Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

40
Property Outline Fall 2009 I. What is Property? a. Property as a absolute right against the world versus property as as a collection of rights (bundle of rights) with content that varies according to context and policy choices b. Trespass to Land i. Any intentional intrusion that deprives another possession of land (even if only temporarily) ii. Jacque v. Steenberg Homes, Inc. 1. Facts: Easiest route to put up mobile home through P’s property, P denied multiple requests, fear of AP (irrational), D went through property anyways, no harm 2. Rule: a. Elements of Trespass: (1)must be intentional, the act (2) physically enter the property, (3)no harm necessary b. Right to exclude is a fundamental property right (categorical/essentialism view) 3. App/ Holding: harm in every trespass even if no damage to the land, it infringes upon the rights of the landowner to trespass. USSC precedent “one of the most essential sticks in the bundle of rights that are commonly characterized as property” Dolan v. City of Tigard. Nominal damages support punitive damages c. Trespass/Nuisance Divide i. Hinman v. Pacific Air Transport (Trespass) 1. Facts: D operates a commercial air line whose aircraft enter P’s airspace sometimes at low altitudes 2. Rules: a. No property right to airspace except so far as one may actually use (ad coelum doctrine impractical, absolute ownership of the sky would make flight impossible) b. Property as a bundle of rights varying in context according to the necessary policies of air travel (utilitarian/functionalist view) c. Type 3 Calebresi and Malamud Rule: Property Rule for the Defendant (see below) d. Dominion: Property, must be capable of exclusive possession. Without possession, no right can be maintained. Air and ocean are incapable of private ownership. Only possess it while you use it then reverts back to public domain 3. App/ Holding: Bundle of Sticks: property is a bundle of sticks enabling you to remove certain parts. Function of air travel outweighs exclusive right to airspace. ii. Hendricks v. Stalnaker (Private Nuisance) 1. Facts: Incompatible uses of the well and the septic system 2. Rules: a. Nuisance: anything which annoys or disturbs the free use of one’s property, or which renders its ordinary use or physical occupation uncomfortable b. Elements of private nuisance i. Intent (know or should know that something would interfere w/ use and enjoyment) ii. Harm (interference with use and enjoyment) iii. Interference must be substantial iv. Interference must be unreasonable: gravity of harm outweighs social value of the activity alleged to cause harm c. When Neither use unreasonable must balance the interests of the landowners 3. App/Holding: since the installation of the septic tank and the well were reciprocal nuisances so only one could stay. Although both parties have the intent to install their well or septic tank and they know it will substantially impair their neighbor’s use and enjoyment of each other’s land they determined that when balancing the two party’s interests, the septic tank was more unreasonable because it required drainage and therefore granted the injunction to the Stalnakers to keep their well . Balance owner’s competing interests. Here it is slightly in favor of the well. d. The Problem of Social Cost; Property and Equity i. Coase Theorem (search for efficient outcomes)

description

property outline

Transcript of Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

Page 1: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

Property Outline Fall 2009

I. What is Property?

a. Property as a absolute right against the world versus property as as a collection of rights (bundle of rights) with content

that varies according to context and policy choices

b. Trespass to Land

i. Any intentional intrusion that deprives another possession of land (even if only temporarily)

ii. Jacque v. Steenberg Homes, Inc.

1. Facts: Easiest route to put up mobile home through P’s property, P denied multiple requests, fear of AP

(irrational), D went through property anyways, no harm

2. Rule:

a. Elements of Trespass: (1)must be intentional, the act (2) physically enter the property, (3)no harm

necessary

b. Right to exclude is a fundamental property right (categorical/essentialism view)

3. App/ Holding: harm in every trespass even if no damage to the land, it infringes upon the rights of the

landowner to trespass. USSC precedent “one of the most essential sticks in the bundle of rights that are

commonly characterized as property” Dolan v. City of Tigard. Nominal damages support punitive damages

c. Trespass/Nuisance Divide

i. Hinman v. Pacific Air Transport (Trespass)

1. Facts: D operates a commercial air line whose aircraft enter P’s airspace sometimes at low altitudes

2. Rules:

a. No property right to airspace except so far as one may actually use (ad coelum doctrine impractical,

absolute ownership of the sky would make flight impossible)

b. Property as a bundle of rights varying in context according to the necessary policies of air travel

(utilitarian/functionalist view)

c. Type 3 Calebresi and Malamud Rule: Property Rule for the Defendant (see below)

d. Dominion: Property, must be capable of exclusive possession. Without possession, no right can be

maintained. Air and ocean are incapable of private ownership. Only possess it while you use it then

reverts back to public domain

3. App/ Holding: Bundle of Sticks: property is a bundle of sticks enabling you to remove certain parts. Function

of air travel outweighs exclusive right to airspace.

ii. Hendricks v. Stalnaker (Private Nuisance)

1. Facts: Incompatible uses of the well and the septic system

2. Rules:

a. Nuisance: anything which annoys or disturbs the free use of one’s property, or which renders its

ordinary use or physical occupation uncomfortable

b. Elements of private nuisance

i. Intent (know or should know that something would interfere w/ use and enjoyment)

ii. Harm (interference with use and enjoyment)

iii. Interference must be substantial

iv. Interference must be unreasonable: gravity of harm outweighs social value of the activity alleged to

cause harm

c. When Neither use unreasonable must balance the interests of the landowners

3. App/Holding: since the installation of the septic tank and the well were reciprocal nuisances so only one could

stay. Although both parties have the intent to install their well or septic tank and they know it will

substantially impair their neighbor’s use and enjoyment of each other’s land they determined that when

balancing the two party’s interests, the septic tank was more unreasonable because it required drainage and

therefore granted the injunction to the Stalnakers to keep their well. Balance owner’s competing interests.

Here it is slightly in favor of the well.

d. The Problem of Social Cost; Property and Equity

i. Coase Theorem (search for efficient outcomes)

Page 2: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Basics: In the absence of transaction costs parties will agree to maximize net wealth. Baseline entitlement

irrelevant; two parties will find the most efficient joint use of the resources (always most valuable use, come

to agreement that is mutually beneficial)

2. Extension of Coase: courts should try to resolve cases in the most efficient way. Almost amorally. In issues of

incompatible uses, courts should give entitlements to minimize transaction costs and be clear (parties will

negotiate in the shadow of the law)

3. Criticisms Entitlement matters, People don’t negotiating well (Jaque), holdouts, free-riders, lack of full

knowledge, Endowment effects (people overvalue what the own), Assembly problems (Hinman): can't expect

airlines to negotiate with everyone, bilateral monopoly issues (only one person to negotiate with), Assumed

awareness of the law

ii. Repeated Trespasses: Baker v. Howard County Hunt

1. Facts: Fox hounds trespassing on P’s small farm, scared chickens, bit wife, P shot at them. Trespasses not

continuance but part of the same course of conduct (foxhunting)

2. Rules: Injunctive relief granted; rights of landowner are paramount to County Hunt activities

a. Injunctions (P must usually satisfy the traditional requirements of equity to obtain injunctive relief)

i. Granting Injunction/ Maxims of Equity:

ii. No adequate remedy at law: damages are insufficient to deter or resolve issue. Action seriously

interferes with enjoyment

iii. Coming in with clean hands: Plaintiff hasn’t done something lawfully bad in return to defendant

3. App/Holding: Since damages won’t suffice in repeated trespass, and Baker has clean hands since he shot the

dogs only to protect his property and not out of maliciousness, the permanent injunction preventing the dogs

and hunt club from entering is granted.

e. Equitable Remedies

1. Types of Injunctions

a. Prohibitive: not do something

b. Mandatory: Do something

c. Declaratory (relief explaining exactly what the legal rights are in a circumstance)

2. Violation of an injunction: can be held in contempt (fine, misdemeanor, or jail)

f. Property and Equity

i. Building Encroachments

1. De minimis (trifling; so insignificant that a court may overlook it)(nominal damages only)

2. Pile v. Pedrick Bright Line Rule (categorical)

a. Facts: Poor survey; factory built intruding 1 and 3/8 inches onto P’s property beneath the surface; P

refused offer for party wall; P refused to collect damages on permanent trespass and insisted D take

down wall from D’s side

b. Rules:

i. Bright Line Rule=injunction to remove: “D has no right, at law or in equity, to occupy land that does

not belong to them”

ii. If a structure even accidently encroaches on the property of another, it can be ordered to be taken

down from the Ds side and bearing all the costs (categorical/essentialism)

iii. Good faith irrelevant

iv. Type 1 Calebresi Malamud Rule: Property Rule for the Plaintiff (see below)

c. App/Holding: Since the wall encroached on neighbors land, even by a couple inches, that still is an

encroachment and is prohibited. Grant injunction, Wall must be torn down and rebuilt on the correct

parcel of land.

3. Golden Press, Inc. v. Rylands (majority rule for good faith violators)

a. Facts: Foundation runs several inches under the surface onto D’s property

b. Rules Fact-Specific Adjudication:

i. Factors for determining whether to grant damages or injunction for removal:

1. Good faith: must act in good faith to have the possibility of paying damages rather than

mandatory removal of encroachment

Page 3: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

2. Degree of trespass: barely encroaches or not

3. Burden on Defendant to remove the encroachment: i.e. if a significant burden to remove

while encroachment is minimal

ii. Restatement of Torts: "Where defendant's encroachment is unintentional and slight, plaintiff's use

not affected and his damage small and fairly compensable, while the cost of removal is so great as to

cause grave hardship or otherwise make its removal unconscionable, mandatory injunction may be

properly denied and plaintiff relegated to compensation on damages."

iii. If encroachment is deliberate and constitutes a willful and intentional taking of another’s land, equity

may require its restoration regardless of the expense

iv. An unintentional encroachment may not warrant a mandatory injunction if the encroachment is

unintentional and slight (only damages) (utilitarian/functionalist)

v. Crystal clear rule turned to mud in fairness to “good faith violators” (liability rule)

c. App/ Holding: Since the neighbor got a survey and build the structure in good faith believing it was on

their land, the degree of trespass in very minimal as it is several feet below ground, and the burden of

removing the structure would be prohibitively expensive, the good faith violator must give just

compensate to the neighbor for the cost of the land where they intruded.

ii. Property Rules versus Liability Rules

1. Calabresi & Melamed (modes of protection for entitlements)

a. Property Rules (holder must consent before entitlement is transferred) supports injunctions

i. Must buy in voluntary transaction

ii. State lets parties decide how much entitlement is worth

iii. Works with Coase theorem

b. Liability Rules (only court can take away entitlement)(damages) supports damages

i. Cannot be transferred or destroyed by parties themselves

ii. Changes in entitlement decided by the state

iii. Covers high transaction costs

iii. Ex Ante/ Ex Post Problem

1. Ex ante: analysis of a situation before some critical event: determining fairness by policy concerns

a. Focuses on incentives and future conduct (aligns more closely with categorical view)

2. Ex Post: analysis of a situation after some critical event: thinking back about fairness and rights

a. Focuses on fairness and distributional concerns

b. Courts are naturally drawn to ex post because this is how controversies are presented to them (fact

specific, aligns more closely with functionalist view)

g. Restitution “unjust enrichment” (non-bargained-for benefits)

i. Elements

1. An enrichment of the D

2. At the expense of the P

3. Under circumstances that are unjust

ii. Windfall must be at the expense of the P

iii. The mistaken improver

1. Producers Lumber & Supply Co. v. Olney Building Co.

a. Facts: P mistakenly builds house on lot that he sold to D, negotiations failed, P razed house

b. Rule:

i. “It is only when a person places permanent improvements upon land belonging to another in a good

faith belief that he is the owner of the land, that he has any remedy”

ii. Normal remedies for good faith improvers (liability rule)(utilitarian/functionalism)

1. let the true owner keep the land and pay the encroacher its value (an equitable award of

restitution)

2. Transfer the lot to the encroacher for its fair market value

3. Sell the property at auction and divide the profits

Page 4: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

c. App/ Holding: Resorted to self-help and committed waste before a court of equity could determine the

rights of the parties (cannot come to court with “unclean hands” and seek the equitable remedy of

reimbursement for the amount he had enhanced the value of the lot) owed damages to the landowner

for full price of the home.

II. Original Acquisition (ways of acquiring property other than purchase or gift)

a. First Possession (new root of title)

i. When is first-in-time possession established? (point of capture) (VERY CONTEXT DEPENDENT)

1. Intent to control

2. Notice (physical demonstration of ownership)

3. Labor (Creation of Value) (Exploitation of Resource)(labor theory / Lockean)

ii. Wild Animals (rules of capture for wild animals is relevant to other natural resources; ex. oil and gas)

1. Pierson v. Post (1805)

a. Facts: P hunting fox with hounds; D w/ full knowledge of P intercepted fox killing and taking it

b. Rules:

i. Rule of Capture: Whoever mortally wounds/captures the fox owns the fox; Requires

a. deprivation of natural liberty;AND

b. certain control by their pursuer

ii. Mere pursuit did not establish a legal right (intent insufficient)

iii. Possession at the time of control or inevitable control (mortally wounding animal) (Exploitation of

Resource)

c. App/ Holding: Since D killed the fox and took it in his hands, he gained possession. P only gave notice

and had intent which is insufficient

2. Ghen v. Rich (1881)

a. Facts: Hunting fin-back whales w/ bomb-lances; sink and rise to the surface; whales identified later by

lance; customary finding fee; D took whale for himself and sold at auction

b. Rules:

i. Bomb-lance holds the whale: If you kill it with clear proof then its yours.

ii. Fast-fish, loose fish rule: whale goes to the salvager

iii. Factors to consider when determining which rule to use

1. General maritime law

2. Universal custom that doesn’t conflict with the law

3. Case is a very limited application

4. Industry will fail with rule changed

c. App/Holding: (utilitarian/functionalist view) Custom applies very narrowly to protect industry.

Considering the factors, the whaler has possession because w/o this rule the industry would fail.

3. Keeble v. Hickeringill (1809)

a. Facts: Keeble makes money from catching ducks and has a duck decoy system to catch them. Neighbor,

Hickeringill maliciously fires his gun on his own property near Keebles to scare his ducks away.

b. Rules:

i. Malicious Hindrance: Person who maliciously hinders another person in their trade or livelihood are

liable for hindering them (protect investment, net social worth considered)

1. P had no possession of ducks but was still a willful disturbance (social utility rationale)

ii. Fair Trade: People have the right to engage in their trade and law protects fair competition (setting

up competing business next door is ok)

iii. Benefits of fair competition:

1. more goods and services with better prices

2. wrong to purposely harm people without gaining anything

3. Protect activities that benefit social welfare

c. App/Holding: Keeble may recover for the disturbance but not for the damage by loss of fowl since it is

impossible to know the amount of ducks scared away.

iii. Salvage Claims

Page 5: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Abandoned or Lost Property

a. Property is abandoned when an owner manifests an intention to relinquish all future claims of

possession or ownership (I.e. having trees growing on a sunken ship)

b. Eads v. Brazelton (1961)

i. Facts: Riverboat w/ bars of lead abandoned; P marked area (buoys) and was called away; D placed

boat over and raised the metal. Knew the lead was abandoned because trees were growing on the

boat.

ii. Rules:

1. Elements of Possession: (labor)(exploitation of resource)

a. Due diligence: clearly positioning yourself to take it and diligently working towards

consumption (notice and intent insufficient)

b. Abandonment: owner relinquishes all claims

2. If not abandoned: Salvor: Person who salvages something owned and gets a generous

proportion of the value of the salvages without ever owning it

iii. App/Holding: Since the person who marked the spot and intended to take it did not exert due

diligence to take it, the lead belongs to the person who put in the effort.

2. Exploiting Minerals: Pedis Possesio

a. When exploring diligently and in good faith for minerals, exclusive right to work a given spot even before

he makes a discovery (labor theory)

iv. Splitting Entitlements: Popov v. Hayashi (2001)

1. Facts: Barry bonds hits record home run. Ball abandoned once left the field. Popov caught ball in his glove

when the mob assailed him. Ball rolled to the side where Hayashi peacefully standing took it and established

clear possession over the ball

2. Rules:

a. Split Entitlement

i. exclusive “pre-possessory interest” in being allowed to complete the catch without interference

ii. exclusive first unambiguous possession

b. Both have superior claim against the world; ball sold at auction and $ split

3. Caveat: Such decisions create wasteful and destructive racing behavior. First possession works best when a

clear winner can be declared at a stage when other competitors are unlikely to compete effectively.

4. App/ Holding: Both own equally b/c Popov would've had full possession if there was no interference from the

mob and Hayashi, not part of the mob first person to unambiguously establish possession. Sold the ball and

split proceeds equally (Equitable Division and Law of Finders)

b. Discovery; Johnson v. M’Intosh (1823) (chains of title to determine who has stronger claim)

1. Facts: Indians sold land to Johnson ancestor, later, Indians grant land to US. US sells to M’Intosh. Johnson sues

for ejectment of M’Intosh.

2. Rules:

a. Discovery: unique right to possess an unclaimed thing

b. Nomo Dat Non Quod Habet principle: can’t give what you don’t have. (When there are two competing

chains of title, you must keep going back until you see who has the earlier claim. Under this, Johnson

would win because he bought the land from the Indians before the US got it from the treaty)

c. Dominion, established by discovery/conquest trumps the right to occupancy of Native Americans

d. Labor theory of value: Possession through use and labor. Indians didn’t use the land by farming so no

dominion

a. Necessity: Must rule in this way or it would cause crazy problems and would uproot American property

system

b. Reasoning: 1) reliance upon history, 2) disruptiveness of resettling, 3) prudent to preserve court

legitimacy

3. App/Holding: Native Americans held incapable of transferring the absolute title of land to others because they

were mere occupants and not in possession of it.

c. Creation

Page 6: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

i. Information: International News Service v. Associated Press (1918)

1. Facts: INS obtaining AP news from legal sources (bulletin boards) and re-publishing it; East Coast AP news

published early on West Coast by INS. Suit for unfair competition and appropriation

2. Rules:

a. Information is a “nonrival” good

b. Primary reason for creating property rights in information is to provide incentives for producing more of

it, not to assure that it is allocated efficiently among potential users of it

c. Lockean / Labor Theory Example

i. Effort, expense, skill, and the just desserts

d. Relativity of title: Only INS enjoined (not a right against the world)

e. Common principle of competitors: each party is under a duty to conduct its business in a way that

doesn’t unfairly injure the other

f. No absolute property in the news: News “acquired by honest labor or lawful business is given the guard

of property”

3. App/Holding: “quasi” property because they are both selling it as such (postpones competition). Only INS

enjoined because proved that they were hurting AP. Rest of the world can still copy and print info.

4. Holmes Dissenting: No property in un-copyrighted combinations of words (categorical/essentialism)

d. Accession

i. Principle of Accession: doctrine where you acquire property that is intimately connected with objects that are already

our property, fruit of trees, offspring of cattle

ii. Doctrine of Accession: common law doctrine: someone mistakenly takes up a physical object that belongs to someone

else and transforms it through her labor into a fundamentally different object

iii. Doctrine of Increase: General rules absent agreement to the contrary, Offspring of Cattle (“the birth follows the

belly”)(partus sequitur ventrem) For domestic animals if you own the stock you own the offspring (Carruth)

iv. Accesssion: Wetherbee v. Green (1871) (action of replevin is retaking property)

1. Facts: Wetherbee cut down trees; thought trees were his; made barrel hoops; Green’s action for replevin to

get all the barrel hoops. Original wood worth $25, the hoops altogether cost $800

2. Rules: Elements to Determine ownership in Accession

a. Intent: Good faith/ bad faith distinction:

i. Bad faith: improved item must revert back to the original owner (categorical)

ii. Good faith: may keep if labor significantly improves item

b. Transformation of the object: Significance and Value to determine title (labor theory) (functionalism)

i. Labor insignificant and original object prominent--> title stays with original owner

ii. Labor prominent and original object insignificant--> title goes to improver

c. Factors in determining significance or prominence of improvement

i. Improver significantly multiplied the value of the original product (wood into a piano)

ii. Transformation of the product is of significant value or important to the improver (beam in a house

from unintentionally taken wood)

d. If title goes to improver: improver must pay damages equivalent to fair market value of the raw

material(pre-transformation) to the original owner (liability rule for good faith improver) (see Golden

Press)

3. App/Holding: Whetherbee took trees in good faith and the value of the improved object is 32 times the price

of the wood alone. Therefore the labor is prominent and original object insignificant, and so Wetherbee must

compensate Green for the cost of the trees but can keep the hoops

v. Accession in Patent Law

1. Minor improvement to original invention: infringe

2. Significant improvement to original invention: still infringe on patent but entitled to a patent of their own

3. Radical improvements: exempted from liability to the original patent owner regardless

vi. Ad Coelum Rule: Edwards v. Sims (1929)

Page 7: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Facts: Edwards discovers cave opening on his land, makes it a public attraction, neighbor sues for underground

trespass. TC: orders survey to determine boundaries of cave. Edwards requests Writ of prohibition of survey

order; cave possibly under Sims’ land; entrance on Edwards’ land

2. Rules:

a. Ad Coelum Rule: whoever owns the land owns to center of earth and to sky(categorical)

b. Rule: Unless there is prior division of estate, owner of land is entitled to free and unfettered control of

his own land above, upon, and beneath the surface.

3. App/Holding: Ad coelum applies (he who owns the surface owns cave rights directly underneath land) Survey

must follow through to determine bounds so that Edwards doesn’t trespass on Sims land underground.

4. Dissent: Only have rights to what you can subject to dominion or use. Since only Edwards can access the cave

since the entrance is on his land, he should own the whole cave regardless of whose land it is under.

(functionalism)(see Hinman)

e. Adverse Possession

i. When an owner sits on their right to exclude, and the statute of limitations for challenging the original unlawful entry

expires, original owner is barred from asserting the right to exclude and there is a new title in the adverse possessor

(evolved from statutes of limitations doctrine)

ii. The adverse possessor becomes the new true owner, and can exercise the right to exclude against all the world,

including the original owner

iii. Majority Rule for Adverse Possession: Lesee of Ewing v. Burnet (1837)

1. Facts: Man sells land twice, one owner possesses the land adversely and takes sues other owner to clear title.

P had older title; D lived across the street, paid taxes on lot, brought actions against trespassers, gave rights to

dig gravel; P stated that someday he wanted to reclaim lot

2. Rules:

a. Elements of Adverse Possession, must possess for the statute of limitations period, possession that is:

i. Actual: actually possession and asserting dominion over the land

ii. Exclusive: excludes the true owner

iii. Open and Notorious: giving notice to outside world and obvious you are claiming possession

iv. Continuous: consistent occupation throughout statute of limitations

v. Adverse: under a claim of right (i.e. no permission from owner)

b. Unnecessary Elements

i. No need for fence, building or other improvement

ii. Residence is unnecessary

iii. Use it for occupational purposes or cultivation

3. App/Holding: Since D actually, exclusively (TO didn’t visit land), Open and notorious (public acts of ownership

suffice: all the people in the area thought it was his), continuous for the whole stat of lims) and adverse under

a claim of right since he wasn’t technically the TO, so D now becomes TO.

iv. Rationales for Adverse Possession

1. Personhood: Possessor may have developed reliance on the property through long-standing possession.

Losing something that one has is relatively more painful than not getting something you don't own. (people

project more value on their property) (Holmes: Adverse possessor has connection w/land)

2. Penalty: designed to discourage true owners from "sleeping on their rights." Private property requires a

gatekeeper to protect the resource from abuse. If the gatekeeper fails their job, the resource may be looted as

an open access commons (lumber). Adverse possession seen as firing bad gatekeepers and replacing them

with more eager ones.

3. Efficiency; Reduces transaction costs: for determining title to assets that last a long time (like land) which can

accrue various potential claims. If you had to investigate every claim to title no matter how old, it would

impair the functioning of markets. Costs of proving or disproving claims invariably increase over time. Reduces

the transaction costs of determining title assets that last for a long time

v. Adverse Possession against the government

1. Presumption that adverse possession does not apply (high monitoring costs of public parks)

2. Historically government has treated squatters generously

Page 8: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

vi. The role of “good faith”: Carpenter v. Ruperto (minority rule of explicit good faith requirement)

1. Facts: Adverse possessor knowingly extended yard into neighbor’s cornfield, uses it as her own for 20+yrs.

Marginally improves it, (bad faith, always knew it wasn’t hers and sues to take possession via Quiet title action

(declaration of court of who owns what)

2. Rules:

a. Minority Rule: few states require Good faith in Adverse Possessors to gain title. Most states don’t care

about good faith or bad faith. (some even require bad faith)

b. Objective facts usually much more compelling than subjective intent for adverse possession

c. When knowledge of lack of title is accompanied by knowledge of no basis for claiming an interest in the

property, a good faith claim of right cannot be established. However courts sometimes look more

favorably on “good faith” actors in close cases.

3. App/Holding: Woman fulfills all elements of adverse possession, but her state (IA) requires Good Faith in

adverse possessors so she is denied.

vii. Tacking: Howard v. Kunto (1970)

1. Facts: Deeds of 3 properties did not correspond to where they built their summer houses, instead of

switching, they sue to take other’s land.

2. Rules:

a. Must Meet all Adverse Possession Requirements:

i. Sufficient Continuity: sufficient when the land is consistently occupied during certain times of the

year. Helps if there are permanent improvements on the land (i.e.home and dock)

b. Tacking: adding of one's own period of land possession to that of a prior possessor to establish

continuous adverse possession for the statutory period

c. General Tacking Rule: tacking of adverse possession is permitted if the successive occupants are in

"privity" (i.e. contractual relationship) (ex: sale, gift, running of deed between parties suffices)

d. By limiting tacking to situations in which successive Adverse Possessors are in “privity of estate” the

court permits tacking when A enters adversely and then sells to B who then sells to C

e. Tacking of adverse possession from previous owners is permitted if it was intended to be in the deed

and mistakenly omitted from the description (such as claiming more land than was in the deed)

3. App/Holding: Since owners occupancy their tract during summer months and created improvements upon the

land, that constitutes “uninterrupted” possession. Did actually, exclusively, open and notoriously, and adverse

under a claim of right too, so since all successive adverse possessors were in privity, can add all the years up to

get adverse possession.

viii. Disabilities

1. Typically, state statutes provide that the statute of limitations is tolled for owners suffering from certain

narrow classes of disabilities, including being under age, insane, legally incompetent or sometimes in prison at

the time the adverse possessor enters the property

a. Disabilities arising later usually do not affect the running of the statute

b. Disabilities in the same of successive owners cannot be tacked

2. Note: can’t adversely possess government property

f. Sequential Possession

i. Multiple persons serially claim property on some theory other than purchase or gift

ii. Property rights may be good against the world, but disputes over property usually take the form A v B, and courts

usually ask only as between A and B who has the superior title

iii. Good faith threshold may be crucial to injunction order (clean hands)(see Baker v. Howard County Hunt), or not to order

an injunction and use a liability rule (see Golden Press)

iv. Armory v. Delamirie (1722) (F1 v. C1) True owner versus finders versus converters (takers)

1. Facts: Chimney sweeper boy found a jewel and brought it to a jeweler to determine the value, the apprentice

took the jewels from the sockets and only returned the sockets.

2. Rules:

a. Finders rights subordinate to true owner but has more rights than anyone else

b. Finder may have legal duty to

Page 9: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

i. Not convert the object to the finder's own use; OR

ii. Deliver the object to anyone other than the true owner

c. Finder's title is a qualified: (does not become the owner)until the statute of limitations for recovery of

personal property runs out allowing the finder to claim title by adverse possession

3. App/Holding: jeweler must either return the jewel or the jury will determine what the most expensive jewel

that could fit in the socket would be and will find him liable for that amount

v. Clark v. Maloney (1840) (F1 v. F2)

1. Facts: P found pine logs floating in river, moored them, D took them claiming he found them in river. Action of

trover used to recover the value of personal chattels that are converted

2. Rules:

a. General Rule: first finder of chattel may keep the item against everyone but the true owner

b. For the First Finder to get the property back he must show the items were

i. His property; AND

ii. Converted by defendants to their own use

c. When not abandoned, loss of chattel does not change the right of property. So, previous owner has

more rights than subsequent finders or converters

3. App/Holding: P showed better title to the logs since he never abandoned them, so he may keep them against

all the world but the rightful owner

4. Rationale: desire to create a stable rule, splitting entitlement would create confusing precedent

vi. Anderson v. Gouldberg (C1 v. C2)

1. Facts: Two converters: both trespassing and cutting down third party logs. Coverter 1 takes trees and leaves

them outside, then converter 2 claims title. Converter 1 sues to get trees back.

2. Rules:

a. Even when a person wrongfully obtains property from another, the first converter still has better title to

the property than anyone else (including other takers) but still subordinate right ti the true owner

b. Complicated set of facts, court applies easy test: He who has better title/possession wins

3. Holding: even if a person wrongfully takes another’s property, the bad faith taker still has more right over the

chattel than any subsequent finders/converters other than true owner

III. Owner Sovereignty and its Limits

a. Protecting the Right to Exclude

i. Civil Actions

1. Developed out of writ system

a. Trespass (used to vindicate the interest that a person in actual possession has in exclusive possession of

land)

b. Ejectment (used to vindicate the interest of a person who has title to land against a person wrongfully in

possession)

c. Detunue (when P alleged unjustly detained specific goods which remained in the D’s possession)

d. Trover (to allege that D had wrongfully converted the P’s goods to his own use)

e. Replevin (originally used when a landlord seized personal property of the P for unpaid rent)

f. Trespass to chattels (when the D interfered or injured the property in some manner falling short of

conversion while it remained in the property of the P)

2. Principal actions for protection of personal property today are: replevin, conversion, and trespass to chattels

3. Intel Corporation v. Hamidi (2003)

a. Facts: D sent mass emails to Intel employees over the company intranet that complained of Intel’s bad

business and hiring practices. Intel unsuccessfully tried to block Hamidi but failed, so suing for injunction.

b. Rules:

i. Trespass to chattel requires injury to

1. the owner's right of possession

2. Harm the value of the personal property (i.e. computer)

Page 10: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

ii. Decisions finding electronic contact to be trespass to computer systems generally involve some actual

or threatened interference with the functioning of the computers. i.e. can prove he is sending

malware, viruses, or Trojans that materially harms computers, then likely can grant injunction.

iii. Theory of “impairment by content”: Some servers were able to sue spam companies because the

large amount of spam actually impaired the functioning of their servers (property) and were granted

injunctions App: no discernable difference in performance of Intel’s computers. So can’t succeed on

impairment

c. App/Holding: Intel retains its right to exclude people from their intranet, but they can’t get an injunction

without showing injury to the chattel or their possession of the chattel. No such thing as nuisance to

chattel

ii. Self-Help

1. Permitted to greater or lesser degrees to vindicate the right to exclude

2. Right to exclude ≠ Right to injunction

a. Courts are unlikely to order injunctions or other remedies that do not accomplish much (see Hamidi)

b. Courts are also unlikely to be too liberal with self-help remedies as they resemble lawlessness (see Berg)

3. A person in possession of property can generally use reasonable force to prevent or terminate an unlawful

entry or other trespass upon land or a trespass against moving property

4. Berg v. Wiley (1973)

a. Facts: D leased property to P for restaurant, reserved the right to retake possession should the lessee fail

to meet lease conditions; P broke lease; D locked P out when she left for the night and re-let the

property

b. Rules:

i. Majority Rule: landlord may rightfully use self-help to retake leased premises form a tenant in

possession without incurring liability for wrongful eviction provided 2 conditions are met

1. Landlord legally entitled to possession when a tenant holds over after the lease term or where

a tenant breaches a lease containing a reentry clause

2. The landlord's means of reentry are peaceful

ii. Minority Rule: self-help is never available and must use judicial process to dispossess a tenant who is

in possession and has not abandoned or voluntarily surrendered the premises

iii. Damages awarded to tenant for wrongful eviction: where LL either has no right to possession or

non-peaceably removed the tenant or both

c. App/ Holding: P did not abandon or surrender the property (so D’s entry was not peaceful). D could only

repossess by suit through judicial system.

5. Williams v. Ford Motor Credit Company

a. Facts: P’s ex-husband stops car payments; Repo men take Mustang in the middle of night w/ little

objection

b. Rules: In a repossession after default: a secured party may proceed to take collateral property without

judicial process if this can be done without “breach of the peace”

c. App/Holding: No “breach of peace” when P neither gives permission nor objects to repossession. Ford

had the right to take the care but ex-husband must reimburse ex-wife for cost of the car

b. Limiting the Right to Exclude (necessity, custom, public accommodation laws, and Antidiscrimination laws)

i. Necessity: Ploof v. Putnam (1908)

1. Facts: P caught on lake in sailboat during storm, moored on D’s dock, D’s servant unmoored the boat; crashed

on the shore destroying ship and injuring those onboard

2. Rules:

a. Necessity: an inability to control movements in the proper exercise of a strict right that justifies entries

upon land and interferences with personal property that would otherwise be trespasses (everyone bears

own loss) (functionalism) Shift in entitlement out of necessity (the ship-owner has a right [more than

privilege] to dock)

i. Animals: cannot be withdrawn instantly, allowed to trespass to drive off sheep as long as D does best

to recall dog

Page 11: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

ii. Highway obstruction: traveler may pass upon adjoining land out of necessity without being a

trespasser

iii. Save goods: may enter other's land to save goods from being destroyed by water or fire

iv. Save Human Life(special force): assaulted in peril may run through another's land, may sacrifice

other's property to save his and other's lives

3. App/Holding: Because of necessity to save life, P had the right to moor on D’s dock. Since D unmoored P and

caused P physical and material injuries, D must compensate P for all those damages.

ii. Vincent v. Lake Erie Transportation

1. D docked his boat through storm (Court held D was justified in docking but must pay for dock damage)

iii. Custom; McConico v. Singleton

1. Facts: D hunted on P's unimproved rural land with explicit prohibition from P.

2. Rules:

a. Custom: something well known and universally exercised for a long time, license may be implied from

habits of the country

i. When custom applies, trespass permitted, even with landowner protest

b. Posting Laws: peeps may hunt on rural land unless prominent sign prohibit

c. Fencing-In Laws: owner of livestock must fence in to protect neighbors

d. Fencing-Out Laws: landowners must fence out harmful livestock

3. App/Holding: No injury to land so customary regime of the right to hunt on unenclosed and uncultivated lands

holds

iv. Public Accommodations

1. Owners of public accommodations have a much more qualified right to exclude

2. Subject to a general duty of nondiscrimination among customers

a. Obligation to serve any person who requests service, provided it was available (cannot refuse service)

b. Must charge customers only reasonable rates for the services they provide

i. Different customers can be charged different prices as long as each fell within zone of reasonable

charges

3. Definition of “public accommodations” expanding (closely tied with Civil Rights Act)

a. Originally a very narrow list of business generally associated w/ travel (innkeepers, common carriers)

b. Often have some form of monopoly

4. Uston v. Resorts International Hotel, Inc. (1982)

a. Facts: D excluded P from their casinos for card counting

b. Rules:

i. Balancing the interests of the property owner and the patron (right to exclude versus the right to

access)

ii. General Principle: the more private property is devoted to public use, the more it must

accommodate the general public and less it can exclude

iii. Public Accommodations Duty: not to act in an arbitrary of discriminatory manner toward person who

come on their premises. Also usually duty to remove disorderly or otherwise dangerous people from

the premises

1. Applies to all property owners who open their premises to the public

iv. Exceptions (when public accommodators may exclude), i.e. disorderly, intoxicated

1. "disrupts the regular and essential operation of the premises"; OR

2. "threatens the security of the premises and its occupants"

c. App/Holding: Absent regulation making technique against the rules, cannot exclude P

5. State v. Schmid

a. Facts: Distributing literature on a private university campus

b. Rule: When a property owner opens their premises to the general public pursuant to their own

property interests, they have no right to exclude people unreasonably Weak right to exclude and strong

right to access

c. Holding: People may distribute literature if no rules specifically bans

Page 12: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

6. State v. Shack

a. Reversed trespass conviction of attorneys and social workers entering property to assist farm-workers

b. Strong right to exclude and a strong right to access

c. Holding: farm owners don’t’ have the right to exclude gov employees who provide health and legal

services to migrant workers

7. Brooks v. Chicago Down

a. “Expert handicappers” excluded from racing track

b. Market forces that preclude outrageous excess give weight to right to exclude over right to access

v. Anti-Discrimination Laws

1. Shelley v. Kraemer (1948)

a. Facts: Neighborhood agreement restricting occupancy to Caucasian race; 35 years later an African

American family is sold property in neighborhood w/o knowing of restrictive covenant. Neighbors sue.

b. Rules:

i. Judicial enforcement of discriminatory covenants between private parties constitutes government

action and is therefore barred by the Fourteenth Amendment (14th

Amendment: No state shall

make or enforce a law which shall abridge the privileges or immunities of US citizens, nor deny any

citizen of equal protection of the laws.)

ii. State action necessary for enforcement private agreement which would result in denial of equal

protection of the laws

iii. Excluding a trespasser does not have such an imposition on core property rights as ouster

c. App/Holding: Can have covenants on the deed but they are unenforceable b/c would constitute “state

action and violate 13th

amendment. Shelleys may stay.

2. Fair Housing Act: Civil Rights Act of 1968

a. Prohibits a range of discriminatory behaviors against members of protected classes:

i. Refusal to rent or sell

ii. To discriminate on terms

iii. To make or print notice or ad that shows discriminatory preferences (always applies, no exceptions)

iv. To discriminatorily claim unavailability incorrectly (lying about availability)

v. For profit, to attempt to induce any person to sell or rent discriminatorily

vi. To discriminate because of handicap of the renter, buyer, intended resident, or any association

b. Must be 1) Protected class, 2) qualified to rent, 3) try to rent, 4) denied, 5) with the property available

i. If the above is satisfied the burden shifts to the D to provide a legitimate, nondiscriminatory reason

c. Refusal to rent to a protected class at any moment counts as a violation.

i. Potential evidence: Rental history, interaction between LL and P i.e. reason for refusal, LL can negate

facts as a defense

d. Craigslist ad for roommate w/ gender preference hypo: falls under privacy and association rights

i. Fair Housing Act only enforceable within constitutional limitations

e. Exceptions

i. “Mrs. Murphy” exception: renting out a few rooms in a single family home where LL lives there too.

Home cannot be intended to have more than 4 single families.

ii. Religious organizations, private clubs, elderly communities

f. Ps under FHA May not need to show discriminatory intent and discriminatory effects suffice

g. 3 purposes of Antidiscrimination laws:

i. Increase housing opportunities for people in protected classes

ii. Eliminate indignity suffered

iii. Eliminate social message of inferiority

h. Attorney General v. Desilets (1994)

i. Facts: Strict Roman Catholic D refused to rent property to unmarried cohabitating couple

ii. Rules:

Page 13: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Marital Status is not necessarily a protected class: Some states have laws against unmarried

sex, and can conflict with religious rights. Married couples also get more benefits under law

than unmarried couples. Considered less important than other types of discrimination.

2. Balancing Test: Balance State interests against the nature of the burden on the D

3. Contextual framings of the benefits and burdens are crucial:

a. Discrimination against marital status (Majority Argument); Cohabitation (Dissent

Argument)

b. Renting apartments (Majority Argument); Free exercise of religion (Dissent Argument)

iii. App/Holding: There is a general state interest is the elimination of discrimination in housing based

on marital status. Commonwealth must show protecting cohabiting couples is more important that

D’s religious freedom. (unlikely for cohabiting couple to win)

c. Other Powers of the Sovereign Owner

i. Licenses

1. Closer to contract than to property (right between two parties and not beyond)(usually cannot get injunctive

relief, only damages)

2. ProCD Inc. v. Zeidenberg (1996)

a. Facts: P uses price discrimination in selling database; D bought restricted consumer version and resold

information in violation of the 3 shrink-wrap licenses inside. ProCD sues for injunction

b. Rules:

i. License is not copyright, so it isn’t a right against the world, but it is a contract between two parties

for the two bound parties to comply with the agreement. Has right to exclude people from certain

actions as per the license agreement.

c. App/Holding: ProCD may not use the consumer version and resell it, they must purchase the commercial

version if they wish to continue the internet business.

d. Limits on Owner Sovereignty

i. Abandonment

1. Considerations of social welfare may override owner sovereignty regarding the right to abandon property

2. Pocono Springs Civic Association, Inc. v. MacKenzie (1995)

a. Facts: D purchased vacant lot, couldn’t sell, tried to give property to D as gift, tried to sell again, stopped

paying taxes, wrote letter to abandon, P sued for community fees

b. Rules:

i. If a person DOESN’T have perfect title: Property is abandoned when owner has voluntarily

relinquished all right, title, claim, and possession with the intention of terminating ownership without

vesting it any other

ii. Traditional Rule: Real property cannot be abandoned (D had perfect title)

1. Fee simple absolute must be sold or transferred

2. Doctrine of abandonment only applies to imperfect titles

iii. Failure to possess land, pay taxes, or intention to abandon don’t matter

c. App/Holding: D has perfect title to the land so they cannot abandon and must continue to pay taxes

ii. Destruction: Everman v. Mercantile Trust Co. (1975)

1. Facts: Will directs expensive house in nice neighborhood to be razed upon death

2. Rules:

a. Destruction Rule: Person may be enjoined to stop destruction of property if (functionalism)

i. There is no good reason for the destruction; AND

ii. the act is against public policy

b. Acts are against public policy when: they have a mischievous tendency so as to be injurious to the

interest of the state apart from illegality or immorality

c. Courts will almost never order the destruction of property causing substantial loss in value

3. App/Holding: Since Will stated no good reason for the razing of the house, the state may intervene and

prevent the razing. Injunction to neighbors granted because would cause great loss in value to society.

iii. Transfer

Page 14: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Permits owner to shed gatekeeper responsibility

2. Two types

a. Quid pro quos (owner relinquishes title in exchange for a reciprocal transfer; ex. $$)

b. Gifts (owner relinquishes title in favor of another w/o explicitly receiving anything in return)

3. Lauderbaugh v. Williams (1962)

a. Facts: Lake Watagwa Association agreement to only sell to members (3 members can veto)

b. Rule:

i. Common law rule against restraints on alienation: Owner may not transfer property to another on

condition that the transferee will not retransfer

ii. Absolute restraints on alienation are void

iii. A limited and reasonable restraint may be valid

iv. Standardless, discretionary restraints on alienation are suspect b/c of the possibility of discrimination

(see Shelley)

c. App/Holding: Not enforceable: Restriction is unlimited in time is subject to the whim and caprice of the

Lake Assoc. member which could unjustly deprive Mrs. Lauderbaugh from alienating her land.

IV. The Forms of Ownership

a. Present and Future Interests in Land (see practice worksheets)

i. Freehold Possessory Estates (leases are non-freehold estates)

1. Fee Simple Absolute: complete ownership in real property. No natural end. Owner can designate a successor

owner (gift, sale, will), If owner died intestate, statute will designate

a. Language to signify “to A and his/her heirs”

i. A person does not have heirs until death (no interest while living)

ii. If language is ambiguous courts will assume fee simple absolute (unless it is clear that a lesser estate

was intended)

2. Life Estate: Limited duration (comes to a natural end with death of named person, usually the holder of the

estate)

a. Followed by a future interest in Remainder or Reverter

b. Language to signify “to A for life” (implied reverter); “to A for life then to B” (remainder to B)

c. Alienable by gift or sale (estate pur autre vie: life estate measured by named person’s lifespan)

i. New owner loses property right when named person dies

3. Fee Tail: Creates a nontransferable life estate to be followed by blood descendants until line ends

a. If A “dies without issue” the fee tail ends

b. Language to signify “to A and the heirs of his/her body”

c. Eliminated by statute in most states

4. Defeasible Fees (interests like a fee simple absolute except they may end on the happening of some named

contingency)(future interests become possessory when such contingency occurs)

a. Fee Simple Determinable: Fee simple ends automatically upon the occurrence of a named event, then…

i. Possibility of reverter: grantor or grantor’s successor gets property in fee simple

ii. Language to signify “to A as long as…” or “to A while…”

iii. (i.e. "O grants blackacre to VULS law school as long as it is used for in the instruction of law, then to

O")

iv. Stat of lims for adverse possession when event triggers

b. Fee Simple Subject to Condition Subsequent

i. Interest can be ended by the occurrence of a named event (not automatic, option of grantor)

1. Must be ended by action (self-help or lawsuit)

2. Power of termination (Grantor has right to reenter and take the premises via self-help or suit

ii. Language to signify “to A but if…” or “to A provided however…”

iii. "O grants Blackacre to VULS, but if it is not used for the instruction of law, then O has the right to

reenter and take the premise")

iv. Clock does not start for adverse possession but still cannot sleep on rights (laches, same as AP)

Page 15: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

c. Fee Simple Subject to Executory Limitation: upon named event, interest goes to a 3rd

party who has an

executory interest (either springing or shifting)

i. Language to signify “To A, but if… then to B” (executory interest to B)

ii. "O grants Blackacre to VULS as long as it is used for law instruction, then to Springfield Animal

Hospital.")

iii. No reversion to the grantor

ii. Future Interests (besides fee simple absolute, other estates do not continue indefinitely and create future interests)

1. Interests Retained by the Grantor

a. Reversion: rights go back to the grantor

i. Follows the natural end of a life estate or when the owner has not disposed of the entire fee

ii. If there is no other interest following a life estate the reversion goes to the original grantor

iii. Language to signify “to A for life” (implied reversion) (owner has not disposed of entire fee)

1. “O grants to A for life, then to O” Reversion to original grantor

b. Possibility of Reverter: interest reverts to grantor upon occurrence of built in limitation

i. Interest of the grantor reserved following a fee simple determinable

ii. Grantor gets back property automatically if the limitation is met

iii. Language to signify “O grants to A as long as… then to O”

1. If grantor dies, his successor will take (by will, intestacy, or sale)

c. Right of Entry / Power of Termination

i. Right of the grantor following a fee simple subject to condition subsequent

ii. Grantor has option to take action (nothing happens automatically)

iii. Language to signify “O grants to A but if… then O has the right to reenter and take”

2. Interests Created in Grantee (third party, not grantor)

a. Remainder: follows a life estate and remainder receives property in fee simple

i. Follows the natural end of a life estate (not to grantor)

ii. Indefeasibly vested

1. Identity of the takers is known

2. No other contingency

3. Language to signify “To A for life, then to B”

iii. Contingent: Uncertainty to the takers

1. Remainder is vested

a. If fails to vest in interest and no other interests then supporting reversion

2. Language to signify “To A for life, then to B if…” (interest is vested)

a. “To A for life, then to his children and their heirs” (uncertainty to the takers)

3. Vested Subject to Complete Defeasance: upon occurrence of a condition, interest can shift to

someone else. (Marge grants Blackacre "to Homer for life, then to Bart; but if Bart fails to

graduate from high school by age 19, then to Lisa") aka. "Condition subsequent" therefore, Lisa

has a "shifting executory interest"

4. Vested Subject to Open: Marge grants Blackacre "to Homer for life, then to his children and

their heirs" and at the time Homer is the father of Bart and Lisa, but not yet Maggie, so Bart

and Lisa are "subject to open" b/c Homer could have other children, therefore, Bart and Lisa

have "vested remainders subject to partial divestment" because with each additional child,

their interest is reduced from (1/2 to 1/3 to 1/4 etc) After Homer dies, Bart, Lisa, and Maggie

will own Blackacre in fee simple absolute

b. Executory Interest

i. An interest in a transferee (not retained by the grantor) that divests or cuts short a previous interest

ii. Language to signify “to A but if… then to B” (third party)

iii. Springing executory interest: if the executory interest divests an interest in the grantor (Marge

grants Blackacre "to Bart for life, remainder to Lisa 5 years after his death.") therefore, there is a

reversion to Marge that would be possessory during the 5 year gap after Bart's death. Lisa has

"springing" executory interest b/c it divests the reversion in the grantor (Marge)

Page 16: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

iv. Shifting Executory Interest: like above, but auto shifts to 3rd

party upon condition

3. Vesting

a. An interest vests in possession when the interest becomes a present possessory one

b. An interest can vest in interest before it vests in possession

b. Maintaining the System

i. Conservation of Estates

1. Whenever a transfer is made all of what the grantor had must be accounted for

2. Ensuring that all the pieces of the estate are accounted for as grantors often convey less than full interest

a. If a holder in fee simple dies without heirs the property escheats to the state (relatively rare)

3. Estate Planning

a. Williams v. Estate of Williams (1993)

i. Facts: Will provides estate to daughters during their lives, “and not to be sold during their lifetime”

and “if any one of them marry their interest ceases and the ones that remain have full control.” Each

daughter had 1/3 life estate defeasible and with an executory interest when the other daughters die

or marry and the successors have executory interest for taking care of their mom.

ii. Rules:

1. Rule of Construction: “language of a single sentence is not to control as against the evident

purpose and intent shown by the whole will” when a predominate purpose of the testator is

expressed, courts must to effectuate that purpose and to construe all subsidiary clauses as

subordinate to the main purpose.

2. Intent: function of construing a will is to ascertain and carry out the predominant purpose and

intent of the testator. very important in holographic wills (handwritten by testator)

b. App/Holding: Intent is clear b/c evidence that author was careful and thorough: GA devised life estates

to the 3 daughters. Evidence: “during their lives,” limits duration to their unmarried state, testator’s

purpose is accomplished after they marry or die then grantor intended his heirs to inherit thru intestate

succession

c. City of Klamath Falls v. Bell (1971)

i. Facts: Corporation conveyed land in gift to city for library; deed provided city should hold the land “so

long as” it complied with the condition (use as library), and if not ‘pass to Schallock and Dagget and

heirs.’ Executory interest violates RAP, replaced with possibility of reverter

ii. Rules:

1. Minority: some states rule that grantor may not alienate a possibility of reverter even if they

attempt to give 3rd

party an executory interest.

2. For Corporations: even if corp. dissolved, possibility of reverter remains and will go to

shareholders and their heirs.

iii. App: Deed created a fee simple determinable, executory interest violated rule against perpetuities

1. Grantors retained possibility of reverter (passed to heirs of shareholders)(same result)

2. A failed attempt by a grantor to transfer his possibility of reverter does not destroy it

3. Fit language into the limited menu (just because executory interest was impermissible does

not give city fee simple) (strike problematic language and reevaluate which form of ownership

still exists)

iv. Holding: For corps, must revert to shareholders. Only shareholders were the grantors, so it goes to

their heirs. Becomes fee simple determination w/ possibility of reverter

ii. Disclaimer

1. Gifts are only valid if accepted (it takes two to transfer)

2. No obligation to accept a property interest (potential recipient can refuse property)(goes to next interest)

iii. Numerus Clausus: catalog of estates is finite and closed. Property, unlike contract is not freely customizable by parties

but rather is standardized into a closed set of approved forms. (building blocks rationale)

1. Merrill and Smith; Conclusion: numerous clauses strikes a rough balance between the extremes of complete

regimentation and complete freedom or customization and this leads to a system of property rights that is

closer to being optimal than that which would be produced by either of the extreme positions.

Page 17: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

2. Three classes of people are affected by creation of idiosyncratic property right: (1)Originating parties

(participants who create the fancy), (2)potential successors, and (3) other market participants. People within

the zone of privity (1+2) have decided to take on the extra burden on the fancy but it creates problems for (3)

other market participants by disproportionally raising information costs. i.e. If Monday only watch exists, 3rd

parties must investigation for type of right they want, whether to repair it, and riskier (clouds on title may

exist).

3. Rationale: Limits confusion from new modes of ownership, prevents excessive fragmentation (too many veto-

wielding co-owners and holdout behavior will cause a resource to be underused) Limited menu of forms;

fewer bizarre property types; complicated conveyances are uniformly sorted

4. Johnson v. Whiton (1893)

a. Facts: Man wills property to 5 grandchildren, 4 have fee simple, one may have fee tail. All trying to

combine interest and sell. Sue to determine whether 1 has fee tail or not. Will conveys: “to my

granddaughter and her heirs on her father’s side”

b. Rules:

i. Fee Tail Rule: If it is obvious certain heirs got fee simple, even if it sounds like another heir got a fee

tail, it cannot be true and all have in fee simple since fee tails are illegal now and won’ t give fee tail

unless 100% clear

ii. “A man cannot create a new kind of inheritance” (granddaughter has fee simple absolute)

iii. Appears similar to a fee tail which has been abolished

c. Could have used precise vocabulary of the estate system to effectuate this conveyance

d. App/Holding: Fee tails are not recognized and can’t create a new form so it is a fee simple absolute and

they may sell it.

5. Garner v. Gerrish (1984)

a. Facts: Landlord leases premise to tenant. “for and during the term of quiet enjoyment from 1977 which

term will end—Gerrish has the privilege of termination *sic+ this agreement at a date of his own choice.”

Also, Landlord may reenter if rent not timely paid. Lease provides that lessee has power of termination

at the date of his own choice and landlord does not

b. Life Tenant Lease Rule: Lease which expressly and unambiguously granted to tenant right to terminate,

and did not reserve to landlord a similar right, does not create a tenancy terminable at will of either

party, but instead created a determinable life tenancy on behalf of tenant.

c. Holding: Since only T has the right to terminate, created a determinable life tenancy.

c. Mediating Conflicts Over Time

i. Waste: Brokaw v. Fairchild (1929)

1. Facts: Will conveyed 4 NYC mansions to each of 4 children in a life estate followed by contingent remainder in

other 3 mansions; son wants to raze untenable house and put up apartments (greatly increase value)

2. Rules:

a. Waste: any act of the life tenant which permanently injures the inheritance

b. General Rule for what life tenants (LT) may do: LT may do whatever is required for the general use and

enjoyment of his estate as he received it btu may NOT exercise acts of ownership such as demolition. LT

may erect new edifice so long as they do not materially injure any existing improvements to the land. Or

can change the property so long as they change it back before the tenancy expires.

c. Ameliorative Waste: Increases market value but permanently changes property

d. Only those with future interests can sue for waste (indefeasibly vested remainders or reversions)

e. Waste can be affirmative or dismissive (damage from failure to repair may constitute waste)

3. App/Holding: Materially changing the nature of the building considered waste whether the value of the

property is enhanced by the alteration

ii. Valuation of Interests

1. An amount in C in the future equals the present value P times the discount factor r, applied for the requisite

number n of time periods, i.e. C = P(1+r)^n

a. or in reverse from a future nominal amount to calculate the present discounted value, i.e. P=C/(1+r)^n

2. Value of future interest depends on the life expectancy of the life tenant

Page 18: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

iii. Restraints on Alienation

1. General: Courts do not usually uphold determinable fees that restrain alienation (limit transferability)

2. Mountain Brow Lodge No. 82, Independent Order of Odd Fellows v. Toscano

a. Facts: Deed reads: “said property is restricted for the use and benefit of the second party, only; and in

the event the same fails to be used by the second party or in the event of sale or transfer… *then to

grantor]”

b. Restraint on alienation is void, but language is disjunctive and land use restriction is valid

i. Created a fee simple subject to condition subsequent w/ regards to land use (w/ reverter)

c. App/Holding: Valid to restrict the use of land, even if such restriction hampers or even completely

impedes alienation. But can’t restrict the sale of land. So Mountain brow lodge can sell the land ,but

they are still the only people who can use it.

3. Courts may permit restraints on land even if they impede transferability

a. Often look to marketability

i. Damages/Injunction v. Forfeiture

1. Forfeiture remedy has hugely negative impact on whether a property is marketable

ii. Number of potential buyers potentially affected

1. Restrictive small universe of potential buyers under clause will likely be deemed invalid

iii. Surrounding land restrictions (In Toscano, property used as parking lot for lodge)

iv. Improvements

1. Does a restriction disallow improvements on the property

v. Charity exception (limited transferability from charity to charity often excepted)

iv. Rule Against Perpetuities (see practice worksheets)

1. Purpose is to prevent Dead Hand Control

2. Strict Rule: “No interest is good unless it must vest, if at all, not later than 21 years after some life in being at

the creation of the interest”

3. Step 1: RAP only applies to the following interests: (1)contingent remainder, (2)executory interest,

(3)remainder subject to open. DOES Not apply to vested interests or interests retained by the grantor:

reversion, possibility of reverter, power of termination

4. Step 2: look through the pool of possible measuring lives: anyone alive and affects vesting at the time the will

is created

a. RAP lasts up to 21 years after the death of the measuring person. If the interest does not definitely vest

within that time, its void

b. Includes a child born after measure person’s death if they were already conceived, and Measuring

people can’t be subject to open

c. Interest is void if the burden of keeping track of measuring lives is too great (to my heirs after the death

of last person in NY phone book

5. Step 3: choose one person as the validating life. Make sure that w/ crazy scenario, all interests vest w/I RAP

(unborn widow, fertile 80 yr old, after born wife.

a. Measuring lives: Do not have to be specifically mentioned in deed, can be implied in the grant, may not

have any special connection to the property (ex. “living heirs of Queen Victoria”)

b. Solution: insert “perpetuities savings clause”: refers explicitly to the possibility of invalidation under the

Rap and specific a backup plan

6. Step 4: if a invalid clause exists, rewrite the will by striking out the bad part and adding a possibility of reverter

to O at the end

7. Exception: doctrine of cy pres: saves gifts to charity from RAP or wastefulness by substituting a similar charity,

also ok w/ Rap if executory interest from one charity to another.

8. Examples of Rule Against Perpetuities

a. O devises “to A for life, then to B if B survives A.” Rule does not apply; A has a life interest and B has a

contingent remainder in fee simple absolute. O’s heirs have a reversion interest (if B does not survive A).

Page 19: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

b. O conveys “to A so long as the property is used for commercial purposes, then to B.” Rule against

Perpetuities renders B’s contingent interest void because it is unknown how long the property will be

used for commercial purposes.

c. O conveys “to A for life, then to B.” O is 93 and in poor health, A is 10 years old. Rule does not apply and

ages are not important; A has a life estate and B has a vested remainder in fee simple absolute.

d. O conveys “to A for life, then to A’s first child to reach 25.” At time of conveyance, A has one child, age

24. Rule applies and renders the interest in A’s children void because A’s first child could die and A could

die, making it conceptually possible that the interest might not vest within A’s life plus 21 years. A has a

life estate, and A’s first child has a contingent remainder.

e. O conveys “to A upon A’s marriage to B.” Rule does not apply because the uncertainty will be resolved

within A’s life plus 21 years. O has a fee simple subject to A’s springing executory interest; A has a

springing executory interest in fee simple absolute

9. Merger rule

i. “O grants to A for life” and then O separately conveys his reversion to A

ii. Courts hold that conveyances can be merged (this would be a fee simple)

10. Limiting Future Interests

a. Rule in Shelley’s Case: At common law, if the same instrument created a life estate in A and gave the

remainder only to A’s heirs, the remainder was not recognized, and A took the life estate and the

remainder. Most jurisdictions have abolished this rule.

i. Effectively abolished Fee Tails

b. Doctrine of Worthier Title: A remainder in the grantor’s heirs is invalid and becomes a reversion in the

grantor. E.g., if O grants Blackacre “to B for life, then to the heirs of O,” B has a life estate, and O has a

reversion, not O’s heirs. This doctrine is generally treated as a rule of construction (i.e., it does not apply

if intent to create remainder in heirs has been clearly manifested). It applies only to inter vivos transfers

(not wills), and only if the word “heirs” is used. It is not recognized in many jurisdictions.

c. Destructibility of Contingent Remainders: At common law, a contingent remainder was destroyed if it

failed to vest before or upon the termination of the preceding freehold estate. Not widely recognized

V. Co- Ownership and Conflicts Between Co-Owners

a. Co-Ownership

i. Tenancy in Common: separate but undivided interest. Separate: independently descendible, conveyable, and devisable;

No right of survivorship; Undivided: each tenant in common must have the right to possess the whole property. No

requirement of equal share. 80, 15,5. (usually presumed unless otherwise specified)

1. ex. (C and D and E are tenants in common and D dies, D’s interest goes to D’s heirs)

2. Creating tenancies in common: Easiest to create (“To A&B” (they do not have to have the same interests) “to

A&B in common to A for life, to B 1/8 interests”)

ii. Joint Tenancy: Same as tenancy in common but also includes right of survivorship: surviving joint tenants automatically

acquires the interest of other joint tenants that die (can’t will to heirs until last survivor has fee simple). Therefore, the

last joint tenant alive owns in fee simple.

1. Requires (4) units at creation:

a. (1) Time: each interest must vest at the same time,

b. (2) Title: each must acquire title by the same instrument or adverse possession (never intestate

succession),

c. (3)Interest: each must have the same legal interest in the property (fee simple, life estate, lease, but not

same fractional share),

d. (4) Possession: each must have the right to possess the whole.

i. Any joint tenant can sever the joint tenancy (sell it for $1 and buy it back so that it is a tenancy in

common) (one party can unilaterally change the form of the ownership this way)

1. To get the unities and joint tenancy back, cotenant has to sell and buy back as a joint tenancy

2. Ex. (C and D and E, D dies, D’s share dissolves and the other joint tenants assume a half portion)

Page 20: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

iii. Tenancy by the Entirety: only for married couples, each owner has a separate and undivided interest, and possession of

the whole, also includes right of survivorship. But, neither spouse can transfer or encumber their share without the

consent of the other. No unilateral exiting. (5 requirements: up+ marriage)

iv. Community Property: for married couples in South and West. All property acquired during the marriage automatically

becomes community property. Each spouse has the right to possess community property and may transfer property in

and out with the other’s consent. Property acquired before the marriage is separate, but may become community

property.

a. Partition (most important legal remedy available to concurrent owners) (usually not used for future interests… see waste)

v. Each cotenant has an automatic right to terminate a co-tenancy at any time

1. Partition in Kind: Division of physical property according to the parties’ respective interests

a. Owelty (payment to correct imbalances in a partition in kind

2. Partition by Sale: Division of proceeds according to the parties’ respective interests

vi. Delfino v. Vealencis (1980)

1. Facts: Tenants in common; P’s seek partition to sell residential property; D runs garbage business and lives on

land.

2. Rules:

a. Partition by Kind (physical partition) is preferred when possible. Consider: size, area, structures,

present and future use, zoning, whether someone using land for home, business, livelihood.

b. Partition by sale between tenants in common should be ordered only when 2 component are satisfied:

i. The physical attributes of land allow for practicable and equitable partition (see above)

ii. The interests of all parties are better served by a partition by sale

c. Side Note: party requesting partition by sale has the burden to demonstrate the sale will promote the

owners’ interests

d. Owelty: payments to correct imbalances in partitions of land

3. App/Holding: Partition in Kind (physical partition)more practicable because interests of D not accounted for

(home and business on property) so D gets to keep house and business on the 1 acres and D must pay owelty

to other tenants in common to compensate them for lose in revenue b/c selling land as residential.

b. Contribution and Accounting: Gillmor v. Gillmor (1984)

vii. Facts: Tenants in common; grazing issue resulting in alleged ouster; both parties could not graze simultaneously. P

wants damages for loss of revenue from exclusion from property to graze.

viii. Rule:

1. Co-Tenants Rights: right to free and unobstructed possession without liability for rents for their use and

occupation. Co-t only liable if interferes with other co-tenant’s right to occupy, use, and enjoy.

2. Establishing Ouster: must demonstrate that activity necessarily excludes cotenant

a. Exclusive use alone is not necessarily an ouster (must exclude the use of other cotenant)

b. Once there is an ouster, adverse possession clock starts ticking

3. Reimbursement for improvements: Generally, when Co-T in sole possession makes repairs or improvements

to common property w/o consent from other co-Ts, improver has no right to contribution; Consider: ongoing

or terminated relationship, necessary to prevent forfeiture(allowed), repairs and maintenance (unlikely),

improvements (not awarded)

1. Exceptions: improver gets compensation from Co-Ts when (1) other co-Ts have stood by and permitted him to

proceed to his detriment (2) If improver acted in good faith believing themselves to be sole owner

ix. App/Holding: Grazing necessarily excluded other cotenant because of issue with overgrazing. Woman gets

compensation for lost revenue from inability to graze and gets injunction to force other co-Ts to allow her to graze.

However, excluder repaired fence and wants compensation. Court divides the repair consts by the percentage of

interest to each party, so cost of repairs is subtracted from woman’s damages.

VI. Entity Property (allows managerial function to be concentrated w/ specialists while use is spread over larger group)

a. Possessory Interests

i. Leases (financing—closely related to loan, risk-spreading—new ventures, and specialization functions—managerial LL)

ii. Lease Types (numerus clausus principle applies; limited menu; ambiguous language will be put into category)

Page 21: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Term of Years: lease for fixed time that ends on specific date (no notice by either party to terminate

relationship) (notice=length of rent cycle) statute of frauds (in writing) usually applies.

2. Periodic Tenancy: lease that auto renews (each party required to give notice to terminate lease) (must give

minimum 6 month notice to end or length of period of recurring rollover)

3. Tenancy at Will: tenancy that lasts as long as both parties wish to continue (either party can terminate at any

time for any reason) Notice equal to the period of time at which rents are made is required in most

jurisdictions

4. Tenancy at sufferance: when tenant remains in possession after their right has ended after original entry was

permitted. Differs from trespasser because original entry was not wrongful (often not regarded as a true

tenancy)

5. Rationale for appeal: (1) de facto financing devise which allows owner to lend possession for rent, (2) risk

spreading devise: allows tenants to have flexibility (pull up stakes and leave rather than property tying them

down) landlord also spreads risk by leasing to multiple tenants, (3)form of entity property where complex

assets can be integrated and professionally managed

6. Warranties/ covenants: covenant to pay rent T LL; covenant to peaceful enjoyment LL T (LL may not

permit to trespass, or T doesn’t pay rent);Covenant to repair (independent); warranty of Habitability LL T, (if

breached, T doesn’t need to pay rent); Duty to mitigate LLT

iii. The Independent Covenants Model

1. Assumption of independent covenants provides that all covenants must be performed without regard to

whether other covenants have been or can be performed

2. Paradine v. Jane (1647)

a. Facts: Term of years lease; prince w/ army kicked tenant off land; claims to not owe rent for that period

b. Rules:

i. Covenant to pay rent and covenant to use and enjoyment: Most basic covenants (LL must not

interfere w/ quiet enjoyment during lease term and tenant must pay rent)

ii. Assumption of independent covenants provides that all covenants must be performed w/o regard to

whether other covenants have been or can be performed

1. If the LL fails to perform a covenant to repair, the tenant must continue to pay rent but can sue

2. Remedy of Distraint (LL could enter w/o permission and take things to collect the rent

c. Rationale: Lessee would have captured windfall profits and therefore accepts risks of losses

i. Exception if complete destruction of property: by outside forces terminates the lease and removes

the tenant from obligations to pay rent

d. App/Holding: Tenant still required to pay rent because LL did not interfere with T’s use and enjoyment

and did not break covenant. Outside disasters are risks that T must bear.

3. Smith v. McEnany (1897) (step towards covenant dependency)

a. Facts: P built on edge of D’s leased property; treated encroachment as eviction; LL (P)sues for rent.

b. Rules:

i. Right to Exclude: if the LL permits something to encroach on T’s leased land, then LL breaches

covenant for quiet enjoyment and T doesn’t need to pay rent. T has the right to use and enjoyment of

the whole property.

ii. Does not absolve tenant of other covenants besides rent (duty to repair)

iii. Actual eviction or ouster by the LL is an exception to the rule of independent covenants from

Paradine. If the LL evicts the tenant, then the tenant’s covenant to pay rent is suspended as long as

the eviction lasts. Court here found that partial ouster completely absolves the tenant from paying

rent, rather than just reducing the amount owed.

iv. Property Rule: Partial ouster by LL completely absolves the tenant from performing the covenant to

pay rent

c. App/holding: LL broke covenant to provide full possession of the property so T doesn’t need to pay rent

from time wall constructed by T liable for not repairing the premise, so subtract damages

4. Sutton v. Temple (1843)

Page 22: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

a. Facts: Tenant refuses to pay rent, LL sues Leased eddish for livestock; paint chips in manure; spread over

property; killed livestock Tenant refused to pay rent, LL sues.

b. Rules:

i. No implied warranty of fitness that the leased premises will be fit for the tenant’s intended purposes

ii. Distinguished from Smith v. Marrable house and furniture supposed to be livable and can easily see.

c. Holding: tenant cannot escape their obligation to pay rent whether premises are fit for their intended

purpose or not (caveat lessee). Tenant must pay all the rent for the whole period of the contract.

iv. Exception to Independent Covenants

1. Forfeiture Clauses

a. Clauses in leases providing that upon the tenant’s violation of enumerated covenants in the least (most

crucially the covenant to pay rent) the tenant’s interest in the lease would be immediately forfeited

i. Two Forms modeled after defeasible fees

1. Fee simple determinable

2. Fee simple subject to condition subsequent (retake and reenter)

2. Constructive Eviction (exception to independent covenants recognized for actual evictions by the landlord)

a. Severely depresses value of tenancy

b. Landlord misfeasance sufficiently serious to cause a reasonable tenant to vacate

i. Tenant is excused from further payment of rent (pro-tenant doctrine)

ii. Can include situations over which LL has no control

c. Blackett v. Olanoff (1977) (nonfeasance)(inaction of LL violates lease)(extends Smith v. McEnany)

i. Facts: Tenants in this case were disturbed by a nightclub that the LL leased next door and didn’t

enforce a noise restriction in that lease. Therefore, b/c residential tenants right to quiet enjoyment of

the premise was substantially diminished, LL’s actions constituted constructive eviction.

ii. Doctrine of Constructive Eviction applies when: T were “very substantially deprived” of quiet

enjoyment of their leased premises “for a substantial time.” So, T’s implied warranty of quiet

enjoyment was violated (by loud music and disturbances from nearby lounge LL leased to other T.)

not reasonably habitable, no difference between nonfeasance and malfeasance

iii. App/Holding: Though LL didn’t create the condition, LL had the power to not enter lease or correct it,

b/c foreseeable that clash of interests would occur. So, allowing the lounge to move in amounted to

constructive eviction of the residential tenants. (when LL in control of condition that will foreseeably

cause problem, but still allows the substantial condition to continue const. evic.)

3. Doctrine of Surrender

a. If tenant vacates premises w/ the intention never to return, there is a mutual release of further lease

obligations by implied contract (contractual release of liability) (pro-tenant doctrine

b. Moment of Acceptance

i. When the landlord takes some action recognizing that the tenant has surrendered the lease

ii. Tenant is liable for the full amount of rent owed up to the moment of acceptance, but not thereafter

iii. Usually original lease distinguished as a matter of law by the landlord’s reentry

c. In Re Kerr (1939)

i. Facts: Tenant in 2 year lease went bankrupt and stopped paying rent. LL relet premises to new

tenant but for a reduced price with several months free at the beginning. LL re-let and sued for rent

i. Rules: Both are Pro-Tenant

1. Doctrine of Surrender: Tenant’s state of mind must be to abandon the leasehold; LL’s must be

to accept the abandonment and retake. Tenant is only liable for full rent until moment LL

accepts the surrender. (if LL relets that signifies surrender)

2. Reenter and relet clause: tenant remains liable to the LL for expected damages if the LL cannot

with reasonable effort relet the premises at a rent equal to or higher than the original rent

reserved.

ii. App/Holding: bankrupt is only liable to LL for the amount of rent before LL relet the premises

v. The model of Dependant Covenants (modern landlord-tenant law)

1. Dependant Covenants: Medico-Dental Building Company of Los Angeles v. Horton and Converse (1942)

Page 23: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

a. Facts: Lease agreement stated no other pharmacy in the building; physician began selling drugs in

building. The lease had a specific rider which makes a difference

b. Rules:

i. General Rule of bilateral commercial contracts

1. Breach sufficiently serious (goes to essence of consideration): can rescind from the lease and

terminate further performance of the contract. (shifting from hard property doctrines to softer

contract doctrines)

2. Breach of less serious covenant (doesn’t go to essence or not materially sufficient to justify

rescission): promisee entitled to sue for damages only.

3. Those features of the lease which are strictly contractual in their nature should be construed

according to the rules and interpretations of contracts generally (leases from property to

contract)

ii. Options of Defendant (pharmacy)

1. Could rescind the lease, not pay further rent

2. Continue under lease and at end of term sue for loss of profits (sue for damages)

3. Could have treated the violation of the covenant by P as putting an end to contract for

purposes of the performance and sued for damages (rescind as a forward going measure, and

sue damages back)

iii. App/Holding: Since the agreement that no one else in the building sell drugs goes to the essence of

the consideration under the lease, the contract is terminated and T does not need to pay rent.

2. IWH (Implied Warranty of Habitability)

a. Continuous obligation to the tenant to maintain the premises in accordance w/ all applicable law

b. Only urban residential housing (usually not extended to commercial leases)

c. Not waivable (even for lower rent) and automatically implied in all leases (departs from contract doctrine

in this regard)

d. Javins v. First National Realty Corp. (1970)

i. Issue: Whether housing code violations which arise during the term of a lease have any effect upon

the tenant’s obligation to pay rent

ii. Facts: Tenants refuse to pay rent. LL sues T for rent. Ts claims they don’t have to pay b/c 1500

housing reg violations.

iii. Rules: Legitimate expectation that the apartment will be fit for habitation for the period for which it

is rented (more like a consumer of goods and services)

1. Rent dependant on LL’s performance of IWH: Under contract principles, the tenant’s

obligation to pay rent is dependent upon the landlord’s performance of his obligations

including his warranty to maintain the premises in habitable condition

2. Implied warranty of Habitability (nearly all states, but only residential leases): By signing the

lease, LL undertakes duty to maintain the premises in accordance with Housing regs or T

doesn’t need to pay rent. (Implied in all res. Contracts)

3. Jury/Judge must find: (1) vios existed during period rent past due; AND (2), how much of the

rent is suspended for LL’s breach of IWH.

4. Remedies for violation of IWH

a. Tenant can vacate w/ no further obligation

b. Order directing specific performance of IWH

c. Action for damages for breach of IWH

d. Set-off against rent liability reflecting the LL’s violation of IWH

e. Some jurisdictions allow the withholding of all of the rent until IWH correct or permits

the tenant to arrange for repair

i. Impact of the IWH crucially relies on enforcement (very spotty)(market tends to sort)

5. Doctrine of retaliatory eviction: LL may not retaliate against a tenant for reporting code

violations or attempting to organize a tenant’s union. (even if it is a periodic tenancy and it is at

Page 24: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

the end of the lease) Cannot give notice to terminate if a court concludes the termination was

motivated by a desire to punish the tenant for asserting rights under housing code

6. Illegal Lease Doctrine: (minority) If LL leases property that is subject to one or more code

violations, so that the premise is rendered unsafe and unsanitary, then the lease is void and

has no effect. (bad b/c LL can evict tenant right away)

iv. Holding: leases of urban dwelling should be interpreted like a contract. Warranty of habitability is a

warranty LL must give to T as set by Housing Regs. Breach of warranty allows T to access usual

remedies for breach of contract. Violations can’t be de minimis and T not pay rent. After LL repairs, T

must pay rent

3. Duty to Mitigate

a. A landlord seeking damages from a defaulting tenant is under a duty to mitigate damages by making

reasonable efforts to re-let an apartment wrongfully vacated by the tenant

b. Sommer v. Kridel (1977)

i. Facts: D’s plans changed; wrote letter to abandon; LL did not respond; did not re-enter to exhibit and

denied inquiries. LL then sues for all the rent. Before LL relet a year or so later.

ii. Rules:

1. Duty to attempt to re-let the premises and mitigate damages (from property to contract)

2. Assessing if LL used “reasonable diligence” to re-let: whether LL offered or showed the apt to

any prospective tenants or advertised in newspaper. (no rule, each case must be judged on its

own facts)

3. LL required to carry the burden of proving he used reasonable diligence in attempting to re-let

a. LL in better position to provide evidence (showings, employed realtor, ads)

iii. App/Holding: No response to surrender was acceptance. Since LL could have avoided the damages

which heven’t actually accrued, T does not need to pay any damages to LL.

c. Relationship between surrender and mitigation of damages

i. Duty to mitigate may arise earlier than surrender (surrender is complete release of liability)

1. Many courts will provide 1 month grace period for duty to mitigate (subtract new rent after)

2. Can argue for both failure to mitigate and surrender simultaneously

3. Many tenants in this situation are judgment-proof and going to court is expensive

vi. Assignment and Sublease (transfer of tenant interests)

1. Sublease: LL has fee simple, then carves out a lease for the prime tenant, who carves out a sublease from a

subtenant, then sub-sublease,

2. Assignment: LL carves out lease from fee simple to a prime tenant, who alienates the prime lease to 1st

assignee, who alienates to 2nd

assignee. Every successive assignee steps into the shoes of the previous

assignee and enters direct relations with the original LL

3. Two Sources of LL-T obligation

a. Privity of contract: obligations that come from being a party to a binding bilateral contract (written

lease) so LL and subtenant no privity

b. Privity of estate: 2 conditions:

i. (1) parties must have interests directly carved out of each other (nested), AND

ii. (2)one party must be in actual possession of the property. When both conditions satisfied, parties

are both bound by privity of estate and privity of contract.

c. In Assignment: LL and prime tenant both priv of contract and estate, when Prime T assigns to 1st

assignee, original LL in privity of estate with 1st

assignee, but not privity of contract. Assignee 1 is only in

privity of contract with prime tenant (and whoever they assign too.) In assignment, then the Prime T

assigns, the parties in privity of estate are bound to the obligations that touch and concern the land in

the original leasehold interest. Also, L may prefer assignment because 1st

A must pay rent to you, but if

1st A defaults, prime T still on the hook via privity of contract

4. 2 concepts relevant to Assignment: i.e. if LL enters lease with Prime T, who assigns lease to 1st

A.

Page 25: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

a. Assumption: occurs when 1st

A expressly agrees as part of an assignment agreement to be bound by the

terms of the original lease, therefore, 1st

A agrees to be bound by privity of contract and privity of estate.

However, Prime T also still bound by privity of contract

b. Novation: when the parties agree to erase any privity of contract liability on the part of the prime

tenant. So when prime T agree to assign to 1st

A, and LL agrees to novation, Prime T is totally off the

hook (no more privity of estate and novation erases privity of contract)

5. ** Assumption and Novation act independently, so you can have one or the other, or both together, or

none)**

6. Assignment and Sublease: Jaber v. Miller (1951)

a. Facts: Jaber rented from original owner; transferred lease to Norber and Son for remainder of lease for

promissory notes; Jaber reserved right to re-enter if no payment; no provision for fire; Miller obtained

lease from Norber and didn’t want to pay Jaber after fire burned down building; Miller argues payments

were rent under a sublease so that the fire provision would apply to him and Not an assignment

b. Rules:

i. Traditional doctrine: If the instrument purports the lessee’s estate for the entire remainder of the

term it is an assignment, regardless of intention (if even one day less of entire term, then sublease)

ii. New rule: Intention of the parties is to govern in determining whether an instrument is an

assignment or a sublease (look at title of agreement, words in agreement, and intent of parties)

c. App/Holding: Jaber and Norber intended an assignment and not a sublease (same result as old rule) so

Miller must continue to pay the $700 notes to Jaber. Evidence of assignment: instrument called

“contract of assignment” and only uses the word “assignment” rather than “sublease” gave promissory

notes rather than rent.

7. Assignment and Sublease: Kendall v. Ernest Pestana, Inc. (1985)

a. Facts: Ernest has assignment sublet to Bixler tried to assign to Kendall; Ernest refused assignment

b. Rules:

i. Law generally favors free alienability of property

ii. New Rule: Lessor can withhold consent only where the lessor has a commercially reasonable

objection to the assignment

1. Property (restraints on alienation and leases as conveyances)(forbids unreasonable restraints)

2. Contract (Recognition of contract principles of duty to good faith and fair dealing)

iii. Commercially reasonable factors: 1) Suitability for use; 2) Legality of use; 3) Need for alteration of

the premises; 4) Nature of occupancy

iv. Denying consent based on personal taste, convenience, or sensibility is not commercially reasonable

1. Cannot deny consent “in order that the LL may charge a higher rent than originally contracted

for)

v. Lessee entitled to capture windfall gains or losses (see Paradine v. Jane)

c. App/Holding: Since clause restricts alienability and Pestana has no good reason to deny the lease,

Pestana must allow Bixler to assign to Kendall

vii. Cooperatives, Condominiums, and Common-Interest Communities

1. Forms of entity property in which multiple persons enjoy possessory interests

2. Often present complicated governance issues

a. Organize themselves collectively in order to manage common areas and shared facilities

i. Usually through some combination of basic organizing document and elected governing body

3. Reasons to own (customizing space, market, control over community)

4. Condo Governance: Nahrstedt v. Lakeside Village Condominium Association, Inc.

a. Facts: P moved into condominium complex w/ 3 cats against pet restriction in project declaration/master

deed; homeowners association enforced restriction and fined P; alleged pet restriction unreasonable

b. Rules:

i. 2 categories of use restrictions:

1. (1) restrictions in the master deed: strong deference,

Page 26: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

a. Rationale: protect general expectation of condo owners, creates stability and

predictability, and reduces litigation costs over exceptions to rule, if restriction recorded

in original declaration it is presumptively valid unless it is arbitrary, violates a

fundamental constitutional right, or violates public policy. (Bundle of Rights)

b. All covenants and restrictions in declaration are enforceable unless unreasonable (i.e.

arbitrary, burden on use of land substantially outweighs restrictions benefits to residents

as a whole, or violates fundamental public policy, or is arbitrary

2. (2)rules created by condo board or their interpretation of rules (less deference)

c. App/Holding: reasonable to have a pet restriction (i.e. allergies, cleanliness)if approved to have it in

master deed, presumed to be reasonable. P may not keep the cats in the condo.

5. Co-op Governance: 40 West 67th

Street v. Pullman

a. Facts: D is crazy tenant in co-op; accuses and harasses old upstairs neighbors; have meeting to vote D

out, evicted D; D refused to leave

b. Rules:

i. Business Judgment Rule: where courts exercise restraint and defer to good faith decisions made by

boards of directors in business settings. (applies to co-op board)

ii. RPAPL 711(1): LL only has right to terminate tenant occupancy during the term of the lease if LL

establishes w/ competent evidence to the satisfaction of the court that the tenant is objectionable

iii. Elements to allow board to vote and evict D: “so long as the board acts for the purposes of the

cooperative, w/in the scope of its authority and in good faith”

iv. An shareholder tenant must prove the board acted

1. Outside the scope of its authority, or

2. In a way that did not legitimately further the purpose, or

3. In bad faith

c. App/Holding: Since board followed the procedures and evidence board provides is reasonable, they

have the authority to evict D.

6. Note on housing cooperatives: Unusual legal animal (buildings is owned by an entity, usually a corporation, in

which the residents own shares and the corporation grants a perpetual lease) (part corporation and part

lease)

VII. Title Records and the Transfer of Property

a. Title Records

i. Nemo Dat Quod non Habet (you can’t give what you don’t have) VERSUS Good Faith Purchasers for Value (often in

opposition to nemo dat)(title recording tries to balance these principles)

ii. Recording (Ex Post Approach) (take deed you want to record to the recording office and the registrar makes no attempt

to approve)(no check for competing claims) (files organized by transacting parties’ names and indexes to

reconstruct)(occasional back-end costs)

iii. Title Search and “Chain of Title”

1. Performing a title search involves tracing the series of transaction from would-be transferor back to a “root of

title” and then tracing forward

a. Look in grantee index to find transferor and follow backwards and then forwards through grantor index

b. Recording Acts

i. Race (original type of recording act)(only 2 states still use race recording acts)

1. first person to record their deed is TO (doesn’t matter if bought before or after other person or good faith)

2. O sells to A and then sells to B, but B records before A, then B has title

3. Creates an exception to the nemo dat principle and no relationship to good faith purchaser for value

a. 1st

party to record wins even if they have actual notice of prior conveyance

4. Strong incentive to record

5. If no one records, goes to Nemo Dat owner

ii. Notice (states evenly split between Notice and Race-Notice)

1. A subsequent good faith bona fide purchaser for value wins unless she has notice (actual, constructive, or

inquiry)

Page 27: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

a. Recorded interest gives constructive or “record” notice

2. Incentive to record immediately in order to be protected from subsequent good faith purchasers

iii. Race-Notice

1. A subsequent good faith purchaser wins only if he has no notice AND records before the prior instrument is

recorded

a. Must satisfy both conditions for title

b. If either condition is not satisfied than the nemo dat holder wins

c. Similar to race statute but solves the problem of the unscrupulous subsequent buyer

iv. The Shelter Rule

1. Exception for certain transferees who otherwise would be barred from obtaining title because they are not

good faith purchasers for value

a. Ex. O conveys to A, who does not record. Then O conveys to B who gives value and has no notice of the

prior conveyance to A. B then records. Then A records. Then B gifts the land to C.

i. C wins against A because shelters under B’s rights

1. Otherwise B would have less than full ownership

2. Original Owner Exception (if B transfers back to O then A would win)

a. O cannot shelter under B’s rights (fear of collusion and has notice because he conveyed)

v. Problems

1. O conveys to A. O then conveys to B, who has no knowledge of A’s deed. Then A records. Then B sells to C

a. Race: A wins, first to record

b. Notice: C wins because C shelters under B’s full property rights who had no notice when he buys so he is

a subsequent purchaser for value in good faith and then can transfer to C. (shelter under B’s rights even

though C has constructive notice)(once you have full title you can convey full title)

c. Race-Notice: A wins, B does not record before A

2. O conveys to A. O then conveys to B, who has no knowledge of A’s deed. Then A records. B then records and

sells to O

a. Race: A wins, first to record

b. Notice: A wins, original grantor cannot shelter under B’s rights

c. Race-Notice: A wins, records before B

3. O conveys to A. O then conveys to B who has actual notice of the deed from O to A. B records , and then A

records. Then B sells to C.

a. Race: C wins, first to record shelters under B’s rights

b. Notice: A wins, B had notice so no title to shelter C

c. Race-notice: A wins, B had actual notice

vi. Good Faith Purchaser for Value: Hood v. Webster (1936)

1. Facts: Widow conveyed land to Hood; then sold to Webster for $1; Webster recorded first; Race-Notice Act

2. App/Holding: Webster not a good faith purchaser for value; “peppercorn transaction” the $1 consideration is

insignificant. Satisfies the rest of statute (but no substantial value to evidence a good faith transaction) Hood

gets title b/c said would pay her $200 a year. Hood still wins even though didn’t pay her a dime.

c. The Limits of Title Searches

i. Adverse Possession Mugaas v. Smith (1949)

1. Facts: P is adverse possessor since 1910; neighbor D buys title in 1941 w/o a description that included the AP.

P sues for quiet title action to keep the adversely possessed land.

2. Rules:

a. Recording does not extinguish AP

b. The fact that P had ceased to use the land in question in such a way that her claim of AP was apparent

did not divest the title she had acquired (does not have to “fly flag forever” over adverse possession)

c. Adverse possession affects the subsequent purchaser even if they have received no actual notice

d. Bad faith adverse possessors are more likely to record quickly

3. App/Holding: AP wins and gets to keep the strip of land.

ii. Wild Deeds (deeds outside the chain of title and can’t be traced back) Zimmer v. Sundell (1941)

Page 28: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Facts: McCanns convey to Raab and then to Gage, Gage never records and sells to P who recorded; so when D

recorded their conveyances, the P’s recorded deed had no apparent connection w/ or derivation from the

McCann’s title (P had fugitive deed)(because Gage did not record, could never find in index)

2. Rules:

a. Good faith purchasers for value who record first are protected under the race-notice statute

i. Exception: excludes from protection those who may purchase from strangers to the title

ii. P purchased from grantor who had no recorded title going back to root (Grantor was a pure stranger

to the title so far as the record disclosed

b. Most courts agree, cannot benefit from the recording act’s exception to nemo dat if traces ownership to

a wild deed

3. App/ Holding: although under stat P would be TO because innocent and recorded 1st

. However, this only

works if one could rely on the titles on record and trace it back to the grantor. Since the deed from McCann

Gage wasn’t recorded until after P and D recorded, P couldn’t have relied on the record, so invalid claim.

Raabs are TO.

VIII. The Law of Neighbors

a. Nuisance

i. Invasion of another’s interest in the private use and enjoyment of land, and the invasion is actual and substantial,

direct, and unreasonable

1. Reasonableness is balanced w/ competing interests (balancing interests)

a. Three basic approached to balance interests and determine reasonableness

i. Objective Threshold of “Badness” (conflated w/ invasion)

ii. Becoming worse (trend over time of a particular use)

iii. Cost benefit analysis

ii. Trespass/ Nuisance Divide: Adams v. Cleaveland-Cliffs Iron Company (1999) (air particles, vibrations, and noise)

1. Facts: Ps live near nation’s largest mine. Dust, noise, and vibrations constantly bother them. They sue for

nuisance and trespass.

2. Rules:

a. Trespass: invasion of possessor’s interest in excusive possession of their land. Requires (1)direct (2)entry

onto (3)P’s land (4)by a tangible, physical object

i. Dust isn’t tangible and is just ambient part of circumstance of space

ii. Direct invasion requirement: Enough that an act is done w/ knowledge that it will to a substantial

certainty result in the entry of foreign matter

b. Nuisance: interference with possessor’s use and enjoyment of their land. Requires proof of

i. (1)substantial harm resulting from D’s

ii. (2)unreasonable interference that causes

iii. (3)substantial harm to use or enjoyment of the property

iv. (4) Employ balancing test between benefit to D and harm to P.

1. Factors

a. (1) Badness: conflated with invasion,

b. (2) Becoming worse: look at the trend, it there is a change for the worse that goes

against them.

c. (3) Cost Benefit: cold cost benefit analysis. If the benefits don’t outweigh the harm, then

it could be a nuisance (could be quantitative.)

c. 4 tests between trespass and nuisance:

i. (1) whether D’s intrusion occurred with D on or off the P’s land,

ii. (2) whether the harm was direct or indirect,

iii. (3) invasion by intangible or tangible thing,

iv. (4) deprive P of possession or use +enjoyment.

d. Damages: recovery in trespass is appropriate for any appreciable intrusion onto land while recovery in

nuisance is appropriate for only substantial and unreasonable interferences w/ P’s right to quiet

enjoyment

Page 29: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

3. App/Holding: Not a trespass because not a Direct invasion or with a tangible object. Also not Nuisance as per

jury verdict in lower ct. likely b/c not “substantial harm” to use and enjoyment

iii. Remedy Issues: Boomer v. Atlantic Cement Company Inc.

1. Facts: D owns cement plant, private nuisance to residents in the area

2. Rules:

a. Disparity in $ consequences: If it would cost a substantial economic loss to an grant injunction, then can

issue injunction that is vacated upon payment of permanent damages for all harm to home value.

b. Permanent Damages: If there is a significant nuisance but injunction would be strongly against economic

efficiency, then can grant permanent damages

3. App/Holding: Injunction granted which shall be vacated upon payment by D for permanent damages to the

decreased housing value (High transaction costs (injunction and removal of cement plant) persuades courts to

adopt liability rule)(Type 2 Calabresi Malamud Rule: Liability Rule for the Plaintiff)

4. Departure from mandatory injunction rule because of a large disparity in economic consequences (ex ante

approach) (damages are scaled to loss in market value)

iv. Coming to Nuisance: Spur Industries, Inc. v. Del E. Webb Development Co. (1972)

1. Facts: Webb develops Sun City near cattle feed-lock; sues for public nuisance

2. Rules:

a. Public nuisance dangerous to public health: Any condition or place in populous areas which constitute a

breeding place for flies, rodents, mosquitoes, which are capable of transmitting diseases to people.

3. App/Holding: Spur may be enjoined (b/c public nuisance that manure creates health issue for nearby

residents) but Webb must indemnify (Type 4 Malamud Rule: Liability Rule for the Defendant) (Developer

must “buy out” the feed-lock that was there before the residences)

4. Distinct from other “coming to the nuisance” cases

a. Brought people to the nuisance to the foreseeable detriment of Spur, so must indemnify for a

reasonable cost of moving or shutting down

b. Easements

i. Nomenclature

1. Nuisance: tort approach to resolving neighborly conflict. Coase theorem situation

2. Easements: property approach to giving some use and enjoyment rights. Should be in writing b/c informality

between neighbors can cause conflict

3. Covenants: contract. About giving the use of property

4. Easement Appurtenant: easement that belongs to another parcel of land. I grant Matt the right to walk

through my land to access his adjacent land, he has an easement appurtenant that belongs to his land

"blackacre" that is carved out of my land "whiteacre."

a. Benefit of the easement belongs to whoever happens to own blackacre and burden of the easement

belongs to whoever happens to own whiteacre.

b. Blackacre= dominant tract and whiteacre the servient tract

5. Easement in Gross: easement that belongs to a particular grantee rather than belonging to the land. So I grant

Matt the right to go skiing on my land, so the easement belongs to him and not whoever owns his land

"Blackacre." So if Matt sold his land to Paul, Paul doesn't have the right to ski unless he gets his own easement

6. Profit a prende: right to enter on the land of another in order toe extract something of value such as timber,

fish from a lake, or fruit or trees. (same rules as easement appurtenant) License remains irrevocable as long as

the profit continues to last.

7. Affirmative Easement: permits the easement holder to perform some affirmative action on the land of

another (i.e. permitting action on servient track that otherwise would be trespass or invasive nuisance) Almost

all easements are affirmative.

a. Common law recognized 4 types: (1) Blocking sunlight , (2) Interfering with the flow of air, (3) Removing

lateral support for a building, (4) Interfering with the flow of water

8. Negative Easement: permits the easement holder to demand that the owner of the servient tract desist from

certain actions that might harm the easement holder

9. Private easement: authorize specific named parties (people or entities) to use land for a designated purpose

Page 30: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

10. Public easement: authorize the general public to use land for designated purposes (beaches, bike trails) Public

can hold negative public easements like scenic or conservation easements

ii. Intro : Numerous clauses applies to easements: Baseball Publishing Co v. Bruton (1938)

1. Facts: Man intends to lease space on a wall to display an advertisement and mails contract to Wall owner who

doesn’t accept the money. The man continues to send him checks and display the advertisements. After 3

years the wall owner takes down the advertisement. Man sues wall-owner to get the right to display the ad.

2. Rules: Must determine which numerous clauses box the agreement fits into.

3. App/ Holding: Not a lease because he only has the right to display the sign on the wall and doesn’t gain

possession of the wall itself. Not a license because licenses are revocable at the will of the possessor of the

land. So it should be an easement since it gives the man a certain right to the property. Actually easement in

equity since in equity a seal is not necessary to the creation of the easement since this is an unsealed contract.

iii. Creation

1. Easements by Implication and Easements by Necessity: Shwab v. Timmons (1999)

a. Facts: P wants easement by necessity over D’s property so Ps can drive to their parcel of landlocked land.

Lake on left, bluffs on right, property above and below. Only way to drive is across neighbor’s land.

Plaintiffs divided and sold the part of the land that used to have road access. They created the

landlocked parcel themselves and wasn’t conveyed to them in that manner.

b. Rules:

i. Elements to create an Easement by Implication:

1. Common ownership:

2. Severance: single parcel gets severed

3. Necessity: that arises at the moment of severance b/c the parcel has no access to a public

road: necessity for the easement must be so clear and absolute that without the easement the

grantee cannot enjoy the use of the property granted to him for the purposes similar

properties are devoted

4. Prior use: Part of the land must be in use at the time of severance (quasi easement)

ii. (i.e. had driveway that went over the land, then severed, can still use the driveway as a driveway)

iii. App: parcels weren’t landlocked at the time it was conveyed to Ps. Ps created the landlocked parcel

themselves by conveying the parcel that had access to the road.

iv. Elements to create an Easement by Necessity:

1. Common Ownership

2. Severance: single parcel severed

3. Very Great Necessity arises at that moment: also requires continuing necessity for the

easement

v. App: no necessity if Ps can access the land by water or walking over the bluffs

c. Holding: no easement by implication or necessity for P.

2. Easements by Prescription: Warsaw v. Chicago Metallic Ceilings Inc. (1984)

a. Facts: Company builds land near boundary, uses D’s land to drive trucks around property for 7 years

without D’s permission. D builds a building on that portion of land so P can’t use it. P sues for injunction

to remove the building to regain access to the road.

b. Rules:

i. Elements to Create an Easement by Prescription:

1. Open and Notorious

2. Continuous: used the path on a regular basis

3. Adverse under a claim of right

4. For an uninterrupted period of 5 years

5. Certain and definite line of travel used repeatedly over time: slight deviations allowed but not

substantial changes in path

ii. Rationale: allows for prompt termination of controversies before the possible loss of evidence and in

stabilizing long continued property uses. (1) Land use is favored over disuse, (2) Reduced litigation:

Page 31: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

preserve the peace by protecting a possession maintained for a statutorily deemed sufficient period

of time

c. App: Ps have openly used D’s land to make turns for 7 years on a nearly daily basis and all the trucks turn

in the same place, so meets all five elements.

d. Holding: P has created an Easement by Prescription over the part of D’s land that they have used to

make turns. D must completely remove the structure from that portion of their land and must not

interfere with P’s use of the easement for the purpose of turning trucks around

3. Easement by Estoppel: Holbrook v. Taylor (1976)

a. Facts: Owner uses part of D’s land as road to transport mine material (1944), mine closes 1949), then

owners built tenant home (1957). Tenants and P uses road again. Home burns down (1961). P’s sell to

new Ps (1964) who builds their home on three acres of the property. D’s give P’s permission to improve

the road. P’s spend $100 to widen, place culverts, and red cinder gravel. D’s want P’s to buy land for

$500, Ps refuse. D’s place metal wires so they cannot use road. P’s sue D for easement by prescription

and estoppel

b. Rules:

i. Elements to create an Easement through Estoppel:

1. True owner gave permission

2. New user relied on that permission to improve the land on the faith and strength of the license

3. To revoke the permission would be inequitable

ii. No statute of lims: so can happen very quickly (1 week even) when all elements met.

iii. Rights a person gains through estoppel: they get an irrevocable license to what was originally

granted permission to do forever so long as it is always used for that purpose. It is also usually

transferable to the new owner because it runs with the land.

iv. * “Where the licensee has exercised the privilege given him and erected improvements or made

substantial expenditures on the faith or strength of the license, it becomes irrevocable and continues

for so long a time as the nature of the license calls for.”

c. App/ Holding: Since D gave permission to improve the land and use it as a driveway, the license to use

the roadway for that purpose may not be revoked because the use of the roadway was established by

estoppel (since P spent money to improve land)

4. Negative Easements: Fontainebleau Hotel Corp. v. Forty-Five Twenty-Five Inc.

a. Facts: Hotel builds giant towers that cast shadow on neighbor hotel’s pool. Neighbor hotel sues for

injunction

b. Rules:

i. Owner's rights: a property owner may put his property to any reasonable and lawful use, so long as

he does no thereby deprive the adjoining landowner of any right of enjoyment of his property which

is recognized and protected by law and so long as his use is not such a one as the law will pronounce

a nuisance.

ii. There is no legal right to the free flow of light and air from the adjoining land. Where a structure

serves a useful and beneficial purpose, it does not give rise to a cause of action either for damages or

for an injunction under the maxim of sic utere tuo ut alienum non laedas. Even though it causes injury

to another by cutting off the light and air and interfering with the view that would otherwise be

available .

iii. Ancient Lights: rule only applies if the sunlight has fallen on a window for 20 years

c. App/ Holding: No right to sunlight. Fontainebleau may keep towers and neighbor gets no compensation.

It does not matter whether the addition to the Fontainebleau may have been constructed partly out of

spite. Mixed motives usually leads to no liability. Pure spite can sometimes lead to greater intervention.

iv. Termination of Easements :

1. by deed,

2. expiration of the term in a contract,

3. determining easements when the event occurs (like in a will),

4. Merger (if a single owner purchases the dominant and servient tract),

Page 32: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

5. terminated by prescription (i.e. putting up a rope and stat of lims runs),

6. Estoppel (abandonment, giving permission to someone to use the land and they improve it),

7. Terms of recording statutes (if easement not recorded with the deed and someone sells the land),

8. Eminent domain

v. Misuse of Easements: Penn Bowling Recreation Center v. Hot Shoppes Inc (1949)

1. Facts: Penn Bowling is overusing their easement in a way that interferes with the servient tract’s use by

parking rather than driving, and overuse by using path to get equipment to other parcels of land outside the

dominant tenement

2. Rules:

a. Non-dominant tract use: not allowed. An easement can only be used by the dominant tract and cannot

be used by parcels of land near the dominant tract but not part of the original dominant tract in the

original agreement

b. Rationale: using an easement beyond its scope (geographic scope, scope of use, etc) constitutes a

continuing trespass: remedy for a continuing trespass is an injunction. A harsh automatic injunction rule

sets up the right incentives for ex ante negotiations. In this case, plaintiff could have avoided the

problem by trying to bargain up front

3. App: the dominant tract may not block the easement and land associated with the dominant tract but not part

of the original dominant tract may NOT use the easement at all.

4. Holding: Until it is clear that the use of the easement is used solely by the dominant tract and no other

unauthorized parties, there will be an injunction to prevent the use of the easement.

c. Covenants

1. Covenants in leases run to successors of the original landlord or tenant if the

a. landlord and tenant intend that they will run; AND

b. covenant is one that touches and concerns the land.

ii. Equitable Servitudes: Tulk v. Moxhay (1848)

1. Facts: seller sells land and includes covenant for buyer to always maintain the solely as a square garden. Buyer

purchases and intends to build buildings on the land. Seller files for injunction to force buyer to keep and

maintain the garden as one.

2. Holding: All purchasers with notice of covenant must conform to the covenant.

3. Reasoning: One is bound to perform an obligation of which he has notice. If a person has notice, then they

have an obligation.

4. Rationale: it would be unfair for someone to buy the land with notice then sell the land the next date for a

higher price without the covenant.

iii. Real Covenants: Neponsit Property Owner's Association, Inc v. Emigrant Industrial Savings Bank (1938)

1. Facts: Neponsit developed land in Queens and conveyed the land with a covenant for the owner to pay $4 a

year for the maintenance of the community which will run until 1940. All subsequent deeds and all deeds in

the community contained this exact covenant. D purchases the land at a judicial sale and fails to pay the $4 a

year. The home owners assoc. places a lien on the land and brings foreclosure proceeding to get the owed

money.

2. Reasoning: D got right of common enjoyment with other property to the beaches, public parks, and roads. To

enjoy these rights, they must be maintained. To maintain the land, the grantor takes $4 a year from each

property owner. That burden of cost affects the value of the property through affecting their enjoyment of the

access to beaches, parks, and roads.

3. Requirements for a covenant to run with the land

a. Intention by both parties: It must appear that grantor and grantee intended that the covenant should

run with the land

b. Touching concerning land: It must appear that the covenant is one "touching" or "concerning" the land

with which it runs

i. Courts have high discretion

ii. Prof. Bigelow's definition of touch and concern: a promise that effects the advantages and the

burdens of the owners of the parcels of land wither benefited or burdened by the promise.

Page 33: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

4. Holding: Since the original grantor and grantee (1)intended the covenant to run with the land and (2)the

covenant may properly be said to touch and concern the land of the defendant, burden of paying $4 a year

runs with the land. Therefore, the company may foreclose the property to exact the fee.

iv. Requirements for Covenants to Run

1. Issue with covenants: whether the benefits and burdens of the deal between the original parties will “run

with the land,” extending to successors of those parties.

2. Requirements for Real Covenants to Run

a. For burden to run

i. Intent for burden to run

ii. Notice

iii. Horizontal privity

iv. Vertical privity

v. Touch and concern

b. For benefit to run

i. Intent for the benefit to run

ii. Vertical privity

iii. Touch and concern

3. Equitable Servitude Theory

a. Three elements must be met for burden of a promise to run w/ the land

i. (1) intent by both original parties for the burden to run w/ land

ii. (2) notice to successive Os of burdened land

iii. (3) promise has to touch and concern the land

b. For benefit of a promise to run w/ the land (1) intent and (2) touch and concern

4. 3rd

Restatement: more contract oriented approach. Abolishes touch and conern and privity requirements.

Enforceability is default subject to limitations of no writing or public policy violation.

a. Rationale: parties may contract as they wish and courts will enforce their agreements without passing on

their substance because it is in the public interest to recognize that individuals have broad powers to

order their own affairs.

v. Notice and the Common Plan Sanborn v. McLean (1925) In subdivisions, covenants trace back to a deal between the

developer and original purchasers

1. Facts: couple (D) buys plot in residential neighborhood. Begin construction of gas station next to their house

on the plot of land. Neighbors (P) sue for injunction

2. Rule/ Following the Common Plan : One must follow the common plan if they can easily see that the whole

neighborhood is residential and could easily discover that some of her neighbors are restrictive covenants

stating the plots can only be used for residential purposes, then even if their deed has no restrictions at all.

a. Notice: constructive notice given when whole neighborhood is uniformly residential and when homes

are continually sold, they remain solely residential all during the past 30 years.

3. Holding: couple must use the land solely for residential purposes. If the gas station building can be used for

any purpose within the restrictions, it doesn’t have to be torn down.

4. Reasoning: many of the homes in the neighborhood had restrictive covenants and the neighborhood with 98

houses all remained residential for past 30 years. All the houses have the right to continue enjoying the

benefits of the restrictive covenants.

vi. Conservation Easements: negative covenants in gross that restrict the future development of land (negative b/c prohibit

servient Landowner from engaging in certain activities, covenants b/c doesn’t fit into 4 type of negative easements, and

gross b/c power to enforce restriction not given to another landowner but to local gov or land trust.

1. Negative covenants in gross probably don’t run with the land since they don’t’ meet the privity requirement.

2. Conservation easements exist only b/c legislation authorizes them and are a new form of property

3. Reasons for rapid proliferation of conservation easements

a. Perpetual conservation easement is designed to give peace of mind to current landowners worried about

their beloved property being sold to developers by their heirs

b. Significant tax benefits: donations are tax deductable for the loss in value of the land with the covenant.

Page 34: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

i. Requirements: land must

1. Be restricted for one of several general purposes: outdoor recreation, wildlife habitat, scenic

enjoyment, agricultural use, or historical importance.

2. Donation must be perpetual

ii. Enviornmentalists concerned with preserving local environmental values see conservation easements

as a potentially powerful tool in combating commercial development

4. Criticism: dead hand control, donor over-valuing their easement for tax-deductions, sometimes given to

people with no public benefit created, public pays for it through tax $ and foregone development

opportunities but have no say in the process b/c done through individual LO negotiations.

vii. Termination of Covenants:

1. Changed Circumstances: Bolotin v. Rindge (1964)

a. Facts: P owns some unimproved lots which are subject to deed restrictions that require the lots to be

used solely for single, private residences which expire in 1970. All the lots but those 4 have been

improved with single family residences. P sues for declaratory relief against tract wide restrictions to

single-family residential use.

b. Rules:

i. A court will declare deed restrictions to be unenforceable when, by reason of changed conditions,

enforcement of the restrictions would be inequitable and oppressive and would harass plaintiff

without benefitting the adjoining owners

ii. A building restriction will not be enforced where changed conditions in the neighborhood have

rendered the purpose of the restrictions obsolete. But if the original purpose of the covenant can still

be realized, it will be enforced even though the unrestricted use of the property would be more

profitable to its owner.

iii. Restatement of Property: a promise as to the use of land is binding upon successors of the promisor

only if the performance will result in benefit “in the physical use or enjoyment of the land.” Physical

use or enjoyment= must make the use or enjoyment more satisfactory to the physical senses and not

enough that the income from it is increased.

c. App: no finding that purpose of the restriction is obsolete and that enforcement of the restriction will no

longer benefit the D. (no adverse monetary effects alone is insufficient)

d. Holding: Remand to determine D derives benefit from restriction remaining

2. Abandonment, estoppel, public policy: Peckham v. Milroy (2001)

a. Facts: P lives in residential community. D’s family moves in and begins operating day-care business in the

home although the house is subject to a restrictive covenant prohibit gthe use fo the property for

business purposes of any kind.

b. Rules:

i. Abandonment

1. Requires proof that prior violations have eroded the general plan and enforcement is therefore

inequitable.

2. A covenant is abandoned when it has been habitually and substantially violated, but a few

violations do not constitute abandonment

ii. App/holding: 1,550 homes and only 4 businesses. Violations are neither habitual nor substantial and

4 constitutes a “few,” so it doesn’t constitute abandonment

iii. Laches

1. Requires 3 elements

a. Knowledge of reasonable opportunity to discover on the part of a potential P that he has

a cause of action against a D; AND

b. An unreasonable delay by the P in commencing that cause of action; AND

c. Damage to the D resulting from the unreasonable delay

2. App: Ds intended to remodel for reasons other than a day care so cost to remodel couldn’t’

come from Mr. Peckham’s delay in bringing suit.

iv. Equitable Estoppel

Page 35: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

1. Requires 3 elements: that must be proved by clear and convincing evidence

a. An admission statement or act inconsistent with the claim asserted afterward; and

b. Action by the other party in reasonable reliance on that admission, statement, or act; and

c. Injury to that party when the first party is allowed to contradict or repudiate its

admission, statement or act

2. Silence can lead to equitable estoppel: where a party knows what is occurring and would be

expected to speak, if he wished to protect his interest, his acquiescence manifests in his tacit

consent.

3. App: P did not stay silent. He complained to the county and D, D also can’t prove they relied on

P’s acquiescence

c. Holding: Restrictive covenants in residential neighborhoods are enforceable

IX. Takings

a. Eminent Domain: government power to take people’s land for just compensation

i. Intro

1. 5th

Amendment: “Nor shall private property be taken for public use without just compensation” + Due Process

Clause together protect US citizens from unfair takings

2. Gov Compromise: Ordinarily, “Property Rule” which protects owner’s right to exclude and must have owner’s

consent to use or buy the property. Eminent Domain is “Liability Rule,” so government can buy the land for

just compensation.

3. Entities who have eminent domain powers: Fed gov, state gov, municipalities, counties, certain agencies,

common carriers, public utilities, and some people if specifically conferred the right from the gov.

4. Standard Eminent Domain Requirements:

a. Condemning authority must show it has been delegated the power of eminent domain by legislature

b. The delegated power is broad enough to encompass the proposed project

c. The exercise of eminent domain is necessary to complete the project

d. Proper procedures have been followed for making these various statutory determinations

e. Project must be for public use

f. Condemning authority must offer just compensation

g. Required to give Notice to the Land owner

h. Must give landowner the opportunity for a hearing

5. Additional requirements

a. Applies to urban renewal or economic development takings: Property must be blighted

ii. Public Use Requirement Kelo v. City of New London, Connecticut (2005)

1. **Property cannot be condemned and retransferred to a commercial entity when the sole rationale is

economic development.

2. Facts: City counsil of New London, CO granted authority to purchase property via eminent domain to

nonprofit org. Plan to build marina, shops, docks, offices, museum to revitalize “distressed” city. Nonprofit

negotiates will all parties, but negotiations fail with nine petitioners who own 15 properties. Landowners sue

for injunction saying the taking violates the “public use” requirement.

3. PP: TC: permanent injunction for those properties in the park area and denied relief for properties in office

space area. App: held that all of the proposed takings were valid. USSC: affirm

4. Rules

a. Sovereign may not take entity’s property solely to transfer it to another entity even though the original

owner is paid just compensation

i. No “purely private takings” allowed under the public use requirement. City can’t take under the

pretext of public purpose when its purpose is to bestow a private gift

b. State may transfer property from one private party to another if future “use by the public” is the

purpose of the taking

c. Broad Rule: public use= public purpose subject to strong deference of the courts to determine.

Page 36: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

i. Berman v. Parker: Area condemned for redevelopment. Man who owns department store sues for

injunction. Agency says the area “must be planned as a whole” for the plan of redevelopment to be

successful” and deferred to agency judgment and affirmed eminent domain.

ii. Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff: court unanimously upheld Hawaiian statute that takes land from

a and gives to B to reduce concentration of land ownership. Explained that the State’s purpose of

eliminating the “social and economic evils of a land oligopoly” qualified as a valid public use.

1. Only the taking’s purpose and not the its mechanics matters in determining public use

2. Legislature has broad latitude in determining what public needs justify eminent domain

iii. *Public purpose depends on a private party’s future use of the concededly non-harmful property that

was taken.

iv. Concurring Opinion: rational basis review: courts should strike down a taking that by a clear showing

is intended to favor a particular private party, with only incidental or pretextual public benefits.

d. App: The City’s determination area was sufficiently distressed to justify a program of economic

rejuvenation is entitled to the court’s deference. Plan also likely will provide appreciable benefits to the

community like new jobs and tax revenue.

e. Holding: Therefore, the plan unquestionably serves a public purpose, so the takings satisfy the public use

requirement of the 5th

amendment.

f. Dissent: Public use requirement: Government may compel an individual to forfeit her property for the

public use, but not for the benefit of another private person. This requirement promotes fairness and

security.

g. 3 categories of taking that comply with the public use requirement

i. Sovereign may transfer private property to public ownership (i.e. for road, hospital, or military base)

ii. The sovereign may transfer private property to private parties, often common carriers, who make the

property available for the public use (i.e. railroad, public utility, or stadium)

iii. In certain circumstances, takings that serve a public purpose also satisfy the Constitution even it the

property is destined for subsequent private use. (Berman and Midkiff)

1. In Berman and Midkiff, the relevant legislative body found that eliminating the existing

property use was necessary to remedy the harm. So a public purpose was realized when the

harmful use was eliminated. Plus, the taking directly achieved the public benefit. (Incidental

benefit, like tax revenue, more jobs, and improve aesthetics, don’t constitute “public use”)

2. App: Kelo and Dery’s well-kept homes are not the source of any social harm.

b. Regulatory Takings (a.k.a. inverse condemnation doctrine): if the government regulates property in an especially severe

way, the regulation will be deemed a “taking” of private property, just as if the government exercised eminent domain, and

thus must provide “just compensation” to the property owner

i. Intro

1. When police power goes too far, and may stray into eminent domain, the regulatory takings doctrine applies

and forces the government to provide “just compensation” to the land owner just as if they had taken the

property via eminent domain.

a. Regulatory Takings adopts a “liability rule” rather than “property rule” approach to protecting property

2. Regulatory Takings Doctrine is the most powerful constraint of the government

3. *Government can impose servitudes on property owners without compensation

ii. Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon (1922) Origins of the Regulatory Takings Doctrine

1. Facts: surface owners signed a deed to conveying their mineral rights to the mining company that included a

covenant waiving the common-law right of subjacent support (the company must make sure their activities

don’t cause damage to buildings and land on the surface)

2. Rules:

a. 3 factors to consider whether a police regulation “goes too far” beyond police power and must be

regarded as eminent domain (where just compensation must be provided)

i. The diminution in value caused by the regulation

ii. The need to protect the public against nuisance-like harms

iii. Reciprocity of advantage among property owners

Page 37: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

b. If surface owner wants to regulate sub-surface owner’s rights to ensure that it doesn’t harm their surface

property (like a house), then the surface owner must provide just compensation to the sub-surface

owner for them to keep sufficient supports if they want protection.

c. “The general rule at least is that while property may be regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes

too far it will be recognized as a taking.”

3. App: Harm to a single house is not common or public, so cannot use eminent domain, if they want to regulate

another property owner’s rights they must provide just compensation.

4. Holding: “So far as private person’s or communities have seen fit to take the risk of acquiring only surface

rights, we cannot see that the fact that their risk has become a danger warrants the giving to them greater

rights than they bought.” So, they must pay just compensation if they want to prevent property owner from

enjoying their property to a certain extent.

a. Mining company doesn’t need to contribute to a fund to pay compensation to surface owners of mining

companies that go bankrupt. Even with this ruling, the company continues to pay subsidence damages

to surface owners where they mine.

5. Dissent: the act protects citizens from nuisance and danger so police power should extend to ensure the

public is protected from those real dangers. The potentially harmful property owner shouldn’t be paid

compensation for them to stop using the land in a harmful manner to other property owners. When private

citizens invoke the Kohler Act, the government should help them if it is a reasonable harm.

c. Penn Central Transportation Co. v. City of New York (1978) 3 new factors to consider for takings

i. Facts: Penn Central owns the Terminal which is designated a historical landmark. Penn Central then enters a 50 year

lease agreement with UGP who wants to build a high rise on top of the Terminal. As the law requires, they submit the

plans to the “Commission” for approval but are denied twice because they think it would destroy the dramatic view of

the building. Penn and UGP did not seek judicial review of the denial and filed suit in NY state court saying it was a

"taking."

ii. PP: TC: granted injunction and declaratory relief. App: reversed b/c although deprived of the property's most profitable

use, they weren't deprived of the property itself. NY Ct of last resort: affirmed, USSC: affirm

c. Rules: i. 5th Amendment: nor shall private property be taken for public use without just compensation.

ii. USSC defined purpose of 5th Amendment: a guarantee designed to bar government from forcing some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should be borne by the public as a whole

iii. Context: Whether a particular restriction will be rendered invalid by the government's failure to pay for any losses proximately caused by it depends largely "upon the particular circumstances in that case."

iv. 3 Factors of particular significance when determining if something is a "taking 1. The economic impact of the regulation on the claimant 2. The extend to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment backed expectations 3. Character of the governmental action

v. Difference between taking and not one: Taking found when the interference with property can be characterized as a physical invasion by government than when interference arises from some public program adjusting the benefits and burdens of economic life to promote the common good.

vi. Government may execute laws or programs that adversely affect recognized economic values. i.e. taxing power d. P Claim #1: gov took "air rights" so they are entitled to just compensation

i. USSC: No, "Taking jurisprudence does not divide a single parcel into discrete segments and attempt to determine whether rights in a particulate segment have been entirely abrogated.

e. P claim #2: constitutes a taking b/c significant diminished value of the Terminal site. i. USSC: Diminution in property value, standing alone, cannot establish a "taking."

1. i.e. 75% diminution and 87.5% diminution, not considered taking f. P claim #3: a taking b/c Landmarks law more severely hurts certain owners in comparison to others.

i. USSC: just because some parties are harmed more than others doesn’t mean it is a taking g. P claim #4: this case is like Causby where gov invasion of airspace destroyed the use of the farm beneath.

i. USSC: the NY law has not impaired the present use of the Terminal and the law doesn’t exploits the parcel for city purposes. Not like Causby at all.

h. App: Not a taking. Since the impact isn't that severe. They have not taken their air rights, its just that they can't built 53 floor building, likely can use the space for other things, also the fact that the rights are transferable to 8 other parcels, at least one of which can build new office buildings shows that there was some valuable compensation.

Page 38: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

i. Holding: Application of NYC's landmark law has not effected a taking of Penn's property. The restrictions imposed are substantially relation to the promotion of the general welfare and not only permit reasonable beneficial use of the landmark site but also afford appellants opportunities further use to enhance not only the Terminal site, but also other properties.

j. Dissent by Rehnquist, the Chief Justice, and Stevens: the NY law constitutes a taking. i. Property: Property is the entire group of rights in the person's ownership. Penn central absent the permission of

the Commission must forever maintain its property in its present state. ii. Taking: Since deprivation to the owner has occurred, the commission has taken substantial property rights from

Penn. iii. 2 examples that Don't constitute a taking

1. A prohibition simply upon the property for purposes that are declared, by valid legislation, to be injurious to the health, morals, or safety of the community, cannot, be deemed a taking.

a. Rationale: That legislation doesn’t disturb the owner in the control of his property for lawful purposes.

b. App: Penn wants to use the land for lawful purposes but is prevented 2. Average reciprocity of advantage: like in zoning where people may be harmed but are in other way

benefited. In this case, Penn is harmed by the millions and are getting very little benefit in return iv. Just Compensation: the fifth amendment does not allow simply an approximate compensation but requires a full

and perfect equivalent for the property taken. 1. Should remand to determine if transfer Development Rights are "just compensation" as in full and perfect

equivalent for the property taken. k. Notes:

i. Mahon's three factors to determine if a "taking" exists 1. Diminution in value 2. Whether the measure is designed to regulate a nuisance; AND 3. Reciprocity of advantage.

ii. Penn Central's 3 new factors 1. Economic impact of the regulation 2. Its interference with reasonable investment backed expectations 3. Character of the government action: reciprocity of advantage considered

iii. Zoning: zoning is not a taking on its face but may constitute a taking if the value of the property becomes near $0 iv. Abrogation: to abolish or take as nonexistent

1. Penn Central Main Point: the government can abrogate an owner's right to destroy property without incurring any taking liability, at least when the financial burden is not too extreme.

2. Abrogation of the right to sell is not a taking 3. Elimination of the right to transmit property upon death will presumptively be regarded as a taking 4. Abrogation of the right to exclude is regarded as particularly serious for takings purposes

v. Context is extremely important in each Takings case vi. Scalia: a regulatory taking generally doesn't occur so long as land retains substantial (albeit not its full) value.

vii. Commentators find 2 unintended consequences of freezing buildings for historical preservation 1. Persons who own buildings that are potential targets for historic preservation designation may rush to

demolish them before they are protected; AND 2. Persons who are contemplating commissioning the construction of new buildings may turn down

dramatic or innovation designs out of fear that they will be rewarded with a historic preservation designation.

l. Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp. (1982) Permanent physical occupation= taking . Facts: Jean Loretto purchases buildings and discovers the existence of the cable. In 1976, on behalf of all owners of

real property in the state on which Teleprompter has placed CATV components. i. Statute: LL may not interfere with the installation of cable television facilities upon his property or premises and

may not demand payment from tenants for permitting CATV or demand payment from CATV than is determined to be reasonable. LL may require CATV or tenant to bear the cost of installation and to indemnify for any damage caused by the installation. LL entitled to one-time $1 normal fee. $1 b/c price that the little property would cost if condemned.

ii. PP: TC: SJ for teleprompter, App: affirm, Last Resort: Affirm, USSC: reverse iii. Rules:

i. Main Rule: A permanent physical occupation authorized by government is a taking without regard to the public interests that it may serve.

Page 39: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

ii. 3 factors to consider: (1) economic impact of the regulation, (2) degree of interference with investment-backed expectations, (3) character of the governmental action

iii. A taking may more readily be found when the interference with property can be characterized as a physical invasion by government than when interference arises from some public program adjusting the benefits and burdens of economic life to promote the common good.

iv. When the physical intrusion reaches the extreme form of a permanent physical occupation, a taking has occurred.

v. Pumpelly v. Green Bay Co: D's construction of a dam that permanently flooded P's property constituted a taking.

1. Rationale: Where real estate is actually invaded by super induced additions of water, earth, sand, or other material, or by having any artificial structure placed on it, so as to effectually destroy or impair its usefulness, it is a taking within the meaning of the Constitution.

vi. Northern Transportation Co v. Chicago: city's construction of a temporary dam in a river to permit construction of a tunnel was not a taking even though the P's were denied access to their premises b/c the obstruction only impaired the sue of the property.

vii. Difference between the two cases: In Pumpelly, there was a physical invasion of the real estate of the private owner and a practical ouster of his possession. In Northern, there was no entry made upon the P's lot.

viii. US v. Causby: frequent flights immediately above a landowner's property constituted a taking 1. Since the flights were so frequent at such a low altitude that respondents could not use their land for

any purpose, their loss was complete. Its the same as if the US gov entered the surface of the land and taken exclusive possession

ix. Con: When the character of the government action is a permanent physical occupation of property, out cases uniformly have found a taking to the extent of the occupation without regard to whether the action achieves an important public benefit or has only minimal impact on the owner.

x. Determining which test to use: So long as these regulations do not require the LL to suffer the physical occupation of a portion of his building by a third party, they will be analyzed under the multifactor inquiry generally applicable to non-possessory governmental activity.

xi. Traditional rule: a permanent physical occupation of property is a taking. xii. 3 factor test used when state imposes restrictions upon an owner's use of his property

IV.App: Teleprompter's cable installation on appellant's building constitutes a taking under the traditional test. The installation involved direct physical attachment of plates, boxes, wires, bolts, and screws to the building, completely occupying space immediately above and upon the roof and long the buildings' exterior wall.

V.Holding: Reverse. The statute constitutes a taking because it allows a third party to enter people's property to place permanent fixtures on the buildings without permission or any say by the landowner.

VI.Dissent by Blackmun, Brennan and White: would affirm. Statute allowing cable box doesn't constitute a taking i. USSC #1: permanent physical occupation is a per se taking b/c it uniquely impairs appellant's powers to dispose of,

use, and exclude other from her property 1. Dissent: states traditionally and constitutionally have exercised their police power to require LLs to

provide utility connections, mailboxes, smoke detectors, fire extinguishers, and the like in the common area of the building.

ii. USSC #2: statue unconstitutionally alters appellant's right to control the use of her one-eight cubic foot of roof space

1. Dissent: If mailboxes are considered ok, then cable boxes should too. iii. USSC #3: statute has deprived appellant of her power to exclude the occupier from possession and use of the

space occupied by the cable 0. Dissent: 2 flaws. (1) assumes that tenants don’t' have a property interest in that space and (2) suggests

gov police law can't take away 1/8 cubic foot of property owner's space that she isn't using. VII. Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council (1992) Total loss of economic benefit of property= taking

a. Facts: 1986, Lucas purchased two beachfront lots for $975,000. 1988, Beachfront Management Act enacted which prohibited Lucas from building occupiable improvements anywhere on his lots

b. PP: TC: yes a taking. When bought no restrictions, after Act, Lucas deprived of any reasonable economic use of the lots and rendered the lots valueless. Ordered gov to pay just compensation in the amount of $1,232,387.50. Supreme Ct of SC: reversed: ruled that when a regulation respecting the use of property is deigned to prevent serious public harm, no compensation is owing under the Takings Clause regardless of the regulation's effect on the property's value. USSC: Reverse, a taking

c. Rules: (Scalia w/ majority) i. Rationale for takings doctrine: "while property may be regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes to far it will

be recognized as a taking.

Page 40: Property Sharfstein Fall09 Outline

ii. Ct generally engages in ad hoc factual inquiry except for 2 per se instances 1. Loretto: Regulations that compel the property owner to suffer a physical invasion of his property. In

general (at least with regard to permanent invasions) no matter how minute the intrusion, and no matter how weighty the public purpose behind it, we can required compensation."

2. Lucas: where there exists categorical treatment appropriate is where regulation denies all economically beneficial or productive use of land.

iii. (There are two discrete categories of regulatory deprivations that are compensable under Fifth Amendment without case-specific inquiry into public interest advanced in support of restraint; the first encompasses regulations that compel property owner to suffer physical invasion of his property, and the second concerns situation in which regulation denies all economically beneficial or productive use of land.)

iv. Difficult issue to determine when there is enough diminution but don't have to worry about that here because 1. Fee simple gets strong protection at common law 2. TC found that Lucas's land is without value because of the regulation

v. When owner of real property has been called upon to sacrifice all economically beneficial use of property in name of common good, that is, to leave his property economically idle, he has suffered a “taking” within meaning of Fifth Amendment.

vi. Where state seeks to sustain regulation that deprives land of all economically beneficial use, it may resist compensation only if logically antecedent inquiry into nature of owner's estate shows that proscribed use interests were not part of his title to begin with.

d. App/Holding: Since the South Carolina Beachfront regulation deprives Lucas of all "economically beneficial use" of his property it constitutes a per se taking and the government is liable to him for "just compensation."

e. Justice Kennedy Concurring: Nuisance law is to narrow to include regulatory takings f. Justice Blackmun Dissenting: find no clear historical compact or understanding of the citizens justifying the new

takings doctrine that the legislature can't deprive a property owner of the only economically valuable use of his land. i. 19th century, state gov often felt free to take property for roads and other public projects w/o paying

compensation ii. 1802 citizens were bound to contribute as much of land as by law of the country were deemed necessary for the

public convenience iii. Courts have been less likely to find that gov action constitutes a taking when the affected land is undeveloped.

g. Justice Stevens Dissent: Court's rule is arbitrary. i. If value diminished by 95% not a taking but 100% a taking but the value of the land isn't zero. Lucas can still use it

for fishing, camping or sell to neighbor as a buffer. ii. Criticizes that the majority takes an ex post perspective without considering the ex ante policy issues.

iii. Generality of the Beachfront Management act is significant. Act regulates the coast line of the whole state. The act applies to owner who have developed their land who cannot rebuild if their home is destroyed nor can they build storm surge walls and they msut refill the beach with sand.

h. Notes: i. 3 categorical per se rules for Takings liability

1. Regulations that permit permanent physical occupations always constitute a taking (Loretto) 2. Regulations that deprive owners of "all economically beneficial or productive use of land" also constitute

a taking a. 2 meanings of "economically beneficial" or "productive

i. When the land has a fair market value of zero (not the case in Lucas) ii. When the gov has denied eth owner the right to build on or otherwise economically extract

value from the land (like in farming) but gov often does this 3. Formal exercise of eminent domain: Rule: when the gov physically takes possession of an interest in

property for some public purpose, it has a categorical duty toe compensate the former owner regardless of whether the interest that is taken constitutes an entire parcel or merely a part thereof.

ii. Temporary deprivation of benefit: regulations that temporarily deprive owners of all economically beneficial use should be assessed under the ad hoc test of Penn Central.