RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID...

58
RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine Casey Rachel Glennerster Edward Miguel Despite their importance, there is limited evidence on how institutions can be strengthened. Evaluating the effects of specific reforms is complicated by the lack of exogenous variation in institutions, the difficulty of measuring institu- tional performance, and the temptation to ‘‘cherry pick’’ estimates from among the large number of indicators required to capture this multifaceted subject. We evaluate one attempt to make local institutions more democratic and egalitar- ian by imposing participation requirements for marginalized groups (including women) and test for learning-by-doing effects. We exploit the random assign- ment of a governance program in Sierra Leone, develop innovative real-world outcome measures, and use a preanalysis plan (PAP) to bind our hands against data mining. The intervention studied is a ‘‘community-driven development’’ program, which has become a popular strategy for foreign aid donors. We find positive short-run effects on local public goods and economic outcomes, but no evidence for sustained impacts on collective action, decision making, or the involvement of marginalized groups, suggesting that the intervention *We thank the GoBifo Project staff—Minkahil Bangura, Kury Cobham, John Lebbie, Dan Owen, and Sullay Sesay—and the Institutional Reform and Capacity Building Project (IRCBP) staff—Liz Foster, Emmanuel Gaima, Alhassan Kanu, S. A. T. Rogers, and Yongmei Zhou—without whose cooperation this research would not have been possible. We are grateful for excellent research assistance from John Bellows, Mame Fatou Diagne, Mark Fiorello, Maryam Janani, Philip Kargbo, Angela Kilby, Gianmarco Leo ´n, Tom Polley, Tristan Reed, Arman Rezaee, Alex Rothenberg, and David Zimmer. David Card, Kevin Esterling, Jim Fearon, Macartan Humphreys, Brian Knight, David Laitin, Ed Leamer, Kaivan Munshi, Ben Olken, Biju Rao, Debraj Ray, Gerard Roland, Ann Swidler, Eric Werker, and seminar audiences at Brown University, Center for Global Development (CGD), Center for Effective Global Action (CEGA), the Econometric Society (North American Summer Meetings), International Growth Centre (IGC), International Monetary Fund, MIT, Northeast Universities Development Conference (NEUDC), New York University, Princeton, Stanford, Stanford Institute for Theoretical Economics (SITE), University of British Columbia, University of California Berkeley, UCLA, University of California, San Diego (UCSD), the Western Experimental Conference, and the Working Group in African Political Economy (WGAPE) have provided helpful comments. We thank the editor, Larry Katz, and five an- onymous referees for excellent suggestions. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the GoBifo Project, the IRCBP, the World Bank Development Impact Evaluation (DIME) initiative, the Horace W. Goldsmith Foundation, the International Growth Centre, the International Initiative for Impact Evaluation (3ie), and the National Bureau of Economic Research African Successes Project (funded by the Gates Foundation). All errors remain our own. ! The Author(s) 2012. Published by Oxford University Press, on behalf of President and Fellows of Harvard College. All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email: journals. [email protected] The Quarterly Journal of Economics (2012), 1755–1812. doi:10.1093/qje/qje027. Advance Access publication on September 7, 2012. 1755

Transcript of RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID...

Page 1: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTSUSING A PREANALYSIS PLAN*

Katherine Casey

Rachel Glennerster

Edward Miguel

Despite their importance, there is limited evidence on how institutions canbe strengthened. Evaluating the effects of specific reforms is complicated by thelack of exogenous variation in institutions, the difficulty of measuring institu-tional performance, and the temptation to ‘‘cherry pick’’ estimates from amongthe large number of indicators required to capture this multifaceted subject. Weevaluate one attempt to make local institutions more democratic and egalitar-ian by imposing participation requirements for marginalized groups (includingwomen) and test for learning-by-doing effects. We exploit the random assign-ment of a governance program in Sierra Leone, develop innovative real-worldoutcome measures, and use a preanalysis plan (PAP) to bind our hands againstdata mining. The intervention studied is a ‘‘community-driven development’’program, which has become a popular strategy for foreign aid donors. Wefind positive short-run effects on local public goods and economic outcomes,but no evidence for sustained impacts on collective action, decision making,or the involvement of marginalized groups, suggesting that the intervention

*We thank the GoBifo Project staff—Minkahil Bangura, Kury Cobham, JohnLebbie, Dan Owen, and Sullay Sesay—and the Institutional Reform and CapacityBuilding Project (IRCBP) staff—Liz Foster, Emmanuel Gaima, Alhassan Kanu, S.A. T. Rogers, and Yongmei Zhou—without whose cooperation this research wouldnot have been possible. We are grateful for excellent research assistance fromJohn Bellows, Mame Fatou Diagne, Mark Fiorello, Maryam Janani, PhilipKargbo, Angela Kilby, Gianmarco Leon, Tom Polley, Tristan Reed, ArmanRezaee, Alex Rothenberg, and David Zimmer. David Card, Kevin Esterling, JimFearon, Macartan Humphreys, Brian Knight, David Laitin, Ed Leamer, KaivanMunshi, Ben Olken, Biju Rao, Debraj Ray, Gerard Roland, Ann Swidler, EricWerker, and seminar audiences at Brown University, Center for GlobalDevelopment (CGD), Center for Effective Global Action (CEGA), theEconometric Society (North American Summer Meetings), InternationalGrowth Centre (IGC), International Monetary Fund, MIT, NortheastUniversities Development Conference (NEUDC), New York University,Princeton, Stanford, Stanford Institute for Theoretical Economics (SITE),University of British Columbia, University of California Berkeley, UCLA,University of California, San Diego (UCSD), the Western ExperimentalConference, and the Working Group in African Political Economy (WGAPE)have provided helpful comments. We thank the editor, Larry Katz, and five an-onymous referees for excellent suggestions. We gratefully acknowledge financialsupport from the GoBifo Project, the IRCBP, the World Bank Development ImpactEvaluation (DIME) initiative, the Horace W. Goldsmith Foundation, theInternational Growth Centre, the International Initiative for Impact Evaluation(3ie), and the National Bureau of Economic Research African Successes Project(funded by the Gates Foundation). All errors remain our own.

! The Author(s) 2012. Published by Oxford University Press, on behalf of President andFellows of Harvard College. All rights reserved. For Permissions, please email: [email protected] Quarterly Journal of Economics (2012), 1755–1812. doi:10.1093/qje/qje027.Advance Access publication on September 7, 2012.

1755

Page 2: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

did not durably reshape local institutions. We discuss the practical trade-offsfaced in implementing a PAP and show how in its absence we could havegenerated two divergent, equally erroneous interpretations of program impactson institutions. JEL Codes: F35, H41, O4

I. INTRODUCTION

Many scholars have argued that the accountability and in-clusiveness of government institutions are key determinants ofeconomic performance (Engerman and Sokoloff 1997; Acemoglu,Johnson, and Robinson 2001; Banerjee and Iyer 2005). There isno consensus, however, on the reforms that will engender betterfunctioning institutions, or on whether it is possible (or even de-sirable) for external actors like foreign aid donors to reshapepower dynamics in less developed countries. This debate hasplayed out vigorously in discussions of aid policy: whereas someargue that large infusions of foreign aid can themselves helpbuild stronger institutions (Sachs 2005), others assert that his-torically rooted institutions and social norms are difficult tounderstand, let alone transform (Easterly 2006).

Progress toward resolving this question is complicated by therarity of exogenous changes in institutional structure and thedifficulty of measuring institutional performance. Thecontext-specific nature of institutions means that there are fewstandard indicators to draw from, and reliance on subjectivemeasures risks bias from ‘‘halo effects’’ (see Olken 2009 regardingcorruption). Moreover, their multidimensionality makes a largenumber of outcomes potentially relevant, tempting the re-searcher to ‘‘cherry pick’’ a subset of results that may be statis-tically significant by random chance. We evaluate one attempt totransform local institutions in Sierra Leone and address thesechallenges by exploiting a randomly assigned governance inter-vention, developing objective measures of institutional perform-ance, and using a preanalysis plan (PAP) to bind our handsagainst data mining.

The intervention studied, a ‘‘community-driven develop-ment’’ (CDD) project, provides what we call ‘‘hardware’’ and ‘‘soft-ware’’ support to rural communities. Hardware includes blockgrants for local public goods, trade skills training, and small busi-ness start-up capital. Software covers technical assistance thatpromotes democratic decision making, the participation of so-cially marginalized groups, and transparent budgeting practices.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1756

Page 3: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

The CDD approach attempts to bolster local coordination—forexample, by setting up village development committees—and toenhance participation, by requiring women and ‘‘youths’’ (adultsunder age 35) to hold leadership positions, sign off on project fi-nances, and attend meetings. The push for CDD reflects a broaderintellectual movement in international development towardgreater participation and empowerment of the poor (Chambers1983; Sen 1985, 1999; World Bank 2001; Narayan 2002). CDDfurther resembles certain ‘‘War on Poverty’’ reforms in the1960s United States, particularly the Office of EconomicOpportunity’s Community Action Program, which bundledsocial service delivery with attempts to politically mobilize mar-ginalized groups, especially African Americans (Rosener 1978;Germany 2007).1 Donors currently channel large amounts ofaid through these programs: Mansuri and Rao (2012) estimatethat the World Bank alone has spent US$50 billion on CDD ini-tiatives over the past 10 years.

Advocates of participatory local governance promise a longand varied list of benefits ranging from more cost-effective con-struction of infrastructure, to a closer match between projectchoice and village needs, to the weakening of authoritarian vil-lage institutions.2 Critics hold concomitant concerns that partici-pation requirements serve as a regressive tax, widening politicalparticipation clogs up rather than expedites decision making(Olson 1982), and external resources attract new leaders, crowdout the most disadvantaged (Gugerty and Kremer 2008), or arecaptured by elites if the program is unable to change the nature ofde facto political power (Bardhan 2002). Any real-world programrisks manipulation during implementation, and skeptical

1. There is remarkable similarity between CDD programs and the design andframing of these earlier U.S. efforts. Germany (2007: 15) writes that ‘‘the OEOpursued an aggressive, innovative and experimental agenda premised on em-powering the poor and giving local people significant authority in fighting poverty.Envisioned by OEO administrators as an attack on the causes of poverty more thanthe symptoms, the War on Poverty was an ambitious effort to reform the psychologyof the poor, the institutions of the ghetto, the systems necessary for upward mobil-ity, and the patterns of black political participation.’’ We thank David Card fordrawing our attention to these parallels.

2. For instance, Dongier et al. (2003) write that: ‘‘Experience demonstratesthat by directly relying on poor people to drive development activities, CDD has thepotential to make poverty reduction efforts more responsive to demands, more in-clusive, more sustainable, and more cost-effective than traditional centrally ledprograms . . . achieving immediate and lasting results at the grassroots level.’’

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1757

Page 4: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

observers fear that donors simply use the jargon of participatorydevelopment for political or public relations purposes while con-tinuing to operate in a top-down manner. Few studies providerigorous empirical evidence regarding these claims (Mansuriand Rao 2004).

Scholars have argued that the incompetence and elite dom-ination of Sierra Leone’s institutions—both in the central govern-ment and the traditional chieftaincy system—in the 1970s and1980s were key contributors to the civil war that took place from1991 to 2002 (Richards 1996; Keen 2003). Emerging from warwith widespread poverty and a dearth of public services, thecountry fell to the very bottom of the United NationsDevelopment Program Human Development Index that meas-ures standards of living, health, and education (United Nations2003), with 2001 per capita income of just US$140 in exchangerate terms (World Bank 2003). To facilitate recovery from andpreclude a return to violence, one of the most high-profile reformswas the reconstitution of elected district-level governments.Housed within the government’s Decentralization Secretariatand funded by the World Bank, the project we study, ‘‘GoBifo’’(or ‘‘Move Forward’’ in Krio, Sierra Leone’s lingua franca), fur-ther extended decentralization by providing financial assistance(of $4,667, or roughly $100 per household) and social mobilizationto village-level committees. Although the objective of makinglocal government institutions more inclusive aimed to addresssome of the perceived root causes of the civil war, GoBifo’sdesign is similar to many other CDD projects in non-postconflictsocieties.

This article assesses the extent to which GoBifo achieved itsgoals of reforming local institutions in rural Sierra Leone, and inso doing makes four contributions. The first general contributionis a discussion of how PAPs can help avoid some common pitfallsin empirical research. The research and project teams agreed to aset of hypotheses regarding the likely areas of program impact in2005 before the intervention began. As the project came to a closein 2009, we fleshed out this document with the exact outcomemeasures and econometric specifications we would use, andarchived this PAP before analyzing the follow-up data (seeOnline Appendix A). ‘‘Tying one’s hands’’ in this way is poten-tially useful where researchers have wide discretion over whatthey report and may face professional incentives to affirm thepriors of their academic discipline or the agenda of donors and

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1758

Page 5: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

policy makers. Explicit ex ante agreements between researchersand program sponsors can offer a layer of protection for ‘‘incon-venient’’ findings and thus reduce the scope for tendentious re-porting. Adherence to a PAP reduces the risk of data mining orother selective presentation of empirical results (cherry picking)and generates correctly sized statistical tests, bolstering the cred-ibility of the findings. More broadly, a system of registrationfor experimental trials would help round out the body of availableresearch evidence, mitigating the publication bias that arisesfrom underreporting null or counterintuitive results. Registra-tion of drug trials and PAPs is required by U.S. law but is uncom-mon in economics.3 We hope our experience contributes to theemerging debate on the pros and cons of PAPs in social science.

The second contribution is the creation of novel measures oflocal institutions and collective action, or structured communityactivities (SCAs). These are concrete, real-world scenarios thatallow us to unobtrusively assess how communities (1) respond toa matching grant opportunity; (2) make a communal decision;and (3) allocate a valuable asset among community members.We feel that these SCAs capture local collective action capacity,and uncover the decision-making processes that underlie it, moreobjectively than lab experiments, hypothetical vignettes, or sur-veys alone.4 The fact that the SCAs were carried out after theGoBifo program ended allows us to measure any persistent im-pacts on institutional performance.

This article’s evaluation of a CDD project will be of particularinterest to development economists and practitioners. We use arandomized experimental design, which produces evidence oncausal impacts in a large study sample of 236 villages and 2,832households. The study’s extended timeframe over four years(2005–2009) allows us to assess longer run impacts than is typic-ally possible. Though four years may be short relative to the life-times over which current institutions emerged, it is not short in

3. The Food and Drug Administration Modernization Act of 1997 led tothe creation of the National Institutes of Health–sponsored web registry http://clinicaltrials.gov in 2000, and a 2007 amendment requires results reporting andimposes financial penalties for noncompliance. In 2005, registration of clinicaltrials became a prerequisite for publication in any member journal of theInternational Committee of Medical Journal Editors. See Rosenthal (1979),Simes (1986), and Horton and Smith (1999).

4. The measures of community negotiations Paluck and Green (2009) devel-oped in Rwanda are a related approach.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1759

Page 6: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

comparison to most community development or other externallyfunded projects. To guide our empirical work, we develop a the-oretical framework for understanding how CDD programs mightimpact local outcomes.

Fourth and finally, we contribute to the growing literatureconcerning the impacts of giving decision-making authority tomarginalized groups. Research in India suggests that politicalquotas for women and members of scheduled castes shift the com-position of public spending toward goods preferred by thesegroups (Pande 2003; Chattopadhyay and Duflo 2004) and reducesbias against female candidates (Beamen et al. 2009). By contrast,we find that requiring women and young adults to take on lead-ership positions, participate in project meetings, and sign off onproject finances does not have any persistent effect on their par-ticipation in local decision making or attitudes regarding theirleadership ability. One explanation for this difference may bethat although Indian quotas give members of historicallyexcluded groups real power over sizable resources within aformal state body (the panchayat), CDD takes a more indirectapproach to de jure reforms—nudging communities towardmore inclusion without explicitly challenging elites—and maynot change the identity of de facto power holders (Acemogluand Robinson 2008). Perhaps because sidelining the chiefs wasnot a program goal, chiefdom officials retained as much controlover village development committees in GoBifo communities asthey held over comparable organizing bodies in control villages.

Our analysis explores a wide range of measures, divided intotwo broad groups: project implementation, local public infrastruc-ture, and economic outcomes (which we call family A), and insti-tutional and collective action outcomes (family B). We find thatthe GoBifo project was well implemented: it established villageorganizations and tools to manage development projects in nearlyall cases and provided the financing to implement them. The dis-tribution of project benefits within communities was largelyequitable, and the leakage of project resources appears minimal.We further find immediate impacts on the stock and quality oflocal public infrastructure, such as schools and latrines. There isalso more market activity in treatment communities, as well asincreases in household asset ownership, suggesting economicbenefits.

However, we find no detectable changes in the second, argu-ably more important, institutional domain (family B). We find no

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1760

Page 7: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

evidence that the program led to fundamental changes in theability to raise funds for local public goods, decision-making pro-cesses, or social norms and attitudes. As an example, despitethe experiences many women gained by participating in andmanaging GoBifo activities, after the project ended they wereno more likely to attend or voice an opinion at community meet-ings. Similarly, there is no evidence that the establishment of ademocratic organizing committee or the experience implementingprojects led to more fundraising in response to a matching grantopportunity. In all, we find no evidence that the programreshaped village institutions, empowered minorities, or improvedcollective action beyond the activities stipulated by the projectitself. The time horizon of the research over four years suggeststhat these findings cannot be dismissed simply as the result of ashort term study.

The rest of the article is structured as follows. Section IIdiscusses the context, intervention, and theoretical framework.Section III covers the research design, PAP, and econometric spe-cifications. Section IV discusses the empirical results, and SectionV concludes.

II. Background

II.A. Institutions in Sierra Leone

Before describing the GoBifo program, we first consider whyexisting institutions in Sierra Leone might warrant reform. Thecountry has a dual system of governance (common in manyAfrican countries; Mamdani 1996) in which the central govern-ment apparatus based in the capital runs in parallel to the ‘‘trad-itional’’ local chieftaincy system, neither of which has historicallybeen particularly democratic or inclusive. Authoritarian centralgovernment leaders in the 1970s and 1980s enriched themselvesthrough illicit diamond deals while providing woefully inad-equate public services (Reno 1995). President Siaka Stevens dis-mantled democratic institutions, initially by abolishing electeddistrict governments in 1972 and ultimately declaring the coun-try a one-party state in 1978. One-party rule continued until the1992 coup that roughly coincided with the start of the civil war(which ran from 1991 to 2002).

As background on the traditional system, the country’s 149paramount chiefs come from hereditary ‘‘ruling houses’’; serve for

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1761

Page 8: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

life once appointed or elected (by a restricted electorate); exertconsiderable control over resource allocation, including land andlabor; operate the local court system that presides outside thecapital; and organize the provision of many local public goods(such as road maintenance). This system largely excludes bothwomen (who are not eligible to serve as chiefs in much of thecountry) and young men from decision making. Political exclu-sion, growing frustration with government incompetence and cor-ruption, and grievances against heavy-handed chiefs are seen asdestabilizing factors that contributed to the war (Richards 1996;Keen 2003).

II.B. The GoBifo Project

After the war, the government of Sierra Leone and its donorpartners, including the World Bank, launched an ambitious in-stitutional reform agenda, which included the reestablishment ofdistrict-level governments. The GoBifo pilot initiative waslaunched to support and deepen this reform by extending decen-tralization down to the ward and village levels.5 The program hadtwo main components: (1) financial assistance in the form of blockgrants to fund local public goods provision and small enterprisedevelopment; and (2) intensive organizing to establish new struc-tures to facilitate collective action (i.e., Village DevelopmentCommittees, VDCs) and institute participation requirements toelevate historically marginalized groups to positions of authority.As examples of the latter, GoBifo required that one of the threeco-signatories on the community bank account be female; encour-aged women and youths to manage their own projects (e.g., smallbusiness training for youths); made evidence of inclusion in pro-ject implementation a prerequisite for the release of fundingtranches; and, as part of their internal review process, requiredfield staff to record how many women and youth attended andspoke up in meetings. To formally link project activities to highertiers of government, VDCs were required to submit their villagedevelopment plans to the appropriate Ward Development

5. Wards are the lowest formal government administrative unit, each coveringaround 10,000people onaverage, andtheelected district councilor representing theward chairs the Ward Development Committee. Though the project we study alsooperated at the ward level, only the village-level intervention was randomized andis thus our focus.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1762

Page 9: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

Committee (WDC) for review, endorsement, and transmission tothe new district councils for approval (GoBifo Project 2007).

The process of establishing new village institutions, trainingcommunity members, and promoting social mobilization of mar-ginalized groups was intense and accounted for a large part ofGoBifo human and financial resources. Specifically, all projectfacilitators were required to reside in one of the six villages as-signed to them and spend approximately one day a week in eachof the villages. After the start of project work in January 2006 andthrough the completion of all village-level projects in July 2009,each village received roughly six months of direct ‘‘facilitation’’over a three-and-a-half-year period (see the timeline in OnlineAppendix B). Furthermore, although just under half of the totalGoBifo budget was dedicated to village- and ward-level blockgrants (US$896,000 or 47%), the balance covered ‘‘capacity devel-opment’’ in village- and ward-level planning (US$589,732 or30%), project management and contingencies (US$255,320 or14%), and monitoring and evaluation (US$177,300 or 9%). Thusfor every $1 spent directly on grants, roughly $1 was spent oncapacity-building, facilitation, and oversight.

Several different types of GoBifo village projects werecommon. The largest share of projects, at 43%, was in the con-struction of local public goods, with 14% in community centers orsports fields, 12% in education (i.e., primary school repairs), 10%in water and sanitation (i.e., latrines), 5% in health (includingtraditional midwife posts), and 2% in roads. Another 26% wasin agriculture, including seed multiplication and communal farm-ing; 14% in livestock (i.e., goat herding) or fishing; and 17% inskills training and small business development initiatives (i.e.,blacksmithing, carpentry, soap making). Leakage of GoBifo fundsappears minimal: when we asked villagers to verify the detailedfinancial reports that were given to the research team by projectmanagement, community members were able to confirm receiptfor 86.5% of the 273 transactions that were cross-checked.6

GoBifo is similar to CDD initiatives in other countries. Theproject implementation stages—establishing a local committee,

6. The discrepancies were of two types: (1) the amounts in community recordswas markedly less than in project accounts; or (2) community members reportedreceiving building materials in kind and could not estimate their value. For each ofthe disputed transactions, the GoBifo accounting team produced hard-copy pay-ment vouchers signed by both a village representative (either the VDC chair orfinance officer) and a project field staff member.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1763

Page 10: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

providing facilitation that aims to shift social norms, and allocat-ing block grants—are standard, as is the pervasive emphasis oninclusive, transparent, and participatory processes. Compared toother projects (Olken 2007; Labonne and Chase 2008), the mostnotable difference is that the village-level component of GoBifodid not involve any intercommunity competition for funding.Regarding the scale of funding, GoBifo disbursed grants wortha bit under $5,000 to communities with 50 households, or 300residents, on average (roughly $100 per household, or $4.50 percapita annually over three and a half years).7

II.C. A Framework of Collective Action and External Aid

We next lay out a stylized local collective action frameworkthat clarifies how an external intervention that provides finan-cing and participation requirements might change local decisionmaking and derive implications that inform the empirical ana-lysis; see Online Appendix C for the formal exposition of themodel. In the model, a social planner determines the optimal in-vestment in local public goods and sets a corresponding tax sched-ule, which is implemented with perfect compliance. Individualresidents then decide whether to voluntarily participate in theplanning and implementation of the public goods projects, takingtheir individual tax burden as given. We feel this framework is areasonable approximation to the context of rural Sierra Leone(and similar societies with strong village headmen), where thetraditional chief has the authority to levy fines and collect taxesto provide basic public goods, but there is variation in residents’involvement in actual decision making and implementation. Inthis setting, the external intervention lowers the marginal cost oflocal public goods provision through financial subsidies and af-fects the fixed costs of collective action by imposing participationrequirements and instilling democratic norms. We allow under-represented groups (i.e., women) to have differential participa-tion costs ex ante, which could be impacted by learning bydoing or demonstration effects during project implementation.

We define three time periods that correspond to our datacollection activities: the preprogram period, when the baseline

7. The Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein (2009) Liberia project providedroughly $20,000 to ‘‘communities’’ that comprised 2,000 to 3,000 residents, roughly$4 per capita, annually over two years.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1764

Page 11: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

survey was fielded; the program implementation phase, wherethe first follow-up survey captured activities that had been com-pleted during the intervention (and launched the structured com-munity activities); and the postprogram period, where the secondfollow-up survey explored what happened with the SCAs after theproject had finished. Because the marginal cost reductions aretied directly to external financial assistance, while the fixed orga-nizing cost reductions could be internalized and maintained, wecan speculatively gain some leverage over which channels are atwork by comparing impacts during the project versus postpro-gram phases. Moreover, studying the postprogram periodallows us to evaluate the persistence and ‘‘sustainability’’ ofimpacts.

First, consider the individual’s decision of whether to contrib-ute time and voluntary labor to the planning and provision oflocal public goods. These decisions are taken in a decentralizedfashion, but they aggregate in a way that affects the cost of publicgoods provision facing the social planner. The fact that individ-uals ignore the aggregate effect of their voluntary labor capturesthe classic externality feature of collective action and implies thateven with perfect tax compliance, the planner will still fail toachieve the first-best level of public goods.

Individuals gain utility from consumption of the currentstock of public goods, private consumption, and a psychic orsocial benefit of participating in collective action that capturesthe intrinsic value of civic involvement. Regarding the latter,Olken (2010) and Dal Bo, Foster, and Putterman (2010) provideevidence that having a say in the decision-making process canhave a large effect on satisfaction and cooperation even if thechoice process has zero impact on the final policy outcome perse. Given historical legacies of exclusion, we assume that whilesome women and youth may derive positive utility from partici-pation, they face additional social costs of speaking up, and thus,on average, their net benefits of civic participation are lower thanfor elder male elites. All residents face the same opportunity costof participating, which reflects the cost of time spent engaging inpublic goods provision instead of wage-earning activities, andthey must pay the tax set by the social planner. The first-orderconditions imply that the individual chooses to participate in col-lective action if and only if the net benefits are nonnegative.

The social planner chooses the level of local public goods in-vestment with the objective of maximizing the sum of individual

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1765

Page 12: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

utilities. The cost of public goods provision has two components: amarginal cost capturing the price of construction materials, and afixed coordination cost of collective action, which is a function ofboth the sum of individual participation decisions and the cap-acity of local institutions. Following the theory motivating par-ticipatory local development, we assume that the fixed costs ofcollective action are falling in both the capacity of local institu-tions and community participation; we assess the empirical val-idity of these assumptions below. The latter condition would betrue if, for example, greater community involvement made publicgoods provision easier by creating greater support for the process.Importantly, even if participation has no effect on coordinationcosts, advocates argue that local civic engagement carries intrin-sic benefits, and therefore project participation belongs in theutility function and its enhancement becomes an appropriate ob-jective for intervention.

Standard first-order conditions imply that the plannerchooses the optimal level of local public goods investment if af-fordable, or a smaller investment that exhausts the villagebudget (at a corner solution) if it is not. Given the poverty andextremely limited public services in rural Sierra Leone, it seemsreasonable to assume the latter, where communities face a bind-ing budget constraint that keeps public investment well belowoptimal levels. This means that there are plenty of public invest-ments—in latrines, water wells, primary schools—whosevillage-wide marginal benefits exceed the marginal cost of con-struction, yet are simply unaffordable given the community’ssmall tax base and inability to borrow (in light of pervasive finan-cial market imperfections). Under these constraints, profitableinvestments become unaffordable because construction prices orcoordination costs are prohibitively high.

Within this framework, participatory local governance inter-ventions aim to have three distinct impacts. First, by subsidizingthe cost of construction materials, the financial grants reduce themarginal cost of public goods provision. Second, the leadershipquotas and participation requirements for women and youth aimto increase the benefits of participation for these historicallymarginalized groups. Such requirements should automaticallytranslate into greater participation in collective activitiesduring project implementation for these groups. Moreover, ifwomen and young men learn by doing, or if their participationexerts positive demonstration effects on others that begin to

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1766

Page 13: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

shift social norms, this experience could trigger a persistent in-crease in their benefits of participation, sustainably raising par-ticipation levels into the postprogram period. Third and finally,this increase in community participation, accompanied by theestablishment of VDCs, plans, and bank accounts, aims toreduce the fixed coordination costs of collective action. The ideais that once these are in place, the next village project should beless costly to identify and execute during both project implemen-tation and the postprogram period. As such, the original GoBifoproject proposal emphasizes the sustainability and broad man-date of these new structures, suggesting they will become ‘‘thefocal point for development interventions’’ in the future (WorldBank 2004).

This simple framework generates three empirical predictionsto take to the data. First, the combination of financial subsidiesand lower coordination costs should unambiguously increasepublic goods investment during the program implementationphase. To assess this, outcome family A includes project imple-mentation indicators to first evaluate whether the grants were infact delivered to villages and new institutions established on theground, and then a set of measures regarding the stock of localpublic goods to assess immediate impacts on investment levels.Second, as we move from project implementation to the postpro-gram period, the marginal investment costs return to baselinelevels while the fixed costs (potentially) remain reduced. Toevaluate whether new village institutions lead to greater publicinvestment in the postprogram period, family B includes take-upof the building materials vouchers (in SCA 1), and other collectiveaction measures beyond the direct program sphere. Third, if par-ticipation requirements for women and youth trigger a perman-ent enhancement in their benefits from participation, we shouldsee more women and youths attending community meetings andtaking part in decision making postprogram. This is captured bythe outcomes in the gift choice component of SCA 2 and householdsurvey responses concerning civic engagement in nonprogramareas. Moreover, enhancing participation by marginalizedgroups could initiate broader changes in social norms and atti-tudes (e.g., regarding the desirability of female leadership), ascaptured in several additional hypotheses under outcome familyB. It remains an empirical question whether any of these predic-tions hold in reality, hence we turn to the data.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1767

Page 14: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

III. Research Design

III.A. Random Assignment

The 118 GoBifo treatment and 118 control villages wereselected from a larger pool of eligible communities using a com-puterized random number generator. They were sampled fromwithin the two study districts, which were chosen to strike a bal-ance in terms of regional diversity, political affiliation, and ethnicidentity, while simultaneously targeting poor rural areas withlimited nongovernmental organization (NGO) presence (seeOnline Appendix D for a map). Bombali district is located in thenorthern region dominated by the Temne and Limba ethnicgroups and traditionally allied with the All People’s Congresspolitical party, one of Sierra Leone’s two largest parties. Bonthedistrict is in the south, where the Mende and Sherbro ethnicgroups dominate and where the other major party, the SierraLeone People’s Party, is strong. Using the 2004 Population andHousing Census, the pool of eligible villages was restricted tothose considered of appropriate size for a CDD project, namely,between 20 and 200 households in Bombali and 10 to 100 house-holds in Bonthe (where villages are smaller). Once the samplewas chosen, the villages were randomized into treatment andcontrol groups, stratifying on ward.8 There were six treatmentand six control villages in each of 19 wards, plus one additionalward on Bonthe Island, where there were only four treatment andfour control communities given the small size of the ward.

Statistics Sierra Leone staff randomly selected 12 house-holds to be surveyed from the census household lists in each vil-lage. Given interest in the dynamics of political exclusion andempowerment, the choice of respondent within each targetedhousehold rotated among four different demographic groups ineach subsequent household surveyed: nonyouth male, youth

8. We ran 500 computer randomizations and saved all resulting assignmentsthat generated no statistically significant differences (at 95% confidence) betweentreatment and control groups in terms of the total number of households per villageand the distance to the nearest road. Among these ‘‘balanced’’ assignments, one wasthen selected at random for the final treatment assignment. Following Bruhn andMcKenzie (2009), we include the ‘‘balancing’’ observables in the regression analysisas covariates to generate correct standard errors. Treatment effect estimates arethus interpreted as impacts conditional on these observables, although results donot change with their exclusion (not shown). There were two minor data issues thatled to a partial resampling of a small number of villages; however, these did notaffect the integrity of the randomization (see Online Appendix E).

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1768

Page 15: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

male, nonyouth female, and youth female. All respondents are atleast 18 years old, and note that the government of Sierra Leone’sdefinition of ‘‘youth’’ includes people up to 35 years of age (al-though the definition is a bit subjective in reality, especially be-cause many Sierra Leoneans do not know their exact age). Thisdata collection strategy means that for each community, and forthe overall sample, responses are roughly balanced across thefour demographic groups.9

The randomization procedure successfully generated twogroups balanced along observable dimensions. Specifically,Table I lists the control group mean and the treatment minuscontrol preprogram difference for a variety of community charac-teristics (including total households, distance to nearest road,average respondent years of education, and indices for civil warexposure and local history of domestic slavery) as well as an il-lustrative selection of preprogram values for outcome measures.There are no statistically significant mean differences across thetreatment and control groups for any of these variables; OnlineAppendix F presents the same estimates for all 96 baseline meas-ures and shows that the difference across treatment and controlgroups is significant at 90% confidence for only 7 of these, roughlyas expected by chance. One noteworthy pattern in the baselinedata is the stark gender difference in local meeting involvement,with twice as many males (59%) than females (29%) speaking atvillage meetings.

III.B. Data Collection and Measurement

This analysis draws on three main data sources: householdsurveys from late 2005 (baseline) and mid-2009 (follow-up);village-level focus group discussions held in 2005 and 2009; andthree novel SCAs conducted in late 2009 shortly after GoBifoactivities had ended. The SCAs were introduced with the initialfollow-up survey in May 2009 and then followed up in an un-announced visit five months later. The research team and enu-merators were operationally separate from GoBifo staff at allstages of the project.

The 2005 household surveys collected data on baseline par-ticipation in local collective activities, as well as household

9. These fourdemographic groups each comprise roughly aquarter of theadultpopulation in these two districts in the 2004 census (ranging from 21% to 31%),indicating that our sample is quite representative.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1769

Page 16: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EI

BA

SE

LIN

E(2

005)

CO

MP

AR

ISO

NB

ET

WE

EN

TR

EA

TM

EN

TA

ND

CO

NT

RO

LC

OM

MU

NIT

IES

(1)

(2)

(3)

Base

lin

em

ean

for

con

trol

sT

-Cd

iffe

ren

ceat

base

lin

eN

Pan

elA

:C

omm

un

ity

chara

cter

isti

csT

otal

hou

seh

old

sp

erco

mm

un

ity

46.7

60.3

0236

(3.6

7)

Dis

tan

ceto

nea

rest

mot

orable

road

inm

iles

2.9

9–0.3

2236

(0.3

6)

Ind

exof

war

exp

osu

re(r

an

ge

0to

1)

0.6

8–0.0

1236

(0.0

2)

His

tori

cal

exte

nt

ofd

omes

tic

slaver

y(r

an

ge

0to

1)

0.3

60.0

3236

(0.0

6)

Aver

age

resp

ond

ent

yea

rsof

edu

cati

on1.6

50.1

1235

(0.1

3)

Pan

elB

:S

elec

ted

vari

able

sfr

om‘‘h

ard

ware

’’fa

mil

yA

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sw

ith

avil

lage

dev

elop

men

tco

mm

itte

e(V

DC

)0.5

50.0

6232

(0.0

6)

Pro

por

tion

vis

ited

by

ward

dev

elop

men

tco

mm

itte

e(W

DC

)m

ember

inp

ast

yea

r0.1

5–0.0

1228

(0.0

5)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sw

ith

afu

nct

ion

al

gra

in-d

ryin

gfl

oor

0.2

30.0

5231

(0.0

5)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sw

ith

afu

nct

ion

al

pri

mary

sch

ool

0.4

10.0

8230

(0.0

6)

Aver

age

hou

seh

old

ass

etsc

ore

–0.0

60.1

1235

(0.0

8)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sw

ith

an

yp

etty

trad

ers

0.5

4–0.0

1226

(0.0

6)

(con

tin

ued

)

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1770

Page 17: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EI

(CO

NT

INU

ED)

(1)

(2)

(3)

Base

lin

em

ean

for

con

trol

sT

-Cd

iffe

ren

ceat

base

lin

eN

Pan

elC

:S

elec

ted

vari

able

sfr

om‘‘s

oftw

are

’’fa

mil

yB

Res

pon

den

tagre

esth

at

chie

fdom

offi

cials

can

be

tru

sted

0.6

6–0.0

1235

(0.0

2)

Res

pon

den

tagre

esth

at

loca

lco

un

cill

ors

can

be

tru

sted

0.6

10.0

0235

(0.0

2)

Res

pon

den

tis

am

ember

ofcr

edit

/savin

gs

gro

up

0.2

5–0.0

3235

(0.0

2)

Am

ong

male

sw

ho

att

end

eda

com

mu

nit

ym

eeti

ng,

resp

ond

ent

spok

ep

ubli

cly

0.5

9–0.0

2235

(0.0

4)

Am

ong

fem

ale

sw

ho

att

end

eda

com

mu

nit

ym

eeti

ng,

resp

ond

ent

spok

ep

ubli

cly

0.2

90.0

3229

(0.0

4)

Res

pon

den

tcl

aim

edto

have

vot

edin

last

loca

lel

ecti

ons

0.8

5–0.0

1235

(0.0

2)

Not

es:

Sig

nifi

can

cele

vel

sin

dic

ate

dby

+p<

.10,

*p<

.05,

**p<

.01.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nth

eses

.T

he

T-C

dif

fere

nce

isth

ep

rep

rogra

m‘‘t

reatm

ent

effe

ct’’

run

onth

ebase

lin

ed

ata

aggre

gate

dto

the

vil

lage-

level

mea

n,

usi

ng

am

inim

al

spec

ifica

tion

that

incl

ud

eson

lyfi

xed

effe

cts

for

the

dis

tric

tco

un

cil

ward

s(t

he

un

itof

stra

tifi

cati

on)

an

dth

etw

obala

nci

ng

vari

able

sfr

omth

era

nd

omiz

ati

on(t

otal

hou

seh

old

san

dd

ista

nce

toro

ad

).R

egre

ssio

ns

for

the

two

bala

nci

ng

vari

able

sin

the

firs

tan

dse

con

dro

ws

excl

ud

eth

eou

tcom

efr

omth

ese

tof

con

trol

s.S

eeO

nli

ne

Ap

pen

dix

Ffo

rth

eT

-Cd

iffe

ren

cefo

rall

94

outc

omes

coll

ecte

din

the

base

lin

esu

rvey

.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1771

Page 18: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

demographic and socioeconomic information. To establish apanel, the field teams sought the same respondents during the2009 follow-up surveys, and the attrition rate was moderate: 96%of the same households were located and reinterviewed, as were76% of the same individual respondents. Where the individualrespondent from 2005 was unavailable, we picked another house-hold member with the same gender and youth status (or samegender only, if no match on both criteria was available) to inter-view in 2009. This approach maintained the overall demographiccomposition of the respondent sample. In the 4% of cases wherethe entire household had moved permanently, we visited thedwelling located three doors down and interviewed someonewith the same gender and youth status. Rates of attrition atboth the individual and household level are balanced across treat-ment groups and do not vary significantly by treatment statusinteracted with several baseline characteristics including re-spondent gender, youth status, education, community meetingattendance, or household assets (see Online Appendix G). Notethat our main analysis is conducted (and many of our outcomemeasures are collected) at the village level, which is the unit oftreatment assignment and for which we have zero attrition.10

During the data collection visits in 2005 and 2009, the fieldteam supervisor assembled key opinion leaders—including VDCmembers, the village chief, as well as women and youth leaders,among others—to describe the condition of local infrastructureand answer questions about local collective processes and activ-ities. Research supervisors also made their own physical assess-ments of construction quality as a cross-check.

Given the difficulties in gauging institutional dynamics andcollective action through survey responses alone, the third maintype of data was gathered through the SCAs. These were de-signed to measure how communities respond to three concrete,real-world situations: (1) raising funds in response to a matchinggrant opportunity, (2) making a community decision between twocomparable alternatives, and (3) allocating and managing anasset that was provided for free. As opposed to hypothetical vi-gnettes or laboratory experiments in the field, these exercises

10. For the outcome variables that rely on household-level responses, we con-struct village-level averages using all individuals interviewed in the follow-upsurvey. However, none of our results are affected by limiting the sample to theoriginal respondents who were resurveyed (see Table III).

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1772

Page 19: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

more directly, realistically, and less obtrusively capture outcomesof interest. We discuss each SCA in detail here.

SCA 1 was designed to measure whether GoBifo producedpersistent effects on villages’ capacity for local collective actionbeyond the life of the project. Each community received six vou-chers they could redeem at a nearby building materials store (inthe nearest large town) if they raised matching funds.Specifically, each voucher was worth 50,000 Leones (roughlyUS$17) only if accompanied by another 100,000 Leones (US$33)from the community. Matching all six vouchers generated900,000 Leones (US$300) for use in the supply store.

Because individuals had negligible savings and faced creditconstraints, take-up of the vouchers is a measure of local capacityfor cooperation. Voucher redemption was recorded by clerks atthe building materials stores. Enumerators returned to all vil-lages five months after the initial distribution of the vouchersto assess the distribution of project contributions and benefits(i.e., did they buy metal for a new roof for the primary school orfor the chief’s home?), the quality of final construction, and howinclusive and transparent the management of the resulting pro-ject had been. In the context of the model, higher take-up in treat-ment communities implies that the program persistently reducedthe fixed costs of collective action, as in this case the marginalcomponent (i.e., the financial subsidies offered through the vou-chers) was exactly the same for treatment and control villages.

Take-up of all the vouchers was always in the community’sself-interest: given the subsidy (and even accounting for trans-port costs), the materials could be profitably resold immediatelyafter purchase at the building material stores. To provide a senseof what types of projects this amount (US$300) could fund, themodal project was to purchase metal sheeting to upgrade theroofing on a community building like a school. In earlier GoBifoprojects, villages were free to divide the funds between multipleprojects, and roughly 20% of all projects were valued at or belowUS$300, indicating that this is a useful amount of funding.

SCA 2 was designed to measure the extent to which commu-nity decision making is democratic and inclusive and to assess thelevel of community participation. The day before survey work, theenumerator teams met with the village head (the lowest levelchiefly authority) and asked him to assemble the entire commu-nity for a meeting the next morning. At the subsequent meeting,the enumerators presented the community with a choice between

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1773

Page 20: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

two gifts each valued at roughly US$40—a carton of batteries(useful for radios and flashlights) versus many small bags ofiodized salt—as a token of appreciation for participating in theresearch. We did extensive field piloting to identify two gifts be-tween which community members would be largely indifferentand for which there was no normatively ‘‘correct’’ choice. Thepiloting suggested that there was more discussion when it wasnot obvious ex ante which option was preferred. (Although it wasnot an outcome of interest in terms of program impacts, twothirds of the communities chose salt and one third the batteriesin both the treatment and control groups.)

The enumerators—who were Statistics Sierra Leone em-ployees and not GoBifo staff—emphasized that the communityitself should decide how to share the gift and then withdrewfrom the meeting to observe the decision-making process fromthe sidelines. The enumerators remained ‘‘outside’’ the commu-nity meeting circle and recorded how the deliberation evolvedwithout making any comments of their own. Among otherthings, the enumerators recorded who participated in any sidemeetings; the degree to which the chief, village head, andelders dominated the discussion; the extent of debate in termsof time and the number of comments; and a subjective assessmentof the apparent influence of different subgroups (e.g., women) onthe final outcome. This exercise provided quantitative data on therelative frequency of female versus male speakers, and youthversus non-youth speakers in an actual community meeting.11

Note that these are the same metrics that the GoBifo facilitatorswere required to track as part of their internal impact assess-ments (GoBifo Project 2008).

SCA 3 was designed to gauge the extent of elite capture ofresources, a common concern for decentralization reforms.During the first follow-up visit in 2009, the enumerators gaveeach village a large plastic tarpaulin sheet as a gift. Tarps arefrequently used in Sierra Leone as makeshift building materials(40% of households have potentially leaky thatched roofs), and inagriculture as a surface for drying grains (as less than a quarterof villages have a functional drying floor). During the second 2009follow-up visit five months later, enumerators recorded which

11. Of the four enumerators, one focused his or her data collection on the par-ticipation of youths, one on women, one on all adults, and the fourth kept carefultrack of each person who spoke publicly.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1774

Page 21: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

households had used the tarp in the intervening period. This ac-tivity also captures an element of collective action, as enumer-ators assessed whether villages had been able to decide on a usefor the tarp, and whether it had been put mainly toward a public(e.g., a communal grain-drying floor) or private end (patching theroof of an individual’s home).

We developed the SCAs precisely because we felt traditionalsurvey measures of collective action and participation were po-tentially unreliable. Thus, ‘‘validating’’ the SCAs using morestandard measures is potentially problematic. Nevertheless,documenting a positive correlation between the SCAs and exist-ing measures would provide some reassurance that there is anunderlying ‘‘signal’’ of collective action capacity that is picked upby both. To provide suggestive evidence on the relevance of theSCAs, we selected variables from the baseline data that sought toassess the same concepts and tested whether they predicted SCAoutcomes four years later. For SCA 1 concerning collective actioncapacity, Online Appendix H shows that the number of vouchersredeemed is positively and significantly predicted by the numberof functional local public goods present in the community at base-line. For SCA 2 regarding the role of women and youth in decisionmaking, Online Appendix H shows that the number of women(youths) attending the deliberation between salt and batteriesis positive and significantly predicted by the baseline number offemale (youth) respondents who reported that they had attendeda community meeting in the past year. Similarly, the number ofwomen (youths) who made a public statement is positively relatedto the baseline number of female (youth) respondents whoclaimed to have spoken up during a recent community meeting,although this correlation is not significant at traditional levels.

SCA 3 concerning elite capture was less successful in gener-ating variation in performance across communities (as discussedin detail below), complicating the validation exercise. Specifically,we find that nearly all communities used the tarp in a public way,as opposed to being privately ‘‘captured.’’ Along similar lines, 57%of respondents reported that they had directly benefited from thetarp, and 90% reported that they received some of the salt orbatteries. One possible explanation is that the highly publicnature of the tarp and gift distribution—which occurred in thesame open community meeting already discussed—may havecurtailed the ability of local leaders to capture the asset. Morespeculatively, it remains possible that we may have seen more

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1775

Page 22: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

‘‘capture’’ during the surprise follow-up visit if the field teams hadinstead surreptitiously handed the tarp to the local headman,which may more closely mimic the way that transfers are some-times made to rural communities; we leave this for futureresearch.12

III.C. The Preanalysis Plan

The econometric analysis follows a PAP that was laid out inthree steps: (1) an outline hypothesis document agreed to withthe GoBifo project implementation team on October 10, 2005; (2)a detailed PAP listing all research hypotheses, the outcomesgrouped under each hypothesis, and econometric specifications(including use of mean effects) that was archived with theAbdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab Randomized EvaluationArchive on August 21, 2009 while data entry, cleaning and rec-onciliation was being carried out and prior to any analysis; and(3) a supplement to the plan covering outcomes collected in thesurprise 2009 follow-up visit (which was fielded five months afterthe first endline survey) that was archived on March 4, 2010. (Theplan and supplement with time stamps are available online athttp://www.povertyactionlab.org/Hypothesis-Registry and inOnline Appendix A.)

The use of PAPs to ‘‘tie the hands’’ of researchers and limitthe risks of data mining and specification search is common inmedical trials. It is much less common, though not unknown, ineconomics. The finding of ‘‘author effects’’ among estimates of theimpact of the minimum wage led to concerns about specificationsearch and publication bias (Card and Krueger 1995). In re-sponse, in the first use of a PAP in economics (to our knowledge),Neumark (1999, 2001) prespecified how data would be used toanalyze the impact of changes in U.S. minimum wage laws in1996 and 1997 before these data became available.

The interest in PAPs has grown with the spread of rando-mized evaluation methods in economics.13 While the

12. For those interested, the detailed SCA supervisor field instructions areincluded in Online Appendix I.

13. At the time of this writing, multiple efforts to establish registries for rando-mized control trials in economics are under discussion, including within theAmerican Economic Association, the American Political Science Association, andthe International Initiative for Impact Evaluation. There have also recently beencalls for PAPs within psychology; see Simmons, Nelson, and Simonsohn (2011).Some other recent publications in economics and political science that use or

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1776

Page 23: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

experimental framework naturally imposes some narrowing ofeconometric specifications, there is still considerable flexibilityfor researchers to define the outcome measures of interest,group outcome variables into different hypothesis ‘‘families’’ ordomains, identify population subgroups to test for heterogeneouseffects, and include or exclude covariates. PAPs are arguably par-ticularly valuable, therefore, when there are a large number ofplausible outcome measures of interest and when researchersplan to undertake subgroup analysis. The process of writing aPAP may have the side benefit of forcing the researchers tomore carefully think through their hypotheses beforehand,which in some cases could improve the quality of the researchdesign and data collection approach.

As with any attempt to ‘‘tie one’s hands,’’ PAPs are not with-out their risks. In particular, a leading concern is that importanthypotheses will be omitted from the initial plan, perhaps due tosimple oversight or to research progress in the discipline duringthe period between writing the PAP and data analysis, whichcould create a desire to carry out additional tests. Another riskis that the exact econometric specification laid out in advancedoes not describe the data as well as one that would have beenchosen ex post if the authors had first ‘‘let the data speak,’’ poten-tially leading to less precise estimates. Some of these risks can bemitigated, for example, by finalizing the set of outcomes afterproject implementation is completed (rather than before thestart of the project) or by specifying a detailed algorithm throughwhich the econometric specification will be determined later (e.g.,based on patterns observed in the control group) rather thanpredetermining the exact specification up front. Such approachesprovide the researcher with some degree of discretion and under-score the fundamental trade-off in the practical implementationof PAPs between flexibility and commitment.

It is tempting to advocate a purist position that rules out anyresearcher discretion to provide the strongest possible safeguardsagainst data mining, specification search, and other forms of ten-dentious reporting. This would entail specifying the completeplan in advance of program implementation and allowing no al-terations. Any flexibility introduces the risk of manipulation: for

discuss PAPs include Olken, Onishi, and Wong (2010), Schaner (2010), Rasmussen,Malchow-Møller, and Andersen (2011), Alatas et al. (2012), Finkelstein et al.(2012), and Humphreys, Sanchez de la Sierra, and van der Windt (2012).

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1777

Page 24: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

example, if a researcher observed that a treatment village hadexperienced a large exogenous shock (orthogonal to the programbeing studied, e.g., a new factory opened there with manyhigh-paying jobs), she could add outcomes to the analysis plan(e.g., wage earnings) and falsely claim that any gains were due tothe intervention itself. The countervailing concern is that rigidlyconforming to the PAP will stifle learning. Moreover, if the rulesgoverning the use of PAPs are too tight, many researchers mayresist their adoption, and the benefits they offer will not be rea-lized. Based on our experience, we advocate a compromise pos-ition that allows some researcher flexibility accompanied by the‘‘price tag’’ of full transparency—including a paper trail of exactlywhat in the analysis was prespecified and when, and public re-lease of data so that other scholars can replicate the analysis—with the hope that this approach will foster the greatest researchprogress.

We found that there are a great many decisions involved inwriting a PAP, and the economics profession has not yet agreedon a set of best practices. In an effort to further this discussion, wedescribe some of the trade-offs we faced, the choices we made, andthings we could have done better in writing and using a PAP. Wefocus on four issues: (1) the timing of writing and registering theplan, (2) defining the research hypotheses and outcome meas-ures, (3) the level of econometric and analytical detail to includein the plan, and (4) statistical adjustments for multiple testing.

Timing of PAPs. First is the question of timing, in particular,how early in the project and research implementation process thePAP should be written and archived. Many medical trials specifythe entire analysis plan—including all outcomes and control vari-ables—before the intervention or data collection have begun.Given that economic development programs are not typically ad-ministered with the same standardized protocols as drug regi-mens, we instead found it useful to follow a hybrid approachthat pinned down the general domains of likely impacts beforeproject implementation began, but fleshed out the exact outcomemeasures later on, before any analysis of the endline data. (Wearchived our PAP while data entry for the 2009 follow-up surveywas taking place; to make the design airtight, future scholarsshould ideally archive their PAP before follow-up data collectionhas even begun.) This approach has several concrete advantages.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1778

Page 25: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

Agreeing with the GoBifo project team to a precise, limited list ofobjectives in the October 2005 hypothesis document (which wasfinalized before baseline data collection had been launched orvillages had been randomized into treatment groups) mitigatedthe risk that, on finding no evidence of impacts on a set of out-comes X, the project’s managers or funders would claim that infact they had been seeking to impact a different set of outcomes Y.One concrete concern for us arose from the GoBifo project team’sinterest in effects on ‘‘social capital,’’ which we felt was not aprecisely defined concept, and thus risked later charges that wehad simply not selected the right aspects of social capital to study.

At the same time, the flexibility to expand the set of outcomesover the course of project implementation allowed us to incorpor-ate lessons learned during the baseline survey and the piloting ofthe SCAs, as well as respond to shifting emphases and implemen-tation issues in the GoBifo project. As an example, when asking inthe baseline survey how respondents would have the communityspend an amount of money comparable to the GoBifo grants, weomitted the response category of ‘‘business skills training,’’ whichwas not part of our understanding of CDD practice at the time.Such training ended up accounting for a nontrivial share of pro-ject grants (as mentioned), and thus the endline survey added aquestion to correct this omission. We believe it is appropriate toinclude in PAPs hypotheses that are generated while the projectis ongoing, including those arising from field observation.Importantly, though, we refrained from dropping any of the ori-ginal 2005 research hypotheses or outcome domains, with theview that documenting the absence of effects on areas that wereoriginally viewed as within the remit of the project would beuseful for the research community.

Another timing consideration is when to make the PAPpublic. Researchers may rightfully worry that PAPs include ex-tensive research design details and making them public immedi-ately would allow other scholars to copy novel insights andeffectively ‘‘scoop’’ the authors of the PAP by beating them topublication. One option to address this legitimate concern is tosimply include the PAP as a supplementary document when thepaper is submitted to a journal, so that referees can comparethe paper to the original analysis plan and then publicly releasethe PAP only on final journal publication. In our view, however,the increased transparency that comes from prior publicationof the PAP enhances the credibility of the process, and

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1779

Page 26: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

we asked the Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab to postthis study’s PAPs on their website before publication of thearticle.

There is a closely related set of issues around the benefits ofcreating public registries of planned trials and PAPs in the socialsciences (similar to the website http://clinicaltrials.gov) to helplimit publication bias. A main benefit of a public registry is thatit would make it more transparent to other scholars which studieshad been started on particular topics but for which papers werenever published. To the extent that these projects had registeredPAPs, there would also be a rich source of information on thedetails of how these studies were to be carried out, leading to abroader understanding of the field and enriched meta-analyses.In our view, it would thus be useful to set a ‘‘time limit’’—poten-tially up to several years—after which a registered PAP would bepublicly released even if the results were not yet published.

Defining the Hypotheses and Outcomes. This ability to accruenew hypotheses over time was the main aspect of our own re-search where flexibility (accompanied by transparency) wasmost useful. Specifically, the 2009 PAP includes one hypothesisnot included in the original 2005 document—regarding impactson social and political attitudes—that arose after observing andreflecting on program activities. We further split one 2005 hy-pothesis into two hypotheses in the 2009 document, separatingimpacts on public goods from other measures of collective action.While writing this article, we added a twelfth hypothesis (calledHypothesis 1 below) by pulling together project implementationoutcomes that had already been listed within the other hypoth-eses but were not explicitly specified as a distinct subgrouping inthe PAP. It is important to note that in making these adjust-ments, no new outcome measures were added or excluded fromthe final PAP list in what we present here. Those who wish toconsider only the results as exactly laid out ex ante can ignoreHypothesis 1. However, we feel that the absence of a project im-plementation hypothesis was an oversight on our part and findthe results of Hypothesis 1 useful to consider. For transparency,our main table of results (Table II) presents family-wise errorrate adjusted p-values for both the original grouping of 11 hypoth-eses and for the ex post expansion to 12 hypotheses. Moreover, wealso accommodate a ‘‘purist’’ approach by calculating the mean

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1780

Page 27: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

indices for only those hypotheses laid out in the 2005 documentand including only those measures collected in the baseline data.As we discuss shortly, the main results of this article are un-changed across these various approaches.

Perhaps more important is the fact that we grouped the vari-ous research hypotheses from the PAP into two distinct ‘‘families’’while writing the article, for ease of interpretation and to facili-tate links to theory. Although we did not specify these twofamilies beforehand, we believe that the groupings—the develop-ment ‘‘hardware’’ of project implementation, public goods and eco-nomic activity (family A), and the ‘‘software’’ of local collectiveaction (family B)—are compelling. Again, the reader is free toignore the two family-level indices and focus exclusively on thetreatment effects estimated for the hypothesis-level indices, aswell as the particular outcome measures. We disclose completeresults for all 334 unique outcome variables, including the exactsurvey question wording, in Online Appendix J.

An alternative and more sophisticated approach to accommo-date flexibility that we did not use but consider promising is pre-specifying an algorithm that researchers will use to makesubsequent judgments on the analysis that depends on informa-tion not available at the time the PAP is written. Such approacheshave already been employed in statistics (see van der Laan andRose 2011). As an illustration of the value of such an approach, wedecided not to include several outcome variables in the final 2009PAP that had minimal variance in the baseline data. For ex-ample, in attempting to gauge respondents’ knowledge of localgovernment activities, we dropped measures that turned outto be far outside the realm of our respondents’ experience.Specifically, after finding that fewer than 1% of respondents atbaseline knew exactly how much was collected in local taxesin their chiefdom section or the official proportion of that taxthat goes to chiefdom coffers versus elected local governmentofficials, we dropped both measures from the endline survey.Though we did not do so, it might have been preferable to includean explicit decision rule in the 2005 hypothesis outline documentto define the variance threshold (in the baseline data) that wewould use in deciding whether to exclude a variable from thefinal PAP.

We could similarly have specified a rule in the 2009 PAPto guide the ‘‘dropping’’ of new outcome measures (not collectedin the baseline survey, such as our SCAs) that fell short of a

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1781

Page 28: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

particular variance threshold or had a high nonresponse ratein the endline data. In a related approach, for example,Finkelstein et al. (2012) examined the distribution of outcomesin their control group endline data to identify and exclude binarymeasures with minimal variance, that is, with a mean very near 0or 1. They further used the control group data to determine themost relevant margins along which to collapse categorical vari-ables into binary measures and allowed the observed degree ofskewness in continuous variables to affect functional form choice.By contrast, in the analysis presented in this article, we did notdrop any outcome measures that had been specified in our 2009PAP, and are thus left with several where the proportion of posi-tive responses in the control group is sufficiently high to make theestimation of treatment effects largely uninformative—for ex-ample, whether the community held a meeting to discuss use ofthe tarp in SCA 3 (in Table V later), which took place in 98% ofcommunities.

Choosing the Optimal Level of Detail. Third is the issue ofthe level of detail to include in a PAP. These ex ante commitmentsare critical for preventing post hoc specification searching and togenerate appropriately sized statistical tests. To eliminate datamining, the final PAP defines both the sets of explanatory anddependent variables, as well as the precise specifications to test,including the set of interaction terms and population subgroupsused to explore heterogeneous treatment effects (Leamer 1974,1983). Our PAP specified that we would run the analysis bothwith and without covariates, on endline data only as well asincorporating baseline data where available, and at each of thenatural levels of aggregation in the data (individual, household,and village). One shortcoming of the approach we took in the 2009PAP is that we did not explicitly state which of these specifica-tions was our primary test and which others would serve as ‘‘ro-bustness checks.’’ If writing our PAP again, we would insteadselect a single econometric specification to be our main ap-proach—in this case, the most natural one would be the conser-vative approach of including minimal regression controls, usingendline data only and carrying out village-level analysis, whichwe focus on in Table II. Fortunately for us, the results in thisarticle are unchanged across different sets of controls, paneldata, and levels of aggregation (as shown in Table III), but in

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1782

Page 29: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

the future other scholars might prefer to eliminate such ambigu-ity from the PAP.

Accounting for Multiple Inference. Given the large numberof outcome variables we consider, the other key risk is overrejec-tion of the null hypothesis due to the problem of multiple infer-ence (Anderson 2008). Our plan thus first commits us to a meaneffects approach that reduces the effective number of tests weconduct by identifying in advance which outcome variables togroup together in testing a hypothesis (see O’Brien 1984; Kling,Liebman, and Katz 2007). Note that the credibility of the meaneffects approach depends critically on specifying in the PAPexactly which outcomes will be grouped under which hypotheses,lest the ability to reshuffle outcome measures across hypothesesopens up another avenue for tendentious reporting. Yet even witha mean effects approach, we are still testing multiple hypotheses,and so use the Westfall and Young (1993) free step-down resam-pling method for the family-wise error rate (FWER), the probabil-ity that at least one of the true null hypotheses will be falselyrejected (as detailed in Anderson 2008). The PAP again lendscredibility to this process by confirming that there were nohypotheses that were tested but excluded from the multiple test-ing adjustment. Grouping the hypotheses into two families, as wedo, also helps combat this issue by further reducing the number ofstatistical tests from 12 to 2, but because we did not specify thetwo families in the PAP, we place less emphasis on them.

Mean effects estimation and the accompanying FWER ad-justed p-value is the primary metric by which we evaluate a hy-pothesis. We also provide results for the outcome measuresindividually to provide a sense of their magnitude and economicsignificance. Online Appendix J lists three distinct p-values foreach particular outcome measure: (1) the ‘‘naive’’ or ‘‘per compari-son’’ p-value, which is appropriate for a researcher with an apriori interest in a specific outcome (see discussion in Kling,Liebman, and Katz 2007); (2) the FWER-adjusted p-values thatlimit the probability of making a Type I error for any specificoutcome within the hypothesis; and (3) the slightly less conser-vative false discovery rate (FDR)–adjusted p-values that limit theexpected proportion of rejections within a hypothesis that areType I errors (Benjamini, Krieger, and Yekutieli 2006;Anderson 2008).

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1783

Page 30: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

III.D. Econometric Specifications

Under each hypothesis, we evaluate specific treatment ef-fects using the following model:

Yc ¼ �0 þ �1Tc þ X 0c�þW0c�þ "c,ð1Þ

where Yc is an outcome (i.e., local school construction) in commu-nity c; Tc is the GoBifo treatment indicator; Xc is a vector of thecommunity-level covariates (controls); Wc is a fixed effect for geo-graphic ward, the administrative level on which the randomiza-tion was stratified; and "c is the usual idiosyncratic error term.Elements of Xc always include the two village-level balancingvariables from the randomization process—distance from a roadand total number of households—and our results are robust to theinclusion of additional control variables specified in the PAP,including an index of civil war violence, ethnolinguistic fraction-alization, and the historical extent of domestic slavery. The par-ameter of interest is b1, the average treatment effect. Asmentioned earlier, although some outcomes are measured atthe household (e.g., radio ownership) or individual level (e.g., pol-itical attitudes), the natural unit of analysis is the village becausesome measures are only collected at that level (e.g., the existenceof a village grain-drying floor) and we thus measure all variablesat this level, taking village averages as necessary. For the subsetof outcome variables that were collected in both the 2005 baselineand 2009 follow-up surveys, our results are robust to leveragingthe panel structure of the data.

As set out in the PAP, we assess the degree of heterogeneoustreatment effects by respondent gender, age, village remoteness,community size, war exposure, domestic slavery, and location ineach of the two study districts. As we do not find evidence forheterogeneous effects along these dimensions, for reasons ofspace we have excluded this discussion from the text (seeOnline Appendix K for details).

The mean effects index for a hypothesis captures the averagerelationship between the GoBifo treatment and the K differentoutcome measures grouped in that hypothesis. Following Kling,Liebman, and Katz (2007), estimation of the mean treatmenteffect: (1) orients each outcome so that higher values always in-dicate ‘‘better’’ outcomes; (2) standardizes outcomes into compar-able units by translating each one into standard deviation units(i.e., by subtracting the mean and dividing by the standard

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1784

Page 31: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

deviation in the control group); (3) imputes missing values at thetreatment assignment group mean; (4) compiles a summary indexthat gives equal weight to each individual outcome component;and (5) regresses the index on the treatment indicator as well asany control variables. This is the mean effects approach specifiedin our PAP and is what we present as our main results for all fullsample outcomes in Table II.

As discussed shortly, the results are robust to using alterna-tive index estimation techniques that were not specified in thePAP (Table III). The seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) ap-proach in Kling and Liebman (2004) accommodates item nonre-sponse (which is important when we extend the set of outcomes toinclude what we call ‘‘conditional outcomes,’’ those that depend onthe existence of a particular public good in the community andtherefore are only measured for a subset of observations) andallows a flexible combination of panel and endline only analyses.The results are also robust to the approach described in Anderson(2008) that weights each component by the inverse of the appro-priate element of the variance-covariance matrix (as measured inthe control group) to maximize the information captured in theindex. This approach ‘‘downweights’’ outcome measures that arehighly correlated with each other, addressing the concern that ineffect we may at times be repeatedly measuring the ‘‘same’’ out-come in a variety of slightly different ways under a givenhypothesis.

IV. Empirical Results

Column (1) of Table II presents a concise summary of themean effect results for all 12 hypotheses, grouped into the twooutcome families. Column (2) provides the corresponding naivep-value that does not account for multiple inference; the remain-ing columns adjust this p-value to control the FWER whenconsidering the hypotheses as a group, where the group is definedas the full set of 12 hypotheses (column (3)), and the 11 hypoth-eses in the 2009 PAP (column (4)).

The three hypotheses under family A are:

. ‘‘GoBifo creates functional development committees’’ (H1);

. ‘‘Participation in GoBifo improves the quality of localpublic services infrastructure’’ (H2); and

. ‘‘Participation in GoBifo improves general economic wel-fare’’ (H3).

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1785

Page 32: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EII

GOB

IFO

TR

EA

TM

EN

TE

FF

EC

TS

BY

RE

SE

AR

CH

HY

PO

TH

ES

IS

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Hyp

oth

eses

by

fam

ily

GoB

ifo

mea

ntr

eatm

ent

effe

cten

dex

Naiv

ep

-valu

eF

WE

R-a

dju

sted

p-v

alu

efo

rall

12

hyp

os

FW

ER

-ad

just

edp

-valu

efo

r11

hyp

osin

2009

PA

P

Fam

ily

A:

Dev

elop

men

tin

frast

ruct

ure

or‘‘h

ard

ware

’’ef

fect

sM

ean

effe

ctfo

rfa

mil

yA

(Hyp

oth

eses

1–3;

39

un

iqu

eou

tcom

es)

0.2

98

**(0

.031)

0.0

00

H1:

GoB

ifo

pro

ject

imp

lem

enta

tion

(7ou

tcom

es)

0.7

03**

(0.0

55)

0.0

00

0.0

00

H2:

Part

icip

ati

onin

GoB

ifo

imp

roves

the

qu

ali

tyof

loca

lp

ubli

cse

rvic

esin

frast

ruct

ure

(18

outc

omes

)0.2

04**

(0.0

39)

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

H3:

Part

icip

ati

onin

GoB

ifo

imp

roves

gen

eral

econ

omic

wel

fare

(15

outc

omes

)0.3

76**

(0.0

47)

0.0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

Fam

ily

B:

Inst

itu

tion

al

an

dso

cial

chan

ge

or‘‘s

oftw

are

’’ef

fect

sM

ean

effe

ctfo

rfa

mil

yB

(Hyp

oth

eses

4–12;

155

un

iqu

eou

tcom

es)

0.0

28

(0.0

20)

0.1

55

H4:

Part

icip

ati

onin

GoB

ifo

incr

ease

sco

llec

tive

act

ion

an

dco

ntr

ibu

tion

sto

loca

lp

ubli

cgoo

ds

(15

outc

omes

)0.0

12

(0.0

37)

0.7

38

0.9

80

0.9

81

H5:

GoB

ifo

incr

ease

sin

clu

sion

an

dp

art

icip

ati

onin

com

mu

nit

yp

lan

nin

gan

dim

ple

men

tati

on,

esp

ecia

lly

for

poo

ran

dvu

lner

able

gro

up

s;G

oBif

on

orm

ssp

ill

over

into

oth

erty

pes

ofco

mm

un

ity

dec

isio

ns,

mak

ing

them

mor

ein

clu

sive,

tran

spare

nt,

an

dacc

oun

table

(47

outc

omes

)

0.0

02

(0.0

32)

0.9

44

0.9

80

0.9

81

H6:

GoB

ifo

chan

ges

loca

lsy

stem

sof

au

thor

ity,

incl

ud

ing

the

role

san

dp

ubli

cp

erce

pti

onof

trad

itio

nal

lead

ers

(ch

iefs

)ver

sus

elec

ted

loca

lgov

ern

men

t(2

5ou

tcom

es)

0.0

56

(0.0

37)

0.1

34

0.6

64

0.6

67

(con

tin

ued

)

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1786

Page 33: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EII

(CO

NT

INU

ED)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Hyp

oth

eses

by

fam

ily

GoB

ifo

mea

ntr

eatm

ent

effe

cten

dex

Naiv

ep

-valu

eF

WE

R-a

dju

sted

p-v

alu

efo

rall

12

hyp

os

FW

ER

-ad

just

edp

-valu

efo

r11

hyp

osin

2009

PA

P

H7:

Part

icip

ati

onin

GoB

ifo

incr

ease

str

ust

(12

outc

omes

)0.0

42

(0.0

46)

0.3

60

0.9

13

0.9

14

H8:

Part

icip

ati

onin

GoB

ifo

bu

ild

san

dst

ren

gth

ens

com

mu

nit

ygro

up

san

dn

etw

ork

s(1

5ou

tcom

es)

0.0

28

(0.0

37)

0.4

50

0.9

13

0.9

14

H9:

Part

icip

ati

onin

GoB

ifo

incr

ease

sacc

ess

toin

form

ati

onabou

tlo

cal

gov

ern

an

ce(1

7ou

tcom

es)

0.0

38

(0.0

37)

0.3

01

0.9

13

0.9

13

H10:

GoB

ifo

incr

ease

sp

ubli

cp

art

icip

ati

onin

loca

lgov

ern

an

ce(1

8ou

tcom

es)

0.0

90*

(0.0

45)

0.0

45

0.3

15

0.3

22

H11:

By

incr

easi

ng

tru

st,

GoB

ifo

red

uce

scr

ime

an

dco

nfl

ict

inth

eco

mm

un

ity

(8ou

tcom

es)

0.0

10

(0.0

43)

0.8

16

0.9

80

0.9

81

H12:

GoB

ifo

chan

ges

pol

itic

al

an

dso

cial

att

itu

des

,m

ak

ing

ind

ivid

uals

mor

eli

ber

al

tow

ard

wom

en,

mor

eacc

epti

ng

ofot

her

eth

nic

gro

up

san

d‘‘s

tran

ger

s,’’

an

dle

ssto

lera

nt

ofco

rru

pti

onan

dvio

len

ce(9

outc

omes

)

0.0

41

(0.0

43)

0.3

48

0.9

13

0.9

14

Not

es:

Sig

nifi

can

cele

vel

s(n

aiv

ep

-valu

e)in

dic

ate

dby

+p<

.10,

*p<

.05,

**p<

.01.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nth

eses

.In

clu

des

fixed

effe

cts

for

the

dis

tric

tco

un

cil

ward

s(t

he

un

itof

stra

tifi

cati

on)

an

dth

etw

obala

nci

ng

vari

able

su

sed

inth

era

nd

omiz

ati

onp

roce

ss—

tota

lh

ouse

hol

ds

per

com

mu

nit

yan

dd

ista

nce

ton

eare

stm

otor

able

road

.T

hes

em

ean

effe

ctes

tim

ate

sare

lim

ited

toen

dli

ne

data

only

an

dth

efu

llsa

mp

lese

tof

outc

omes

that

excl

ud

esall

con

dit

ion

al

outc

omes

(i.e

.,th

ose

that

dep

end

onth

est

ate

ofan

oth

ervari

able

,e.

g.,

qu

ali

tyof

infr

ast

ruct

ure

dep

end

son

the

exis

ten

ceof

the

infr

ast

ruct

ure

).C

onst

ruct

ion

ofth

em

ean

effe

cts

ind

exin

colu

mn

(1)

giv

eseq

ual

wei

gh

tto

each

com

pon

ent

(fol

low

ing

Kli

ng,

Lie

bm

an

,an

dK

atz

2007)

as

spec

ified

inth

eP

AP

.F

am

ily-w

ise

erro

rra

te(F

WE

R)

ad

just

edp

-valu

esli

mit

the

pro

babil

ity

ofm

ak

ing

an

yT

yp

eI

erro

rsw

hen

con

sid

erin

gth

eh

yp

oth

eses

as

agro

up

,w

her

eth

egro

up

isd

efin

edas

the

fin

al

set

of12

hyp

oth

eses

orth

eor

igin

al

11

hyp

oth

eses

inth

ep

resa

naly

sis

pla

n(W

estf

all

an

dY

oun

g1993

free

step

-dow

nre

sam

pli

ng

met

hod

as

det

ail

edin

An

der

son

2008).

For

the

com

ple

teli

stof

all

vari

able

su

nd

erea

chh

yp

oth

esis

—in

clu

din

gth

eex

act

wor

din

gof

surv

eyqu

esti

ons

an

dtr

eatm

ent

effe

ctes

tim

ate

s—se

eO

nli

ne

Ap

pen

dix

J.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1787

Page 34: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EII

I

GOB

IFO

TR

EA

TM

EN

TE

FF

EC

TS

BY

HY

PO

TH

ES

IS,

AL

TE

RN

AT

IVE

SP

EC

IFIC

AT

ION

S

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Hyp

oth

eses

by

fam

ily

Cov

ari

an

cew

eigh

tin

g(A

nd

erso

n2008)

SU

Rap

pro

ach

(Kli

ng

an

dL

iebm

an

2004)

Incl

ud

ep

an

eld

ata

Incl

ud

efu

llse

tof

con

trol

s

Excl

ud

ere

pla

cem

ent

hou

seh

old

s(a

ttri

tion

)

Incl

ud

eco

nd

itio

nal

outc

omes

Res

tric

tto

2005

hyp

oth

eses

Fam

ily

A:

Dev

elop

men

tin

frast

ruct

ure

or‘‘h

ard

ware

’’ef

fect

sH

1:

Pro

ject

imp

lem

enta

tion

0.9

22**

0.7

00**

0.6

88**

0.6

95**

0.7

06**

0.4

71**

(0.0

56)

(0.0

52)

(0.0

63)

(0.0

55)

(0.0

56)

(0.0

58)

H2:

Loc

al

pu

bli

cse

rvic

es0.2

33**

0.2

03**

0.1

79**

0.2

06**

0.2

05**

0.0

99*

0.1

49**

(0.0

40)

(0.0

40)

(0.0

40)

(0.0

39)

(0.0

39)

(0.0

40)

(0.0

48)

H3:

Eco

nom

icw

elfa

re0.5

65**

0.3

71**

0.3

62**

0.3

62**

0.3

75**

0.2

71**

0.2

22**

(0.0

50)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

47)

(0.0

45)

(0.0

48)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

57)

Fam

ily

B:

Inst

itu

tion

al

an

dso

cial

chan

ge

or‘‘s

oftw

are

’’ef

fect

sH

4:

Col

lect

ive

act

ion

–0.0

43

0.0

16

0.0

38

0.0

11

0.0

14

-0.0

40

0.1

34*

(0.0

36)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

42)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

31)

(0.0

59)

H5:

Incl

usi

onof

vu

lner

able

gro

up

s0.0

00

0.0

01

0.0

02

0.0

00

0.0

04

0.0

15

0.0

67

(0.0

29)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

30)

(0.0

31)

(0.0

32)

(0.0

27)

(0.1

16)

H6:

Loc

al

au

thor

ity

0.0

50

0.0

56

0.0

51

0.0

52

0.0

39

0.0

53

-0.0

06

(0.0

35)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

33)

(0.0

70)

H7:

Tru

st0.0

39

0.0

42

0.0

47

0.0

36

0.0

48

0.0

28

0.0

21

(0.0

46)

(0.0

44)

(0.0

61)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

43)

(0.0

50)

H8:

Gro

up

s0.0

31

0.0

27

0.0

30

0.0

27

0.0

45

0.0

07

-0.0

48

(0.0

37)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

39)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

34)

(0.0

54)

H9:

Info

rmati

onabou

tgov

ern

an

ce0.0

17

0.0

37

0.0

28

0.0

31

0.0

45

0.0

33

0.0

97*

(0.0

38)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

40)

(0.0

36)

(0.0

37)

(0.0

35)

(0.0

43)

(con

tin

ued

)

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1788

Page 35: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EII

I

(CO

NT

INU

ED)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Hyp

oth

eses

by

fam

ily

Cov

ari

an

cew

eigh

tin

g(A

nd

erso

n2008)

SU

Rap

pro

ach

(Kli

ng

an

dL

iebm

an

2004)

Incl

ud

ep

an

eld

ata

Incl

ud

efu

llse

tof

con

trol

s

Excl

ud

ere

pla

cem

ent

hou

seh

old

s(a

ttri

tion

)

Incl

ud

eco

nd

itio

nal

outc

omes

Res

tric

tto

2005

hyp

oth

eses

H10:

Part

icip

ati

onin

gov

ern

an

ce0.1

60**

0.0

92**

0.0

84

+0.0

82

+0.0

88

+0.1

31**

0.0

88

+

(0.0

44)

(0.0

43)

(0.0

45)

(0.0

44)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

45)

(0.0

50)

H11:

Cri

me

an

dco

nfl

ict

0.0

41

0.0

10

0.0

27

0.0

14

–0.0

13

0.0

11

0.0

10

(0.0

48)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

54)

(0.0

43)

(0.0

42)

(0.0

39)

(0.0

68)

H12:

Pol

itic

al

an

dso

cial

att

itu

des

–0.0

11

0.0

40

0.0

40

0.0

35

–0.0

11

0.0

05

(0.0

44)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

41)

(0.0

44)

(0.0

46)

(0.0

37)

Not

es:

Sig

nifi

can

cele

vel

s(n

aiv

ep

-valu

e)in

dic

ate

dby

+p<

.10,

*p<

.05,

**p<

.01.

Rob

ust

stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nth

eses

.In

clu

des

fixed

effe

cts

for

the

dis

tric

tco

un

cil

ward

s(t

he

un

itof

stra

tifi

cati

on)

an

dth

etw

obala

nci

ng

vari

able

sfr

omth

eor

igin

al

ran

dom

izati

on—

tota

lh

ouse

hol

ds

per

com

mu

nit

yan

dd

ista

nce

ton

eare

stm

otor

able

road

.O

utc

omes

incl

ud

edp

erh

yp

oth

esis

vary

by

colu

mn

:co

lum

ns

(1)–

(5)

incl

ud

efu

llsa

mp

leou

tcom

eson

ly(1

84

un

iqu

eou

tcom

esin

tota

l),

colu

mn

(6)

incl

ud

esbot

hfu

llsa

mp

lean

dco

nd

itio

nal

outc

omes

(i.e

.,th

ose

that

dep

end

onth

est

ate

ofan

oth

ervari

able

,e.

g.,

qu

ali

tyof

infr

ast

ruct

ure

dep

end

son

the

exis

ten

ceof

the

infr

ast

ruct

ure

,334

un

iqu

eou

tcom

esin

tota

l),

an

dco

lum

n(7

)in

clu

des

63

un

iqu

eou

tcom

es.

Col

um

n(1

)w

eigh

tsea

chin

dex

com

pon

ent

by

the

inver

seof

the

ap

pro

pri

ate

elem

ent

ofth

evari

an

ce-c

ovari

an

cem

atr

ix(a

sin

An

der

son

2008)

wh

ere

the

matr

ixis

esti

mate

din

the

con

trol

gro

up

(zer

ore

pla

ces

an

yn

egati

ve

esti

mate

dw

eigh

ts).

Col

um

n(2

)u

ses

stack

edor

din

ary

least

squ

are

sou

tcom

e-by-o

utc

ome

as

inK

lin

gan

dL

iebm

an

(2004).

Col

um

n(3

)u

ses

the

Kli

ng

an

dL

iebm

an

(2004)

ap

pro

ach

inco

rpor

ati

ng

pan

eld

ata

wh

ere

avail

able

.C

olu

mn

(4)

use

sth

eK

lin

g,

Lie

bm

an

,an

dK

atz

(2007)

ap

pro

ach

wit

hth

efu

llse

tof

con

trol

vari

able

ssp

ecifi

edin

the

PA

P.

Col

um

n(5

)u

ses

Kli

ng,

Lie

bm

an

,an

dK

atz

(2007)

an

dex

clu

des

all

end

lin

esu

rvey

rep

lace

men

tin

div

idu

als

an

dh

ouse

hol

ds.

Col

um

n(6

)u

ses

Kli

ng

an

dL

iebm

an

(2004)

an

din

clu

des

outc

ome

mea

sure

sth

at

ap

ply

only

toa

subse

tof

obse

rvati

ons

(not

efi

ve

vari

able

sfr

omth

eP

AP

wer

eom

itte

dd

ue

toin

suffi

cien

tob

serv

ati

ons:

com

mu

nit

yfi

nan

cial

con

trib

uti

ons

top

erip

her

al

hea

lth

un

it,

pala

va

hu

t,m

ark

et,

an

dgra

inst

ore

(H2

an

dH

4)

an

dex

iste

nce

offo

otball

equ

ipm

ent

(H2))

.C

olu

mn

(7)

use

sK

lin

g,

Lie

bm

an

,an

dK

atz

(2007)

rest

rict

edto

the

hyp

oth

eses

wri

tten

dow

nin

the

2005

pre

pro

gra

md

ocu

men

tan

dto

full

sam

ple

outc

omes

incl

ud

edin

the

base

lin

e2005

surv

ey.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1789

Page 36: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

The positive and significant (at 99% confidence) mean effectestimate of 0.298 standard deviation units for family A(Hypotheses 1, 2, and 3) indicates that GoBifo achieved its mostimmediate objective of providing the organizational and financialmeans to encourage local public goods construction and smallenterprise development. Specifically, the coefficient onHypothesis 1 indicates that the program was well executed, per-haps more so than many other real-world projects: GoBifoincreased measures of local organization and linkages to facilitatecollective action by 0.703 standard deviations on average. Thisstrong implementation performance in turn led to immediate im-pacts on local infrastructure. The estimated mean effect of 0.204for Hypothesis 2 reflects positive effects on the stock and qualityof local public goods; while the 0.376 coefficient for Hypothesis 3reflects gains in general economic welfare. The mean effects esti-mates for the first three hypotheses are significant at 99% confi-dence across all p-value adjustments. Reflecting back on thetheoretical framework, these increases provide strong supportfor the prediction that the combination of lowering the marginalcost of public goods through grants, as well as reducing coordin-ation costs through the establishment of new institutions, led togreater public investment. The next question is how much of thiseffect was driven by changes in institutions, norms, and collectiveaction.

The nine hypotheses in family B include:

. ‘‘Participation in GoBifo increases collective action andcontributions to local public goods’’ (H4);

. ‘‘GoBifo increases inclusion and participation in commu-nity planning and implementation, especially for poorand vulnerable groups; GoBifo norms spill over intoother types of community decisions, making them moreinclusive, transparent and accountable’’ (H5);

. ‘‘GoBifo changes local systems of authority, including theroles and public perception of traditional leaders (chiefs)versus elected local government’’ (H6);14

. ‘‘Participation in GoBifo increases trust’’ (H7);

. ‘‘Participation in GoBifo builds and strengthens commu-nity groups and networks’’ (H8);

14. The PAP states: ‘‘this is not an explicit objective of the GoBifo project lead-ership itself, but it is a plausible research hypothesis.’’

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1790

Page 37: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

. ‘‘Participation in GoBifo increases access to informationabout local governance’’ (H9);

. ‘‘GoBifo increases public participation in local govern-ance’’ (H10);

. ‘‘By increasing trust, GoBifo reduces crime and conflict inthe community’’ (H11); and

. ‘‘GoBifo changes political and social attitudes, makingindividuals more liberal toward women, more acceptingof other ethnic groups and ‘strangers,’ and less tolerantof corruption and violence’’ (H12).15

The small and not statistically significant mean effect esti-mate for family B (Hypotheses 4–12), at 0.028 standard deviationunits (standard error 0.020) provides no evidence that the experi-ence of working together in GoBifo, and the introduction of newinstitutions and processes, durably changed the nature of localcollective action. The program’s democratic decision making and‘‘help yourself’’ approach did not appear to spill over into otherrealms of village life or persist into the postprogram period. Wefind no evidence that GoBifo led to fundamental changes in localcapacity to raise funds and act collectively outside of the project,the nature of decision making, the influence of women or youths,or a range of social capital outcomes. In the context of the model,these null results suggest that GoBifo did not permanently in-crease the benefits of civic engagement for marginalized groupsand that the organizing institutions established did not persist-ently reduce the fixed costs of collective action. Although this es-timate is close to being significant at traditional confidence levels,with a p-value of 0.155, it is very close to 0 and an order of mag-nitude smaller than the family A effect.

The results are robust to alternative specifications, includingthe Anderson (2008) reweighting mean effects approach(Table III, column (1)), the Kling and Liebman (2004) SURmean effects approach (column (2)), including panel specificationswhere the data is available (column (3)), including additional con-trol variables (column (4)), dropping endline survey replacementhouseholds to partially address attrition (column (5)), including‘‘conditional outcomes’’ that apply only to a subset of observations

15. Regarding hypothesis 12, the PAP notes: ‘‘this was not part of the original[2005] program hypotheses document but relates closely to GoBifo projectobjectives.’’

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1791

Page 38: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

(column (6)), and restricting the set of hypotheses and outcomesto those specified in the preprogram 2005 hypothesis document(column (7)).

IV.A. Family A: Development Infrastructure or ‘‘Hardware’’Effects

The first hypothesis focuses on project implementation andmeasures the extent to which GoBifo successfully establishedVDCs, helped communities draw up development plans andopen bank accounts, and created links between the villagesand their local government representatives. The first panel ofTable IV presents results for several outcomes under this hypoth-esis that demonstrated statistically significant treatment effects,where the first four ‘‘full-sample’’ outcomes apply to all commu-nities within the sample; the remaining three ‘‘conditional’’ out-comes in Panel A depend on the existence of public infrastructureand thus only apply to those communities that have the particu-lar good. Table IV reports unadjusted p-values that are appropri-ate for those with an a priori interest in the individual outcome;the corresponding FWER- and FDR-adjusted values are pre-sented in Online Appendix J.

Regarding interpretation, the treatment effect estimate inthe first row of Table IV indicates there was an increase of 40 per-centage points in the existence of a VDC. VDCs already existed inmany Sierra Leonean villages when GoBifo was launched, havingbeen introduced by humanitarian assistance groups during thewar-torn 1990s (Richards, Bah, and Vincent 2004). By the post-program period, this treatment effect led the proportion of treat-ment communities with a VDC to be nearly double that of thecontrols. The corresponding coefficient in the second row indi-cates that GoBifo increased the likelihood that a communitywas visited by a member of its WDC in the past year by 13 per-centage points. Row 3 shows a positive treatment effect on theexistence of village development plans by 30 percentage points,nearly a 50% increase on the base of 62% in the controls. Row 4reveals an increase in having a village bank account of 71 per-centage points, a nearly 10-fold increase. The household surveyalso asked whether a member of the WDC or district council was‘‘directly involved in the planning, construction, maintenance, oroversight’’ of local public goods. The positive and significant treat-ment effects on primary schools, grain-drying floors, and latrines

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1792

Page 39: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EIV

ILL

US

TR

AT

IVE

SE

LE

CT

ION

OF

ST

AT

IST

ICA

LL

YS

IGN

IFIC

AN

TT

RE

AT

ME

NT

EF

FE

CT

S,

FA

MIL

YA

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

Ou

tcom

evari

able

Mea

nin

con

trol

sT

reatm

ent

effe

ctR

obu

stst

d.

err.

N

Pan

elA

:H

yp

oth

esis

1:

pro

ject

imp

lem

enta

tion

Vil

lage

dev

elop

men

tco

mm

itte

e0.4

60.4

0**

(0.0

5)

235

Vis

itby

WD

Cm

ember

0.2

10.1

3*

(0.0

6)

234

Vil

lage

dev

elop

men

tp

lan

0.6

20.3

0**

(0.0

5)

221

Com

mu

nit

yban

kacc

oun

t0.0

80.7

1**

(0.0

5)

226

Alo

cal

pol

itic

ian

was

invol

ved

inm

an

agin

gth

ein

frast

ruct

ure

:P

rim

ary

sch

ool

0.4

20.1

8**

(0.0

6)

138

Gra

in-d

ryin

gfl

oor

0.2

40.1

3*

(0.0

6)

115

Latr

ine

0.2

20.1

6**

(0.0

4)

169

Pan

elB

:H

yp

oth

esis

2:

loca

lp

ubli

cse

rvic

esF

un

ctio

nal

trad

itio

nal

mid

wif

ep

ost

inth

eco

mm

un

ity

0.0

80.1

7**

(0.0

4)

235

Fu

nct

ion

al

latr

ine

inth

eco

mm

un

ity

0.4

60.2

1**

(0.0

6)

234

Fu

nct

ion

al

com

mu

nit

yce

nte

rin

the

com

mu

nit

y0.0

30.0

9**

(0.0

3)

236

Com

mu

nit

yto

oka

pro

pos

al

toan

NG

Oor

don

orfo

rfu

nd

ing

0.2

9–0.1

5**

(0.0

5)

229

En

um

erato

r’s

ph

ysi

cal

ass

essm

ent

ofco

nst

ruct

ion

qu

ali

ty(i

nd

exfr

om0

to1):

Pri

mary

sch

ool

0.5

80.1

1+

(0.0

6)

123

Gra

in-d

ryin

gfl

oor

0.3

80.1

6*

(0.0

8)

101

Latr

ine

0.2

70.1

8**

(0.0

5)

154

Pan

elC

:H

yp

oth

esis

3:

econ

omic

wel

fare

Tot

al

pet

tytr

ad

ers

invil

lage

2.4

30.7

0*

(0.3

4)

225

Tot

al

goo

ds

onsa

leof

10

4.4

50.5

7*

(0.2

4)

236

Hou

seh

old

ass

etsc

ore

–0.1

60.3

0**

(0.0

9)

236

Att

end

edtr

ad

esk

ills

train

ing

0.0

60.1

2**

(0.0

2)

235

Not

es:

Sig

nifi

can

cele

vel

s(p

erco

mp

ari

son

p-v

alu

e)in

dic

ate

dby

+p<

.10,

*p<

.05,

**p<

.01.

Tre

atm

ent

effe

cts

are

esti

mate

don

end

lin

ed

ata

only

.In

clu

des

fixed

effe

cts

for

the

dis

tric

tco

un

cil

ward

s(t

he

un

itof

stra

tifi

cati

on)

an

dth

etw

obala

nci

ng

vari

able

sfr

omth

eor

igin

al

ran

dom

izati

on:

tota

lh

ouse

hol

ds

per

com

mu

nit

yan

dd

ista

nce

ton

eare

stm

otor

able

road

.W

her

ein

dic

ate

d,

outc

omes

are

con

dit

ion

al

onth

eex

iste

nce

offu

nct

ion

al

infr

ast

ruct

ure

inth

eco

mm

un

ity.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1793

Page 40: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

suggest that GoBifo successfully led local politicians to increasetheir involvement in village projects, consistent with its objectiveof supporting the broader decentralization process.

Hypothesis 2 explores treatment effects on the quantity andquality of local public goods. When considering individual out-comes, the measures under Hypothesis 2 naturally form threesubgroups: those regarding the stock of local public goods, thequality of such goods, and community financial contributions totheir construction and upkeep. Regarding the stock, the firstthree rows of Panel B in Table IV present impacts for an illustra-tive sample of goods, where we find marked increases in the pro-portion of villages with a functional traditional midwife post by 17percentage points, latrine by 21 points, and community center by9 points.

The last three rows of Table IV, Panel B show positive GoBifoimpacts on the construction quality of three of the most commonpublic goods—primary schools, grain-drying floors, and la-trines—as determined through direct physical assessment byenumerators. These measures combine impacts from theGoBifo-funded infrastructure projects, as well as any effectsfrom better maintenance of existing infrastructure. However, asthere is no evidence that management practices did in fact changein treatment villages (as detailed shortly), the leading interpret-ation is that the positive impacts are being driven by the grants.

The final subgroup of outcomes concerns community finan-cial contributions to existing infrastructure, and these areomitted from Table IV because of a lack of statistically significanteffects. Combined with the negative and significant effect onwhether the community approached another NGO or donor forfinancial support (in Panel B), these provide suggestive evidencethat GoBifo funds may have served as a substitute for the com-munity’s own resources. At a minimum, they provide no evidencethat GoBifo grants served as a catalyst for additional fundraisingnor that project experiences encouraged participants to seek outfurther development assistance. The SCA findings discussedbelow reinforce this view.

Hypothesis 3 relates to general economic activity and house-hold welfare, because roughly a sixth of the grants were used tolaunch projects dedicated to job skills training or small businessdevelopment—such as carpentry and soap making—that, if wellimplemented, could translate into higher earnings. Along similarlines, another 40% of the grants went toward investments in

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1794

Page 41: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

agriculture and livestock, another common type of small businessinvestment. Moreover, GoBifo injected cash grants into very poorcommunities, and as with any assistance, a portion of the fundsare surely fungible.

The first two outcomes in Panel C of Table IV refer tovillage-level outcomes, where we see a 30% increase in thenumber of petty traders (0.7 more traders on a base of 2.4 inthe control group) and a 13% increase in goods locally availablefor sale. We also observe improvements in an asset ownershipscore (created using principal components analysis), where theunderlying assets include common household durables (e.g.,radios, mobile phones), amenities like drinking water sourceand sanitation, and the materials used in the dwelling’s roof,walls, and floor. The project tripled the proportion of respondentswho had recently participated in skills training: a 12 percentagepoint increase on a base of 6% in control communities. We find noevidence that the program impacted total household income (notshown), however, income is quite difficult to measure among sub-sistence farmers and the treatment effect estimate is relativelyimprecise.

IV.B. Family B: Impacts on ‘‘Software’’: Local Institutions andNorms for Collective Action

The positive treatment effects for outcome family A suggestthat investment in local public goods did increase substantiallyduring the project. To determine the role played by more effectivelocal institutions (rather than the block grants alone), we nextexamine postprogram outcomes after the block grants had beenspent. The first hypothesis under family B (Hypothesis 4) coversoutcomes relating to collective action and contributions to localpublic goods. The mean effect for this hypothesis is not statistic-ally distinguishable from 0 under any p-value adjustment (0.012standard deviations with a standard error of 0.037, Table II); ofthe 62 full-sample and conditional outcomes evaluated, only 7treatment effects are significant at 95% confidence, with 3 posi-tive in sign and 4 negative. The subset of outcomes relating to thematching grant opportunity (SCA 1) provides the most succinctand concrete illustration, as the ability to mobilize around a newopportunity, and raise funds for it, captures the essence of localcollective action. In the top panel of Table V we cannot reject zerodifferential take-up of the subsidized building vouchers: 62

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1795

Page 42: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

treatment (52%) and 64 control villages (54%) redeemed vouchersat local supply stores. Nor can we reject equality in the number ofvouchers redeemed across treatment and control areas.

Other outcomes under this hypothesis consider householdcontributions to existing local public goods, where we expandthe set of contributions to include labor, local materials, or foodfor project workers, yet continue to find no evidence of treatmenteffects. We also find no evidence for differences in contributions toseveral local self-help groups (i.e., rotating savings groups, laborgangs) or in financial support for community teachers. Last,while treatment villages were much more likely to have a com-munal farm, by 23 percentage points (significant at 99% confi-dence), we cannot reject that the total number of respondents intreatment areas who had worked on a communal farm in the pastyear was the same as in controls. This presents a telling exampleof how our results document a proximate effect of project activ-ities on a local organization established to capture that funding—that is, the subsidized provision of seeds and tools led to thecreation of a community farm—yet find no evidence that thesetranslated into lasting impacts on participation in that organiza-tion or changes in behavior.

These findings raise questions about GoBifo’s long-term im-pacts. Clearly, community members gained experience in work-ing together to implement projects over the nearly four years ofthe project. Yet we find no evidence that their GoBifo-specificexperiences lead to greater capacity to take advantage of newopportunities that arose after the program ended. Most strik-ingly, while GoBifo often created new structures designed to fa-cilitate local development by reducing organizational costs—theVDC, a development plan, a bank account, and a communalfarm—we do not find evidence that these structures left thembetter able to take advantage of the realistic matching grant op-portunity in SCA 1.

Hypothesis 5 in family B includes outcomes relating to thecivic involvement of socially marginalized groups. Because theinclusion of women and youth held great prominence inGoBifo’s objectives and facilitator operating manuals, it alsoreceived special attention in the data collection. Covering an ex-haustive battery of measures, the mean effect cannot be distin-guished from 0 and has a narrow confidence interval (seeTable II), providing no evidence of impacts on the role of womenor youth in local decision making or on the transparency and

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1796

Page 43: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EV

ILL

US

TR

AT

IVE

TR

EA

TM

EN

TE

FF

EC

TS,

ST

RU

CT

UR

ED

CO

MM

UN

ITY

AC

TIV

ITIE

S(S

CA

S)

(1)

(2)

(3)

SC

Aou

tcom

eM

ean

for

con

trol

sT

reatm

ent

effe

ctR

obu

stst

d.

err.

Pan

elA

:C

olle

ctiv

eact

ion

an

dth

ebu

ild

ing

mate

rials

vou

cher

sG

oBif

om

ean

effe

ctfo

rS

CA

1(1

7ou

tcom

esin

tota

l)0.0

00.0

0(0

.05)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sth

at

red

eem

edvou

cher

sat

bu

ild

ing

mate

rials

stor

e0.5

4–0.0

2(0

.06)

Aver

age

nu

mber

ofvou

cher

sre

dee

med

at

the

stor

e(o

ut

of6)

2.9

50.0

6(0

.35)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sth

at

hel

da

mee

tin

gto

dis

cuss

the

vou

cher

s0.9

8–0.0

5*

(0.0

2)

Pan

elB

:P

art

icip

ati

onin

the

gif

tch

oice

del

iber

ati

onG

oBif

om

ean

effe

ctfo

rS

CA

2(3

3ou

tcom

esin

tota

l)0.0

00.0

0(0

.04)

Du

rati

onof

gif

tch

oice

del

iber

ati

on(i

nm

inu

tes)

9.3

61.5

4(1

.12)

Tot

al

ad

ult

sin

att

end

an

ceat

gif

tch

oice

mee

tin

g54.5

13.5

7(2

.88)

Tot

al

wom

enin

att

end

an

ceat

gif

tch

oice

mee

tin

g24.9

91.9

8(1

.59)

Tot

al

you

ths

(ap

pro

xim

ate

ly18–35

yea

rs)

inatt

end

an

ceat

gif

tch

oice

mee

tin

g23.5

72.0

6(1

.32)

Tot

al

nu

mber

ofp

ubli

csp

eak

ers

du

rin

gth

ed

elib

erati

on6.0

40.2

2(0

.40)

Tot

al

nu

mber

ofw

omen

wh

osp

oke

pu

bli

cly

du

rin

gth

ed

elib

erati

on1.8

8–0.2

0(0

.22)

Tot

al

nu

mber

ofyou

ths

(ap

pro

xim

ate

ly18–35

yea

rs)

wh

osp

oke

pu

bli

cly

2.1

40.2

3(0

.24)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sth

at

hel

da

vot

ed

uri

ng

the

del

iber

ati

on0.1

00.0

7(0

.04)

Pan

elC

:C

omm

un

ity

use

ofth

eta

rpG

oBif

om

ean

effe

ctfo

rS

CA

3(1

8ou

tcom

esin

tota

l)0.0

0–0.0

3(0

.05)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sth

at

hel

da

mee

tin

gto

dis

cuss

use

ofth

eta

rp0.9

8–0.0

3(0

.02)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sth

at

stor

edth

eta

rpin

ap

ubli

cp

lace

0.0

60.0

5(0

.04)

Pro

por

tion

ofco

mm

un

itie

sth

at

had

use

dth

eta

rp(5

mon

ths

aft

erre

ceip

t)0.9

0–0.0

8+

(0.0

4)

Giv

enta

rpu

sed

,p

rop

orti

onof

com

mu

nit

ies

usi

ng

the

tarp

ina

pu

bli

cw

ay

0.8

60.0

2(0

.05)

Pro

por

tion

ofh

ouse

hol

ds

that

dir

ectl

yben

efite

dfr

omth

eta

rp0.5

7–0.0

1(0

.04)

Not

es:

Sig

nifi

can

cele

vel

s(p

erco

mp

ari

son

p-v

alu

e)d

enot

edby

+p<

.10,

*p<

.05,

an

d**

p<

.01.

Tre

atm

ent

effe

cts

esti

mate

don

foll

ow-u

pd

ata

.In

clu

des

fixed

effe

cts

for

the

dis

tric

tco

un

cil

ward

s(t

he

un

itof

stra

tifi

cati

on)

an

dth

etw

obala

nci

ng

vari

able

sfr

omth

eor

igin

al

ran

dom

izati

on:

tota

lh

ouse

hol

ds

per

com

mu

nit

yan

dd

ista

nce

ton

eare

stm

otor

able

road

.S

am

ple

size

vari

esbet

wee

n225

an

d236

for

all

outc

omes

inth

eta

ble

exce

pt

the

seco

nd

tola

st,

wh

ich

isco

nd

itio

nal

onh

avin

gu

sed

the

tarp

an

dh

as

N=

161.

Th

eS

CA

-wid

em

ean

effe

ctes

tim

ate

sfo

llow

Kli

ng

an

dL

iebm

an

(2004)

toacc

omm

odate

the

mix

ture

offu

llsa

mp

lean

dco

nd

itio

nal

outc

omes

.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1797

Page 44: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

accountability of decision making more generally. Of 82 distinctoutcomes, only 7 were significant at 95% confidence, with 4 posi-tive and 3 negative treatment effects.

Enumerator observations during SCA 2, when villages met todecide between salt and batteries, provide a clear illustration. InPanel B of Table V there is no evidence for treatment effects onthe total number of adults, women, and youths who attended themeeting or spoke publicly during the deliberation. On average, 25women attended these meetings, but just 2 of them made a publicstatement during the discussion about which item to choose. Theestimated difference between the number of women who spoke intreatment versus control communities is only –0.20 (std. err.0.22), and the proportion of males who spoke during the meetingremained twice as high as the proportion of females in the treat-ment villages, the same as at baseline. We similarly find no evi-dence of impacts on whether any smaller ‘‘elite’’ groups broke offfrom the general meeting to make the gift choice without broaderconsultation; the duration of the deliberation; or how democraticthe decision process appeared to the enumerators, for example, byholding a vote. These patterns are consistent with the data fromrespondent reports recorded immediately after the meeting ofhow the tarp allocation choice in SCA 3 was made, includingwhich individuals had the final ‘‘say’’ and to what extent the de-cision was dominated by local elites (i.e., village headmen andmale elders). Moreover, respondent opinions collected duringthe second 2009 follow-up survey reveal no evidence of treatmenteffects on reports about how decisions were made to distribute thesalt or batteries (SCA 2); how to use the tarp (SCA 3); whether toraise funds for the building materials vouchers, and if so, how tomobilize funds, which items to purchase, and how to manage anyconstruction (SCA 1).

Despite all of the effort in GoBifo to elevate the position ofwomen and youth, we do not observe any improvement in theirrole relative to older men in community decision making. Evenfor relatively low-cost actions like speaking up in meetings, wefind no evidence that the project translated into greater ‘‘voice’’for marginalized groups. In the context of the theory, this sug-gests a lack of persistent gains in the individual benefits ofparticipation for these groups and provides additional evidencethat the increase in public investment observed during projectimplementation was likely driven by the financial subsidy

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1798

Page 45: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

rather than fundamental changes in local institutions or de factopower.16

Hypothesis 6 (which we included in the PAP out of researchinterest but was not an official aim of GoBifo project manage-ment) asks whether by espousing more democratic ways of mana-ging local development, the project reduced the role of thetraditional chiefly authorities. Taking all outcomes together, wecannot reject a coefficient of 0 on the mean effect for Hypothesis 6(Table II). Many outcomes under this hypothesis estimate theextent to which the village head and elders dominated the SCAdecisions. Though we find variation in how these decisions aremade—at one extreme, in two villages the chief decided betweenthe salt and batteries in less than one minute without anyoneelse’s input, while at the other an open discussion lasted nearlyan hour and was followed by a formal vote—as mentioned, we findno systematic differences across treatment and control villages.

A leading explanation for the apparent lack of institutionalchange, with some support in the data, is that elites exerted sub-stantial control over the new organizations GoBifo created. As anexample, we find that traditional elites retained their leadershipof the VDC: in both treatment and control villages (for theroughly half of control communities with a VDC in 2009), approxi-mately 88% of VDC chairs are men, 87% are older than 35, and52% are traditional chiefdom authorities and elders. While par-ticipation requirements translated into some gains for women (a6.6 percentage point increase in the proportion female membersand a near doubling of the proportion of female treasurers, 57%versus 31%), we cannot reject that the representation of youthsremained at the same low level as in control areas (at 26%). Thesepatterns highlight a tension inherent in the CDD approach: lever-aging the capacity of existing institutions may be expedient forimmediate project implementation while simultaneously limitingthe likelihood of fundamental institutional transformation orchanges in de facto power for marginalized groups.

We therefore tested the related hypothesis that CDD mayenable local elites to capture a disproportionate share of economicbenefits by distributing the tarp (SCA 3) during the first 2009follow-up visit and observing how it was being used in the

16. However, we cannot rule out that the subsidy was particularly effective (i.e.,led to such notable increases in public goods) in part because of the project’s facili-tation and emphasis on participation and transparency.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1799

Page 46: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

unannounced visit five months later. Although the analysis findsno evidence of treatment effects on elite capture, it also revealsthat the level of elite capture is, perhaps surprisingly, relativelylow in the study communities. Panel C of Table V shows that forthe 90% of communities that had used the tarp by the time of thesecond visit, 86% had put the tarp toward a public purpose, suchas a communal rice-drying floor or local ceremony. The most ob-vious example of elite capture would be use of the tarp to patchthe roof of a single individual’s house, which happened in lessthan 3% of all villages. That said, only 6% of villages were storingthe tarp in a public place when not in use (with the vast majoritystoring it in the chief’s residence) and several communities hadnot yet used the tarp, suggesting a failure to agree on a use, therisk of future elite capture, or both.

The next three hypotheses explore proxies for ‘‘social capi-tal’’—self-expressed trust of others (Hypothesis 7), involvementin local groups and networks (Hypothesis 8), and access to infor-mation (Hypothesis 9)—emphasized alongside collective actionand inclusion in the official GoBifo project objectives (WorldBank 2004; GoBifo 2007). The analysis finds no evidence of treat-ment effects on social capital, with all three mean effects indicesindistinguishable from 0. Beginning with trust, the only signifi-cant effect is an increase in reported trust of NGOs and donorprojects: residents in treatment communities were 5.4 percentagepoints more likely to agree that NGOs or donors ‘‘can be believed’’(the closest Krio translation for trust) as opposed to you ‘‘have tobe careful’’ in dealing with them. There is no evidence for effectson the remaining 11 indicators, which include respondentself-reports on their trust for various groups and hypotheticalvignettes, such as entrusting money to a neighbor to purchasegoods on your behalf.

Enumerators asked respondents whether they were amember of a local self-help group (i.e., credit/savings group,school committee, women’s group, youth group, among others)and if so, whether they had attended a meeting and contributedfinancially or in labor in the past month (Hypothesis 8). We findno significant treatment effects on these indicators nor on othermeasures of local cooperation, such as whether the respondenthad helped a neighbor rethatch the roof of their house, atime-intensive activity that one cannot easily do alone.

There is also no evidence of treatment effects on households’access to information about local government or governance

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1800

Page 47: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

(Hypothesis 9). Among 21 outcomes, only 1—the proportion ofvillages visited by a WDC member, already discussed—showsstatistically significant effects. As examples, we fail to reject azero treatment effect for measures of how much respondentsknow about what the community is doing with the building vou-chers (SCA 1) and tarp (SCA 3), whether they can name theirdistrict council and chiefdom leaders, and their ability toanswer objective questions about how local taxes are collectedand used.

Although the mean effect index for participation in local gov-ernance in Table II (Hypothesis 10) is positive and statisticallysignificant if one considers the unadjusted p-value, this resultdoes not survive the FWER adjustments (columns (3) and (4)).It is also largely driven by the outcomes already discussed underfamily A (certain outcome measures are included under multiplehypotheses). Specifically, we find large impacts on the existenceof VDCs and village plans and increases in the oversight of localpublic goods by chiefdom authorities that mirror earlier resultson the involvement of local government representatives. There isno systematic evidence, however, of more active individual polit-ical engagement, such as self-reported voting or running for localoffice.

There is no evidence that the program affected the level ofcrime and conflict or the mechanisms through which they areresolved, leading to a zero mean effect for hypothesis 11(Table II). Of the 10 indicators considered, only one—the 2 per-centage point reduction in household reports of physical fightingover the past year—is significant at 95% confidence. While thenine null results suggest that project efforts to enhance conflictmanagement capacity may not have created lingering benefits, onthe positive side it provides some reassurance that the infusion ofexternal grant money at least did not appear to spark increasedconflict.

The twelfth and final hypothesis concerns the nature of indi-vidual political and social attitudes. The GoBifo program’s em-phasis on the empowerment of women and youth and thetransparency of local institutions, may have engendered a moreequitable or ‘‘progressive’’ outlook toward politics and societymore generally. Even if there are no changes in actual decision-making processes or local collective outcomes (as above), amarked change in expressed attitudes might still mean that the‘‘seeds’’ for future social change had been planted. Enumerators

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1801

Page 48: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

gauged attitudes using pairs of opposing statements, such as ‘‘Ascitizens, we should be more active in questioning the actions ofleaders’’ versus ‘‘In our country these days, we should have morerespect for authority,’’ and asking respondents which statementthey agreed with more. These paired statements capture re-spondent views on a diverse range of topics including the accept-ability of violence in politics (a particularly salient issue inpostwar Sierra Leone), domestic violence, youth and women inleadership roles, paying bribes, and coerced labor. Once again,there is no evidence of significant program effects, despite theconcern that social desirability bias might lead some respondentsto express views promoted by the program. The only significantimpact is a 4 percentage point increase in agreement with thestatement that young people can be good leaders. However,recall the lack of evidence that this change in opinions translatedinto more youths holding actual leadership positions on the VDCor to more youth participation in the SCA meetings. Attitudinalchange may be a necessary step toward changing future behavior,but almost four years of an intensive CDD program did not lead todetectable changes in a range of expressed attitudes.

IV.C. Robustness and Validity Checks

This section evaluates the robustness of the results. To start,we consider typical threats to randomized experiments.Fortunately, there were no problems with treatment noncompli-ance: all communities assigned to the treatment group receivedthe program and none of those in the control group participated.Respondent attrition rates are no different in treatment and con-trol areas. The baseline statistics presented in Table I and OnlineAppendix F suggest that the randomization process successfullycreated two groups of villages that were similar along a widerange of observables. Note further that the results are unchangedin panel analyses that use baseline data when available(Table III). Thus, for spurious differences between the twogroups to explain the positive impacts in family A, the treatmentgroup would on average have had to be on a different trajectorythan the controls, but there is no reason to believe this shouldsystematically be the case given the randomized research design.

We next consider reasons the treatment effect estimatesmight be underestimates. Given the moderate size of the grantsand the fact that villages were geographically spread out, we feel

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1802

Page 49: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

that spillovers from village-level interventions in treatment areasto control communities are unlikely. Of greater concern would bethe risk that the projects GoBifo simultaneously implemented atthe ward level systematically benefited the control group at theexpense of the treatment group. There was a separate pot of fund-ing for each ward that was allocated by the WDC (see SectionII.B). Bias could result if WDC members took into account theplacement of GoBifo village-level projects in deciding where tolocate the ward projects and targeted those areas that had notalready benefited, perhaps as a way of compensating them forlosing out on village-level assistance. However, there are nomeaningful differences in the targeting of ward-level projectsacross treatment and control villages; if anything, treatment vil-lages are slightly more likely to benefit (not shown).

A final concern is that the outcome measures were simplyinsufficiently refined to detect subtle decision-making, institu-tional, political, or social differences between treatment and con-trol communities. Although some of our measures are certainlybetter than others, our main strength lies in the diversity ofmeasures we use and the fact that they all produce similar re-sults. We combine different data-collection approaches, for ex-ample, employing both survey self-reports on the percentage offemale and male respondents who spoke during the SCA meet-ings with direct enumerator observation. The research teams alsogathered information from a variety of sources: they conductedinterviews in respondent homes, held focus group discussionswith key opinion leaders, observed a community decision as itunfolded, and recorded their own independent assessment ofthe construction quality of local infrastructure. Taking all thesedata together, the ‘‘zero’’ GoBifo program effects in family B arequite precisely estimated. To illustrate, the maximum true posi-tive treatment effect on the proportion of women speaking (in thesalt-versus-battery SCA 2 deliberation) that we may have incor-rectly ruled out at 95% confidence is one additional femalespeaker per every 4.3 villages we visited, which is quite small.In the mean effects analysis, which combines many outcomemeasures, confidence intervals are tighter still. As an example,the 95% confidence interval for the mean effect across all out-comes in family B is (–0.012, 0.068) measured in standard devi-ation units, which is a narrow interval containing 0. A Type IIerror that incorrectly failed to reject the null for either value

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1803

Page 50: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

bracketing this interval would lead us to overlook an effect ofnegligibly small magnitude.

IV.D. Alternative Interpretations and the Perils of Data Mining

Section IV.B shows that evaluating the institutional changeoutcomes jointly under their prespecified hypotheses generatesno evidence of program impacts. Yet without the discipline of thePAP and mean effects approach, we could have instead selectedan assortment of individual treatment effects to tell a range ofstories. Though such data mining poses a risk for any analysis, itmay be particularly problematic for assessing institutional out-comes. The multidimensionality of institutions—governing polit-ical, economic, and social behaviors—implies a large number ofoutcomes under family B, some of which will have statisticallysignificant treatment effects by pure chance. Moreover, becauseinstitutions are amorphous and contextually determined, there isno commonly agreed-on set of standard measures defining thecore of each domain, allowing the researcher to either deliber-ately or unintentionally ‘‘cherry pick’’ a set of treatment effectswhose selectively is difficult to detect from the outside.17

To underscore just how misleading such data mining can be,Table VI uses our data to construct two alternative interpret-ations—one negative, one positive—about GoBifo’s impacts oninstitutions.

The selective collection of negative treatment effects in thetop panel of Table VI suggests that the heavy emphasis placed onparticipation during GoBifo implementation activities created‘‘meeting fatigue’’ within treatment villages, which eventuallytranslated into poor management of local development projectsand political apathy. Specifically, respondents were less likely toreport that they had attended a meeting to decide what to do withthe tarp after the research teams had left the village. Tracing thisinitial backlash against participation through the course of thetarp SCA, we see that villagers were less likely to report that‘‘everyone had equal say’’ in deciding how to use the tarp, actually

17. By contrast, any study regarding the returns to education would by neces-sity focus on individual wages. Of course, even in the measurement of labor out-comes, the analyst retains considerable discretion over outcomes, for example, totalearnings, hours worked, occupation, employment sector, so issues of multiple test-ing and cherry picking are likely to also be relevant in domains other than the studyof institutions.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1804

Page 51: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

TA

BL

EV

I

ER

RO

NE

OU

SIN

TE

RP

RE

TA

TIO

NS

UN

DE

R‘‘C

HE

RR

YP

ICK

ING’’

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

Ou

tcom

evari

able

Mea

nfo

rco

ntr

ols

Tre

atm

ent

effe

ctR

obu

stst

d.

err.

NH

yp

o

Pan

elA

:G

oBif

o‘‘w

eak

ened

’’in

stit

uti

ons

Att

end

edm

eeti

ng

tod

ecid

ew

hat

tod

ow

ith

the

tarp

0.8

1–0.0

4+

(0.0

2)

236

H5

Ever

ybod

yh

ad

equ

al

say

ind

ecid

ing

how

tou

seth

eta

rp0.5

1–0.1

1+

(0.0

6)

232

H5

Com

mu

nit

yu

sed

the

tarp

(ver

ified

by

ph

ysi

cal

ass

essm

ent)

0.9

0–0.0

8+

(0.0

4)

233

H4

Com

mu

nit

yca

nsh

owre

searc

hte

am

the

tarp

0.8

4–0.1

2*

(0.0

5)

232

H5

Res

pon

den

tw

ould

lik

eto

be

am

ember

ofth

eV

DC

0.3

6–0.0

4*

(0.0

2)

236

H10

Res

pon

den

tvot

edin

the

loca

lgov

ern

men

tel

ecti

on(2

008)

0.8

5–0.0

4*

(0.0

2)

236

H10

Pan

elB

:G

oBif

o‘‘s

tren

gth

ened

’’in

stit

uti

ons

Com

mu

nit

yte

ach

ers

have

bee

ntr

ain

ed0.4

70.1

2+

(0.0

7)

173

H4

Res

pon

den

tis

am

ember

ofa

wom

en’s

gro

up

0.2

40.0

6**

(0.0

2)

236

H8

Som

eon

eto

okm

inu

tes

at

the

mos

tre

cen

tco

mm

un

ity

mee

tin

g0.3

00.1

4*

(0.0

6)

227

H5

Bu

ild

ing

mate

rials

stor

edin

ap

ubli

cp

lace

wh

enn

otin

use

0.1

30.2

5*

(0.1

0)

84

H5

Ch

iefd

omof

fici

al

did

not

have

the

mos

tin

flu

ence

over

tarp

use

0.5

40.0

6*

(0.0

3)

236

H6

Res

pon

den

tagre

esw

ith

‘‘Res

pon

sible

you

ng

peo

ple

can

be

goo

dle

ad

ers’

’an

dn

ot‘‘O

nly

old

erp

eop

leare

matu

reen

ough

tobe

lead

ers’

0.7

60.0

4*

(0.0

2)

236

H6,

H12

Cor

rect

lyable

ton

am

eth

eyea

rof

the

nex

tgen

eral

elec

tion

s0.1

90.0

4*

(0.0

2)

236

H9

Not

es:

Sig

nifi

can

cele

vel

s(p

erco

mp

ari

son

p-v

alu

e)in

dic

ate

dby

+p<

.10,

*p<

.05,

**p<

.01.

Tre

atm

ent

effe

cts

esti

mate

don

foll

ow-u

pd

ata

.In

clu

des

fixed

effe

cts

for

the

dis

ctri

ctco

un

cil

ward

s(t

he

un

itof

stra

tifi

cati

on)

an

dth

etw

obala

nci

ng

vari

able

sfr

omth

era

nd

omiz

ati

on(t

otal

hou

seh

old

san

dd

ista

nce

toro

ad

)as

con

trol

s.

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1805

Page 52: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

put the tarp to use, or be able to produce the tarp for inspection bythe survey team. This deterioration in community participationappears to have further manifested in declining civic engagementmore broadly, as evidence by decreased interest in holding localoffice (as a VDC member) and lower turnout in recent localelections.

The second panel of Table VI presents the opposite story:these treatment effects suggest that the positive experiences com-munities gained implementing GoBifo projects catalyzed othercollective activities and encouraged villagers to incorporate newdemocratic practices into other realms of decision making. Theseshifts in collective norms and behaviors in turn created space fornew leaders in the community and incited greater interest inpolitics more generally. More specifically, the outcomes in PanelB reveal gains in nonproject collective action, like increased train-ing for community teachers and a greater prevalence of women’sgroups. Broad adoption of the democratic norms promoted by theproject is evidenced by increased minute taking at communitymeetings, a greater likelihood of storing building materials in apublic place, and local chiefs playing a less dominant role inmanaging the tarp. Finally, the CDD experience instilled amore accepting attitude toward youths taking on leadershiproles and increased citizen awareness of national politics, asseen by the greater ability to correctly name the date of thenext general election.

These two plausible, opposite, and equally erroneous inter-pretations illustrate the risks of allowing researchers completediscretion to choose the subset of outcomes to highlight ex postand the potential value of employing a PAP.

V. Conclusion

This article evaluates a well-implemented program thatsought to provide public goods and change institutions in SierraLeone. Our evidence suggests that the intervention was success-ful in setting up new village structures, improving local publicgoods, and enhancing economic welfare. We do not, however, findevidence of lasting changes in village institutions, local collectiveaction capacity, social norms and attitudes, or the nature of defacto political power.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1806

Page 53: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

The results run counter to the currently popular notion inforeign aid circles that CDD is an effective method to sustainablycatalyze collective action and fundamentally alter local decisionmaking. There is no evidence that the establishment of local com-mittees, development plans, and bank accounts led to permanentreductions in the fixed organizing costs of collective action, likelybecause communities did not adopt and apply the new structuresto communal endeavors beyond the immediate project. Exposureto democratic project processes similarly did not make traditionalelites more willing to seek out the views of others in making com-munity decisions, nor were villages any better able to raise fundsin response to a matching grant opportunity. Whereas ‘‘good’’ in-stitutions may be critical for economic performance, our findingsprovide another piece of evidence that institutions and socialnorms are difficult to change. Consistent with this perspective,the related U.S. Community Action Program is thought to havehad at best limited success in achieving its ambitious goals:Germany (2007: 8) writes that ‘‘by the early 1970s, the ebullientvisions of the mid-1960’s had been discarded.’’

At the same time, our results challenge the aid pessimist’sview that external assistance cannot improve the lives of the poorin countries with ‘‘weak’’ institutions. We find that well-allocatedexternal aid can have a positive impact on welfare. Indeed, ourresults suggest that in this context, the comparative advantage ofthe World Bank and other donors may lie more in providing de-velopment ‘‘hardware,’’ and less in instigating institutional andsocial change, at least with current tools such as CDD.

The results further suggest that participation requirementsdid not foster learning by doing or demonstration effects largeenough to change attitudes, norms, or behaviors toward margin-alized groups. Despite requirements on the inclusion of womenand youth in project decision making and intensive facilitationdesigned to enhance their influence, nearly four years later wesee that women and youths are no more likely to voice opinionsabout how the community should manage new public assets.Returning to the comparison between informal interventionsfocused on reshaping norms, like the program studied here, andchanges to the rules of formal institutions, like female leadershipquotas, the existing evidence suggests that the latter may be amore effective way to alter de facto power dynamics and socialperceptions in a modest timeframe (Chattopadhyay and Duflo2004; Beaman et al. 2009). Importantly, however, we cannot

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1807

Page 54: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

rule out that part of GoBifo’s success in using grants to deliverpublic goods was due to its emphasis on transparency and theinclusion of marginalized groups during the program.

Our findings also resonate with the mixed CDD impactsdocumented in related research. In the Philippines, Labonneand Chase (2008) found that CDD increased participation in vil-lage assemblies and interaction between residents and villageleaders but did not initiate broader social change. Voss (2008)uncovered mixed impacts of the Kecamatan DevelopmentProgram in Indonesian household welfare and access to services.Focusing on roads constructed in the same program, Olken (2007)found that enhanced top-down project monitoring through gov-ernment audits was more effective in reducing corruption thanincreased grassroots participation in village-level accountabilitymeetings. Fearon, Humphreys, and Weinstein’s (2009, 2011) ran-domized evaluation of a Liberian community-driven postwar re-construction project found positive impacts on contributions to apublic goods game in one of two treatment arms, but no evidenceof program spillovers on contributions to existing public goods orspeaking up in meetings. Beath, Christia, and Enikolopov (2011)showed that an experimental CDD program in Afghanistan led tomoderate positive impacts on community economic well-beingand attitudes toward government, again with few impacts on col-lective action. Avdeenko and Gilligan (2012) found no CDD im-pacts on lab experiment public goods and trust games in Sudan.

Turning to empirical methods, this paper underscores theimportance of PAPs to limit data mining and generate appropri-ately sized statistical tests, and discusses some of the practicaltrade-offs we faced in implementation. We confront the funda-mental tension between researcher discretion versus commit-ment and argue that flexibility to explore questions that ariseas the research and project unfold is sometimes desirable yetshould only be exercised in tandem with complete transparencyover deviations from the ex ante specifications. In the context of aPAP, limited flexibility with full transparency allows the schol-arly community to make its own assessments about the credibil-ity of different results. We show how misleading an undisciplinedinterpretation of treatment effects can be in the absence of a PAPby constructing two opposing and equally erroneous narrativesbased on our data.

Because the results of this article concern one program in onecountry, any general policy implications are clearly speculative.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1808

Page 55: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

However, we can conclude with certainty that more research isneeded to identify the interventions that can successfully pro-mote inclusive collective action. Employing a PAP may enhancethe credibility of such pursuits.

Supplementary Material

An Online Appendix for this article can be found at QJEonline (qje.oxfordjournals.org).

STANFORD GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS

ABDUL LATIF JAMEEL POVERTY ACTION LAB

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY, AND NBER

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson, ‘‘The Colonial Originsof Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,’’ AmericanEconomic Review, 91, no. 5 (2001), 1369–1401.

Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson, ‘‘Persistence of Power, Elites, andInstitutions,’’ American Economic Review, 98, no. 1 (2008), 267–293.

Alatas, Vivi, Abhijit Banerjee, Rema Hanna, Benjamin A. Olken, andJulia Tobias, ‘‘Targeting the Poor: Evidence from a Field Experiment inIndonesia,’’ American Economic Review, 104, no. 2 (2012), 1206–1240.

Anderson, Michael L., ‘‘Multiple Inference and Gender Differences in the Effectsof Early Intervention: A Reevaluation of the Abecedaian, Perry Preschool,and Early Training Projects,’’ Journal of the American StatisticalAssociation, 103, no. 484 (2008), 1481–1495.

Avdeenko, Alexandra, and Michael J. Gilligan, ‘‘Community-Driven Developmentand Social Capital: Lab-in-the-Field Evidence from Sudan,’’ NYU workingpaper (2012).

Banerjee, Abhijit, and Lakshmi Iyer, ‘‘History, Institutions, and EconomicPerformance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,’’American Economic Review, 95, no. 4 (2005), 1190–1213.

Bardhan, Pranab, ‘‘Decentralization of Governance and Development,’’ Journal ofEconomic Perspectives, 16, no. 4 (2002), 185–205.

Beaman, Lori, Raghabendra Chattopadhyay, Esther Duflo, Rohini Pande, andPetia Topalova, ‘‘Powerful Women: Does Exposure Reduce Bias?’’ QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 124, no. 4 (2009), 1497–1540.

Beath, Andrew, Fotini Christia, and Ruben Enikopolov, ‘‘Winning Hearts andMinds through Development Aid: Evidence from a Field Experimentin Afghanistan,’’ MIT Political Science Department Research Paper No.2011–14 (2011).

Benjamini, Y., A. Krieger, and D. Yekutieli, ‘‘Adaptive Linear Step-Up ProceduresThat Control the False Discovery Rate,’’ Biometrika, 93 (2006), 491–507.

Bruhn, Miriam, and David McKenzie, ‘‘In Pursuit of Balance: Randomization inPractice in Development Field Experiments,’’ American Economic Journal:Applied Economics, 1, no. 4 (2009), 200–232.

Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger, ‘‘Time-Series Minimum-Wage Studies: AMeta-Analysis,’’ American Economic Review, 85, no. 2 (1995), 238–243.

Chambers, Robert. Rural Development: Putting the First Last. (London:Longman, 1983).

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1809

Page 56: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

Chattopadhyay, Raghabendra, and Esther Duflo, ‘‘Women as Policy Makers:Evidence from a Randomized Policy Experiment in India,’’ Econometrica,72, no. 5 (2004), 1409–1443.

Dal Bo, Pedro, Andrew Foster, and Louis Putterman, ‘‘Institutions and Behavior:Experimental Evidence on the Effects of Democracy,’’ American EconomicReview, 100, no. 5 (2010), 2205–2229.

Dongier, Philippe, Julie Van Domelen, Elinor Ostrom, Andrea Rizvi,Wendy Wakeman, Anthony Bebbington, Sabina Alkire, Talib Esmail, andMargaret Polski, ‘‘Community-Driven Development,’’ A Sourcebook forPoverty Reduction Strategies. vol. 1 (Washington, DC: World Bank, 2003),301–331.

Easterly, William. The White Man’s Burden: Why the West’s Efforts to Aid the RestHave Done so Little. (New York: Penguin, 2006).

Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff ‘‘Factor Endowments,Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth among New WorldEconomies: A View from Economic Historians of the United States,’’ InHow Latin America Fell Behind, ed. Steven Haber (Stanford, CA: StanfordUniversity Press, 1997).

Fearon, James, Macartan Humphreys, and Jeremy M. Weinstein, ‘‘DevelopmentAssistance, Institution Building, and Social Cohesion after Civil War:Evidence from a Field Experiment in Liberia,’’ Center for GlobalDevelopment Working Paper 194, 2009.

———, ‘‘Democratic Institutions and Collective Action Capacity: Results from aField Experiment in Post-Conflict Liberia,’’ Stanford University workingpaper, 2011.

Finkelstein, Amy, Sarah Taubman, Bill Wright, Mira Bernstein,Jonathan Gruber, Joseph Newhouse, Heidi Allen, Katherine Baicker, andthe Oregon Health Study Group, ‘‘The Oregon Health InsuranceExperiment: Evidence from the First Year,’’ Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 127, no. 3 (2012), 1057–1106.

Germany, Kent B. New Orleans after the Promises: Poverty, Citizenship,and the Search for the Great Society. (Athens: University of Georgia Press,2007).

GoBifo Project, ‘‘Operations Manual: Version 2 June 2007,’’ (Mimeo, 2007).———, ‘‘Results towards Goals and Objectives,’’ (Mimeo, 2008).Gugerty, Mary Kay, and Michael Kremer, ‘‘Outside Funding and the Dynamics of

Participation in Community Associations,’’ American Journal of PoliticalScience, 52, no. 3 (2008), 585–602.

Horton, R., and R. Smith, ‘‘Time to Register Randomized Trials,’’ British MedicalJournal, 319 (1999), 865.

Humphreys, Macartan, Raul Sanchez de la Sierra, and Peter van der Windt,‘‘Fishing, Commitment and Communication: A Proposal for ComprehensiveNonbinding Research Registration,’’ Political Analysis (2012), forthcoming.

Keen, David, and ‘‘Greedy Elites, ‘‘Dwindling Resources, Alienated Youths: TheAnatomy of Protracted Violence in Sierra Leone,’’ International Politics andSociety, 2 (2003), 67–94.

Kling, Jeffrey R., and Jeffrey B. Liebman, ‘‘Experimental Analysis ofNeighborhood Effects on Youth,’’ University working paper, 2004.

Kling, Jeffrey R., Jeffrey B. Liebman, and Lawrence F. Katz, ‘‘ExperimentalAnalysis of Neighborhood Effects,’’ Econometrica, 75, no. 1 (2007), 83–119.

Labonne, Julien, and Robert Chase, ‘‘Do Community-Driven DevelopmentProjects Enhance Social Capital? Evidence from the Philippines,’’ WorldBank Policy Research Working Paper 4678, 2008.

Leamer, Edward E., ‘‘False Models and Post-Data Model Construction,’’ Journalof the American Statistical Association, 69, no. 345 (1974), 122–131.

———, ‘‘Let’s Take the Con out of Econometrics,’’ American Economic Review, 73,no. 1 (1983), 31–43.

Mamdani, Mahmood. Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy ofLate Colonialism. (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996).

Mansuri, Ghazala, and Vijaynedra Rao, ‘‘Community-Based and -DrivenDevelopment: A Critical Review,’’ World Bank Research Observer, 19, no. 1(2004), 1–39.

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1810

Page 57: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

———, Localizing Development: Does Participation Work? (Washington, DC:World Bank, 2012).

Narayan, Deepa. Empowerment and Poverty Reduction: A Sourcebook.(Washington, DC: World Bank, 2002).

Neumark, David, ‘‘The Employment Effects of Recent Minimum Wage Increases:Evidence from a Pre-Specified Research Design,’’ NBER Working Paper No.7171, 1999.

———, ‘‘Evidence on Employment Effects of Recent Minimum Wage Increasesfrom a Pre-Specified Research Design,’’ Industrial Relations, 40, no. 1(2001), 121–144.

O’Brien, Peter C., ‘‘Procedures for Comparing Samples with Multiple Endpoints,’’Biometrics, 40, no. 4 (1984), 1079–1087.

Olken, Benjamin A., ‘‘Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experimentin Indonesia,’’ Journal of Political Economy, 115, no. 2 (2007), 200–249.

———, ‘‘Corruption Perceptions vs. Corruption Reality,’’ Journal of PublicEconomics, 93, nos. 7–8 (2009), 950–964.

———, ‘‘Direct Democracy and Local Public Goods: Evidence from a FieldExperiment in Indonesia,’’ American Political Science Review, 104, no. 2(2010), 243–267.

Olken, Benjamin A., Junko Onishi, and Susan Wong, ‘‘Indonesia’s PNPMGenerasi Program: Interim Impact Evaluation Report (World Bank, 2010).

Olson, Mancur. The Rise and Decline of Nations. (New Haven, CT: YaleUniversity Press, 1982).

Paluck, E. L., and D. P. Green, ‘‘Deference, Dissent, and Dispute Resolution: AnExperimental Intervention Using Mass Media to Change Norms andBehavior in Rwanda,’’ American Political Science Review, 103 (2009),622–644.

Pande, Rohini, ‘‘Can Mandated Political Representation Provide DisadvantagedMinorities Policy Influence? Theory and Evidence from India,’’ AmericanEconomic Review, 93, no. 4 (2003), 1132–1151.

Rasmussen, Ole Dahl, Nikolaj Malchow-Møller, and Thomas BarnebeckAndersen, ‘‘Walking the Talk: The Need for a Trial Registry forDevelopment Interventions,’’ Journal of Development Effectiveness, 3, no. 4(2011), 502–519.

Reno, William. Corruption and State Politics in Sierra Leone. (Cambridge:Cambridge University Press, 1995).

Richards, Paul. Fighting for the Rainforest: War, Youth and Resources in SierraLeone. (London: James Currey; Portsmouth, NH: Heinemann for theInternational African Institute, 1996).

Richards, Paul, Khadija Bah, and James Vincent, ‘‘The Social Assessment Study:Community-Driven Development and Social Capital in Post-War SierraLeone,’’ unpublished working paper commissioned for the NationalCommission for Social Action of the Government of Sierra Leone.

Rosener, Judy B., ‘‘Citizen Participation: Can We Measure its Effectiveness?’’Public Administration Review, 38, 5, 457–463.

Rosenthal, Robert, ‘‘The File Drawer Problem and Tolerance for Null Results,’’Psychological Bulletin, 86, no. 3 (1979), 638–641.

Sachs, Jeffrey D. The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time. (NewYork: Penguin, 2005).

Schaner, Simone. ‘‘Intrahousehold Preference Heterogeneity, Commitment andStrategic Savings: Theory and Evidence from Kenya,’’ MIT Working Paper,2010; http://econ-www.mit.edu/files/6221.

Sen, Amartya. Commodities and Capabilities. (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1985).———. Development as Freedom. (New York: Knopf, 1999).Simes, R. J., ‘‘Publication Bias: The Case for an International Registry of Clinical

Trials,’’ Journal of Clinical Oncology, 4 (1986), 1529–1541.Simmons, Joseph P., Leif D. Nelson, and Uri Simonsohn, ‘‘False-Positive

Psychology: Undisclosed Flexibility in Data Collection and Analysis AllowsPresenting Anything as Significant,’’ Psychological Science, 22 (2011),1359–1366.

United Nations, Human Development Report 2004. (New York: United NationsDevelopment Program, Oxford University Press, 2003).

RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS 1811

Page 58: RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID …emiguel.econ.berkeley.edu/assets/miguel_research/8/...RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE ON AID IMPACTS USING A PREANALYSIS PLAN* Katherine

van der Laan, Mark J., and Sherri Rose, ‘‘Targeted Learning: Causal Inference forObservational and Experimental Data,’’ Springer Series in Statistics. (NewYork: Springer, 2011).

Voss, John, ‘‘Impact Evaluation of the Second Phase of the KecamatanDevelopment Program in Indonesia, World Bank,’’ Jakarta ResearchPaper, 2008.

Westfall, P, and S. Young Resampling-Based Multiple Testing. (New York: Wiley,1993).

World Bank, World Development Report 2000/2001: Attacking Poverty.(Washington, DC: World Bank, 2001).

———, World Development Report 2003: Sustainable Development in a DynamicWorld. (Washington, DC: World Bank, 2003).

———, ‘‘Japan Social Development Fund Grant Proposal: Capacity Developmentto Strengthen Social Capital in Sierra Leone,’’ (Mimeo, 2004).

QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS1812