Predatory Growth

download Predatory Growth

of 5

Transcript of Predatory Growth

  • 7/27/2019 Predatory Growth

    1/5

    commentary

    apri l 19, 200 8 EPW Economic & Political Weekly10

    Pd Gwh

    amit bhaduri

    The much-hyped story o Indias

    economic growth hides the truth

    about heightened inequality,

    the blatant biases against the

    poor, the hostility o the state

    toward welare, and the misery

    wrought upon the poorest o the

    poor. Only an alternative path to

    development that lays stress on

    dignity and participation o all

    sections can be an answer to the

    ravages o predatory growth.

    Over the last two decades or so, the

    two most populous large coun-

    tries in the world, China and

    India, have been growing at rates consi-

    derably higher than the world average. In

    recent years the growth rate o national

    product o China has been about three

    times, and that o India approximately

    two times that o the world average. This

    has led to a clever deence o globalisation

    by a ormer chie economist o the Inter-

    national Monetary Fund (IMF) [Fisher

    2003]. Although China and India eature

    as only two among some 150 countries or

    which data are available, he reminded us

    that together they account or the major-

    ity o the poor in the world. This means

    that even i the rich and the poor countries

    o the world are not converging in terms o

    per capita income, the well above the

    average world rate o growth o these two

    large countries implies that the current

    phase o globalisation is reducingglobal inequality and poverty at a rate as

    never beore.

    Statistical hal truths can be more mis-

    leading at times than untruths. And this

    might be one o them, insoar as the expe-

    riences o ordinary Indians contradict

    such statistical arteacts. Since citizens

    in India can express reasonably reely

    their views at least at the time o

    elections, their electoral verdicts on the

    regime o high growth should be

    indicative. They have invariably been neg-

    ative. Not only did the shining India

    image crash badly in the last general elec-

    tion, even the present prime minister,

    widely presented as the guru o Indias

    economic liberalisation in the media,

    could never personally win an election in

    his lie. As a result, come election time,

    and all parties talk not o economic

    reorm, liberalisation and globalisation,

    but o greater welare measures to be

    initiated by the state. Gone electiontimes, and the reorm agenda is back.

    Something clearly needs to be deciphered

    rom such predictable swings in political

    pronouncement.

    Livd expis

    Politicians know that ordinary people are

    not persuaded by statistical mirages andnumbers, but by their daily experiences.

    They do not accept high growth on its ace

    value as unambiguously benecial. I the

    distribution o income turns viciously

    against them and the opportunities or

    reasonable employment and livelihood do

    not expand with high growth, the purpose

    o higher growth would be widely

    questioned in a democracy. This is indeed

    what is happening, and it might even

    appear to some as paradoxical. The estive

    mood generated by high growth is mari-

    nated in popular dissent and despair,

    turning oten into repressed anger. Like a

    malignant malaise, a sense o political

    unease is spreading insidiously along with

    the near double-digit growth. And, no

    major political party, irrespective o their

    right or let label, is escaping it because

    they all subscribe to an ideology o growth

    at any cost.

    Uqul GwhWhat exactly is the nature o this paradox-

    ical growth that increases output and pop-

    ular anger at the same time? India has

    long been accustomed to extensive pover-

    ty coexisting with growth, with or without

    its socialist pattern. It continues to have

    anywhere between one-third and one-

    ourth o its population living in sub-

    human, absolute poverty. The number o

    people condemned to absolute poverty

    declined very slowly in India over the last

    two decades, leaving some 303 million

    people still in utter misery. In contrast

    China did better with the number o

    absolutely poor declining rom 53 per cent

    to 8 per cent, i e, a reduction o some 45

    percentage points, quite an achievement

    compared to Indias 17 percentage points.

    However, while China grew aster,

    inequality or relative poverty also grew

    aster in China than in India. Some claim

    that the increasing gap between the

    richer and the poorer sections in theChinese society during the recent period

    has been one o the worst in recorded

    Amit Bhaduri ([email protected]) is

    with the Council or Social Development andthe Jawaharlal Nehru University, both in

    New Delhi.

  • 7/27/2019 Predatory Growth

    2/5

    commentary

    Economic & Political Weekly EPW april 19, 2008 11

    economic history, perhaps with the excep-

    tion o some ormer socialist countries

    immediately ater the collapse o the

    Soviet Union.

    The share in national income o the

    poorest 20 per cent o the population in

    contemporary China is 5.9 per cent,

    compared to 8.2 per cent in India[Radhakrishna 2008]. This implies that

    the lowest 20 per cent income group in

    China and in India receives about 30 and

    40 per cent o the per capita average in-

    come o their respective countries. How-

    ever, since China has over two times the

    average per capita income o India in

    terms o both purchasing power parity,

    and dollar income, the poorest 20 per

    cent in India are better o in relative

    terms, but worse o in absolute terms.

    The Gini coecient, lying between zero

    and one, measures inequality, and increases

    in value with the degree o inequality.

    In China, it had a value close to 0.50 in

    2006, one o the highest in the world.

    Inequality has grown also in India, but

    less sharply. Between 1993-94 and

    2004-05, the coecient rose rom 0.25 to

    0.27 in urban, and 0.31 to 0.35 in rural ar-

    eas. Every dimension o inequality, among

    the regions, among the proessions and

    sectors, and in particular between urbanand rural areas has also grown rapidly in

    both countries, even aster in China than

    in India. In short, China has done better

    than India in reducing absolute poverty,

    but worse in allowing the gap to grow

    rapidly between the rich and the poor

    during the recent period o high growth.

    A central act stands out. Despite vast

    dierences in the political systems o the

    two countries, the common actor has

    been increasing inequality accompanying

    higher growth. What is not usually

    realised is that the growth in output and

    in inequality are not two isolated pheno-

    mena. One requently comes across the

    platitude that high growth will soon be

    trickling down to the poor, or that redistri-

    butive action by the state through scal

    measures could decrease inequality while

    keeping up the growth rate. These state-

    ments are comortable but unworkable,

    because they miss the main characteristic

    o the growth process underway. Thispattern o growth is propelled by a

    powerul reinorcing mechanism, which

    the economist Gunner Myrdal had once

    described as cumulative causation. The

    mechanism by which growing inequality

    drives growth, and growth uels urther

    inequality has its origin in two dierent

    actors, both related to some extent

    to globalisation.

    Jblss Gwh

    First, in contrast to earlier times when less

    than 4 per cent growth on an average was

    associated with 2 per cent growth in

    employment, India is experiencing a

    growth rate o some 7-8 per cent in recent

    years, but the growth in regular employ-

    ment has hardly exceeded 1 per cent. This

    means most o the growth, some 5-6 per

    cent o the GDP, is the result not o employ-

    ment expansion, but o higher output per

    worker. This high growth o output has its

    source in the growth o labour productivi-

    ty. According to ocial statistics, between

    1991 and 2004 employment ell in the

    organised public sector, and the organised

    private sector hardly compensated or it.

    In the corporate sector, and in some orga-

    nised industries, productivity growth

    comes rom mechanisation and longer

    hours o work. Edward Luce oFinancial

    Times (London) reported that the

    Jamshedpur steel plant o the Tatasemployed 85,000 workers in 1991 to pro-

    duce one million tonnes o steel worth

    $ 0.8 million. In 2005, the production rose

    to ve million tonnes, worth about $ ve

    million, while employment ell to 44,000.

    In short, output increased approximately

    by a actor o ve, employment dropped

    by a actor o hal, implying an increase in

    labour productivity by a actor o 10.

    Similarly, Tata Motors in Pune reduced

    the number o workers rom 35,000 to

    21,000 but increased the production o

    vehicles rom 1,29,000 to 3,11,500 between

    1999 and 2004, implying a labour produc-

    tivity increase by a actor o our. Stephen

    Roach, chie economist o Morgan Stanley,

    reports similar cases o Bajaj motor cycle

    actory in Pune. In the mid-1990s the ac-

    tory employed 24,000 workers to produce

    one million units o two-wheelers. Aided

    by Japanese robotics and Indian inorma-

    tion technology, in 2004, 10,500 workers

    turned out 2.4 million units more thandouble the output with less than hal

    the labour orce, an increase in labour

    productivity by a actor o nearly six.1 One

    could multiply such examples, but this is

    broadly the name o the game everywhere

    in the private corporate sector.

    augd Pf d mis

    The maniold increase in labour produc-

    tivity, without a corresponding increase inwages and salaries, becomes an enormous

    source o prot, and also a source o inter-

    national price competitiveness in a globa-

    lising world. Nevertheless, this is not the

    entire story, perhaps not even the most

    important part o the story. The whole

    organised sector to which the corporate

    sector belongs, accounts or less than

    one-tenth o the labour orce. Simply by

    the arithmetic o weighted average, a 5-6

    per cent annual growth in labour produc-

    tivity in the entire economy is possible

    only i the unorganised sector accounting

    or the remaining 90 per cent o the

    labour orce also contributes to the

    growth in labour productivity. Direct

    inormation is not available on this count,

    but several micro-studies and surveys

    show the broad pattern. Growth o labour

    productivity in the unorganised sector,

    which includes most o agriculture, comes

    rom lengthening the hours o work to a

    signicant extent, as this sector has nolabour laws worth the name, or social se-

    curity to protect workers. Subcontracting

    to the unorganised sector along with casu-

    alisation o labour on a large scale become

    convenient devices to ensure longer hours

    o work without higher pay. Sel-employed

    workers, totalling 260 mill ion, expanded

    astest during the high growth regime,

    providing an invisible source o labour

    productivity growth [the data in Ranga-

    rajan et al 2007 could be interpreted this

    way]. Ruthless sel-exploitation by many

    o these workers in a desperate attempt to

    survive by doing long hours o work with

    very little extra earning adds both to pro-

    ductivity growth, oten augmenting

    corporate prot, and human misery.

    However, inequality is increasing or

    another reason. Its ideology oten de-

    scribed as neoliberalism is easily visible at

    one level; but the underlying deeper rea-

    son is seldom discussed. The increasing

    openness o the Indian economy to inter-national nance and capital fows, rather

    than to trade in goods and services, has

  • 7/27/2019 Predatory Growth

    3/5

    commentary

    apri l 19, 200 8 EPW Economic & Political Weekly12

    had the consequence o paralysing many

    pro-poor public policies. Despite the act

    that we continue to import more than we

    export (unlike China), Indias comortable

    oreign reserves position is mostly the

    result o accumulated portolio invest-

    ments and short-term capital infows rom

    various nancial institutions. To keep theshow going in this way, the scal and the

    monetary policies o the government need

    to comply with the interests o the nan-

    cial markets. That is the reason why

    successive Indian governments have will-

    ingly accepted the Fiscal Responsibility

    and Budget Management Act (2003)

    restricting decit spending. Similarly, the

    idea has gained support that the govern-

    ment should raise resources through

    privatisation and so-called public-private

    partnership, but not through raising scal

    decit, or not imposing a signicant turn

    over tax on transactions o securities.

    These measures rattle the sentiment o

    the nancial markets, so governments

    remain wary o them.

    The hidden agenda, vigorously pursued

    by governments o all colour, has been to

    keep the large private players in the nan-

    cial markets in a happy mood. Since the

    private banks and nancial institutions

    usually take their lead rom the IMF andthe World Bank, this bestows on these

    multilateral agencies considerable power

    over the ormulation o government poli-

    cies. However, the burden o such policies

    is borne largely by the poor o this coun-

    try. This has had a crippling eect on poli-

    cies or expanding public expenditure or

    the poor in the social sector. Inequality

    and distress grows as the state rolls back

    public expenditure in social services like

    basic health, education, and public distri-

    bution and neglects the poor, while the

    discipline imposed by the nancial mar-

    kets serves the rich and the corporations.

    This process o high growth traps roughly

    one in three citizens o India in extreme

    poverty with no possibility o escape

    through either regular employment growth

    or relie through state expenditure on

    social serv ices. The high growth scene o

    India appears to them like a wasteland

    leading to the hell described by the great

    Italian poet Dante. On the gate o his im-agined hell is written, This is the land

    you enter ater abandoning all hopes.

    Extremely slow growth in employment

    and eeble public action exacerbates ine-

    quality, as a disproportionately large share

    o the increasing output and income rom

    growth goes to the richer section o the

    population, not more than say the top 20

    per cent o the income receivers in India.

    At the extreme ends o income distribu-tion the picture that emerges is one o

    striking contrasts. According to theForbes

    magazine list or 2007, the number o

    Indian billionaires rose rom nine in 2004

    to 40 in 2007: much richer countries like

    Japan had only 24, France 14 and Italy 14.

    Even China, despite its sharply increasing

    inequality, had only 17 billionaires. The

    combined wealth o Indian billionaires

    increased rom $ 106 to $ 170 billion in the

    single year, 2006-07 [inormation rom

    Forbes quoted in Jain and Gupta 2008].

    This 60 per cent increase in wealth would

    not have been possible, except through

    transer on land rom the state and central

    governments to the private corporations

    in the name o public purpose, or

    mining, industrialisation and special

    economic zones (SEZs). Estimates based

    on corporate prots suggest that, since

    2000-01 to date, each additional per cent

    growth o GDP has led to an average o

    some 2.5 per cent growth in corporateprots. Indias high growth has certainly

    beneted the corporations more than

    anyone else.

    Ater several years o high growth along

    these lines, India o the 21st century has

    the distinction o being only second to the

    US in terms o combined total wealth o its

    corporate billionaires coexisting with the

    largest number o homeless, ill-ed and

    illiterates in the world. Not surprisingly,

    or ordinary Indians at the receiving end,

    this growth process is devoid o all hope

    or escape. Nearly hal o Indian children

    under six years suer rom under-weight

    and malnutrition, nearly 80 per cent

    rom anaemia, while some 40 per cent o

    Indian adults suer rom chronic energy

    decit. Destitution, chronic hunger and

    poverty kill and cripple silently thou-

    sands, picking on systematically the more

    vulnerable. The problem is more acute in

    rural India, among small children, preg-

    nant emales, dalits and adivasis, espe-cially in the poorer states [Radhakrishna

    2008], while market-oriented policies and

    reorms continue to widen the gap

    between the rich and the poor, as well as

    among regions.

    I elsiiis Dd

    The growth dynamics in operation is

    being ed continuously by growing

    inequality. With their income rapidlygrowing, the richer group o Indians

    demand a set o goods, which lie outside

    the reach o the rest in the society (think

    o air-conditioned malls, luxury hotels,

    restaurants and apartments, private cars,

    world class cities where the poor would be

    made invisible). The market or these

    goods expands rapidly. For instance, we

    are told that more than three in our

    Indians do not have a daily income o $ 2.

    They can hardly be a part o this growing

    market. However, the logic o the market

    now takes over, as the market is dictated

    by purchasing power. Its logic is to pro-

    duce those goods or which there is enough

    demand backed by money, so that high

    prices can be charged and handsome

    prots can be made. As the income o the

    privileged grows rapidly, the market or

    the luxury goods they demand grows even

    aster through the operation o the

    income elasticities o demand. These

    elasticities roughly measure the per centgrowth in the demand or particular goods

    due to 1 per cent growth in income (at un-

    changed prices). Typically, goods con-

    sumed by the rich have income elasticities

    greater than unity, implying that the

    demand or a whole range o luxury

    goods consumed by the rich expands

    even aster than the growth in their

    income. Thus, the pattern o production is

    dictated by this process o growth through

    raising both the income o the rich aster

    than that o the rest o the society, and

    also because the income elasticities oper-

    ate to increase even aster the demand or

    luxuries than income.

    ai-P

    The production structure resulting rom

    this market-driven high growth is heavily

    biased against the poor. While demand

    expands rapidly or various up-market

    goods, demand or the basic necessities

    o lie hardly expands. Not only is therelittle growth in the purchasing power o

    the poor, but the reduction in welare

  • 7/27/2019 Predatory Growth

    4/5

    commentary

    Economic & Political Weekly EPW april 19, 2008 13

    expenditures by the state stunts the

    growth in demand or necessities. The

    rapid shit in the output composition in

    avour o services might be indicative o

    this process at the macro level [Rakshit

    2007]. But specic examples abound. We

    have state-o-the-art corporate run expen-

    sive hospitals, nursing homes and spas orthe rich, but not enough money to control

    malaria and tuberculosis which require

    inexpensive treatment. So they continue

    to kill the largest numbers. Lack o sani-

    tation and clean drinking water transmit

    deadly diseases especially to small chil-

    dren which could be prevented at little

    cost, while bottled water o various brands

    multiply or those who can aord. Private

    schools or rich kids oten have monthly

    ees that are higher than the annual

    income o an average unskilled Indian

    worker, while the poor oten have to be

    satised with schools without teachers, or

    class rooms.

    Over time an increasingly irreversible

    production structure in avour o the rich

    begins to consolidate itsel, because the

    investments embodied in the specic

    capital goods created to produce luxuries

    cannot easily be converted to producing

    basic necessities (the luxury hotel or spa

    cannot be converted easily to a primaryhealth centre in a village, etc). And yet, it

    is the logic o the market to direct invest-

    ments towards the most productive and

    protable sectors or the ecient alloca-

    tion o resources. The price mechanism

    sends signals to guide this allocation, but

    the prices that rule are largely a conse-

    quence o the growing unequal distribu-

    tion o income in the society. The market

    becomes a bad master when the distri-

    bution o income is bad.

    Highd mis h P

    There are insidious consequences o such

    a composition o output biased in avour

    o the rich that our liberalised market sys-

    tem produces. It is highly energy, water

    and other non-reproducible resources

    intensive, and oten does unacceptable

    violence to the environment. We only have

    to think o the energy and material con-

    tent o air-conditioned malls, luxury hotels

    and apartments, air travels, or private carsas means o transport. These are no doubt

    symbols o world class cities in a poor

    country, by diverting resources rom the

    country side where most live. It creates a

    black hole o urbanisation with a giant

    appetite or primary non-reproducible

    resources. Many are orced to migrate to

    cities as ertile land is diverted to non-

    agricultural use, water and electricity are

    taken away rom arms in critical agricul-tural seasons to supply cities, and develop-

    mental projects displaces thousands.

    Hydroelectric power rom the big dams is

    transmitted mostly to corporate indus-

    tries, and a ew posh urban localities,

    while the nearby villages are let in dark-

    ness. Peasants even close to the cities do

    not get electricity or water to irrigate their

    land as urban India increasingly gobbles

    up these resources. Take the pattern o

    water use. According to the Comptroller

    and Auditor General report released to the

    public on March 30, 2007, Gujarat

    increased the allocation o Narmada

    waters to industry veold during 2006,

    eating into the share o drought-aected

    villages. Despite many promises made to

    villagers, water allocation stagnated at

    0.86 million acres eet (MAF), and even

    this is being cut.

    Water companies and sot drink giants

    like Coca Cola sink deeper to take out pure

    groundwater as ree raw material or theirproducts. Peasants in surrounding areas

    pay, because they cannot match the tech-

    nology or capital cost. Iron ore is mined

    out in Jharkhand, Chhattisgarh and Orissa

    leaving tribals without home or livelihood.

    Common lands which traditionally pro-

    vided supplementary income to the poor

    in villages are encroached upon systemati-

    cally by the local rich and the corporations

    with active connivance o the government.

    The maniest crisis engulng Indian agri-

    culture with more than a hundred thousand

    suicides by armers over the last decade

    according to ocial statistics is a pointer to

    this process o pampering the rich who use

    their growing economic power to domi-

    nate increasingly the multitude o poor.

    n Pl h Ps

    The composition o output demanded by

    the rich is hardly producible by village

    artisans or the small producers. They nd

    no place either as producers or as consumers;instead, economic activities catering to the

    rich have to be handed over to large

    corporations who can now enter in a big

    way into the scene. The combination o

    accelerating growth and rising inequality

    begins to work in unison. The corporations

    are needed to produce goods or the rich,

    and in the process they make their high

    prots and provide well-paid employment

    or the rich in a poor country who providea part o the growing market. It becomes a

    process o destructive creation o corporate

    wealth, with a new coalition cutting across

    traditional right and let political divisions

    ormed in the course o this road to high

    growth. The signboard o this road is

    progress through industrialisation.

    The middle class opinion makers and

    the media persons unite, and occasionally

    oer palliatives o air compensation to

    the dispossessed. Yet, they are at a loss as

    to how to create alternative dignied liveli-

    hoods or those aected by large-scale dis-

    placement and destruction in the name o

    industrialisation. Talks o compensation

    tend to be one-sided, as they ocus usually

    on ownership and, at best use rights to

    the landed. However, the multitude o the

    poor who eke out a living without any

    ownership or use right to landed property,

    like agricultural labourers, shermen, or

    cart-drivers in rural areas, or illegal squat-

    ters and small hawkers in cities, seldomgure in this discussion about compensa-

    tion. And yet, they are usually the poorest

    o the poor, outnumbering by ar, perhaps

    in the ratio o 3 to 1, those who have some

    title to landed property. Ignoring them al-

    together, the state acquires with single-

    minded devotion land, water and resources

    or the private corporations or mining,

    industrialisation or SEZs in the name o

    public interest.

    With some tribal land that can be ac-

    quired according to the PESA (1996) Act

    only through the consent o the commu-

    nity (gram sabha), consent is requently

    manuactured at gun point by the law and

    order machinery o the state, i the money

    power o the corporations to bribe and

    intimidate proves to be insucient. The

    vocal supporters o industrialisation

    never stop to ask, why the very poor who

    are least able, should bear the burden o

    economic progress o the rich.

    It amounts to a process o internal colo-nisation o the poor, mostly dalits and adi-

    vasis and o other marginalised groups,

  • 7/27/2019 Predatory Growth

    5/5

    commentary

    apri l 19, 200 8 EPW Economic & Political Weekly14

    through orcible dispossession and subju-

    gation. It has set in motion a social process

    not altogether unknown between the im-

    perialist master race and the colonised

    natives. As the privileged thin layer o

    the society distance themselves rom the

    poor, the speed at which the secession

    takes place comes to be celebrated as ameasure o the rapid growth o the country.

    Thus, India is said to be poised to become a

    global power in the 21st century, with the

    largest number o homeless, under-

    nourished, illiterate children coexisting with

    billionaires created by this rapid growth.

    An unbridled market whose rules are

    xed by the corporations aided by state

    power shapes this process. The ideology o

    progress through dispossession o the

    poor, preached relentlessly by the united

    power o the rich, the middle class and the

    corporations colonise directly the poor,

    and indirectly it has begun to colonise

    our minds. The result is a sort o

    uniorm industrialisation o the mind, a

    standardisation o thoughts which sees no

    other alternative. And yet, there is a atal

    faw. No matter how powerul this united

    campaign by the rich corporations, the

    media and the politicians is, even their

    combined power remains deenceless

    against the actual lie experiences o thepoor. I this process o growth continues

    or long, it would produce its own demons.

    No society, not even our malunctioning

    democratic system, can withstand beyond

    a point the increasing inequality that

    nurtures this high growth. The rising

    dissent o the poor must either be sup-

    pressed with increasing state violence

    fouting every norm o democracy, and

    violence will be met with counter-violence

    to engul the whole society. Or, an alter-

    native path to development that depends

    on deepening our democracy with popular

    participation has to be ound. Neither the

    rulers nor the ruled can escape or long

    this challenge thrown up by the recent

    high growth o India.

    Note

    1 Data collected by Aseem Srivastava, Why ThisGrowth Can Never Trickle Down, Aseem can bereached at [email protected].

    References

    Alternative Economic Survey, India (2006-07): byAlternative Survey Group, New Delhi, DannishBooks.

    Dev, S Mahendra (2008): Inclusive Growth in India,Oxord University Press, New Delhi.

    Fisher, S (2003): Globalisation and Its Challenges,American Economic Review, Papers and Procee-dings, Vol 93, No 2.

    Government o India, Economic Survey (2006-07):Ministry o Finance, New Delhi.

    Green Le t Weekly (2007): Issue No 710, May.

    Rakshit, Mihir (2007): Service-led Growth, Moneyand Finance, February.

    Radhakrishna, R (2008): India Development Report,(ed), Oxord University Press.

    Rangarajan, C et al (2007): Revisiting Employ-ment and Growth, Money and Finance,September.

    Jain, Anil, Kumar and Parul Gupta (2008): Global-isation: The Indian Experience, Mainstream,Delhi, February 8-14.