Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010...

39
Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and Magne Mogstad The distributional impact of public services when needs differ Abstract: Despite a broad consensus on the need to take into account the value of public services in distributional analysis, there is little reliable evidence on how the inclusion of such non-cash income actually affects poverty and inequality estimates. In particular, the equivalence scales applied to cash income are not necessarily appropriate when including non-cash income, because the receipt of public services is likely to be associated with particular needs. In this paper, we propose a theory- based framework designed to provide a coherent evaluation of the distributional impact of local public services. The valuation of public services, identification of target groups, allocation of expenditures to target groups, and adjustment for differences in needs are derived from a model of local government spending behaviour. Using Norwegian data from municipal accounts and administrative registers we find that the inclusion of non-cash income reduces income inequality by about 15 percent and poverty rates by almost one-third. However, adjusting for differences in needs for public services across population subgroups offsets about half the inequality reduction and some of the poverty decrease. Keywords: Income distribution, poverty, public services, non-cash income, needs adjustment, equivalence scales JEL classification: D31, H72, I30 Acknowledgement: We would like to thank the Norwegian Research Council for financial support, Marit Østensen and Simen Pedersen for preparing the data, and Kathleen Short, Terje Skjerpen, and two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions and comments. Address: Rolf Aaberge, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected] Manudeep Bhuller, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected] Audun Langørgen, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected] Magne Mogstad, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected]

Transcript of Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010...

Page 1: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department

Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and Magne Mogstad

The distributional impact of public services when needs differ

Abstract: Despite a broad consensus on the need to take into account the value of public services in distributional analysis, there is little reliable evidence on how the inclusion of such non-cash income actually affects poverty and inequality estimates. In particular, the equivalence scales applied to cash income are not necessarily appropriate when including non-cash income, because the receipt of public services is likely to be associated with particular needs. In this paper, we propose a theory-based framework designed to provide a coherent evaluation of the distributional impact of local public services. The valuation of public services, identification of target groups, allocation of expenditures to target groups, and adjustment for differences in needs are derived from a model of local government spending behaviour. Using Norwegian data from municipal accounts and administrative registers we find that the inclusion of non-cash income reduces income inequality by about 15 percent and poverty rates by almost one-third. However, adjusting for differences in needs for public services across population subgroups offsets about half the inequality reduction and some of the poverty decrease.

Keywords: Income distribution, poverty, public services, non-cash income, needs adjustment, equivalence scales

JEL classification: D31, H72, I30

Acknowledgement: We would like to thank the Norwegian Research Council for financial support, Marit Østensen and Simen Pedersen for preparing the data, and Kathleen Short, Terje Skjerpen, and two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions and comments.

Address: Rolf Aaberge, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected]

Manudeep Bhuller, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected]

Audun Langørgen, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected]

Magne Mogstad, Statistics Norway, Research Department. E-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

Discussion Papers comprise research papers intended for international journals or books. A preprint of a Discussion Paper may be longer and more elaborate than a standard journal article, as it may include intermediate calculations and background material etc.

Abstracts with downloadable Discussion Papers in PDF are available on the Internet: http://www.ssb.no http://ideas.repec.org/s/ssb/dispap.html For printed Discussion Papers contact: Statistics Norway Sales- and subscription service NO-2225 Kongsvinger Telephone: +47 62 88 55 00 Telefax: +47 62 88 55 95 E-mail: [email protected]

Page 3: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

3

1. Introduction Most studies of poverty and income inequality focus exclusively on cash income and omit the value of

public services. Smeeding et al. (1993; p 230) suggest that this practice may be due to the fact that

“the problems inherent in the measurement, valuation, and imputation of non-cash income to

individual households on the basis of micro data files are formidable.” Nevertheless, the conventional

focus on cash income yields an incomplete and perhaps misleading picture of the distribution of

economic well-being, not least because about half of welfare state transfers in developed countries are

in-kind benefits such as health insurance, education and other services (Garfinkel et al., 2006).

As the tax burden levied on households represent a deduction from their disposable income, it is

important to account for the services which governments provide to households through these taxes.

The omission of public services from the definition of income may call into question the validity of

income comparisons across population subgroups, over time, and between countries. Furthermore, this

omission can have important policy implications given the wide range of policies that aim to fight

poverty and reduce inequality. For these reasons, the Canberra Group (Expert Group on Household

Income Statistics, 2001) and Atkinson et al. (2002) have expressed the need for more research on the

distributional impact of public services. Definition and measurement of public in-kind benefits require

solutions of conceptual as well as practical problems, which have been raised and explored in a

number of studies.1 While these studies represent a significant step forward, our aim is to further

develop a framework for evaluating the distributional impact of public services.

Extended income. The term extended income denotes the sum of disposable cash income and non-cash

income, where non-cash income accounts for the value of local public services received by different

individuals and households. The measurement of non-cash income involves three steps: Valuation,

allocation, and adjustment for differences in needs through the use of equivalence scales. Our paper

departs from the previous literature in that a model of local government spending behaviour forms the

basis for each step. This framework therefore provides a coherent framework for evaluating the

distributional impact of public services.

1 See e.g. Smeeding (1977), Ruggles and O’Higgins (1981), Gemmell (1985), Smeeding et al. (1993), Evandrou et al. (1993), Ruggeri et al. (1994), Slesnick (1996), Antoninis and Tsakloglou (2001) and Garfinkel et al. (2006).

Page 4: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

4

Valuation and allocation. From a model of local government behaviour, we derive a linear

expenditure system that proves useful in explaining differences in spending of municipalities across

sectors and between population subgroups. In particular, the allocation of public service expenditure to

households is based on estimates of sector-specific minimum quantities assigned to different target

groups. These estimates are identified from information on sector-specific expenditures and the

demographic characteristics of the population in each municipality. The estimation of the model is

based on detailed local government accounts and community characteristics for Norwegian

municipalities.

In our main analysis, we follow the previous literature closely in valuating public services at the cost

of their provision. However, we perform a sensitivity analysis in which the value of public services is

adjusted by estimated price indices that account for variation in production costs across municipalities,

in line with the suggestions of Aaberge and Langørgen (2006).

Needs adjustment. The importance of accounting for needs and economies of scale in households’ in

analyses of cash income distributions is universally acknowledged. As argued by Radner (1997),

however, equivalence scales designed to account for needs and economies of scale in cash income are

not necessarily appropriate when analyzing extended income. For instance, the elderly tend to utilize

health services more often than younger people due to different health status, and children have a

genuine need for education. As a consequence, studies using the equivalence scales designed for cash

income risk overestimating the equivalent incomes of groups with relatively high needs for public

services. A contribution of this paper is to relax the assumption that the relative needs of different

subgroups remain unchanged when the definition of income changes.

To derive an equivalence scale for extended income, we use the minimum expenditures identified in

the spending model of the local governments as a basis for assessing the relative needs for public

services of different target groups. The justification of this approach is that the estimated minimum

expenditures can be considered as a result of central government regulations, expert opinion, and/or a

consensus among local governments about how much spending the different target groups need, given

the budget constraint that the municipalities face. The fact that the equivalence scale is based on the

same model used to derive the allocation method does not imply that the allocated non-cash income is

exactly offset by the needs of the different target groups. The reasons are threefold. First, the

recipients live in different municipalities which have different economic capacity to produce public

services. Second, local governments have discretion in their spending across service sectors, as well as

Page 5: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

5

in spending priorities on different target groups. And third, since the needs-adjusted equivalence scale

is defined as a weighted average of the scale for cash income and the scale for non-cash income, the

needs adjustment is a function of both cash and non-cash income. This means that individuals who are

equal with respect to needs for public services and who belong to the same municipality, are affected

differently by the needs adjustment if their cash incomes differ.

The Norwegian case. Norway emerges as an interesting country for studying the distributional impact

of local public services for reasons beyond data availability and quality. First of all, Norway is a

relatively large country with a dispersed population and relatively large public sector where local

governments play an important role in the provision of public services. In Norway, the central

government has introduced an equalization program in the grant system for local governments.

However, important income components such as income from hydroelectric power plants and regional

development transfers are not accounted for in the equalization scheme. Moreover, there is variation in

local government spending across service sectors, as well as in spending priorities on different target

groups (Aaberge and Langørgen, 2003). Consequently, some municipalities may be more effective

than others in fighting poverty and reducing inequality, either because they can provide a generally

higher level of services or because they are targeting vulnerable groups.

Outline. Section 2 discusses the model of local government spending behaviour and the methods used

to valuate and allocate public services, before justifying the equivalence scales for non-cash income

and extended income. Section 3 describes the empirical implementation of these methods and reports

estimation results from the model of local government spending. Section 4 presents empirical results

showing the impact of local public services on poverty and income inequality estimates, before

Section 5 concludes.

2. Local public services This section describes the model of local government spending behaviour, before presenting the

methods used to valuate and allocate public services and derive the equivalence scales for non-cash

income and extended income.

It should be noted that it is beyond the scope of this paper to evaluate the distributional impact of

public services that are not provided by local governments, most notably central government

administration and infrastructure, defence, police services, secondary and post-secondary education,

Page 6: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

6

and public hospitals. Though figuring out how to value, allocate, and needs adjust those services is

important, it is left for future research.

2.1. Spending behaviour of local governments

As was demonstrated by Aaberge and Langørgen (2003), the linear expenditure system (LES) proves

helpful in explaining differences in the spending behaviour of Norwegian municipalities, provided that

account is taken for heterogeneity in expenditure needs and in local preferences for allocation of

income to different services. To account for heterogeneity in preferences over service sectors and

target groups of local governments, we use the following specification of a Stone-Geary utility

function,

(2.1) 1 1

log ,s k

ij ijij

i j ij

xV

γβ

γ= =

−=

where V is utility of the local government, and ijx is the production of service i per person of target

group j. The parameter ijγ is interpreted as the minimum quantity per person of service i targeted to

group j and can also be considered as a measure of the local government’s assessment of the need for

different services targeted to different population subgroups. The parameter ijβ is interpreted as the

marginal budget share for spending on group j in service sector i.

When the local government is assumed to allocate resources both to different service sectors and to

different target groups, the budget constraint can be specified as

(2.2) 1 1 1 1

,s k s k

i ij j ij ji j i j

y x z u zπ= = = =

= =

where y is total per capita income of the local government, iπ is the cost per unit in the production of

service i, jz is the population share that belongs to target group j and ij i iju xπ= is the spending per

person on service i for target group j. Thus, ij ju z is spending of type i targeted to group j measured per

person in the population. By maximizing utility in (2.1) subject to the budget constraint (2.2), we

obtain the following linear expenditure system,

Page 7: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

7

(2.3) 1 1

1 1

, 1,2,..., , 1,2,..., ,

1,

s k

ij j i ij j ij i ij ji j

s k

iji j

u z z y z i s j kπ γ β π γ

β

= =

= =

= + − = =

=

where 1 1

s k

i ij ji j

y zπ γ= =

− is discretionary income, that is, the income remaining when the minimum

expenditures have been covered. Minimum expenditure in sector i targeted to group j is defined by

i ij jzπ γ . Exclusion restrictions of the type 0ijγ = capture the fact that each target group does not

necessarily receive all services.

Since allocation of spending to target groups, iju , is normally not reported in accounting data we

identify the parameters of the model by imposing the following multiplicative structure on the

marginal budget shares,

(2.4) 1

1

, 1,2,..., , 1,2,..., ,

1,

1, 1,2,..., ,

ij i ij

s

ii

k

ijj

i s j k

i s

β β θ

β

θ

=

=

= = =

=

= =

where iβ is the marginal budget share for service sector i, and ijθ is the share of sector-specific

discretionary income in service sector i that is allocated to target group j. Inserting (2.4) into (2.3) and

aggregating across target groups within each service sector yield

(2.5) 1 1 1

, 1,2,..., ,k s k

i i ij j i i ij jj i j

u z y z i sπ γ β π γ= = =

= + − =

where 1

k

i ij jju u z

== is expenditure (per capita) in service sector i, which is reported in the

accounting data of the municipalities. The total per capita minimum quantity in sector i is defined by

1

k

i ij jjzγ γ

== . Thus, owing to the additive properties of the linear expenditure system, it is possible

to estimate minimum quantities for different target groups and different service sectors. By allowing

the minimum quantity parameters ijγ to vary across target groups, we obtain a flexible modelling

framework that accounts for different needs for public services across different demographic groups.

We also allow the unit cost parameters iπ and the marginal budget share parameters iβ to vary with

Page 8: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

8

observed variables. However, for the purpose of identification we assume that certain variables affect

unit costs but not minimum quantities. This assumption helps to clarify the distinction between unit

costs and service needs of the population.2 Specifically, we introduce the following specification for

the unit cost parameters:

(2.6) 0 1 ( ) , 1,2,..., ,i i ih h hh

p p i sπ π π = + − =

where hp is a variable that affects unit costs in at least one of the service sectors and hp is the

national mean of variable hp . For instance, we assume that settlement pattern and economies of scale

affect unit costs, which means that small municipalities with a dispersed population are allowed to

face different unit costs in service production compared to other municipalities. By contrast, the

sector-specific minimum quantities ( iγ ) depend on population shares of different target groups which

capture the local need for services such as child care, education and care for the elderly.

Equation (2.6) is expressed in terms of variables measured as deviations from national average levels.

Consequently, the parameter 0iπ can be interpreted as the average price level in service sector i.

Minimum quantities and unit costs are, however, only identified up to a multiplicative constant, since

multiplying unit costs by a constant and dividing subsistence output by the same constant cannot be

traced from the reduced form parameters of the model. Natural scales of measurement for output and

unit costs of local public services are not available. However, since expenditures are defined by the

product of output and unit costs an appropriate scale emerges by normalizing the average price levels

to 1 ( 0 1, 1,2,...,i i sπ = = ). This means that unit cost iπ is defined as a price index with the average for

the entire country equal to 1. Moreover, it follows that service outputs are measured in money terms

and are interpreted as monetary values of output for an average price level. Note, however, that the

normalization of prices imposes no restrictions on the model other than a choice of measurement scale

for prices and outputs.

Heterogeneity in marginal budget shares is due to different preferences across municipalities for

allocating discretionary income to service sectors. Let

2 Aaberge and Langørgen (2003) used a different approach by replacing the minimum expenditure terms with linear functions of observed municipality characteristics.

Page 9: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

9

(2.7)

0

01

1

, ( 1,2,..., ),

1,

0 0,

i i ih hh

s

ii

s

ihi

t i s

for all h

β β β

β

β

=

=

= + =

=

= ≠

where ht is a taste variable that affects the preferences for allocating discretionary income. For

instance, the party composition of the local government council may influence such service priorities.

This specification allows for different political priorities over service sectors across local

governments. Such priorities are assumed to affect the allocation of discretionary income to services

sectors, whereas the minimum quantities are assumed to be determined by variation in local needs that

are reflected in the relative size of different target groups.

2.2 Allocation method

As noted above, the allocation of spending to different services is reported in local government

accounts. Yet the allocation of spending to target groups is not observed, reflecting data availability in

most countries. This means that marginal budget share ijθ for different target groups are not identified.

A feasible solution to this problem is to utilize the information captured by the minimum quantities ijγ

to determine the relative priority of different target groups. By assuming that the sector-specific

discretionary income is allocated to target groups by the same proportions as minimum expenditures,

that is,

(2.8) 1

, 1,2,..., , 1,2,..., ,ij jij k

ij jj

zi s j k

z

γθ

γ=

= = =

the local government model is fully identified. Thus, the parameter ijθ can be interpreted as the

proportion of the minimum quantity (and minimum expenditure) in sector i received by target group j.

Inserting (2.8), (2.4) and (2.5) in (2.3) gives the following allocation of spending to target groups

(2.9) 1

, 1,2,..., , 1,2,..., ,ij jij j ik

ij jj

zu z u i s j k

z

γγ

=

= = =

which means that sector-specific spending is allocated to target groups by the same proportions as

minimum quantities (and minimum expenditures). Note that the share of expenditure received by a

target group is an increasing function of the target groups’s share of the population, as well as of the

estimated minimum quantity per person in the target group. As is demonstrated by (2.9), estimates of

Page 10: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

10

the target-group-specific expenditures iju can be derived from estimates of the minimum quantities

ijγ , and from data on sector-specific expenditures and proportions of the population belonging to

various target groups.

2.3 Equivalence scales

Equivalence scales play an important role in analysis of inequality and poverty as a means for

achieving interpersonal comparability of cash income. Both the methods for deriving equivalence

scales and the normative assumptions made by them are subject to considerable debate. While

theoretically justified equivalence scales can be constructed from the cost functions for households

with different demographic characteristics, most empirical analysis typically use more pragmatic

scales adjusting crudely for differences in household size and composition (see e.g. Coulter et. al.

1992). In either case, the equivalence scales designed for cash income are not necessarily appropriate

when analyzing extended income, because the receipt of public services (like education for children

and care for the elderly) are associated with particular needs.3 If we were to use the equivalence scales

designed for cash income on extended income, we risk overestimating the equivalent extended income

for individuals with high needs for public services.

To derive an equivalence scale for extended income, consider a social planner employing the

minimum expenditures identified in the spending model of the local governments as a basis for

assessing the relative needs of different target groups. The justification for this approach is that the

estimated minimum expenditures can be considered as a result of central government regulations,

expert opinion, or a consensus among local governments about how much spending the different target

groups need, given the budget constraint that the municipalities face. Moreover, we assume that the

social planner uses the same functional form for measuring individual well-being produced by public

services as is used by local governments to decide the spending on public services.

However, while the marginal budget share parameters of the utility function (2.1) of the local

governments allow for heterogeneity in spending across sectors as well as across target groups, the

aim of the social planner is to employ a social evaluation framework that treats individuals

symmetrically and independent of where they live after adjusting for relevant non-income

heterogeneity. Thus, we replace the marginal budget share parameters ijβ of the utility function (2.1)

3 For example, the equivalence scales estimated by Jones and O’Donnell (1995) and Zaidi and Burchardt (2005) imply that the disable have relatively high needs, so their cash and non-cash incomes should be correspondingly adjusted when evaluating the distribution of extended income.

Page 11: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

11

with parameters that solely depend on the group- and sector-specific minimum expenditures i ij jzπ γ .

The following specification

(2.10) 0 1

, 0,1,..., , 1,2,..., ,i ij jij s k

i ij ji j

zi s j k

z

π γβ

π γ= =

= = =

appears particular attractive since it captures the needs structure exhibited by the minimum quantity

parameters. Note that sector 0 is added as a composite good that includes consumption financed by the

cash income, where 0 jγ is the minimum quantity of cash income per person for target group j and 0π

represents the price index of private consumption. Next, by inserting (2.10) in (2.1) we get

(2.11) 0 1

logs k

ij ijij

i j ij

xW

γβ

γ= =

−=

,

which will be considered as the evaluation function of the social planner. The cost function of the

social planner is given by

(2.12) 01 02,...,,

0 1 0 11 1

( , , ) min log .sk

s k s ki ij j ij ij

i ij j s kx x xi j i j iji ij ji j

z xC w x z w

z

π γ γπ

γπ γ= = = == =

− = ≥

π z

where ( )1 2 kz ,z ,...,z=z gives the relative distribution of the population on target groups. Thus, from

the social planner’s point of view ( , , )C w π z gives the minimum cost (per capita) to get welfare level

w for a population characterized by k target groups. By solving the minimization problem (2.12) we

find that the cost function C admits the following decomposition

(2.13) ( ) ( )0 1

, , 1s k

wi ij j

i j

C w e zπ γ= =

= + π z .

Let ( , )jC w π be defined by

(2.14) ( ) ( )0

, 1 , 1,2,...,s

wj i ij

i

C w e j kπ γ=

= + =π .

Inserting (2.14) in (2.13) yields the following decomposition of the cost function

(2.15) ( ) ( )1

, , ,k

j jj

C w C w z=

=π z π .

Page 12: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

12

Due to the Stone-Geary structure of the social evaluation function W defined by (2.11), it is

straightforward to prove that ( , )jC w π can be considered as a separate cost function for a member of

target group j. The cost function jC shows how much money the social planner has to spend on each

person in target group j to ensure that the social welfare level w is attained for each member of target

group j ( 1 2j , ,...,k= ). Thus, the associated price-adjusted target group-specific equivalence scale

jNPA is defined by

(2.16) ( )( )

0 0 0

0 0 0

,, 1,2,..,

,

s s s

i ij i ij ijj i i i

j s s sr

ir ij iri i i

C wNPA j k

C w

π γ π γ γ

γ γ γ

= = =

= = =

= = = =

π1

,

where the reference target group r is a single adult below 67 years of age,4 and the (hypothetical)

reference municipality is characterized by a price vector with all prices equal to 1. It follows from

(2.16) that the equivalence scale jNPA is independent of the income levels of the target groups.5 Note

that the jNPA accounts for needs for public services as well as for needs for cash income. Since

0 0

s s

j i ij iji i

π π γ γ= =

= can be interpreted as a target-group-specific price index and 0 0

s s

j ij iri i

NA γ γ= =

=

as an average needs-adjusted equivalence scale, jNPA admits the following convenient decomposition

(2.17) j j jNPA NAπ= .

In the general case the equivalence scale depends on variation in the price level across municipalities.

The reason for this is that residents in high-cost municipalities require higher spending to reach the

same standard of living as residents in low-cost municipalities. To pin down the distributional impact

of allowing for changes in the relative needs of subgroups when we move from cash to extended

income, we assume that prices do not vary across municipalities, which means that j jNPA NA= . To

assess the importance of allowing for variation in production costs, we will allow for differences in

unit costs using the more general jNPA equivalence scale.

Another convenient decomposition property of the equivalence scale defined by (2.16) is given by

4 Moreover, the reference household is assumed not to possess any of the characteristics that trigger additional expenditure needs, such as unemployment, refugee status, divorce or poverty. 5 This structure, called independence of base utility, has previously been discussed by Lewbel (1989) and Blackorby and Donaldson (1993).

Page 13: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

13

(2.18)

0

0

0 0

0

1

1

(1 ) , 1,2,..., ,

,

, 1,2,..., ,

, 1,2,..., ,

j r j r j

rr s

iri

jj

r

s

i ijij s

iri

NPA CI NC j k

CI j k

NC j k

θ θγθ

γπ γγ

π γ

γ

=

=

=

= + − =

=

= =

= =

where jCI is the equivalence scale for cash income, NCj is the scale for non-cash income, and rθ is

the weight that is given to cash income in the combined NPA scale for extended income. While the NC

scale is a function of the minimum expenditures identified in the spending model of local

governments, we will follow the previous literature in using a pragmatic scale for CI . In our main

results, we will apply the much used EU scale for cash income, but as a robustness check we employ

the OECD scale instead. The combined NA scale (and NPA scale) requires assessment of the weight

rθ . The empirical implementation in Section 3.4 discusses two alternative methods for determining

this parameter.

The equivalence scales in equations (2.17) and (2.18) can be defined both on individual and household

level. As there are no clear-cut economies of scale in the consumption of public non-cash income,

such as education and health care, the local public services are treated as private goods in the NC scale

for public services. The NC scale on the household level is computed by summation of individual

scales over all individuals that belong to a given household. The parameter rθ in equation (2.18) does

not differ across individuals or municipalities. Thus, the parameter is not affected by aggregation over

households. Since the EU scale is defined on the household level, it can be weighted together with the

NC scale aggregated to the household level, using the parameter rθ as the weight for cash income. It

follows that economies of scale in consumption are included in the NA scale (and NPA scale) to the

degree that the equivalence scale for cash income (the EU scale) accounts for economies of scale. A

comparison of the EU scale and the estimated NA scales based on data from Norway is given in

Section 4.2.

3. Empirical implementation This section describes the empirical implementation of the methods outlined above using Norwegian

data. We also outline the methods used to evaluate the income distribution. Specifically, Section 3.1

describes the data and some definitional issues. Estimation results of the model for local government

Page 14: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

14

spending are given in Section 3.2. Section 3.3 describes how the value of public services is allocated

to individuals. Section 3.4 defines equivalent income measures that are utilized in the analysis of

income distribution. Inequality measures and poverty thresholds are defined in Section 3.5.

3.1 Data

Population of study. Our analytical sample is based on administrative registers with household,

geographic, and demographic information for the entire resident population of Norway in 2007. Table

3.1 shows the population composition by demographic and geographic characteristics. Roughly four

out of five people live in urban municipalities, including the capital Oslo. Furthermore, nearly three-

quarters of the population live as couples. In addition, immigrants make up almost one-tenth of the

population.

Table 3.1 Population of study

Population group Population share (%)

Single parents 9

Couples with children 49

Couples without children 19

Singles, 44 years or below 7

Singles, 45-66 years 5

Singles, 67 years or above 6

Household type

Other households 5

Urban 70

Oslo 12 Centrality

Rural 18

Non-immigrants 91 Ethnic origin

Immigrants 9

Population size (millions) 4.7

Public services and expenditure. Local government accounts in Norway provide detailed information

on sector-specific expenditure. Table 3.2 summarizes the differences in sector-specific per capita

public spending across the 431 municipalities in Norway in 2007. We see that the largest expenditure

component is care for the elderly and disabled (long-term care), closely followed by primary

education. These two sectors account, on average, for more than half of the total expenditure of

municipalities. We also note that there are considerable differences in per capita public spending

across municipalities in all service sectors.

Page 15: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

15

Table 3.2 Public spending per capita on different services across municipalities

Public spending per capita Service sector

Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum

Administration 569 329 219 2 891

Primary education 1 155 238 756 2 117

Other education 84 49 5 557

Child care 435 100 243 962

Health care 253 127 108 967

Social assistance 72 45 0 284

Child protection 127 54 14 506

Long-term care 1 500 468 633 5 066

Culture 202 142 73 2 101

Infrastructure 225 289 0 3 183

All services 4 396 1 553 2 051 15 451

Note: Numbers are calculated by averaging spending per capita across municipalities for each sector. All numbers are in Euros (exchange rate of 9 NOK per Euro is used).

Table 3.4 shows our classification of local public services into ten different sectors, and the associated

target groups. From the administrative registers, we can compute the population shares of different

target groups in every municipality. We therefore have a one-to-one correspondence between our

population of study and the population shares used in the estimation of the model of local government

spending.

The specification of target groups aims at producing mutually exclusive groups within each

service sector. By not including partially overlapping target groups, we are able to avoid

misleading double-counting of minimum quantities, while at the same time accounting

properly for interaction effects pertaining to population subgroups that share more than one of

the characteristics that are used by local governments to target the public services.

Cash and extended income. Table 3.3 defines our cash income and extended income measure.

We see that the cash income measure includes earnings, self-employment income, capital

income, and public cash transfers, from which direct taxes are subtracted. We use the term

extended income to denote the sum of cash income and the value of in-kind benefits provided

through public services. The data on cash income is based on Tax Assessment Files, which

are collected from tax records and other administrative registers, rather than interviews and

Page 16: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

16

self-reporting methods. The coverage and reliability of Norwegian data on cash income are

considered to be very high, as is documented by the fact that the quality of such national

datasets of income received the highest rating in a data quality survey in the Luxembourg

Income Study database (Atkinson et al., 1995).

Table 3.3 Definition of cash income and extended income

Market income = Employment income (earnings, self-employment income)

+ Capital income (interest, stock dividends, sale of stocks)

Total income = Market income

+ Public cash transfers (e.g. old-age pension, unemployment and disability benefits, child benefits and single parents benefits, social assistance)

Cash income = Total income – direct taxes

Extended income = Cash income + non-cash income

3.2 Estimation results

The estimation of the model defined by (2.5)–(2.7) is based on detailed local government accounts and

community characteristics for Norwegian municipalities in 2007. The model accounts for spending on

the ten service sectors displayed in Table 3.4, and in the estimation we also include the budget surplus

(net operating result) as a sector in the model. The budget surplus is treated as a residual sector, which

means that the model is representing an extended linear expenditure system, see Lluch (1973).

Expenditures are defined exclusive of user fees and employer payroll taxes, and are measured on a per

capita basis in the model specification. We estimate the model simultaneously by the method of

maximum likelihood.

The minimum quantity parameters are displayed in Table 3.4, the unit cost parameters are displayed in

Table 3.5, and Table A.1 in Appendix A presents estimates of the marginal budget share parameters.

Importantly, the parameter estimates are statistically significant and of the expected signs.

Minimum quantity parameters. Consider the parameter estimates reported in Table 3.4, showing the

increase in minimum quantity when the target group is increased by one person. One main finding is

that there is substantial variation in the minimum quantity estimates across target groups. Below we

discuss the identified target groups and associated minimum quantities in each of the ten service

sectors.

Page 17: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

17

Table 3.4 Estimates of minimum quantity parameters

Sector Function Target groups Parameter

estimate T-

stat. R2-adj.

Administration All local administrative services

All residents 251 10.42 0.88

Primary education

Ten years of primary education

Population 6-12 years of age Population 13-15 years of age

5 414 8 694

11.87 9.16

0.79

Other education

After-school education and adult education

Population 6-15 years of age Recently domiciled refugees 20-59 years of age

255

6 202

7.23

7.71 0.36

Child care

Municipal and publicly subsidized kindergartens

Children 1-5 years with full-time employed parents Remaining children 1-5 years of age

10 650

4 405

20.43

13.73 0.60

Health care

All health services provided by general practitioners

All residents 124 11.14 0.75

Social assistance

Social services targeted towards disadvantaged individuals

Poor and unemployed 16-59 years of age Remaining recently domiciled refugees 0-59 years Remaining divorced or separated 16-59 years

17 030 6 493

1 258

5.43 10.40

10.11

0.54

Child protection All services related to child protection

Poor children 0-15 years with lone parent Poor children 0-15 years with couple parents Non-poor children 0-15 years with lone parent Non-poor children 0-15 years with couple parents

3 893 2 048 2 115

163

3.79 3.49 4.64

2.45

0.13

Long-term care

Nursing homes and home care for the elderly and disabled

Population 0-66 years of age Population 67-79 years of age Population 80-89 years of age Population 90 years and above Mentally disabled 16 years and above

347 2 721 5 452

14 655 45 119

4.33 2.70 2.92 2.57

12.05

0.84

Culture

Sports, arts, museums, libraries, cinemas and churches

All residents 91 8.38 0.67

Infrastructure

Water supply, road maintenance, sewage and refuse collection

All residents 22 0.90 0.58

Note: All parameter estimates are in Euros (a fixed exchange rate of 9 NOK per Euro is used). Number of observations = 378.

Page 18: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

18

Consider first primary schools, which are compulsory for children 6–15 years of age. It follows that

service provision increases as a function of the number of children in this age group. We also see that

children aged 6–12 years receive not as much services as children aged 13–15 years. This difference is

due to the fact that the latter group faces more extensive and demanding lessons, which requires

teachers with higher qualifications.

Local governments operate a few other education services that are not included in the sector for

primary education. The service sector “Other education” includes day care facilities for

schoolchildren, music schools, special schools and adult education. Except for adult education, the

relevant group that benefits from “Other education” is the age group 6-15 years. Adult education is

particularly directed toward recently domiciled refugees in the age group 20-59 years. Recently

domiciled refugees include refugees who have resided in Norway less than five years.

Moving on to the child-care sector, we see that the service provision increases in the population share

of children in pre-school age (1-5 years). The target group is divided into children with and without

full-time employed parents. The marginal cost is higher for the group with full-time employed parents,

since these families depend more on professional day-care services, which contributes to higher

demand for and coverage in kindergartens.

Next, consider child protection sector, which includes investigation of alleged child abuse, orphan

homes, foster care, adoption services, and services aimed at supporting at-risk families so they can

remain intact. Children less than 16 years of age are the primary target group for child protection. The

estimation results show that the risk and spending is highest among children that belong to a poor

family with a lone parent. Risk and spending levels are intermediate for children that are poor with

couple parents or non-poor with a lone parent. The lowest spending levels are found among children

that are non-poor with couple parents. Poor families include those with incomes below half of median

income, where incomes are defined by after-tax private incomes exclusive of social assistance cash

transfers. In-kind benefits are not included in the income definition when defining poor families that

are highly prone to receive some of the municipal services.

A large share of spending in the social assistance sector is cash transfers to support families with

insufficient means from other sources of income. The sector also includes some in-kind benefits that

aim to prevent alcohol and drugs abuse and other social problems. The potential recipients are either

poor, unemployed, refugees or divorced/separated, or possess different combinations of those

Page 19: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

19

characteristics. To account for interaction effects between different characteristics, the potential

recipients are divided into mutually exclusive target groups that include all possible combinations of

the above mentioned characteristics. The estimates for each subgroup are used to identify target

groups with high, intermediate and low risk and spending. The resulting target group classification

shows that the poor who are also unemployed is a high-risk group for receiving social assistance. The

second target group that receives intermediate spending per person is recently domiciled refugees. The

third target group that receives a lower, although significant spending level, is the divorced and

separated.

Long-term care includes nursing homes, ambulant nurses and home care. The potential recipients are

the elderly and disabled. Since elderly people have a higher probability of becoming recipients of

long-term care, spending needs are higher for the elderly than for younger people. Subsistence output

is increasing with age, and is highest for the elderly 90 years and above. By contrast, spending needs

per person is much lower in the age group 0-66 years. However, the group of mentally disabled, which

by and large is a subgroup of the age group 0-66 years, is included to account for the additional cost

from being mentally disabled. This additional minimum expenditure is rather high, and is above

45,000 Euros per person in the mentally disabled group.

When it comes to administration, municipal health care, culture, and infrastructure, the target group is

taken to be the whole population. The financing of local public health services is shared with the

central government such that local governments pay for a basic capacity, whilst additional costs due to

utilization and health care needs are financed through the national social security system. Thus the

local government minimum quantity for health care does not vary as a function of socio-demographic

variables. Similarly, for culture, administration and infrastructure, we have not identified any

characteristic that yields variation in minimum quantities. Thus, the estimated minimum quantity is a

constant, which means that the entire population is treated as the relevant target group.

Unit cost parameters. Consider the estimated parameters for variables that affect unit costs, displayed

in Table 3.5. These parameters form the basis for the price-adjusted equivalence scales in equation

(2.16) and the construction of price indices in equation (2.6). We see that there is significant variation

in unit costs in three of the service sectors: administration, primary education and health care.

Page 20: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

20

Table 3.5 Estimates of unit cost parameters

Administration Primary education Health care

Inverse population size 1.48 (8.77) 0.26 (8.25) 1.19 (6.53)

Distance to municipal sub-district center - - 0.16 (8.55) 0.28 (4.97)

Note: T-statistics are in parentheses. Number of observations = 378.

The estimated unit costs in these three service sectors are decreasing as a function of population size.

The chosen functional form is the inverse population size, which captures that the decreasing function

is convex and close to zero when population is sufficiently large. The positive impact of inverse

population size on unit costs may originate from fixed costs in the operation of local governments.

Significant parameter estimates for inverse population size are taken as proof of economies of scale.

An important reason for smaller municipalities to have higher unit costs is that they use a larger share

of resources on administration. Furthermore, class sizes are in general smaller in smaller

municipalities, implying more teachers per student and therefore higher costs. Similarly, to maintain a

basic capacity of primary physicians in smaller municipalities the physician-patient ratio becomes

relatively large, which increases the unit cost.

We also find that greater dispersion of the local settlement pattern increases unit costs in education and

health care. The estimated positive relationships are interpreted as reflecting costs of providing

services on a decentralized level. For example, when it comes to primary education, municipalities

with a high dispersion of settlement tend to supply a decentralized school structure with relatively few

students per school and rather small class sizes. The aim is to provide a school structure that does not

impose unreasonable travelling distances on the school children. Similarly, patients in primary health

care are also entitled to have a physician within reasonable travelling distance. The costs to maintain

such services are therefore higher in sparsely populated areas. To capture dispersion of settlement in

the municipality, we use an explanatory variable defined as the average distance to the centre of the

municipal sub-district. Note that the distance variable has no significant effect in the administration

sector.

The price indices defined in equation (2.6) reflect the relative differences across municipalities in unit

costs for providing different services. Summary statistics for the estimated price indices are reported in

Table 3.6. Note that the mean values are above 1 because municipalities with different population

sizes are given equal weights, which means that weights per capita are higher in smaller

municipalities. Small municipalities are found to encounter high unit costs due to economies of scale

Page 21: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

21

and dispersed settlement. Moreover, we find large variation across municipalities in unit costs,

particularly in administration and health care.

Table 3.6 Variation in unit costs across municipalities

Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum

Administration 1.41 0.64 0.87 7.85

Primary education 1.13 0.17 0.94 2.52

Health care 1.43 0.58 0.83 6.37

Note: Number of observations = 431.

3.3 Allocating local public services

In line with the allocation rule in equation (2.9), we use the above estimates to allocate the values of

local public services to individuals. We assume that people who live in the same municipality and

belong to the same target group, receive equal non-cash income. Specifically, the in-kind transfer from

sector i received by each member of group j is then given by the estimate of iju , which may vary

across municipalities. Thus, variation in allocated in-kind benefits across people is partly due to

differences in individual characteristics that trigger expenditure needs. In addition, there is variation in

local government spending across service sectors, as well as in spending priorities on different target

groups.

The target groups that are treated as recipients in the analysis may deviate from the group of actual

recipients. There are two reasons for this. First, we usually do not observe the group of actual

recipients. Hence, the identified target groups serve to approximate groups of actual recipients.

Although the simulated recipients are not necessarily the same as the actual recipients, a good

approximation of the underlying distributional profiles of public services should be obtained, provided

that the relevant characteristics of recipients are taken into account.6 Second, in line with Smeeding et

al. (1993), the services child protection, social assistance, health care, and long-term care are viewed

as insurance benefits received by everyone covered by the insurance scheme, regardless of actual use.

The received expenditure of such services is interpreted as expected non-cash income, which depends

on the risk of becoming a recipient. Risk factors are accounted for by the characteristics of target

groups that are assumed to receive the different services.

6 In the child care sector we also utilize additional information about coverage in kindergartens on the municipal level. Estimated recipient probabilities in different target groups are used to draw the correct number of recipients for each municipality. Local public expenditure on child care is allocated equally to the simulated recipients.

Page 22: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

22

3.4 Equivalent income definitions

When analyzing poverty and inequality among households of varying size and composition, it is

necessary to adjust the measure of income to enable comparison across individuals. As discussed

above, interpersonal comparison of income is typically achieved by using equivalence scales. We

consider four different definitions of equivalent income, depending on whether we consider cash or

extended income and how we adjust for differences in needs for non-cash income. The different

definitions of equivalent income are displayed in Table 3.7.

Table 3.7 Alternative definitions of equivalent income

Equivalent income Income measure Equivalence scale

Cash income (EU) Cash income EU scale

Extended income (EU) Extended income EU scale

Extended income (NA) Extended income Needs-adjusted EU scale

Extended income (NPA) Extended income Needs- and price-adjusted EU scale

Following the previous literature in inequality and poverty closely, we use the EU scale to adjust for

differences in cash income needs. This yields the measure of equivalent cash income, which typically

forms the basis for studies of poverty and inequality. To obtain the measure of extended income, we

add non-cash income to cash income. In line with previous studies, we use the same scale to adjust for

needs for extended income as is used to adjust cash income. Consequently, extended income is

adjusted by the EU scale. Thus, the first step is to change the income measure without changing the

equivalence scale. The second step is to change the equivalence scale for extended income by taking

into account the needs for public services of different target groups. Needs-adjusted extended

equivalent income is derived by using the NA scale from Section 2.3 to adjust for differences in needs.

The NA scale is a weighted average of the EU scale for cash income and the NC scale for non-cash

income. The NA scale assumes that the sector-specific price indices are constant across municipalities,

which is a special case of the NPA scale defined in equation (2.19). Thus, the third step is to introduce

price adjustment in the equivalence scale, so the needs adjustment is based on the NPA scale, which

yields needs- and price-adjusted extended equivalent income.

In order to empirically implement the NA and NPA scales, it is necessary to assign a value to the

weight rθ given to cash income, defined in equation (2.19). In particular, we set the minimum

quantity of cash income for the reference group, 0rγ , equal to the minimum pension entitlement for a

single person in the social security system. By doing so, we are assuming that the minimum pension

Page 23: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

23

for single pensioners equals the minimum quantity of cash income required for single adults below 67

years of age, i.e. the reference group used in the NA and NPA scales. We then estimate that rθ should

be 0.95. As a robustness check, we have set 0rγ equal to the EU poverty threshold derived from the

equivalent cash income in the entire population. As the poverty threshold nearly equals the minimum

pension entitlement for singles, our estimates of rθ barely move. Therefore, we only report the results

where the minimum pension is used to determine rθ .

3.5 Measuring inequality and poverty

Inequality measures. To summarize the informational content of the Lorenz curve and to achieve

rankings of intersecting Lorenz curves, the conventional approach is to employ the Gini-coefficient.

To examine the extent to which the empirical results depend on the choice of inequality measure, the

Gini-coefficient is typically complemented with measures from the Atkinson or Theil family.

However, the Gini-coefficient and inequality measures from the Atkinson or the Theil family have

distinct theoretical foundations which make it inherently difficult to evaluate their capacities as

complimentary measures of inequality. As demonstrated by Aaberge (2007), an alternative approach

for examining inequality in the distribution of income is to rely on Gini’s Nuclear Family defined by

(3.1) ( )1

2

0

( ) ( ) , 1,2,3kkC F k u u L u du k−= − =

where C1 is equivalent to a measure of inequality that was proposed by Bonferroni (1930), whilst C2 is

the Gini coefficient. As demonstrated by Aaberge (2000, 2007) C1 exhibits strong downside inequality

aversion and is particularly sensitive to changes that concern the poor part of the population, whilst C2

normally pays more attention to changes that take place in the middle part of the income distribution.

The C3-coefficient exhibits upside inequality aversion and is thus particularly sensitive to changes that

occur in the upper part of the income distribution. In this paper, we will examine the sensitivity of the

empirical results to the choice of inequality measure by complementing the information provided by

C2 with its two close relatives C1 and C3. Hence, we meet the most common criticism of the Gini-

coefficient, namely that it is insensitive to redistribution of income at the lower end of the distribution.

Poverty thresholds. We follow common practice in most developed countries and specify a set of

poverty thresholds as a certain fraction of the median income. Specifically, we will focus on a set of

poverty thresholds defined as 60 per cent of the median of the chosen measure of income. Recognizing

the inherent arbitrariness of specifying an exact poverty threshold, it can be instructive to apply other

Page 24: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

24

thresholds to evaluate the robustness of the results. Moreover, by applying multiple thresholds one can

obtain a fuller picture of the problem of poverty in a society. Thus we will supplement the analysis

with poverty thresholds defined as 50 percent of the median of the chosen measure of income.7

4. Distributional impact of public services This section examines the impact on inequality and poverty estimates of accounting for non-cash

income from local public services, and, moreover, adjusting for differences in needs for such services

across individuals.

4.1 Main results

Overall inequality and poverty. Table 4.1 reports the income shares by decile for each measure of

equivalent income outlined in Table 3.7. As the distribution of income may vary substantially within

each decile group, we need to be cautious in drawing firm conclusions from Table 4.1 about the

distributional impact of public services. With this caveat in mind, the second column indicates that

local public spending is quite redistributive, given the cash income shares reported in the first column.

We find that the income shares increase in lower decile groups and decrease in higher decile groups

when non-cash income is added to cash income. However, the third column suggests that substituting

the EU-scale with the NA-scale in the needs-adjustment of extended income offsets some of the

redistributional impact of public services. The final column shows that price-adjustment appear to

have little impact on how needs-adjusted extended equivalent income is distributed across the decile

groups.

To investigate further the distributional impact of public services, the upper panel of Table 4.2

employs the inequality measures outlined above. When comparing the first and the second column, we

see that including non-cash income reduces inequality by about 15 percent. This suggests that public

services are targeted toward individuals with relatively low cash income. However, as is clear from the

third column, using our method to adjust for differences in needs offset about two-third of the

inequality reduction stemming from the inclusion of non-cash income. Hence, the method used to

make needs adjustment appears to be fairly important when drawing lessons about the redistributive

nature of public services. Finally, column five demonstrates that allowing for variation across

municipalities in unit costs for producing public services has little impact on inequality.

7 Following official poverty statistics in Norway and several other developed countries, students and wealthy individuals are

not counted as poor. Because we lack credible data on wealth, an individual is classified as wealthy if he or she is registered with equivalent gross financial capital greater than three times the median equivalent cash income.

Page 25: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

25

Table 4.1 Income shares by deciles for different income measures

Income share by decile (%)

Cash income Extended income Decile

EU EU NA NPA

1st 3.7 4.4 4.1 4.1

2nd 6.0 6.7 6.3 6.3

3rd 7.1 7.7 7.2 7.2

4th 8.0 8.5 8.0 8.0

5th 8.8 9.2 8.8 8.8

6th 9.6 9.8 9.6 9.6

7th 10.5 10.5 10.5 10.5

8th 11.6 11.4 11.6 11.6

9th 13.3 12.7 13.3 13.3

10th 21.2 19.2 20.5 20.6

Overall mean 32 317 38 308 31 136 31 146

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted EU scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted EU scale. Income is reported in Euros (exchange rate of 9 NOK per Euro is used).

Table 4.2 Inequality and poverty by income measure

Inequality Relative reduction in inequality (%)

Cash income Extended income Extended income Indicator

EU EU NA NPA EU NA NPA

Bonferroni )( 1C 0.358 0.308 0.338 0.339 14.0 5.6 5.3

Gini )( 2C 0.246 0.206 0.233 0.234 16.3 5.3 4.9

3C 0.199 0.165 0.189 0.190 17.1 5.0 4.5

Poverty incidence (%) Relative reduction in poverty (%)

Cash income Extended income Extended income Threshold (% of median)

EU EU NA NPA EU NA NPA

50 5.1 3.4 4.2 4.2 33.3 17.6 17.6

60 9.5 6.9 7.2 7.1 27.4 24.2 25.3

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted EU scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted EU scale. The three inequality measures are calculated for each of the four equivalent income distributions. Poverty thresholds are calculated on the basis of median in each of the four income distributions. For each income measure, the relative reduction in inequality/poverty is given as the per cent decrease compared to inequality/poverty when cash income is used.

When comparing rows 1-3, we see that the findings are fairly robust to the choice of inequality

measure. Interestingly, the inequality measure that is most sensitive to changes in the lower part of the

distribution, C1, records the smallest (percentage) reduction when applying the EU scale to extended

Page 26: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

26

income. However, the picture is reversed when using the NA or the NPA scale, in which case C1

records the largest (percentage) decrease in inequality. This illustrates that redistribution of extended

income at the lower end of the distribution plays a more important role when using our method to

adjust for differences in needs.

The lower panel of Table 4.2 shows the share of the population with income below the poverty line

according to the different definitions of income. We see that poverty rates are reduced by almost one-

third, when we consider extended income instead of the conventional cash income measure. However,

using our method to adjust for differences in needs offsets some of the poverty reduction, in particular

when the relatively low poverty threshold of 50 percent of the median is used. This indicates that there

is a concentration of individuals with low cash income who have relatively high needs for public

services, which is ignored when one uses the EU scale to adjust extended income. Just as for the

inequality estimates, allowing for variation across municipalities in unit costs for producing public

services has little impact on poverty incidence.

Poverty profile. Below, we investigate the impact of public services on the poverty profile. For

brevity, we only report results using a poverty threshold of 60 percent of the median.

Table 4.3 shows the effect of accounting for local public services on poverty rates by household type.

When focusing on cash income, the poverty rates are rather high among elderly (mostly female) living

in single person households, due to the fact that the poverty thresholds exceed the guaranteed

minimum pension. However, as elderly people receive a high level of publicly provided care and

health services, their poverty rates drop radically when we focus on extended income. The same is true

for households with children, especially single parents, since they are major recipients of services such

as education and child care. For these subgroups, however, the poverty rates rise again when we use

our method to adjust for differences in needs. Due to the age structure and the relatively high fertility

rate of Non-Western immigrants, their poverty rates also decline considerably when non-cash income

are taken into account. The relatively high levels of non-cash income also reflect higher needs for

public services, as their poverty rates rise again when we make needs adjustment according to the NA

scale. The groups that receive the least non-cash income are singles and couples without children in

the pre-retirement phase. The poverty rates for these households therefore increase when we consider

extended income. However, their poverty rates fall when we use our method to adjust for needs. This

finding comes as no surprise, as these households have no children who need child care or education,

and their need for publicly provided long-term care is small.

Page 27: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

27

Table 4.3 also shows poverty incidence by centrality. The results show that incorporating public

services into the income measure reduces the poverty rates in rural areas relative to urban areas and,

especially, compared to Oslo. When we use our method to adjust for differences in needs, a similar

pattern appears: While the poverty rate in rural areas is unchanged, we see that poverty rates rise again

in urban areas (especially Oslo). This indicates that public transfers targeted towards individuals living

in urban areas often reflect higher needs.

Table 4.3 Poverty profile in different population groups by income measure

Poverty incidence

Cash income Extended income Population group Population

share EU EU NA NPA

29 years or below 3.3 21.4 26.6 18.9 18.8

30-44 years 3.9 15.8 21.6 13.5 13.5

45-66 years 5.0 18.2 27.6 12.4 12.4 Singles

67 years or above 5.7 45.8 27.7 27.2 27.2

29 years or below 1.3 4.4 5.9 4.1 4.1

30-44 years 1.9 3.7 4.7 3.5 3.5

45-66 years 8.6 2.8 4.6 2.0 2.0

Couples (without

children) 67 years or above 7.0 9.1 5.3 5.0 5.0

0-5 years 18.8 6.9 1.8 6.7 6.7

6-17 years 21.7 2.9 0.9 2.5 2.5 Couples (with children) 18 years or above 8.7 1.4 1.8 1.1 1.1

0-5 years 1.8 29.2 5.3 24.3 24.1

6-17 years 4.8 12.3 2.6 9.2 9.1 Single parents

18 years or above 2.5 6.8 8.4 5.7 5.7

Other households 5.0 6.2 4.2 5.5 5.5

Non-immigrants 91.1 8.0 6.2 5.6 5.6

Immigrants 8.9 24.9 14.2 23.1 22.9

Western 2.3 16.6 15.1 14.5 14,4 Ethnic origin

Non-Western 6.6 27.8 13.9 26.1 25,7

Urban 81.7 9.4 7.1 7.4 7.3

Oslo 11.7 13.1 9.3 10.6 10.5 Centrality

Rural 18.3 10.1 6.4 6.4 6.7

All population 100 9.5 6.9 7.2 7.1

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted EU scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted EU scale. Poverty thresholds are calculated as 60 percent of the median in each of the four income distributions.

Page 28: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

28

Figure 4.1 Changes in poverty status for alternative income measures

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted EU scale. Poverty thresholds are calculated as 60 percent of the median in each of the three income distributions.

Figure 4.1 demonstrates the degree of overlap in individuals’ poverty status when changing the

measure of equivalent income. We immediately see that accounting for the value of non-cash income

and the method used to adjust for differences in needs not only change the poverty rate, but also which

individuals that are classified as poor. Specifically, only 4.2 percentage points are poor according to all

three income measures. The overlap in poverty status is largest between cash income and the extended

income measure using our method for needs adjustment.

4.2 Sensitivity analysis

Balanced budget. In the analysis above, we have followed standard practice in empirical analysis of

the distributional impact of public services in disregarding that the cost of their provision may differ

from the direct taxes levied on individuals and households.8 In principle, if we include the value of

public services we should also take into account the associated cost borne by the individuals. A

possible concern is, therefore, that the direct taxes and the public expenditure on cash benefits and

public services may not balance out at the aggregate level. Table 4.4 displays the aggregated direct

taxes and public expenditure on cash benefits and public services in the ten service sector under study.

We see that direct taxes fall short of covering public expenditure, producing a deficit of about 8.7

million Euros.

8 A notable exception is Garfinkel et al. (2006), who try to balance the expenditure on public services and the tax revenues.

Page 29: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

29

Table 4.4 Aggregate direct taxes and expenditure on cash benefits and public services

Budget component Euros (in million)

Direct taxes 33 551

– Cash benefits 28 743

– Expenditure on public services 13 549

= Surplus - 8 741

In practice, it is difficult to assess whether an analysis of the distributional impact of public services

can be given a balanced budget interpretation. This is primarily because the revenue and expenditure

side of government budgets are detached, in the sense that particular components of expenditure are

not tied to particular sources of revenue. Thus, it is not clear which type of expenditure is financed by

which type of revenue. Moreover, the statutory burden of a tax does not necessarily describe who

actually bears the burden of it. For example, Gruber (2005) argues that empirical evidence generally

suggests that income taxes are borne by the households that pay them, payroll taxes are borne by

workers regardless of statutory incidence, indirect taxes are shifted towards prices, and corporate taxes

are in part shifted forward to the owners of capital but also borne by consumers and workers.

On the one hand, a balanced budget interpretation of the results reported in Tables 4.1-4.3 may be

justified if the economic burden of the deficit is already reflected in individuals’ observed cash

income. In that case, the above analysis takes into account both the value of public services and the

associated cost born by the individuals. This could be the case if employers’ payroll taxes finance the

deficit, and workers bear the burden of such payroll taxes through lower wages. Alternatively, the

deficit may be financed by corporate taxes, which could be fully shifted towards individuals’ returns

from capital income. In addition, a balanced budget interpretation can be rationalized if someone

besides the individuals finances the deficit, like the large Norwegian petroleum fund.

On the other hand, a balanced budget interpretation of the results reported in Tables 4.1-4.3 is

problematic if the deficit was, in fact, financed by indirect taxes on private goods. In that case, the

above analysis includes the value of public service, but not fully the associated cost born by the

individuals. As robustness check, we therefore assume that the deficit is fully born by individuals

through value-added taxes (VAT) on private goods. In Norway, VAT on private goods is generally

about 25 %, generating as much as 21 million Euros in public revenues in 2007. Mirroring the

proportional nature of VAT, it is necessary to deduct 8 percent from the cash income of each

individual to finance the deficit of 8.7 million Euros. Table 4.5 reports the inequality and poverty

results after deducing a proportional tax of 8 percent from individuals’ cash income. Since our poverty

Page 30: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

30

and inequality measures are scale invariant with respect to the chosen income measure, we know a

priori that the estimates based on cash income are unaffected. However, this argument does not hold

true when extended income forms the basis for the analysis, since it is the sum of cash and non-cash

income. It is, therefore, reassuring to find that the poverty and inequality estimates based on extended

income barely move when the proportional tax on individual cash income is introduced. Thus, the

results are robust to alternative assumptions about how public spending is financed.

Table 4.5 Inequality and poverty by income measure, assuming that value-added taxes finance the deficit

Inequality Relative reduction in inequality (%)

Cash income Extended income Extended income Indicator

EU EU NA NPA EU NA NPA

Bonferroni )( 1C 0.358 0.306 0.333 0.333 14.5 7.0 7.0

Gini )( 2C 0.246 0.205 0.229 0.230 16.7 6.9 6.5

3C 0.199 0.164 0.186 0.186 17.6 6.5 6.5

Poverty incidence (%) Relative reduction in poverty (%)

Cash income Extended income Extended income Threshold (% of median)

EU EU NA NPA EU NA NPA

50 5.0 3.4 4.0 4.0 33.3 20.6 21.0

60 9.5 6.9 6.8 6.8 26.9 28.0 28.3

Note: All individuals are deducted 8 percent of their cash income. NA: Needs-adjusted EU scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted EU scale. The three inequality measures are calculated for each of the four equivalent income distributions. Poverty thresholds are calculated on the basis of median in each of the four income distributions. For each income measure, the relative reduction in inequality/poverty is given as the percent decrease compared to inequality/poverty when cash income is used.

Equivalence scale for cash income. Below, we discuss the results from a sensitivity analysis showing

that our main findings about the distributional impact of public services are robust to the choice

between two of the most used equivalence scales for cash income. While the results based on the EU

scale are reported in Tables 4.1-4.3, Appendix B displays the findings based on the OECD scale.

As shown in Table 4.6, the OECD scale gives the first adult the weight 1, with each additional adult

given the weight 0.7 and each child the weight 0.5. Thus, the OECD scale places lower weight on

economies of scale in consumption when considering household cash income compared to what the

EU scale does. This implies that individuals from smaller households (singles or couples without

children) would be evaluated as relatively better off when we use the OECD scale.

Page 31: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

31

Table 4.6 Needs-adjusted EU and OECD scales by household size and age composition

EU-scale OECD-scale

Unadjusted Needs adjusted Unadjusted Needs adjusted No. of adults/ children

Age, years

1 adult 2 adults 1 adult 2 adults 1 adult 2 adults 1 adult 2 adults

17-29 1 1.5 1 1.5 1 1.7 1 1.7

30-44 1 1.5 1 1.5 1 1.7 1 1.7

45-66 1 1.5 1 1.6 1 1.7 1 1.8

67-79 1 1.5 1.1 1.9 1 1.7 1.1 2.0

80-89 1 1.5 1.3 2.2 1 1.7 1.3 2.4

No children

90- 1 1.5 1.8 3.1 1 1.7 1.8 3.3

0-5 1.3 1.8 1.5 2.0 1.5 2.2 1.6 2.4

6-12 1.3 1.8 1.7 2.2 1.5 2.2 1.9 2.6 1 child

13-16 1.3 1.8 1.9 2.4 1.5 2.2 2.1 2.8

0-5 1.6 2.1 2.1 2.6 2 2.7 2.4 3.1 2 children

6-12 1.6 2.1 2.5 3.0 2 2.7 2.8 3.6

0-5 1.9 2.4 2.7 3.3 2.5 3.2 3.3 4.0 3 children

6-12 1.9 2.4 3.1 3.8 2.5 3.2 3.8 4.5

Note: The EU scale with needs adjustment is a weighted average of the unadjusted EU scale and a needs scale for non-cash income (both defined on a household level). Similarly, the OECD scale with needs adjustment is a weighted average of the unadjusted OECD scale and a needs scale for non-cash income. The needs adjusted EU/OECD scales take account of both differences in household size and differences in needs for public services across households. In Table 4.6, households are categorized according to household size and age group of the youngest member in the household (for households without children, this corresponds to the youngest adult). Table 4.6 presents averages of the estimated needs adjusted EU/OECD scales for different households.

The choice between OECD and EU scale for cash income also matters for the NA scale, defined in

equation (2.17), since it is a weighted average of the chosen scale for cash income and the NC scale

for public services. Table 4.6 provides a comparison of the NA scales for the two choices of

equivalence scales for cash income. Compared to both the EU and OECD scale, we see that the NA

scales are relatively high for the elderly and households with two or more children, capturing that the

needs for public services are particularly high in these groups. Moreover, the differences between the

two NA scales mirror the differences between the OECD and the EU scales.

As demonstrated in Tables 4.2 and B.2, the choice between the EU and the OECD scale affects the

level of poverty. Because the OECD scale assigns less weight to economies of scale within

households, the relative high incidence of low income among the smaller households implies higher

overall poverty when using the EU scale instead of the OECD scale. It is also evident that the

Page 32: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

32

inequality estimates are slightly higher when we use the EU scale. But more importantly, we see that

our main conclusions about the distributional impact of public services are robust to whether we let the

EU or the OECD scale form the basis of the analysis. Including non-cash income reduce income

inequality by around 15-20 percent and poverty rates by more than one-third, irrespective of whether

we use the EU or the OECD scale. Moreover, adjusting for differences in needs for public services

across population subgroups offsets much of the inequality reduction and some of the poverty

decrease. However, Tables 4.3 and B.3 reveal that the impact of public services on the poverty profile

differs somewhat depending on the scale used for some household groups. This mostly pertains to the

poverty rates of singles and couples without children below 67 years of age.

5. Conclusion As emphasized by Atkinson et al. (2002, p 103): “As the level and distribution of individual services

does affect comparisons across households and across countries where the extent of state provision

differs, social transfers in kind should in principle be included in the definition of income”. Most

empirical studies of inequality and poverty, however, focus exclusively on cash income and omit the

value of public services, which is worrisome given that about half of welfare state transfers in

developed countries are in-kind (Garfinkel et al., 2006).

Over the last few decades, a number of studies have addressed this issue, investigating the impact on

poverty and inequality estimates of extending the income measure with non-cash income from public

services. While these studies represent a significant step forward, a concern is that they use

equivalence scales designed to account for economies of scale and differences in needs for cash

income, which are not necessarily appropriate when analyzing extended income. For instance, the

elderly tend to utilize health services more often than younger people due to different health status,

and children have a genuine need for education. Hence, the economic resources of groups with high

needs for public services might be overestimated.

A contribution of our paper is to relax the assumption that the relative needs of different subgroups

remain unchanged when the definition of income is extended to include non-cash income. We also

departure from previous studies in that the valuation of public services, identification of target groups,

allocation of expenditures to target groups, and adjustment for differences in needs are all derived

from the same model of local government spending behaviour. This theory-based framework provides

a coherent method for evaluating the distributional impact of public services. In particular, our

approach ensures internal consistency between the methods used for allocation and needs-adjustment.

Page 33: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

33

Combining administrative registers and municipal accounting data from Norway, we apply the

proposed method to examine empirically the distributional impact of public services. The main

insights from the empirical analysis may be summarized in four conclusions. First, including non-cash

income reduces income inequality by about 15 percent and poverty rates by almost one-third. Second,

adjusting for differences in needs for public services across population subgroups offsets about half of

the inequality reduction and some of the poverty decrease. Third, accounting for the value of non-cash

income and adjusting for differences in needs for public services not only change the poverty rate, but

also the type of individuals that are classified as poor. And fourth, allowing for differences between

municipalities in unit costs for providing public services does not change the picture of inequality and

poverty.

Whether these findings extend to other countries is an open question. However, the proposed

framework for evaluating the distributional impact of public services might be employed also in at

least some other countries, since it does not require information about spending on individual level or

on specific target groups. All that is required is detailed knowledge about institutional features of the

public service provision in the country of study, information on sector-specific expenditure by region,

as well as sufficiently rich micro data, like censuses, to compute the socio-economic characteristics of

the population in the various regions and to perform the distributional analysis.

Page 34: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

34

References Aaberge, R. (2000): ‘Characterizations of Lorenz curves and income distributions’, Social Choice and Welfare, 17, 639-653

Aaberge, R. (2007): ‘Gini’s nuclear family’, Journal of Economic Inequality, 5, 305-322

Aaberge, R., and A. Langørgen (2003): ‘Fiscal and Spending Behavior of Local Governments: Identification of Price Effects When Prices are Not Observed’, Public Choice, 117, 125–61

Aaberge, R., and A. Langørgen (2006): ‘Measuring the Benefits from Public Services: The Effects of Local Government Spending on the Distribution of Income in Norway’, Review of Income and Wealth, 52, 61–83

Antoninis, M. and Tsakloglou, P. (2001): Who benefits from public education in Greece? Evidence and policy implications. Education Economics 9, 197-222.

Atkinson, A., L. Rainwater and T. Smeeding (1995): Income Distribution in OECD Countries: Evidence from the Luxembourg Income Study, Paris, OECD

Atkinson, A., B. Cantillon, E. Marlier and B. Nolan (2002): Social Indicators: The EU and Social Inclusion, Oxford University Press, Oxford

Blackorby, C. and D. Donaldson (1993): ‘Adult-equivalence scales and the economic implementation of interpersonal comparisons of well-being’, Social Choice and Welfare, 10, 335-361

Bonferroni, C. (1930): Elementi di Statistica Generale. Firenze: Seeber

Coulter, F., F. Cowell, and S. Jenkins (1992): ‘Equivalence Scale Relativities and the Extent of Inequality and Poverty’, Economic Journal, 102, 1067-82

Evandrou, M., J. Falkingham, J. Hills and J. Le Grand (1993): Welfare Benefits In Kind and Income Distribution, Fiscal Studies, 14, 57-76.

Expert Group on Household Income Statistics (2001): Final Report and Recommendations, Ottawa, Canada

Garfinkel, I., L. Rainwater and T. Smeeding (2006): ‘A Re-examination of Welfare States and Inequality in Rich Nations: How In-Kind Transfers and Indirect Taxes Change the Story’, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 25, 897–919

Gemmell, Norman (1985): ‘The Incidence of Government Expenditure and Redistribution in the United Kingdom,’ Economica, 52, 335–44

Gruber, J. (2005): Public Finance and Public Policy, New York: Worth Publishers

Jones, A. and O. O’Donnell (1995): ‘Equivalence Scales and the Costs of Disability’, Journal of Public Economics, 56, 273-289

Lewbel, A. (1989): ‘Household Equivalence Scales and Welfare Comparisons’, Journal of Public Economics, 39, 377-391

Lluch, C. (1973): ‘The extended linear expenditure system’, European Economic Review, 4, 21-32

Radner, D. (1997): ‘Noncash Income, Equivalence Scales, and the Measurement of Economic Well-Being’, Review of Income and Wealth, 43, 71-88

Ruggeri, G., D. Van Wart and R. Howard (1994): ‘The Redistributional Impact of Government Spending in Canada’, Public Finance, 49, 212–43

Ruggles, P., and M. O’Higgins (1981): ‘The Distribution of Public Expenditure among Households in the U.S.’, Review of Income and Wealth, 27, 137–64

Page 35: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

35

Smeeding, T. (1977): ‘The Antipoverty Effectiveness of In-Kind Transfers’, Journal of Human Resources, 12, 360-378

Smeeding, T. M., P. Saunders, J. Coder, S. Jenkins, J. Fritzell, A.J.M. Hagenaars, R. Hauser and M. Wolfson (1993): ‘Poverty, Inequality, and Family Living Standards Impacts across Seven Nations: The Effect of Noncash Subsidies for Health, Education and Housing’, Review of Income and Wealth, 39, 229-256

Slesnick, D. (1996): ‘Consumption and Poverty: How Effective are In-Kind Transfers?’, Economic Journal, 106, 1527-1545

Zaidi, A. and T. Burchardt (2005): ‘Comparing Incomes when Needs Differ: Equivalization for the Extra Costs of Disability in the U.K.’, Review of Income and Wealth, 51, 89-114

Page 36: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

36

Appendix A

Estimation of marginal budget share parameters Table A.1 Estimates of marginal budget share parameters

Variable Service sector:

Administration Primary

education Other

education Child care Health care

Constant 0.226 (8.53)

0.091 (2.55)

-0.007 (-0.76)

-0.005 (-0.26)

0.046 (2.24)

Average education level for persons 30-59 years

-0.035 (-3.66)

0.002 (0.18)

0.009 (2.68)

0.018 (2.92)

-0.003 (-0.38)

Share of socialists in municipal council

0.009 (0.53)

0.002 (0.08)

0.008 (1.07)

-0.021 (-1.52)

0.014 (1.18)

Share of population in densely populated areas

0.001 (0.12)

0.021 (1.46)

0.000 (-0.06)

0.005 (0.56)

0.017 (2.48)

Variable Service sector:

Social assistance

Child protection Long-term

care Culture Infrastructure

Constant -0.018 (-1.50)

-0.017 (-1.42)

0.329 (5.52)

0.027 (1.63)

0.140 (4.00)

Average education level for persons 30-59 years

0.008 (1.62)

0.009 (1.77)

-0.043 (-1.89)

0.018 (3.21)

-0.005 (-0.43)

Share of socialists in municipal council

0.016 (1.79)

0.012 (1.29)

-0.015 (-0.37)

-0.025 (-2.42)

0.064 (2.64)

Share of population in densely populated areas

0.005 (0.87)

0.002 (0.27)

0.025 (1.15)

0.011 (1.40)

-0.073 (-4.13)

Note: T-statistics are in parentheses. Number of observations = 378.

Table A.1 displays the estimated coefficients of the marginal budget shares as specified in equation

(2.7). The parameters in Table A.1 are estimated simultaneously with the parameters in Tables 3.3 and

3.4 by the method of maximum likelihood. Note that marginal budget share coefficients for the

residual sector, net operating result, can be derived from the coefficients in Table A.1, and from the

constraints which secure that the sum of marginal budget shares over all sectors is equal to 1. It is

found that the marginal budget shares are affected by education level, share of socialist representatives

in the municipal council and population density. The higher the education level, the stronger are the

local government preferences for child care services, other education and culture, while the priority of

administration is low in well educated communities. It is found that socialist parties give high priority

to infrastructure and low priority to culture and net operating result. Municipalities with high

population density give high priority to health care and low priority to infrastructure.

Page 37: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

37

Appendix B

Results based on the OECD scale Table B.1 Income shares by deciles for different income measures, OECD-scale

Income share by decile (%)

Cash income Extended income Decile

OECD OECD NA NPA

1st 3.8 4.8 4.3 4.3

2nd 6.2 7.0 6.5 6.5

3rd 7.1 7.8 7.3 7.3

4th 7.9 8.4 8.0 8.0

5th 8.7 9.0 8.7 8.7

6th 9.5 9.7 9.5 9.5

7th 10.4 10.3 10.4 10.4

8th 11.6 11.2 11.5 11.6

9th 13.4 12.5 13.2 13.3

10th 21.4 19.2 20.6 20.6

Overall mean 27 202 32 072 27 310 27 318

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted OECD scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted OECD scale. Income is reported in Euros (exchange rate of 9 NOK per Euro is used).

Table B.2 Inequality and poverty by income measures, OECD-scale

Inequality Relative reduction in inequality (%)

Cash income Extended income Extended income Indicator

OECD OECD NA NPA OECD NA NPA

Bonferroni )( 1C 0.356 0.291 0.331 0.332 18.3 7.0 6.7

Gini )( 2C 0.246 0.197 0.230 0.231 19.9 6.5 6.1

3C 0.200 0.160 0.187 0.188 20.0 6.5 6.0

Poverty incidence (%) Relative reduction in poverty (%)

Cash income Extended income Extended income Threshold (% of median)

OECD OECD NA NPA OECD NA NPA

40 2.6 1.6 2.5 2.5 38.5 3.8 3.8

50 4.3 2.4 3.9 3.9 44.2 9.3 9.3

60 7.9 4.3 5.8 5.8 45.6 26.6 26.6

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted OECD scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted OECD scale. The three inequality measures are calculated for each of the four equivalent income distributions. Poverty thresholds are calculated on the basis of median in each of the four equivalent income distributions. For each income measure, the relative reduction in inequality/poverty is given as the per cent decrease compared to inequality/poverty when cash income is used.

Page 38: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

38

Table B.3 Poverty incidence for different population groups, OECD-scale

Poverty incidence

Cash income Extended income Population group Population

share OECD OECD NA NPA

29 years or below 3.3 12.4 13.3 14.0 14.0

30-44 years 3.9 7.8 8.5 9.6 9.6

45-66 years 5.0 5.9 6.9 6.6 6.6 Singles

67 years or above 5.7 8.8 6.3 8.1 8.1

29 years or below 1.3 2.3 2.6 2.9 2.9

30-44 years 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.5 2.5

45-66 years 8.6 1.3 1.5 1.3 1.3

Couples (without children)

67 years or above 7.0 3.9 1.7 2.2 2.2

0-5 years 18.8 5.0 0.9 4.1 4.1

6-17 years 21.7 2.0 0.5 1.7 1.7 Couples (with children) 18 years or above 8.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7

0-5 years 1.8 17.3 2.1 10.7 10.6

6-17 years 4.8 6.1 1.1 4.3 4.3 Single parents

18 years or above 2.5 3.3 3.2 3.7 3.7

Other households 5.0 4.0 2.0 3.8 3.8

Non-immigrants 91.1 3.0 1.8 2.8 2.8

Immigrants 8.9 17.4 8.4 15.3 15.1

Western 2.3 11.8 9.9 11.5 11.5 Ethnic origin

Non-Western 6.6 19.3 7.9 16.7 16.4

Urban 81.7 4.4 2.6 4.1 4.1

Oslo 11.7 8.0 4.6 7.0 6.9 Centrality

Rural 18.3 3.6 1.7 2.8 2.8

All population 100 4.3 2.4 3.9 3.9

Note: All numbers are in per cent. NA: Needs-adjusted OECD scale. NPA: Needs-and price-adjusted OECD scale. Poverty thresholds are calculated on the basis of median in each of the four equivalent income distributions, and thereby depend upon the income measure and the scales used in calculating equivalent incomes.

Page 39: Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen and ...Discussion Papers No. 621, May 2010 Statistics Norway, Research Department Rolf Aaberge, Manudeep Bhuller, Audun Langørgen

39

Figure B.1 Changes in poverty status for alternative income measures, OECD-scale

Note: NA: Needs-adjusted OECD scale. Poverty thresholds are calculated as 50 per cent of the median in each of the three income distributions.