Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

30
MSc Accountancy & Control Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance. Financial Accounting Karn Shah 10262156 Draft Version Date: 22-06-2015 Dr. W.H.P Janssen Word count: 10.307

Transcript of Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Page 1: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

MSc Accountancy & Control

Shareholder ownership and tax

avoidance.

Financial Accounting

Karn Shah

10262156

Draft Version

Date: 22-06-2015

Dr. W.H.P Janssen

Word count: 10.307

Page 2: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

2

Statement of Originality

This document is written by student Karn Shah who declares to take full responsibility for the

contents of this document. I declare that the text and the work presented in this document is

original and that no sources other than those mentioned in the text and its references have

been used in creating it. The Faculty of Economics and Business is responsible solely for the

supervision of completion of the work, not for the contents.

Page 3: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

3

Contents

Abstract .................................................................................................................................................. 4

1.0 Introduction ..................................................................................................................................... 5

2.0 Literature review and hypotheses .................................................................................................. 7

2.1.1 Tax avoidance definitions .......................................................................................................... 7

2.1.2 Benefits and costs involving tax avoidance ................................................................................ 8

2.2 Agency Theory ........................................................................................................................... 10

2.3.1 Concentration of ownership definition ..................................................................................... 11

2.3.2 Types of investors .................................................................................................................... 12

2.4 Hypothesis ................................................................................................................................... 12

3.0 Research Methodology .................................................................................................................. 13

3.1 Sample selection .......................................................................................................................... 13

3.2 Variable alternatives .................................................................................................................... 14

3.2.1 Tax avoidance measures ........................................................................................................... 14

3.2.2 Concentration of ownership measurements .............................................................................. 15

3.3 Variables measurement ............................................................................................................... 16

3.3.1 Tax avoidance ........................................................................................................................... 16

3.3.2 Concentration of Ownership..................................................................................................... 17

3.3.3 Control variables ...................................................................................................................... 17

3.4 Model .......................................................................................................................................... 19

4.0 Descriptive statistics & Empirical results ................................................................................... 19

4.1 Descriptive Statistics ................................................................................................................... 19

4.2.1 Results ..................................................................................................................................... 21

4.2.2 Discussion ............................................................................................................................... 22

5.0 Sensitivity Analysis ........................................................................................................................ 23

5.1 Sensitivity analysis – 10% threshold ........................................................................................... 23

5.2 Sensitivity analysis – 20% threshold ........................................................................................... 25

6.0 Conclusion ...................................................................................................................................... 26

Bibliography ........................................................................................................................................ 28

Page 4: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

4

Abstract

This paper provides empirical evidence on the relationship between concentration of

ownership and the tax avoidance activities of a firm. More specifically, this paper questions

whether there is an association between the concentration of ownership and tax avoidance.

This is done to contribute to the growing stream of literature about shareholder concentration

and tax avoidance and to answer to the call for more empirical evidence. This paper also

stimulates the ongoing discussion about tax avoidance as a societal issue.

To answer the proposed research question, a regression analysis will be conducted to

determine the relationship between the concentration of ownership and the tax avoidance of a

firm. The sample consists of 492 firm-year observations coming from a total of 125 firms.

The results show that there is no association between the concentration of ownership

and the amount of tax avoidance of a firm. This contradicts prior literature which states that

the concentration of ownership either has a positive or a negative relationship to tax

avoidance. The results can be contradicting because of a few reasons. The first reason is that

the sample is too small and did not capture all the effects of the entire population. The second

reason is that the measure used for tax avoidance did not capture all the effects of tax

avoidance.

This paper has a few limitations. One of the limitations is that the sample is too small

due to range constraints from the Blockholders database. This constraint resulted in another

limitation, which was the inability to use the long-run tax avoidance as there were not enough

year observations to compute this measure.

Page 5: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

5

1.0 Introduction Tax studies in general are found in various research fields such as accounting, finance,

economics and law, which makes tax studies very varying and comprehensive. This varying

aspect makes tax research particularly difficult, because every field has its own particular

interests and even their own languages (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). One of the topics within

tax research is tax avoidance. Tax avoidance is a fairly young and rising topic in the

accounting research (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). Dyreng, Hanlon & Maydew define tax

avoidance as anything that reduces the firm's cash effective tax rate. This means that tax

avoidance does not have to be anything illegal (2008).

Dyreng et al. found that firms are able to avoid taxes over a long period of time. They

developed a measure called "long-run cash effective tax rate" which describes the firm's

ability to avoid taxes over a long period of time for as long as ten years. They also discovered

that annual cash effective tax rates are not good predictors of long-run cash effective tax rates

(2008). So this study contributed mainly in a descriptive way by designing a measure for

long-run tax avoidance. But the authors did not know why some firms engaged in tax

avoidance and others did not and they let this question open for future research (Dyreng et

al., 2008). Hanlon & Heitzman state that there are multiple determinants for tax avoidance.

One of the reasons for tax avoidance could be the ownership structure of the firm (2010).

Desai & Dharmapala state that concentrated ownership leads to a greater incentive to

avoid taxes (2008). They base this on the theoretical notions of the agency theory, but there is

no empirical evidence to support this notion. The authors also discuss some other

determinants for tax avoidance such as: information systems, corporate control and high

powered incentives (Desai & Dharmapala, 2008). They continue by stating that the role of

taxes and ownership patterns have yet to be explored and they call for more empirical work

(Desai & Dharmapala, 2008). So this study mainly sets up a basis for future research by

implying that there is a certain relationship between the ownership structure of a firm and its

tax avoiding activities and calls for empirical research.

Chen et al. indirectly reply to that call for more empirical research. They found that

family firms with relatively few shareholders are less tax aggressive than their non-family

counterparts. These results show that family owners are willing to forgo tax benefits to avoid

the non-tax costs such as potential penalties and reputation damage (2009). So this research

also studied the link between the shareholder construction and tax avoiding activities and was

insightful by helping towards a better understanding of the impact of equity ownership and

agency conflicts on firms' tax avoiding activities. But this study was focused on family owned

Page 6: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

6

firms, which differ from non-family owned firms. While this piece of empirical evidence

showed the tax aggressiveness of family firms, which are highly concentrated firms,

compared to non-family firms, it left the tax aggressiveness of highly concentrated firms

compared to lowly concentrated firms open for future research.

The underlying notion for the relationship between the shareholder construction and

tax avoiding activities is the agency problem. According to Chen et al., firms with a high

ownership structure (i.e. less shareholders but with relatively high ownership per shareholder)

have a better managerial and shareholder interest alignment and therefore there are less

conflicts between the owners and managers (2009). Because there are less conflicts between

owners and managers, there will be more tax avoiding activities within a firm. However, there

is also some indication that highly concentrated firms may actually engage less in tax

avoiding activities. According to Hanlon & Heitzman, concentrated firms are more concerned

with long-term results and are worried about arising costs, such as reputational costs (2010).

Also, concentrated firms could engage in less tax avoiding activities because individuals have

intrinsic motivations on tax evasion and will compare these to their risks and highly

concentrated firms act more like individuals than non-concentrated firms.

The aforementioned disagreement in previous literature and the call for empirical

research makes it interesting to investigate the relationship between concentration of

shareholder ownership and tax avoidance. The following question will be investigated: is

there a relationship between the concentration of ownership and the tax avoidance of a firm?

Desai and Dharmapala state that tax avoidance and ownership patterns have yet to be

explored (2008). This thesis would contribute to the direct call for more empirical evidence on

this subject, which is a fairly new and undiscovered topic. To my knowledge there is little

empirical research done in the way this research will be done, therefore this research will

contribute to the growing stream of literature regarding tax avoidance and ownership

structure.

Tax avoidance is also a societal issue. It is seen as unethical to have big corporations

like Apple pay a relatively low amount of tax and meanwhile increase the tax burden on

civilians to push government bills (Doward, The Guardian, 2014). Conducting this research

could give more insight to the thought process of corporations that engage in tax avoiding

activities, which could result in more understanding on corporate tax avoiding activities.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows: section two will cover the literature review

and hypothesis. This will be followed by section three that describes the sample used in the

research and the research design itself. In section four, the main results of the research will be

Page 7: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

7

discussed followed by section five, in which the sensitivity analyses are described. Lastly,

section six will conclude this paper.

2.0 Literature review and hypotheses In this section I will discuss three topics. First, in the literature review, I will discuss tax

avoidance, mainly explaining the definition of tax avoidance and the costs and benefits

resulting from tax avoidance. The second topic is the agency theory. First, I will give a

general explanation of the agency theory. After that I will try to make a link between the

agency theory and the problem that is being researched. The third topic discussed in this part

is the concentration of ownership. Also here I will begin by defining shareholder structure and

continue to discuss different types of investors. With these three topics discussed, a

hypothesis will be constructed.

2.1.1 Tax avoidance definitions

As stated earlier, tax avoidance is hard to define and measure. Tax studies are done across

many fields and therefore there is no single definition of tax avoidance (Hanlon & Heitzman,

2010). The most broad definition of tax avoidance comes from Dyreng et al., where they

studied a firm's ability to reduce their long-run cash effective tax rate in any way possible.

The authors defined tax avoidance as anything that reduced their long-run cash effective tax

rate (2008). These are mainly activities done in compliance with the law or those in gray-

areas. Hanlon & Heitzman build upon this notion and define tax avoidance as the reduction of

explicit taxes (2010). The difference between Hanlon & Hetzman's definition and Dyreng et

al.'s definition is that Hanlon & Heitzman do include illegal activities and identify different

types of tax avoidance. On the one hand are the types of tax avoidance that are perfectly legal,

and on the on the other hand would be the more aggressive and noncompliance types of

activities (2010).

These two definitions are accepted in the tax research community and are used in

various empirical researches. One of those researches is that from Kim et al. (2011). In this

research, the authors studied whether tax avoidance could be used as a predictor for stock

price crashes. The authors used the definition for tax avoidance as provided by Hanlon &

Heitzman (Kim et al., 2011). A different study that uses this definition is that from Chen et

al. (2010). This study was already briefly discussed and the authors of this study studied the

tax aggressiveness of family firms relative to the tax aggressiveness of non-family firms.

They defined tax aggressiveness as the downward management of taxable income through tax

Page 8: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

8

planning activities, including legal, illegal and grey-area activities (Chen et al., 2009). As we

have seen earlier, this definition corresponds with the definition given by Hanlon &

Heitzman (2010).

Something noteworthy is that Hanlon & Heitzman (2010) stated that tax avoidance is

hard to define because it exists in multiple research fields and that there is no generally

accepted definition. However, this was only brought to attention after Hanlon & Heitzman’s

paper (2010). This is because both Kim et al. (2010) and Chen et al. (2009) do not discuss

different definitions of tax avoidance. This could imply that there may have been more

obscurity on the definition of tax avoidance than previously thought and that Hanlon &

Heitzman emphasized on a previously uncharted matter (2010).

2.1.2 Benefits and costs involving tax avoidance

Before deciding whether avoiding taxes will be beneficial, the firm has to assess the tradeoff

between the marginal benefits against the marginal costs of avoiding taxes (Chen et al, 2009).

Considering tax avoidance, there are more types of costs than benefits. Usually, the benefits

are quite clear. The main benefit of avoiding taxes would obviously be saving cash so that it

can be used for other purposes such as reinvestments in the firm or for higher dividend

payouts. Therefore, in this section, the emphasis will lie on the costs involving tax avoidance.

One of the main elements involving tax avoidance is rent seeking behavior, also

known as rent extraction (Chen et al., 2009). These two definitions will be used

interchangeably from now on. According to Tullock, the concept of rent seeking is when a

firm or individual attempts to gain economic benefits without reciprocating this to the society

through wealth creation (1967). The term rent seeking was actually coined in 1974 by

Krueger (1974). Chen et al. refer to rent extraction as the non-value maximizing activities that

decision makers follow at the cost of shareholders. Some examples they give are: aggressive

financial reporting, perk consumption such as receiving target-related bonuses and related-

party transactions (2009).

For decision makers, there are some benefits regarding rent seeking. They can, for

instance, manage earnings to meet or beat their earnings benchmarks, which might result in a

monetary gain for them (Chen et al., 2009). Firms could also make use of tax shelters to save

on tax payments, which also could result in a personal monetary gain (Desai et al., 2006).

However, these rent seeking activities also bare costs with them. For instance, if a firm is

making use of illegal methods to avoid taxes, the IRS could impose penalties which obviously

would hurt the firms earnings (Chen et al., 2009). Another cost of rent seeking behavior is a

Page 9: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

9

potential price cut in the shareholder price. According to Chen et al. this can occur when other

shareholders become aware of the tax avoiding activities to extract rents and as a result bid

the firm price down (Chen et al., 2009). Basically, firms, or managers, can choose to practice

tax avoiding activities such as making use of tax shelters, that result in personal monetary

gain, which is a form of rent extraction. Managers can also make use of complex tax avoiding

activities to hide their intent of rent extracting activities (Chen et al, 2009; Desai &

Dharmapala, 2006).

Another type of cost that firms have to take into account are political costs.

Essentially, political costs are potential costs that can be imposed on the firm by external

parties as a result of political actions and or measures (Watts & Zimmerman, 1978).

According to Watts & Zimmerman, the political sector has an incentive to redistribute wealth

among various groups, and the corporate sector is particularly vulnerable to these

redistributions (1978). According to the political cost hypothesis, firms will tend to show

lower profits to steer away any attention from politicians by using different means, such as:

social responsibility campaigns, government lobbying and the selection of certain accounting

procedures (Watts & Zimmerman, 1978). By minimizing the attention to the firm's high

earnings, firms can minimize their potential costs as a result of politically imposed measures

(Watts & Zimmerman, 1978). Tax avoidance can be used as a method to influence potential

political costs. This means that when a firm is deciding on their level of tax avoidance, they

also should consider the potential political costs involved when the level of tax avoidance is

higher. This would mean that their earnings would be higher and would lead to increased

scrutiny from politicians, which could result in political costs (Watts & Zimmerman, 1978).

The last type of cost that will be discussed is reputational costs. Existing evidence

shows that there is a positive relationship between a firm's long-term performance and having

a good reputation (Roberts & Dowling, 2002). Reputation costs are costs that are incurred as a

result of a loss in reputation. An example of this is the 2010 BP oil spill, also known as the

'Deepwater Horizon oil spill.' As the events unfolded, starting on the 20th of April, BP's share

price dropped lower and lower. It went from $59.88 per share before the event, to $27.02 at its

lowest following a few months after the event1. In the study of Chen et al., it was shown that

family firms are less tax aggressive than non-family firms. This was a result of two factors:

concerns of getting a potential penalty imposed by the IRS and the concerns of losing

1 https://www.google.com/finance?q=NASDAQ%3ABP&ei=I4I_Vdn8PMSr8QOOx4HoDQ,

Dates: 16-04-2010, $59.88 & 25-06-2010, $27.02.

Page 10: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

10

reputation or family name (2009). So a firm has to take into account whether the loss of

reputation is worth the benefits of tax avoidance.

2.2 Agency Theory

In order to understand the relationship between tax avoidance and the concentration of

ownership of a firm, one must have some basic knowledge on the agency theory. This

information is also needed to construct a hypothesis. Therefore, I will explain the agency

theory in this section, following by the link between tax avoidance and ownership

concentration. After addressing these topics, I will construct a hypothesis.

Just like tax research, the agency theory is researched in various fields of studies such

as accounting, economics, finance and political science (Eisenhardt, 1989). The agency theory

describes the relationship between the principal and the agent. The agent is hired by the

principal to perform services on the principal’s behalf (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Jensen &

Meckling state that there is a good chance that the agent will not act in the best interests of the

principal if both the agent and the principal are utility maximizers, meaning they act

according their own interests (1976). This divergence in interest can cause problems that

occur between shareholders (principal) and management (agent). These problems occur

because they each have their own goals or because the principle is unable to monitor (or

afford to monitor) the agent’s work (Eisenhardt, 1989). Another important problem between

the principal and the agent is the problem of risk sharing. The agent might have a different

attitude towards risk and therefore have different preferences. As a result, this could hurt the

principal's firm (Eisenhardt, 1989). In other words, the agency problem describes a conflict

of interests between the principal and the agent, where the agent (management) could be

interested in maximizing its own wealth instead of the firms wealth.

There are two distinct problems associated with the agency theory. The first one is the

moral hazard problem. Moral hazard is essentially the problem that the agent does not put in

enough effort in his work (Eisenhardt, 1989). In this case, the principal is taking the risk

without having the information whether the agent will work adequately. The agent however,

does know how much effort he will put in his work. This difference of information between

two parties is called information asymmetry. The second problem associated with the agency

theory is adverse selection. Adverse selection in the agency theory is the fact that agents can

claim to have certain skills for a job and that the principal is not able to verify these claims.

(Eisenhardt, 1989). This is also a form of information asymmetry.

There are some ways for the principal to align the agent’s interests with his own to

Page 11: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

11

minimize any agency conflicts (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). One way is to incentivize the

agent to act towards a behaviour that better fits the principal. This can be done for instance by

giving out bonuses when certain targets are met, or giving the agent a share of the equity so

that his motives are more in line with the principal’s (Jensen & Meckling, 1976). More

specifically, the increase in ownership results in less managerial opportunism according to

Jensen & Meckling (1976). The reasoning behind incentivizing is that the outcomes of the

agency contract coalign and the rewards are now dependent on the same actions. This results

in a reduction of the self-interest conflicts between principal and agent (Eisenhardt, 1989).

Another way to minimize agency conflicts is for the principle to verify the agent’s

behaviour, which is called monitoring. When the agent knows that the principal is able to

verify the agent’s behaviour, the agent is less likely to shirk and will behave in the interests of

the principal (Eisenhardt, 1989). An example of monitoring is having a board of directors that

monitors and restricts the management’s activity on behalf of the shareholders. Monitoring,

however, also includes costs. These monitoring costs make it, in most cases, impossible for

the principal to ensure that the agent is only taking decisions that are optimal for the firm

(Jensen & Meckling, 1976).

2.3.1 Concentration of ownership definition

The term concentration of ownership refers to the allocation of the shares between the

shareholders. If there is a low amount of shareholders with relatively more shares per

shareholder, then there is a high concentration of ownership. Therefore, the shares are

concentrated, meaning they are close together, and not dispersed (La Porta et al., 1998). The

definition of concentration of ownership seems to be unambiguous in previous literature. For

instance, Ding et al. do not give a definition of ownership concentration, which implies that

they assume that there is but one definition (2007).

The concentration of ownership of a firm has been used to study relationships between

various subject matters, but not a lot for the relationship with tax avoidance. One of the

pioneering works concerning shareholder concentration was the paper from La Porta et al.

This study examined the legal rules surrounding the protection of shareholders and creditors.

One of their findings was that the concentration of ownership of the largest public company is

negatively related to the investor protection (1998). Following this study, other researches

also have studied the concentration of ownership of firms, such as: Burkart & Panunzi (2006)

and La Porta et al (1999). After these studies, a few researchers started linking tax avoidance

with ownership structures.

Page 12: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

12

2.3.2 Types of investors There are different types of investors and these different types each have their own

characteristics (Bruton et al., 2010). These characteristics influence the investor’s behaviour

and lead to different choices. Therefore, in this section, I will discuss the two main types of

investors, institutional and transient investors, their behavior and how this might influence the

level of tax avoidance.

The first type of investors that will be discussed are the (non-transient) institutional

investors. Institutional investors are institutions that invest funds on behalf of others and

manage great amounts of equity. Some examples of institutional investors are: insurance

companies, hedge funds, retirement funds and mutual funds. According to Bushee,

institutional investors are more sophisticated than regular, individual investors (1998). This

means that they possess more knowledge than other types of investors. This is logical as they

are specialized in trading stocks. This sophistication results in more monitoring and more

disciplining the managers (Bushee, 1998). This could suggest that, because of more

monitoring and disciplining, firms with institutional investors have less tax avoidance.

The second type of investors are transient investors. According to Bushee, transient

investors are investors that usually hold a small amount of stocks in various companies and

trade for short term profits. They usually make their trading decisions based on short term

values such as current earnings (1998). Note that institutional investors can also be transient

investors as it is a kind of behaviour of the investor. Transient investors are more likely to

pressure managers to meet short term goals, so that the firm's stock price increases and the

investor can sell the stocks (Bushee, 1998). This could suggest that, because of more pressure

to meet short term goals, firms with transient investors have more tax avoidance.

2.4 Hypothesis

The agency theory as discussed in section 2.2, is the backbone of the relationship between tax

avoidance and concentration of ownership. For instance, Chen et al. state that firms with a

high ownership structure have a better managerial and shareholder interest alignment and

therefore there are less conflicts between the owners and managers (2009). This reduction in

conflicts between owners and managers results in more tax avoiding activities (Chen et al.,

2009). Desai & Dharmapala state that tax avoiding activities are viewed as an activity that

shareholders advocate (Desai & Dharmapala, 2006). Desai and Dharmapala also state that,

with regards to the agency theory, a highly concentrated ownership of a firm leads to a greater

incentive to avoid taxes (Desai & Dharmapala, 2008). This notion is also mentioned by

Page 13: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

13

Hanlon & Heitzman (2010) who state that firms with concentrated ownership may avoid

more taxes because the controlling owners benefit more from the tax savings.

On the other hand, there is also some indication that highly concentrated firms may

actually engage less in tax avoiding activities. According to Hanlon & Heitzman,

concentrated firms are more concerned with long-term results and are worried about arising

costs, such as reputational costs (2010). As discussed earlier, family firms, which generally

are concentrated, show less tax avoiding activities than non-family firms. This is because

family firms are willing to forgo tax benefits to avoid concerns from other stakeholders. These

concerns are about the family shareholders showing rent seeking behaviour and trying to hide

that through tax avoiding activities (Chen et al., 2009). Also, concentrated firms could engage

in less tax avoiding activities because individuals have intrinsic motivations for tax evasion

and will compare these to their risks. As concentrated shareholders have more to say about a

firm’s behaviour, the firm in general acts more like an individual than an non-concentrated

firm (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010).

As we have just seen, there is some disagreement in the literature concerning the

relationship between tax avoidance and shareholder concentration. It can either be a positive

relationship, where a high concentration of ownership results in more tax avoiding activities,

or a negative relationship, where a high concentration of ownership leads to less tax avoiding

activities. Therefore, to test this relationship, I have constructed the following null hypothesis:

H0: There is no association between the concentration of ownership and the amount of tax

avoiding activities of a firm.

3.0 Research Methodology In the following section I will describe the sample selection, following with the different

measures that can be used as a proxy for tax avoidance. After that, I will discuss the different

measures for concentration of ownership. After discussing the different alternatives for tax

avoidance and concentration of ownership, I will make a choice between the different

measures and explain why those measures were used. Lastly, I will discuss the empirical

model used in the research.

3.1 Sample selection

The sample of firms in this research are derived from the S&P SmallCap 600 (S&P 600). The

S&P 600 is a stock market index that measures the small-cap segment of the U.S. equity

market. This stock market index is ideal for this research as it is more likely that there are

Page 14: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

14

more firms with a lower number of shareholders due to the size of the market capitalization of

the firms.

Two databases are used to gather all the data that is needed to conduct this research.

Firstly, the database Blockholders is used to gather information about the firms' concentration

of ownership. Due to scope limitations in this database, the sample period is 1996-2001.

Secondly, the database Compustat is used to gather information about tax avoidance and also

the information on control variables are extracted from this database.

The data from the two databases results in a total of 2944 firm year observations. Most

of the observations are from Compustat, which had information on 471 firms. Blockholders,

however, only had information on 180 firms, making the sample much smaller. The

Blockholders database does not have any information on the remaining 291 firms and there is

no explanation why. It is unclear whether these firms did not have any large shareholders

during that time period, or that the database was unable to collect relevant information on

those firms. Merging the two datasets and removing missing data results in 492 firm year

observations coming from a total of 125 firms, forming the actual sample.

With this sample, an archival database research will be conducted. More specifically, a

regression analysis will be conducted to determine the relationship between the concentration

of ownership and the tax avoidance of a firm.

3.2 Variable alternatives

In the following section I will discuss the different measures that can be used to measure tax

avoidance and shareholder concentration. After discussing the different measures, a choice

will be made later on in section 3.3.

3.2.1 Tax avoidance measures

There are many ways to measure tax avoidance and each measure has its own advantages and

disadvantages. Also, not every measure is suitable for every research question. In this section

I will discuss the main, usable measures, their meaning and their advantages and

disadvantages.

One of the more common types of tax avoidance measures used in tax research is the

'effective tax rate' (from now on: ETR) measure. This measure incorporates the average rate

of tax per dollar of income or cash flow (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). This measure is

determined by dividing an estimate of the tax liability of a firm by a measure of before-tax

profits or cash flow (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). For example, to calculate the GAAP ETR

one has to divide the 'worldwide total income tax expense,' which in this case is the estimate

Page 15: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

15

of the tax liability, by the 'worldwide total pre-tax accounting income,' which is the before tax

profit (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). The GAAP ETR uses the total income tax expense, which

means that if a firms defers taxes, this will not alter the GAAP ETR, as it is still a tax expense.

Another measure, the Cash ETR, uses the same denominator, but for the numerator it uses

'worldwide cash taxes paid' which means that it is affected by tax deferral strategies. At the

same time, Cash ETR is not affected by changes in tax accounting in accruals, but GAAP

ETR is (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). This shows that even the slightest change in variables

can result in an essential change in result.

Additionally, there is another type of ETR, which is more focused on the long term

implications of tax avoidance. This is the 'Long-run ETR' and was developed by Dyreng et al.

(2008). This measure is computed with the same variables used in the Cash ETR, but here the

sum of ten years of those variables is used. The main benefit of using this method is that it

takes away the year-to-year volatility in annual effective tax rates (Dyreng et al., 2008). One

of the detriments of using all ETR variants is that they do not distinguish between real

activities that are tax-favoured, avoidance activities that are meant to actually avoid taxes and

targeted tax benefits from lobbying activities (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). This can result in

taking into account non-tax avoiding activities.

Another type of measurement for tax avoidance is the unrecognized tax benefit. This

measure is used as a proxy for tax avoidance and can be obtained directly from the FIN 48

disclosure of a firm (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). FIN 48 is an official interpretation issued by

The Financial Accounting Standards Board in 2006 and its purpose is to clarify the

accounting for uncertainty in income taxes. This is done by providing the criteria used to

recognize and measure the uncertain tax benefits (Cazier et al., 2009). According to Hanlon &

Heitzman, one of the underlying determinants for unrecognized tax benefits are the financial

reporting incentives. Managers may use the unrecognized tax benefit to manage earnings

upwards and it is therefore also used as a proxy for earnings management (2010). This

measure is subjected under the judgement of management which makes it less objective.

3.2.2 Concentration of ownership measurements

According to Sjögren, Overland & Mavruk, choosing your measure for the concentration of

ownership of a firm is important. A different choice of measure can lead to different

conclusions (2012). Therefore, I will discuss a few different measures so that I will be able to

make a choice between these measures for the concentration of ownership, which will be used

when testing the hypothesis.

Page 16: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

16

There are a few different ways to measure the concentration of ownership of a firm.

One is to take the average percentage of common shares owned by the three largest

shareholders of the firm. This technique was developed by La Porta et al. (1998), but also

used by Ding et al. for their research (2007). An advantage of this type of measure is that one

can arrange a sample of firms from a low concentration of ownership to a high concentration

of ownership, comparably to Sloan's study, where he ranked firms based on their amount of

accruals (1996).

Another type of measurement is called the 'weakest link principle.' With this principle,

a firm is concentrated if it has an owner with more than a certain threshold of shares or voting

power (Edwards & Weichenrieder, 2009). This threshold can be for example 5%, 10% or

20%. If no one shareholder can be identified meeting this threshold, then the firm is not

concentrated but dispersed (Edwards & Weichenrieder, 2009). An advantage for this method

is that one can divide a sample of firms into two groups, one group of with firms that meet the

threshold and one group of firms that do not meet the threshold. Choosing between these

measures will rely on the research methodology and that will be discussed in the following

sections.

3.3 Variables measurement

3.3.1 Tax avoidance

As discussed earlier, there are a few different methods to measure tax avoidance. One of those

measures is the Long-run ETR as described in Dyreng et al. (2008). The main benefit of

using this method is that it takes away the year-to-year volatility in annual effective tax rates

(Dyreng et al., 2008). However, this method is only effective when the sample period is a

longer term, such as ten years (Dyreng et al., 2008). As stated earlier, due to scope limitations

of the Blockholders database, the sample period of this research is only six years, and even

then, there are not always six years of data for every firm. For this reason, choosing the Long-

run ETR as a tax avoidance measure, will not have any added value in this research.

Therefore, instead of using the Long-run ETR, the yearly GAAP ETR will be used

such as in the paper of Chen et al. (2009) and described in the paper of Dyreng et al. (2008).

The GAAP ETR is calculated as:

Page 17: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

17

where i stands for firm and t stands for year. This dependent variable will be called

GAAPETR. This measure captures the average rate at wich a firm is taxed as it divides the tax

expense by the taxable income (Dyreng et al., 2008). The main benefit of this measure is that

if a firm defers taxes, it does not alter the tax expense, capturing any methods of avoiding

taxes with the use of accruals (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). However, this measure does not

take away any year-to-year volatility, which could result in incomplete results (Dyreng et al.,

2008). Any values lower than 0 and higher than 1 will be dropped, in line with the research of

Chen et al. (2009).

3.3.2 Concentration of Ownership

One of the ways to measure concentration of ownership is to take the average of the largest

three shareholders of the firm (La Porta et al., 1998). The database Blockholders, however,

does not provide any information on individual shareholders, making this approach unusable.

Another approach to measure concentration of ownership is the weakest link principle

(Edwards & Weichenrieder, 2009). With this measurement, a firm is concentrated if a

shareholder has more than a set amount of shares or voting power. The set amount can be for

instance 5%, 10%, 25% or anything else that could imply a concentrated ownership. This

method will be used in this research. As a threshold, I have chosen 5% because shareholders

with at least 5% of shares of a company are called 'major shareholders' (Sjögren et al., 2012).

This independent variable will be called CONCENTRATED and is a dummy variable. This

means that CONCENTRATED is measured as an indicator variable coded as ‘1’ if the firm

has one or more shareholders with 5% or more of total shares and as ‘0’ otherwise. The

Blockholder database provides data for the percentage of shares held by a blockholder,

corrected for overlapping shareholdings (Dlugosz et al., 2006). The dummy variable is

calculated as follows:

where i stands for firm and t stands for year.

3.3.3 Control variables

Besides the independent variable CONCENTRATED, a number of control variables are used.

As this research is focused on the relationship between shareholder concentration and tax

avoidance, any outside factors influencing the results are unwanted. Therefore, there are a few

control variables that have to be taken into account.

Page 18: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

18

The first control variable is the leverage of a firm, which will be called LEV. This

variable is calculated as follows:

.

where i stands for firm and t stands for year. Firm leverage is used as a control variable

because prior literature shows us that highly leveraged firms have lower effective tax rates

than low leveraged firms (Stickney & McGee, 1982). This would mean that firms with a high

amount of leverage will show higher tax avoidance in the research model, irrespective of the

firm’s concentration of ownership. Therefore, leverage needs to be controlled for. High

leveraged firms have lower effective tax rates because there are a lot of tax benefits of debt.

This is because firms in the US are taxed on their equity and not on their debt (Graham,

2000).

The next control variable is the size of a firm, which will be called SIZE. This variable

is calculated as follows:

where i stands for firm and t stands for year. The natural logarithm of firm size is taken to

eliminate the big differences in firm size. Firm size is controlled for because prior literature

shows us that larger firms have higher effective tax rates than smaller firms (Zimmerman,

1983). For the research model, this would mean that the larger firms will show lower tax

avoidance, whether or not the firm has a high concentration of ownership and therefore, the

size of a firm needs to be considered. According to Zimmerman, large firms have higher

effective tax rates because they are more subject to political scrutiny, resulting in higher

political costs (1983).

The last control variable is the market-to-book ratio of a firm, which proxies the

growth of a firm and will be called MARKBOOK (Chen et al., 2009). This variable is

calculated as follows:

where i stands for firm and t stands for year. Firm growth is a control variable because

growing firms may make more investments in tax beneficial assets (Chen et al., 2009). In this

research model, that would mean that growing firms will show higher tax avoidance, whether

Page 19: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

19

or not the firm has a high concentration of ownership. For this reason, firm growth needs to be

controlled for.

3.4 Model

To test whether shareholder concentration is associated with tax avoidance, the following

regression model will be used:

where i stands for firm and t stands for year. As stated earlier, the dependent variable is

calculated by using the GAAP ETR of a firm. If highly concentrated firms conduct more tax

avoiding activities than low concentrated firms, is expected to be negative. This is because

the lower the ETR is, the more tax is avoided. If highly concentrated firms conduct less tax

avoiding activities, then is expected to be positive. If there is no correlation between tax

avoidance and equity of ownership, the is expected to be close to 0. The control variables

are used to capture possible relationships between tax avoidance and the concentration of

ownership that could otherwise influence the results.

4.0 Descriptive statistics & Empirical results

In this section the descriptive statistics and their meanings will be discussed. Afterwards the

empirical results of the research will be discussed.

4.1 Descriptive Statistics

The descriptive statistics for tax avoidance, shareholder ownership and the control variables

are illustrated in table 1.

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics

Variable Observations Mean

Standard

Deviation Median

Min Max

GAAPETR 492 .3512 .0866 .3646

0 .7571

CONCENTRATED 492 .8434 .3637 1

0 1

LEV 492 .1827 .1436 .1792

0 .6471

SIZE 492 6.2813 .7150 6.2924

4.3823 9.5648

MARKBOOK 492 2.2252 3.8616 1.9002

-73.5788 17.6199

Page 20: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

20

The GAAPETR is 0.3512 which means that the firms in this sample are, on average, taxed for

35,12% on their pretax income. The standard deviation is relatively low, which means that

there is not much of a dispersion regarding the effective tax rate among the different firms in

the sample. Just like in the paper of Chen et al. (2009), the range of effective tax rate is

between 0 and 1.

The dummy variable CONCENTRATED has a mean of .8434, which means that

84,34% of the firms in the sample have one or more shareholders with 5% or more of the total

shares. This shows that the majority of the sample has a concentrated ownership structure,

which may result in an under-representation of the non-concentrated firms.

Table 2 gives an overview of the correlation between the variables. The values in

parentheses are the p-values of the correlation.

GAAPETR CONCENTRATED LEV SIZE MARKBOOK

GAAPETR 1

-

CONCENTRATED -0.0442 1

(0.3279) -

LEV 0.1418 -0.1513 1

(0.0016) (0.0008) -

SIZE 0.0715 -0.0632 -0.0773 1

(0.1133) (0.1613) (0.0867) -

MARKBOOK 0.2039 -0.0046 -0.1784 0.1741 1

(0.0000) (0.9196) (0.0001) (0.0001) - Table 2: Correlation Matrix

The independent variable and the control variables are not highly correlated with each other,

the highest correlation is between the leverage of a firm and its market-to-book ratio, which is

-0.1784. This means that a higher market-to-book ratio leads to a lower amount of leverage

which corresponds with previous literature from Binks & Ennew. They stated that high

growth firms may be adversely affected by credit constraints (1996).

The correlation between the variables LEV and CONCENTRATED is -0.1513 which

means that the ownership concentration of a firm is negatively correlated with the amount of

leverage. If a firm is more concentrated, it will have less leverage. This could be explained by

the fact that larger shareholders are not willing to accept the risk of the debt, because the

shareholders bear the majority of the risk (Jensen & Meckling, 1976).

The fact that the independent variable and the control variables are not highly

correlated with each other, means that there is no collinearity in the model, thus there is no

Page 21: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

21

need to drop any independent variables.

The correlation between the dependent variable and the independent variable is very

low and has a high p-value, which indicates that it is close to zero. This means that there is no

correlation between the concentration of ownership and the effective tax rate of a firm. The

actual coefficient of CONCENTRATED will be discussed in the next section.

4.2.1 Results

In the following sections I will discuss the results of the regression analysis. I will analyze and

discuss the coefficients and their meaning.

Table 3 reports the results of the OLS regression analysis between the effective tax

rate of a firm and the concentration of ownership.

coefficient t-statistic p-value

CONCENTRATED -0.0029 -0.28 0.779

LEV 0.1111***2

4.11 0

SIZE 0.0054 1.02 0.31

MARKBOOK 0.0051***

5.1 0

Constant 0.2876***

7.91 0

Observations (N) 492

F-value 10.09

Prob > F 0

R-squared 0.0766

Adj R-squared 0.069

Table 3; Results of Regression Analysis

The null hypothesis states there is no association between the concentration of

ownership and the amount of tax avoiding activities of a firm. The coefficient

CONCENTRATED is slightly negative, but not significantly less than 0, which means that

the null hypothesis is not rejected. This means that, in this sample, there is no effect between

the concentration of ownership and tax avoidance activities, which is not in line with the

prediction that shareholder concentration is either positively or negatively associated with tax

avoidance. This does not align with the current literature, which states that a higher

2 *** indicates that the coefficient is significant at the one per cent level.

Page 22: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

22

concentration of ownership either results in more tax avoiding activities (Desai &

Dharmapala, 2008; Chen et al., 2009) or less tax avoiding activities (Hanlon & Heitzman,

2010; Chen et al., 2009).

Another coefficient that contradicts prior literature, is the coefficient for the variable

LEV. This is the variable that determines a firm’s leverage. Table 3 shows that the coefficient

is significantly positive. This means that firms with a higher leverage have a higher effective

tax rate. In other words, firms with higher leverage practice less tax avoiding activities. This

is not in line with Stickney & McGee (1982), which stated the opposite.

The coefficient MARKBOOK, which proxies for firm growth, is also significantly

positive. This means that if a firms market-to-book ratio increases, they conduct less tax

avoiding activities. Growing firms have higher market-to-book ratios because their market

value is higher than their book value as a result of investors thinking that these firms are

undervalued (Chen & Zhao, 2006). This means that growing firms actually conduct less tax

avoiding activities than full-grown firms, which also contradicts previous literature.

4.2.2 Discussion

In the previous section, the results of the regression showed that the concentration of

ownership is not associated with tax avoiding activities, which is not in line with the

prediction nor with the previous literature. There might be a few reasons for this disagreement

between the results and prior literature.

One of the reason that could explain this difference is that the sample is quite specific

and small. The sample is small because the database Blockholders only has data on firms

from 1996 to 2001. Also, does it not have data for every firm in the S&P Smallcap 600. This

is understandable, as collecting information on the shareholder concentration is difficult and

not always available. The small sample might not be able to capture all the effects of the

entire population and therefore result in a different outcome. Also, as stated earlier, the

independent variable consists for 84,34% of firms with a concentrated ownership structure.

This could imply an under-representation of the firms with a non-concentrated ownership

structure.

A second reason could be that the measure used for tax avoidance, GAAP ETR, did

not take away the year-to-year volatility and it did not reflect deferred taxes as tax avoidance.

According to Dyreng et al., there are two disadvantages to using the GAAP ETR. The first

one is that this measure does not take away any year-to-year volatility as it is an annual

measure (2008). Another disadvantage is that GAAP ETR includes both current and deferred

Page 23: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

23

taxes and that means that the GAAP ETR will not reflect tax avoidance in the form of

deferring taxes (Dyreng et al., 2008). It could be that these aspects have caused different

results.

Another reason for conflicting results could be that the threshold for the concentration

of ownership was chosen too low. For a firm to be concentrated in this research, it has to have

one or more shareholders with 5% or more of the total shares, this was done in line with

Sjögren et al.’s paper (2012). However, it is possible that the effects of large shareholders are

better represented by shareholders with a larger percentage of shares than 5% (Sjögren et al,

2012). For this reason, a few sensitivity tests concerning the threshold will be conducted

These will be discussed in the next chapter.

5.0 Sensitivity Analysis In the following section some additional analyses will be conducted to test whether a different

threshold for the concentration of ownership has an effect for the outcome of the regression.

There is a lot of subjectivity in determining the threshold for a firm with a concentrated

ownership and using a different measure can lead to different results (Sjögren et al, 2012).

Therefore, to test whether these outcomes hold true for other thresholds, I conduct these

additional sensitivity analyses.

5.1 Sensitivity analysis – 10% threshold

I start by changing the dummy variable CONCENTRATED from being coded as ‘1’ if the

firm has one or more shareholders with 5% or more of total shares and as ‘0’ otherwise to

being coded as ‘1’ if the firm has one or more shareholders with 10% or more of total shares

and as ‘0’ otherwise. As stated earlier, determining the threshold for the concentration of

ownership requires some subjectivity and there are different thresholds that can be set

(Sjögren et al., 2012). The reason to raise the threshold to 10% specifically is because it is in

line with the empirical research of Maury & Pajuste, where they investigate whether having

multiple large shareholders has an effect on the valuation of the firm (2005).

Table 4 shows the descriptive statistics of the new regression with the new variable

called XCON, where X stands for the Roman numeral 10.

Page 24: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

24

Table 4: Descriptive Statistics Sensitivity Analysis 10% Threshold

The descriptives of the old variables are unchanged. The mean of XCON is noticeably lower

at 0.2703 than the mean of CONCENTRATED. This means that, in this sample, 27.03% of

the firms have one or more shareholders with at least 10% of total shares. This shows that the

new threshold results in a higher representation of the non-concentrated firms. Also, this

means that the majority of the large shareholders possess somewhere between 5-10% of total

shares.

Table 5 shows the results of the regression between the effective tax rate and the new

variable XCON.

Coefficient t-statistic p-value

XCON 0.0013 0.15 0.879

LEV 0.1127***3

4.2 0

SIZE 0.0056 1.03 0.301

MARKBOOK 0.0052***

5.11 0

CONSTANT 0.2840***

8.27 0

Observations (N) 492

F-value 10.08

Prob > F 0

R-squared 0.0765

Adj R-squared 0.0689

Table 5: Results of Sensitivity Analysis 10% Threshold

3 *** indicates that the coefficient is significant at the one per cent level.

Variable Observations Mean Standard Deviation Median Min Max

GAAPETR 492 0.3512 0.0866 .3646 0 0.7571

XCON 492 0.2703 0.4445 0 0 1

LEV 492 0.1827 0.1436 .1792 0 0.6471

SIZE 492 6.2813 0.7150 6.2924 4.3823 9.5648

MARKBOOK 492 2.2252 3.8616 1.9002 -73.5788 17.6199

Page 25: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

25

Consistent with the main finding in section 4.2.1 the coefficient of the dependent variable

XCON is statistically close to 0 with the raised threshold, which means that H0 is not

rejected. This strengthens the earlier finding where there was no effect between the

concentration of ownership and tax avoidance activities. This also holds true when a

concentrated firm is defined as a firm with one or more shareholders with 10% or more of the

total shares.

5.2 Sensitivity analysis – 20% threshold

A different threshold that is used to define a concentrated ownership is the 20% threshold. La

Porta et al. (1999) define a shareholder with 20% of voting rights a controlling shareholder.

Even though voting rights are different from owning shares, voting rights are also used as a

measure for concentration of ownership (Sjögren et al., 2012). Berle & Means define a

controlling shareholder as a shareholder that owns 20% or more of the total shares (1932).

This 20% threshold is a higher measure that is used to define a concentrated ownership

(Sjögren et al., 2012) and testing with this threshold will improve the credibility of the main

findings.

For this sensitivity analysis, I create a new dummy variable as in the previous

sensitivity analysis. I start by changing the dummy variable CONCENTRATED from being

coded as ‘1’ if the firm has one or more shareholders with 5% or more of total shares and as

‘0’ otherwise to being coded as ‘1’ if the firm has one or more shareholders with 20% or more

of total shares and as ‘0’ otherwise. This new variable is called XXCON, where XX stands for

the Roman numeral 20. Table 6 shows the descriptive statistics of the new regression with the

variable XXCON.

Variable Observations Mean Std. Dev. Median Min Max

ETR 492 0.3512 0.0866 .3646 0 0.7571

XXCON 492 0.0813 0.2735 0 0 1

LEV 492 0.1827 0.1436 .1792 0 0.6471

SIZE 492 6.2813 0.7150 6.2924 4.3823 9.5648

MARKBOOK 492 2.2252 3.8616 1.9002 -73.5788 17.6199

Table 6: Descriptive Statistics Sensitivity analysis 20% Threshold

Again, the descriptives of the old variables are unchanged. The new variable XXCON has a

mean of 0.0813, which means that, in this sample, 8,13% of the firms have one or more

Page 26: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

26

shareholders with 20% or more of the total shares. This is significantly lower than the

previous variables and shows that there are not a lot of firms in the sample that own more than

one fifth of a firm.

Table 7 shows the results of the regression between the effective tax rate and the new

variable XXCON.

Coefficient t-value p-value

XXCON -0.0083 -0.59 0.557

LEV 0.1088***4

3.98 0

SIZE 0.00526 0.98 0.329

MARKBOOK 0.0051***

5.1 0

CONSTANT 0.2875***

8.29 0

Observations (N) 492

F-value 10.17

Prob > F 0

R-squared 0.0771

Adj R-squared 0.0695

Table 7: Results of Sensitivity Analysis 20% Threshold

The coefficient for XXCON is still statistically close to 0. This sensitivity analysis also

supports the initial findings. So H0 is not rejected which means that there is no association

between the concentration of ownership and the amount of tax avoiding activities of a firm

when the threshold is set at 20%.

6.0 Conclusion There is a great amount of previous literature on tax avoidance to be found as it is a complex

and rising topic (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010). However, the amount of studies on tax

avoidance in relation to the concentration of ownership is limited and there still is a call for

empirical evidence on the subject (Desai & Dharmapala, 2008). This research is a reply to that

call for empirical evidence.

This research examines whether the concentration of ownership is associated with tax

avoidance. More specifically, I test whether a high concentration of ownership is associated

4 *** indicates that the coefficient is significant at the one per cent level.

Page 27: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

27

with a change in tax avoiding activities. The measure that is used to determine tax avoiding

activities is the GAAP effective tax rate of a firm. The independent variable, firm

concentration, is a dummy variable which is coded as a '1' for firms with one or more

shareholders with 5% or more of total shares, and as '0' otherwise.

The findings show that there is no association between shareholder concentration and

tax avoiding activities. Thus, the null hypothesis, which stated that there is no association

between the concentration of ownership and the amount of tax avoiding activities, is not

rejected. This contradicts prior literature, which states that a higher concentration of

ownership either results in more tax avoiding activities (Desai & Dharmapala, 2008; Chen et

al., 2009) or less tax avoiding activities (Hanlon & Heitzman, 2010; Chen et al., 2009). The

findings hold up against additional sensitivity analyses, where the threshold of concentration

of ownership was increased to 10% and 20%.

There could be a few reasons why the findings contradict prior literature. The first

reason is that the sample is quite specific and small. The small sample might not be able to

capture all the effects of the entire population and therefore result in a different outcome. A

second reason could be that the measured used for tax avoidance did not take away year-to-

year volatility as it is an annual measure and that it did not capture deferred taxes as tax

avoidance (Dyreng et al., 2008).

There are some limitations to this study. As said earlier, the sample size is small

because of the range restrictions of the Blockholders database. The small sample size could

negatively influence the quality of the findings because a larger sample strengthens the

statistical power of a research. This limitation can be overcome by future researchers by either

choosing a different sample or using a different database that is available to them. There is

another limitation as a result of the range restriction of the Blockholders database. That is the

fact that it is not possible to measure the long-term tax avoidance, as you need data from firms

over a period of at least ten years (Dyreng et al., 2008). By not being able to use this measure

I was not able to take away the year-to-year volatility in annual effective tax rates, which

could have led to qualitatively stronger findings. This limitation can also be overcome by

using a different database that does have the appropriate data available.

This study contributes to the growing stream of literature on tax avoidance as it

answers to the call of empirical evidence. The findings of this study are not in line with prior

literature which means that there still is some ambiguity around the effect of shareholder

concentration on tax avoidance and that this topic should be continued to be researched in the

future. Another contribution that is paper makes, is that it stimulates the discussion about

Page 28: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

28

corporate tax avoidance as an ethical and societal issue. It is argued that corporate tax

avoidance is unethical and that it costs tens of billions of dollars in lost revenue every year to

developing countries (Jones, 2015). This shows that corporate tax avoidance is still a societal

issue and this paper contributes to that discussion by providing additional insights and

bringing up this subject.

Bibliography Berle, A. A., & Means, G. (1932). The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New Jersey:

Transaction Publishers.

Binks, M. R., & Ennew, C. T. (1996). Growing firms and the credit constraint. Small Business

Economics, 8(1), 17-25.

Bruton, G. D., Filatotchv, I., Chahine, S., & Wright, M. (2010). Governance, Ownership Structure,

and Performance of IPO Firms: The Impact of Different Types of Private Equity Investors and

Institutional Environments. Strategic Management Journal, 31(1), 491-509.

Burkart, M., & Panunzi, F. (2006). Agency conflicts, ownership concentration, and legal shareholder

protection. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 15(1), 1-31.

Bushee, B. J. (1998). The Influence of Institutional Investors on Myopic R&D Investment Behavior.

The Accounting Review, 73(3), 305-333.

Cazier,R. Rego, S., Tian, X., & Wilson, R. (2009) Early Evidence on the Determinants of Unrec-

ognized Tax Benefits. Working paper, University of Iowa and Texas Christian University

Chen, L., & Zhao, X. (2006). On the relation between the market-to-book ratio, growth oppurtunity,

and leverage ratio. Finance Research Letters, 3(1), 253-266.

Chen, S., Chen, X., Cheng, Q., & Shevlin, T. (2009). Are family firms more tax aggresive than non-

family firms? Journal of Financial Economics, 95(1), 41-61.

Desai, M. A., & Dharmapala, D. (2006). Corporate tax avoidance and high-powered incentives.

Journal of Financial Economics, 79(1), 145-179.

Desai, M. A., & Dharmapala, D. (2008). Tax and corporate governance: an economic approach. Tax

and Corporate governance, 13-30.

Ding, Y., Hope, O.-K., Jeanjean, T., & Stolowy, H. (2007). Differences between domestic accounting

standards and IAS: Measurement determinants and implications. Journal of Accounting and

Public Policy, 26(1), 1-38.

Dlugosz, J., Fahlenbach, R., Gompers, P., & Metrick, A. (2006). Large Blocks of Stock: Prevalence,

Size and Measurement. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12(1), 594-618.

Doward, J. (2014, October 5). How Apple’s Cork HQ became the centre of a bitter global ware over

corporate tax avoidance. The Guardian. Retrieved from http://www.theguardian.com

Page 29: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

29

Dyreng, S. D., Hanlon, M., & Maydew, E. L. (2008). Long-Run Corporate Tax avoidance. The

accounting Review, 83(1), 61-82.

Edwards, J. S., & Weichenrieder, A. J. (2009). Control rights, pyramids, and the measurement of

ownership concentration. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 72(1), 489-508.

Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989). Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review. The Academy of Management

Review, 14(1), 57-74.

Graham, J. R. (2000). How Big Are the Tax Benefits of Debt. The Journal of Finance, 55(5), 1901-

1942.

Hanlon, M., & Heitzman, S. (2010). A review of tax research. Journal of Accounting and Economics,

50(1), 127-178.

Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs

and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360.

Jones, S. (2015, June 2). Tax dodging by big firms ‘robs poor countries of billions of dollars a year.’

The Guardian. Retrieved from http://www.theguardian.com

Kim, J.-B., Li, Y., & Zhang, L. (2011). Corporate tax avoidance and stock price crash risk: Firm-level

analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 100(1), 639-662.

Krueger, A. O. (1974). The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society. The American Economic

Association, 64(3), 291-303.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and Finance. Journal of

Political Economy , 106(6), 1113-1155.

La Portal, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate Ownership Around the World.

The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471-517.

Maury, B., & Pajuste, A. (2005). Multiple large shareholders and firm value. Journal of Banking &

Finance, 29(1), 1813-1834.

Roberts, P. W., & Dowling, G. R. (2002). Corporate Reputation and Sustained Superior Financial

Performance. Strategic Management Journal, 23(2), 1077-1093.

Sjögren, S., Overland, C., & Mavruk, T. (2012). Keeping it real or keeping it simple? Ownership

concentration measures compared. The 4th workshop of the Nordic Corporate Governace

Network.

Sloan, R. G. (1996). Do Stock Prices Fully reflect information in Accruals and Cash Flows about

Future Earnings? The Accounting Review, 71(3), 289-315.

Stickney, C. P., & McGee, V. E. (1982). Effective corporate tax rates the effect of size, capital

intensity, leverage and other factors. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 1(2), 125-152.

Tullock, G. (1967). The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies and Theft. Western Economic Journal,

5(3), 224-232.

Page 30: Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance.

Shareholder ownership and tax avoidance

30

Watts, R. L., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1978). Towards a Postitive Theory of the Determination of

Accounting Standards. The Accounting Review, 563(1), 112-134.

Zimmerman, J. L. (1983). Taxes and Firm Size. Journa of Accounting and Economics , 5(1), 119-149.