC funds that go to pre-seed and seed investments growing?

3. How many included angel investors as well?

4. What types of entrepreneurs get pre-seed money from the VCs?

5. What types of entrepreneurs get seed money from the VCs?

6. How many VC partnerships have/had EIR programs?

7. How do VCs choose entrepreneurs for the EIR programs?

8. Would the late “angel investor” be the EIR of today?

9. What is a High Status Entrepreneur in Israel (2005)?

10. Differences in how “trust” played a role in the investments where the entrepreneur is of High Status or EIR?

11. Does trust play a role for equity invested by the VC partner?

12. Will entrepreneurs that have “high marks” in previous knowledge characteristics require higher VC sweat equity than those with “low marks”?

13. Do “High Status” entrepreneurs do better than “first time” entrepreneurs?

14. Do “EIR” entrepreneurs do better than other “High Status” entrepreneurs?

15. Are there differences in the results of angel/pre-seed capital investments according to EIR, High Status or First Time entrepreneurs?

Research Methods

In order to answer these questions, up to 20 VC partners and the entrepreneurs (EIR

entrepreneurs, other “High Status” entrepreneurs and “first time” entrepreneurs) who have

Page 36: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

36

received startup/seed investments (equity investment at the beginning of a venture’s life)

will be interviewed. Ventures that include angel investors will also be included. This mix will

allow comparisons between many types of VC-Entrepreneur relationships and can shed light

on pre-seed investments and the EIR programs in particular.

Page 37: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

37

REFERENCES

Acs, Z. and Audretsch, D. 2005. Handbook of entrepreneurship research: An interdisciplinary survey and introduction. New York: Springer.

Aldrich, H. and Waldinger, R. 1990. Ethnicity and entrepreneurship. Annual Review of

Sociology, 16: 11-35. Amit, R., Glosten, L. and Muller, E. 1990. Does venture capital foster the most promising

entrepreneurial firms? California Management Review, 32: 102-111. Amit, R., Brander, J. and Zott, C. 1998. Why do venture firms exist?: Theory and Canadian

evidence. Journal of Business Venturing, 13 (6): 441-66. Ardichvili, A., Cardozo, R. and Ray, S. 2003. A theory of entrepreneurial opportunity

identification and development. Journal of Business Venturing, 18 (1): 105-24. Ariav, G. and Goodman, S. 1994. Israel: Of swords and software plowshares.

Communications of the ACM, 37 (6): 17-21. Arthurs, J. and Busenitz, L. 2003. The boundaries and limitations of agency theory in the

venture capitalist/entrepreneur relationship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice: 145-162.

Avrahami, Y. and Lerner, M. 2003. The effect of combat service and military rank on

entrepreneurial careers: The case of Israeli MBA graduates. Journal of Political and Military Sociology, 31 (1): 97-118.

Barney, J., Busenitz, L., Fiet, J. and Mosel, D. 1994. Determinants of a new venture team's

receptivity to advice from venture capitalists. In W. Bygrave, S. Birley, N. Churchill, E. Gatewood, F. Hoy, R. Keeley, & W. Wetzel (Eds.), Frontiers of entrepreneurship research: 321-335. Babson Park: Babson College.

Baron, R. 1998. Cognitive mechanisms in entrepreneurship – entrepreneurship in the 1990s.

Journal of Business Venturing, 15: 79-91. Becker, G. S. 1965. A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75: 493-517. Bednarz, A. 2005. There’s battle tested … and there’s the Israeli Military. Network World, 5:

20-22. Begley, T. and Boyd, D. 1987. A comparison of entrepreneurs and managers of small

business firms. The Journal of Management, 13: 99-108. Blau, P. and Duncan, D. 1967. The American occupational structure. New York: Wiley.

Page 38: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

38

Bohren, O. 1998. The agent's ethics in the principle-agent model. Journal of Business Ethics, 17 (7): 745-56.

Brockhaus R. and Horwitz, P. 1986. The psychology of the entrepreneur. The Art and

Science of Entrepreneurship, 25-48. Brush, C. 1992. Marketplace information scanning activities of new manufacturing ventures.

Journal of Small Business Management, 30 (4): 41-54. Brush, C. 1992. Research on women business owners: Past trends, a new perspective and

future directions. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 16 (4): 5-31. Brush, C. and Vanderwerf, P. 1992. A comparison of methods and sources for obtaining

estimates of new venture performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 7 (2): 157-172.

Bruton, G, Fried, V. and Hisrich, R. 1997. Venture capitalist and CEO dismissal.

Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 21 (3): 41-85. Burt, R. 1992. Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Boston, MA: Harvard

University Press. Burt, R. 1998. The gender of social capital. Rationality and Society, 10 (1): 5-46. Burt, R. 2000. The network structure of social capital. Research on Organizational

Behavior, 22: 345-423. Busenitz, L. and Barney, J. 1997. Differences between entrepreneurs and managers in large

corporations: Biases and heuristics in strategic decision making. Journal of Business Venturing, 12 (1): 9-30.

Busenitz, L. 1999. Entrepreneurial risk and strategic decision making: It's a matter of

perspective. The Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 35 (3): 325-341. Buttner, H. and Moore, D. 1997. Women's organizational exodus to entrepreneurship: Self-

reported motivations and correlates with success. Journal of Small Business Management, 35 (1): 34-47

Bygrave, W. and Timmons, J. 1992. Venture capital at the crossroads. Boston, MA:

Harvard Business School Press. Cable, D. and Shane, S. 1997. A prisoner’s dilemma approach to entrepreneur-venture

capitalist relationship. Academy of Management Review, 22 (1).

Page 39: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

39

Carroll,G.and Mosakowitski, E. 1987. The career dynamics of self-employment. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32: 570-589.

Carter, T. 1997. Crisis management for sales force managers. Journal of Professional

Services Marketing, 15 (2): 87 -94. Casson, M. 2003. The entrepreneur: An economic theory, 2nd Edition. Southampton:

Edward Elgar Publishing. Chen, C., Greene, P. and Crick, A. 1998. Does entrepreneurial self-efficacy distinguish

entrepreneurs from managers? Journal of Business Venturing, 13 (4): 295-316. Choo, F. and Trotman, K. 1991. The relationship between knowledge structure and

judgments for experienced and inexperienced auditors. The Accounting Review, 66 (3): 464-86.

Christensen, C. 1997. The innovators dilemma: When new technologies cause great firms

to fail. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Cooper, A., Gimeno-Gascon, J. and Woo, C. 1994. Initial human and financial capital as

predictors of new venture performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 9 (5): 371-95.

Cummins, B. 2005. I got my MBA in the Israeli Army. New York Times, March 3. Dahl, M. and Reichstein, T. 2005. Are you experienced? Prior experience and the survival

of new organizations. DRUID Working Paper, 05-01. Dahlqvist, J., Davidson, P. and Wiklund, J. 2000. Initial conditions as predictors of new

venture performance: A replication and extension of the Cooper et al. study. Enterprise & Innovation Management Studies, 1: 1-17.

Davis, G. and Greve, H. 1997. Corporate elite networks and governance changes in the

1980s. American Journal of Sociology, 103: 1-37. Di Gregorio, D. and Shane, S. 2003. Why do some universities generate more start-ups than

others? Research Policy, 32 (I 2): 209-235. Dobbin, F. and Dowd, T. 1997. How policy shapes competition: early railroad foundings in

Massachusetts. Administrative Science, 42: 501-29. Eisenhardt, K. M. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of

Management Review, 14: 57–74.

Page 40: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

40

Evans, D. and Leighton, L. 1989. Some empirical aspects of entrepreneurship. American Economic Review, 79: 519-35.

Farmer, T. 1993. Testing the effect of risk attitude on auditor judgments using multiattribute

utility theory: Professional adaptation. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance, 8 (1): 91-115.

Florida R. and Kenney, M. 1998a. Venture capital-financed innovation and technological

change in the USA. Research Policy, 17: 119-37. Florida R. and Kenney M. 1998b. Venture capital, high technology and regional

development. Regional Studies., 22: 33-48. Fox, M. and Hamilton, R. 1994. Ownership and diversification: Agency theory or

stewardship theory. The Journal of Management Studies, 31 (1): 69 -83. Fried, V. and Hisrich, R. 1995. The venture capitalist: a relationship investor. California

Management Review, 37 (2): 101-13. Gartner, W.B. 1988. Who is an entrepreneur? Is the wrong question. Entrepreneurship

Theory Practice, 13 (4): 47-68. Gartner, W. and Shane, S. 1995. Measuring entrepreneurship over time. Journal of Business

Venturing, 10: 283-301. Garud, R. and Karnoe, P. 2003. Bricolage versus breakthrough: Distributed and embedded

agency in technology entrepreneurship. Research Policy, 32 (2): 277-230. Gimeno, J., Folta, T., Cooper, A. and Woo, C. 1997. Survival of the fittest? Entrepreneurial

human capital and the persistence of underperforming firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 750-783.

Gompers, P. and Lerner, J. 2003. Equity financing. In Z. Acs & D.B. Audretsch (Eds.),

Handbook of entrepreneurial research: 267-298. New York, NY: Springer. Gorman, M., and Sahlman, W. 1989. What do venture capitalists do? Journal of Business

Venturing, 4: 231-248. Gupta, A.and Sapienza, H. 1992 . Determinants of venture capital firms' preferences

regarding the industry diversity and geographic scope of their investments. Journal of Business Venturing, 7: 347-362.

Hansen, E. 1995. Entrepreneurial networks and new organization growth. Entrepreneurship

Theory and Practice, 19 (4): 7-19.

Page 41: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

41

Harrison, R., Dibbon, M. and Mason, C. 1997. The role of trust in the informal investor’s investment decision: An exploratory analysis. Entrepreneurship Theory, Summer.

Hayek, F. 1945. The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35 (4): 519-

530. Hoffman, H., and Blakely, J. 1987. You can negotiate with venture capitalists. Harvard

Business Review, (March-April): 6-24. Holland, J., Gottfredson, G. and Baker, H. 1990. Validity of vocational aspirations and

interest inventories: Extended, replicated, and reinterpreted. Journal of Counseling Psychology, 37 (3): 337-72.

Holzman, Z. 2005. The serial entrepreneur: A desired commodity. IVC Journal, 5. Huse, M. and Landstorm, H. 1997. European entrepreneurship and small business research:

Methodological openness and contextual differences. International Studies of Management & Organization, 27 (3): 3-12

IVC Surveys on VC activity in Israel. www.ivc-online.com. IVC Research Center. 2005. IVA Yearbook 2005. Tel-Aviv, Israel: Israel Venture

Association (IVCA). Jacobius, A. 2004. Venture Capital firms provide support—but without cash. Pensions and

Investments, 32 (26). Jensen M. and Meckling, W. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs

and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305-360. Kalish, S. 2005. Right from the start: a perspective on entrepreneur in residency (EIR)

programs. IVC Journal, 5. Kelly, P. and Hay, M. 2003. Business angel contracts: the influence of context. Venture

Capital, 5 (4): 287-312. Kihlstrom, R. and Laffont, J. 1979. A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm

formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87 (4): 719-39. Kirzner, I. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago

Press. Kirzner, I. 1985. Discovery and capitalist process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Page 42: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

42

Kirzner, I. 1997. Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 35: 60-85.

Klepper, S. 2001. Employee start-ups in high industries. Industrial and Corporate Change,

10 (3): 639-74. Klepper, S. 2002. The capabilities of new firms and the development of the US automotive

industry. Industrial and Corporate Change, 11 (4): 645-65. Korsgaard, A., Schweiger, D. and Sapienza, H. 1995. Building commitment, attachment, and

trust in strategic decisions. Academy of Management Journal, 38 (1): 60-86. Lazerson, M. and Lorenzoni, G. 1999. Resisting organizational inertia: The evolution of

industrial districts. Journal of Management & Governance, 3 (4): 361-86. Landstrom, H., Frank, H. and Veciana, J. 1997. Entrepreneurship and small business

research in Europe. Aldershot, UK. Landstrom, H. and Huse, M. 1996. Trends in European entrepreneurship and small-

business research. SIRE, Working Paper 1996:3, University of Halmstad and Vaxjo, Sweden.

Lazerson, M. and Lorenzoni, G. 1999. The firms that feed industrial districts: A return to the

Italian source. Industrial & Corporate Change, 8(2): 235-67. Levy, H. and Lazarovitch-Porat, E. 1995. Signaling theory and risk perception: An

experimental study. Journal of Economics and Business, 47 (1): 39-56. Lin, C. 1998. Success factors of small- and medium-sized enterprises in Taiwan: An analysis

of cases. Journal of Small Business Management, 36 (4): 43-56. MacMillan, I., Siegel, R. and Narasimha, P. N. S. 1985. Criteria used by venture capitalists to

evaluate new venture proposals. Journal of Business Venturing, 1 (1): 119-128. MacMillan, I. and Narasimha, P. 1987. Characteristics distinguishing funded from unfunded

business plans evaluated by venture capitalists. Strategic Management Journal, 8: 579-85.

MacMillan, I., Kulow, D. and Khoylian, R. 1989. Venture capitalists involvement in their

investments: Extent and performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 4: 27-47. Mason, C. and Harrison, R. 1996. Informal venture capital: a study of the investment process,

the post-investment experience and investment performance. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 8: 105-125.

Page 43: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

43

McClelland, D. 1961. The achieving society. Princeton, NJ: D. Van Nostrand. Merton, R. 1973. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica, 41 (5): 867-

887. OECD. 2002. OECD investment policy reviews: Israel. September. OECD. 2003. Venture capital policy review: Israel. STI Working Paper, 3. Portes, A. 1998. Social capital: Its origins and applications in modern sociology. Annual

Review of Sociology, 24 (1): 1-25. PricewaterhouseCoopers. 2005. Moneytree Surveys about VC Activity. MoneyTree Report.

www.pwcmoneytree.com. PricewaterhouseCoopers. 2005. Moneytree Surveys about Israel VC Activity. MoneyTree

Report. www.pwc.co.il. Raban, Y., Lerner, M. and Honig, B. 2005. Linkage of new Israeli high tech companies to the

military and defense systems. IVC Journal, 5. Roberts, E. 1991. High stakes for high-tech entrepreneurs: Understanding venture capital

decision making. Sloan Management Review, 9: 1-20. Roberts, M. and Tempest, N. 1998. ONSET Ventures. Harvard Business School Cases, 30.

Rosenstein, J., Bruno, A. V., Bygrave, W. D. and Taylor, N. T. 1993. The CEO, venture

capitalists and the board. Journal of Business Venturing, 8: 99–113. Rotemberg, J. 1994. Human relations in the workplace. Journal of Political Economy, 102

(4): 684-728. Sahlman, W. 1990. The structure and governance of venture capital organizations. Journal

of Financial Economics, 27: 473-521 Sahlman, W. 1994. Insights from the venture capital model of project governance. Business

Economics, 29 (3): 35-8. Sahlman, W. 1997. How to write a great business plan. Harvard Business Review, 75 (4):

98-108. Sapienza, H. 1989. Variations in venture capitalist-entrepreneur relations: Antecedents

and consequences. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Maryland, US.

Page 44: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

44

Sapienza, H. 1991. Comets and duds: Characteristics distinguishing high and low performing high potential ventures. In N. Churchill, W. Bygrave, J. Covin, D. Sexton, D. Slevin, K. Vesper and W. Wetzel (Eds.), Frontiers of entrepreneurial research: 111-27. Babson Park, US: Babson College.

Sapienza, H. 1992. When do venture capitalists add value? Journal of Business Venturing,

7 (1): 9-27. Sapienza, H. and Gupta, A. 1994. Impact of agency risks and task uncertainty on venture

capitalist-CEO interaction. Academy of Management Journal, 37 (6): 1618-32. Saxenian A. 1994. Regional advantage: Culture and competition in Silicon Valley and

route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Schecter, Z. 2005. A VC approach to seed investing. IVC Journal, 5. Schumpeter, J. A. 1934-1976. The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press. Sexton, D., Upton, N., Washoltz, L. and McDougall, P. 1997. Learning needs of growth

oriented entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing, 12: 1-8. Shepherd, D. and DeTienne, D. 2005. Prior knowledge, potential financial reward, and

opportunity identification. Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice, 29 (1): 91-112. Simon, H. 1973. Organization man: Rational or self-actualizing? Public Administration

Review, 33 (4): 346-353. Shane, S. 1993. Cultural influences on national rates of innovation. Journal of Business

Venturing, 8: 59-73. Shane, S. 1996. Hybrid organizational arrangements and their implications for firm growth

and survival: a study of new franchisors. Academy of Management Journal, 39 (1): 216-34.

Shane, S. 2000. Prior knowledge and the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities.

Organization Science, 11 (4): 448-69. Shane, S. 2001a. Technology opportunities and new firm creation. Management Science, 47

(2): 205-20. Shane, S. 2001b. Technology regimes and new firm formation. Management Science, 47

(9): 1173-81.

Page 45: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

45

Shane, S. 2003. A general theory of entrepreneurship: The individual-opportunity nexus. Northhampton: New Horizons in Entrepreneurship Series, Edward Elgar Publishing.

Shane , S. and Cable, D. 2002. Network ties, reputation and the financing of new ventures.

Management Science, 48 (3): 364-81. Shane, S. and Khurana, R. 2003. Bringing individuals back in: The effects of career

experience on new firm founding. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12 (3): 519-560.

Shane, S. and Venkataraman, S. 2000. The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of

research. Academy of Management Review, 26 (1): 13-17. Shaver, K. and Scott, R. 1991. Person, process, and choice: The psychology of new venture

creation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Winter: 23-42. Shaver,K., Gartner, W., Crosby, E., Bakalarova, K. and Gatewood, E. 2001. Attributions

about entrepreneurship: A framework and process for analyzing reasons for starting a business. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 26 (2): 5-34.

Singh, R., Hills, Hybels, R. and Lumpkin, G. 1999. Opportunity recognition through social

network characteristics of entrepreneurs. In P Reynolds, W. Bygrave, S. Manigart, C. Mason, H. Sapienza and K. Shaver (Eds.), Frontier of entrepreneurial research: 228-41. Babson Park, US: Babson College.

Solymossy E. 2000. Entrepreneurial dimensions: The relationship of individual, venture

and environmental factors to success. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Case Western Reserve University.

Starr, D. 2000. Entrepreneurs in residence-who needs them? Vault, June 7. Steier, L. and Greenwood, R. 1995. Venture capitalist relationships in the deal structuring

and post-investment stages of new firm creation. Journal of Management Studies, 32 (3): 337-58.

Thornton, P. 1999. The sociology of entrepreneurship. Annual Review of Sociology, 25: 19-

46. Trajtenberg, M. 2001. Government support for commercial R&D: lessons from the Israeli

experience. NBER conference on Innovation Policy and the Economy, Washington, US.

Van Osnabrugge, M. 1998. Do serial and non-serial investors behave differently? An

empirical and theoretical analysis. Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice, 22 (4): 23-42.

Page 46: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

46

Van Osnabrugge, M. 2000. A comparison of business angel and venture capitalist investment procedures: an agency theory-based analysis. Venture Capital, 2 (2): 91-10.

Van Osnabrugge, M. and Robinson, R. 1999. Financing entrepreneurship: Business angels

and venture capitalists compared. Working Paper, Harvard Business School Division of Research: 1-38.

Van Osnabrugge, M. and Robinson, R. 2001. The influence of a venture capitalist's source of

funds. Venture Capital, 3 (1): 25-39. Venkatraman, S. 1997. The distinctive domain of entrepreneurship research. In J.A. Katz

(Ed.), Advances in entrepreneurship, firm emergence and growth, Volume 3: 119-38. Greenwich, CT.

VentureOne Corporation. National Annual Reports, Newark, NJ. Warner, M. 1998. The new way to start in Silicon Valley. Fortune, 138 (4). Watson, R. and Myers, M. 2001. IT industry success in small countries: The cases of Finland

and New Zealand. Journal of Global Information Management, 9 (2): 4-15. Weber, E. and Hsee, C. 1998. Cross-cultural differences in risk perception, but cross-cultural

similarities in attitudes. Management Science, 44 (9):1205-18. White, H. 1981. Where do markets come from? American Journal of Sociology, 87: 517-47. White, S. and Reynolds, P. 1996. Government programs and high growth new firms. In P.

Reynolds, S. Birley, J. Butler, W. Bygrave, P. Davidsson, W. Gartner and P. McDougall (Eds.), Frontiers of entrepreneurial research: 621-35. Babson College

Wholey, D., Christianson, J. and Sanchez, S. 1993. The effect of physician and corporate

interests on the formation of health maintenance organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 99 (1): 164-200.

Wiklund J. 1998. Small firm growth and performance: Entrepreneurship and beyond.

Jonkoping International Business School: Jonkoping. Wiklund J. 1999. The sustainability of the entrepreneurial orientation-performance

relationship. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 24 (1): 37-48. Zacharakis, A., Meyer, D. and DeCastro, J. 1999. Differing perceptions of new venture

failure: A matched exploratory study of venture capitalists and entrepreneurs. Journal of Small Business Management, 37 (3): 1-14.

Page 47: STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY …s3.amazonaws.com/lyro-production...STARTUP/SEED STAGE INVESTMENT BY VENTURE CAPITAL FUNDS (IN ISRAEL): ENTREPRENEURS IN RESIDENCY AND EXECUTIVE

47

Zahra S. 1993. A conceptual model of entrepreneurship as firm behaviour: a critique and extension. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 16: 5-21.

Zahra, S. and LaTour, M. 1987. Corporate social responsibility and organizational

effectiveness: A multivariate approach. Journal of Business Ethics, 6 (6): 459-6. Zider B. 1998. How venture capital works. Harvard Business Review, 11 (12): 131-1.