Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

518
Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government

Transcript of Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Page 1: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Science 100

Introduction to

American Government

Page 2: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Class Number/Section

Class Number: 2294

Section: 4

Page 3: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Value of POSC 100 - 1

Government and Politics Impact almost Every Area of Our Lives

We will examine about as important a group of questions as possible:

Page 4: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Value of POSC 100 - 2

1 – Why Have Government?

2 – How Representative of the Views of Americans are Governmental Policies and Actions?

Page 5: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Value of POSC 100 - 3

3 – How Fair are the Policies American

Governments Produce?

4 – How do Governmental Policies and Actions Affect the Degree of Freedom Americans Possess?

NOTE: Goals May Clash! What’s Good for

Fairness May Not Be Good for Freedom

Page 6: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Content of POSC 100 - 1

Three Sections of the Course:

1. The Need, Purpose, Structure and Performance of Government

2. Mass Politics and Un-Elected

Policymakers

Page 7: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Content of POSC 100 - 2

3. Elected Policy-Makers and Public

Policy

Approach the material in each of these three sections from the standpoint of REPRESENTATION, FAIRNESS

and FREEDOM

Page 8: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

CONDUCT!!!

If you stay in this class you are agreeing to the following rules: (1) Come on Time - if you’re late you must sit on the end in a back row; (2) Stay the Whole Time - if you must leave early (e.g., doctor’s appointment) you need to let me know at the beginning of class; (3) No Talking Unless You are Responding to Me or Another Student’s Comments.

Page 9: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

CONDUCT!!!

The previous rules are all mentioned in the syllabus. You’ll be sanctioned if you don’t follow them. Beginning with the second class meeting and omitting exam days, each student will receive 1 bonus point on their next exam for each class period I don’t have to call someone out for talking in class, leaving class early or arriving late and trying to sit in other than the last couple rows.

Page 10: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

CONDUCT!!!

Either every student receives the possible bonus point for that class meeting or no student receives it. For example, Exam #1 is on the 9th class meeting. Therefore, there are a maximum of 7 bonus points each student could receive on Exam #1 (i.e., 1 point for each class meeting between meetings 2 and 8). If class is cancelled the bonus point will be awarded. There are no bonus points for the final exam or the quizzes.

Page 11: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Grading - 1

As the syllabus, which is in the coursepack

[and is available at my website:

www.csulb.edu/~cdennis (click on “Courses”)] discusses, your grade is based upon four equally weighted components:

Page 12: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Grading - 2

Your best two performances on Exams 1-3. Thus, you poorest performance on Exams 1-3 is dropped. Which of the following is your worst test?

(your score/lowest A)

90/88 91/93 88/85

Page 13: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Grading - 3

The Final Exam counts the same as each of Exams 1-3, however, the Final Exam

CANNOT be dropped.

The last component of your grade is your total score on a series of UNANNOUNCED QUIZZES. Your lowest two scores are dropped.

Page 14: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Grading - 4

Missed Exams and Quizzes: If you miss one of Exams 1-3, for ANY REASON, that is AUTOMATICALLY the exam you drop.

The first two missed quizzes (regardless of the reason you missed) are AUTOMATICALLY dropped.

Page 15: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Grading - 5

Thus, to qualify for a makeup exam you would have to miss two of the first three exams and have a valid excuse posted with me within one week of the second missed exam. To qualify for a makeup quiz you would have to miss three quizzes and have a valid excuse posted with me within one week of the third missed quiz.

Page 16: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Grading - 6

Grades in this section will be like the typical POSC 100 class – about 2.6 on a 4 point scale

Page 17: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Course Materials- 1

You Will Need the Following Materials

from: www.csulb.edu/~cdennis (Click on “Courses”)

1. The Coursepack – Contains the Syllabus, Study Guides and Reading Material Used Later in the Course;

2. Introductory Email/Textbook Information

3. PowerPoint slides

Page 18: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Course Materials- 2

Textbooks:

1. Thomas Patterson, The American

Democracy, 9-11th alternate edition (note it’s the “alternate” edition)

2. Lawrence L. Giventer, Governing California, 2nd edition

Both are bound together in the CSULB

Bookstore. Buying earlier editions can cause you to miss exam questions.

Page 19: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Course Materials- 3

By the beginning of next week you will need to read the first of a series of weekly newspaper columns. Each column will state the days quiz questions could come from that column. No questions on the exams will be taken from the newspaper columns. All the newspaper columns are currently available at my website www.csulb.edu/~cdennis) click on “Courses” and look under POSC 100 for “Newspaper Columns.”

Page 20: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Newspaper Columns

The Newspaper Columns file is password protected. Since the password is not available in any of the material you can download you need to write it down.

Page 21: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Course Materials- 3

For each newspaper column be able to do the following: (1) summarize the column in two sentences; and (2) explain why the column was important enough that I assigned it. If you can do these two things you should be able to answer any question I’ll ask from the newspaper columns.

Page 22: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Make Use of Me!

I. Office Hours: 8:00-9:30 & 10:45-11:00 M,W in SPA-241

II. Phone: See Email I Sent Containing My Phone Number (which isn’t available in downloadable material) - call times: 1:30-2:30 & 3:30-4:30 Tuesday, Thursday, Friday, Saturday and Sunday (No Messages - I Don’t Return Phone Calls) Call – Email Isn’t Good for Questions

Page 23: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Make Use of Me!

III. The Phone is a Method of Helping You

Understand the Lectures. It’s NOT a Method of Avoiding Class or NOT taking Notes when You’re in Class. When You Call, I Will Typically Ask, “What Do Your Notes Say?” I’m Here to Help People Who are Making the Effort to Attend Class and Take Notes.

Page 24: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Make Use of Me!

You can download ALL of the PowerPoint slides for this course at my website (look under the appropriate course). However, knowing these slides is NOT NEARLY sufficient. The slides are outlines and DO NOT contain much of the lecture material that is on the quizzes and tests. I’m glad to help you but for that to happen you’ll need to take notes in class.

Page 25: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 1

I. NEED FOR GOVERNMENT

A. Free Market: voluntary exchanges

between mutually consenting individuals

B. Capitalism: private ownership of

production and distribution

C. THE FREE MARKET/CAPITALISM NEEDS GOVERNMENT!!!

Page 26: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 2

1. Without the government DEFINING what constitutes private property (e.g., the air waves), the SCOPE of private property (e.g., the sidewalk on your property is not under your control) and PROTECTING private property rights (e.g., by the police) the free market/capitalism COULDN’T function.

Page 27: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 3

2. To Provide Public Goods – Characteristics of Public Goods:

a. No one is excluded

Page 28: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 4

b. One person’s consumption of the

good does not reduce the amount available for someone else.

Page 29: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 5

1. Examples: (a) Clean Air – Why would one individual, or group, provide it if everyone else could benefit for free?

(b) National Defense – Would you want private individuals to control nuclear weapons?

(c) Tennessee Valley Authority

(d) Some Medical Research

Page 30: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 6

3. Economic Regulation

a. Natural Monopolies - Government regulation to counteract price gouging by monopolies

b. Where harm is caused by agents who don’t bear the true cost of their action – e.g., individuals and firms that pollute justify a carbon tax

Page 31: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 7

4. Macroeconomic Management

a. Countercyclical spending to offset a recession

1. Balancing the federal budget during a recession would be a disaster!

Page 32: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 8

b. Employer of Last Resort

1. The goal of a business is profit NOT providing jobs.

2. Because government is NOT profit driven, it can create jobs when it is NOT economically profitable for the private sector to do so.

Page 33: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 9

3. It’s well documented that persistent unemployment results in a permanent loss of output and

labor productivity.

4. The U.S. had successful government employment programs during the Great Depression of the 1930s.

So have many other nations.

Page 34: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 10

5. Social Values

a. The ingenuity of capitalism’s “creative destruction” means that business

CANNOT pursue social values/goals over profitability. Thus, the very strength of capitalism is a prime reason why it can be argued that a strong social safety net is absolutely necessary.

b. Example: Increasing Income Inequality

Page 35: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 11

Share of Income Going to the Richest 1% of American Households:

1970 – 9.0%

1990 -14.3%

2012- 21.5%

The above figures are about TWICE as high as in Europe. Should Government Reduce this Huge Increase in Inequality?

Page 36: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 12

c. Effects of Globalization or Internationally Mobile Capital on the Rich and Poor

1. The internet/advanced communications permits emerging nations to rapidly import new technologies.

Page 37: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 13

2.Opening nations such as China to international trade greatly

increased the supply of low skill workers which reduced the income of low skill/income Americans.

3. Governments have competed for capital by lowering taxes, labor standards and government regulation of

business.

Page 38: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 14

4. Lowered labor costs reduce product prices which much more benefits high income Americans whose income aren’t reduced much by international competition.

5. Thus, a very good case can be made that the “winners” under this

scenario should compensate the “losers.”

Page 39: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 15

d. In a private market each person’s “worth” is determined by how much money they have whereas in a political market each voter has one vote. Thus, votes are distributed more equally than money.

Page 40: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 16

e. Therefore, the electoral incentives of government produce a distribution of goods/services that more favors middle and low income groups than occurs in a private market.

f. This is one fundamental reason why liberals like government more than conservatives.

Page 41: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government – 17

6. Lack of Information

Example: Health Care

Page 42: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 18

Comparison of U.S. and Foreign Health Care Systems (2009-2013)

Per Capita WHO

Spending  Ranking

U.S. $8,895 37th

France $4,690 1st

Canada $5,741 30th

U.K. $3,647 18th

Page 43: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Need for Government - 19

What incentive do U.S. insurance companies, pharmaceutical companies, and physicians have to tell you the preceding information?

Page 44: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

POSC 100 – Course Materials

The Coursepack – Contains the Syllabus, Study Guides and Reading Material Used Later in the Course – is available

at: www.csulb.edu/~cdennis (Click on “Courses”)

Page 45: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 1

I. Government Under the Articles of Confederation

 

A. Unanimous Vote of the States Needed to Amend

1. Is Unanimity Necessary for

Representation?

Page 46: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 2

B. National Government Couldn’t Require States to Pay Taxes

1. If some states don’t pay, is this fair?

C. No President or Supreme Court

Page 47: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 3

D. Military Security Needs in the West and the Recession in the Northeast Pitted Region against Region.

1. The national government couldn’t get a unanimous vote. So

these crises weren’t solved.

2. Representation? Fairness?

Page 48: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 4

II. The Constitutional Convention

A. Philosophy of James Madison

1. Freedom “To” (action – e.g., speech) vs. Freedom “From” (e.g., food stamps - government protects you from starving)

Page 49: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 5

2. The Constitution is mainly concerned with protecting the “freedom to.”

B. Philosophy of John Rawls

1. Equal right to the most extensive system of liberties consistent with the guarantee of the

same liberties for all.

Page 50: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 6

2. Any social and economic inequalities should redound to the benefit of society’s least advantaged individuals.

C. How would you compare Madison and Rawls on “fairness” and “representation”?

Page 51: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 7

D. For Madison, Government was the Major Threat to the "Freedom To“ (e.g., Congress shall make no law abridging freedom of speech)

1. Government can be an extender of the “freedom to.”

Page 52: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 8

2. Economic Inequality was not a major concern of Madison.

3. Compared to the Democracies of Western Europe, the U.S. is a

low tax, low social service country.

Page 53: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 9

Tax rates as a percentage of the economy are much lower in the U.S. than in most wealthy democracies:

U.S. – 32.2%, Canada – 38.3%,

Great Britain – 41.2%, Germany – 44.6%,

Italy – 47.8%, Sweden – 50.9%,

France – 52.9% and Denmark – 57.4%.

Source: OECD as reported in NY Times

11/16/14

Page 54: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government – 10A

Federal Taxes as a percentage of our economy are lower today than they have been in over 60 years.

1951- 16.1 % (before Medicare enacted)

1971 – 17.3%

2001 – 19.5%

2011 – 15.4%

Page 55: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government – 10B

Effective Tax Rates on Income of

$100,000 in 2012

Nation Income Tax Social Security

U.S. – 26.0% 18.7% 7.3%

G. Brit.- 31.4% 24.1% 7.3%

Sweden- 36.3% 36.3% 0%

France – 42.0% 20.0% 22.0%

Germany-43.8% 28.3% 15.5%

Page 56: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government – 10C

Government Mandated Paid Annual Leave and Paid Days of Vacation

U.S. - 0

Great Britain - 20

Sweden - 25

German - 30

France - 31

Page 57: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 11

E. Fearing Government, the Founders Made it Difficult for the Government to Act.

1. Separation of Powers

a. Parliamentary Systems combine executive and legislative power

Page 58: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 12

b. Parliamentary Systems encourage more issue oriented voting than

Presidential systems

c. U.S. uses a “winner-take-all” (candidate with most votes wins) rather than proportional (a party receives seats equal to it’s share of the vote) system to elect

representatives.

Page 59: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 13

e. States with approximately 11% of the U.S. population elect a sufficient number of senators (42) to prevent legislation.d. Winner-take-all systems typically produce less government spending to help the poorthan proportional systems.

1. The closer middle class voters’ incomes are to the poor, the more the political power of the poor increases.

Page 60: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 14

2.Checks and Balances

3. Federalism

Page 61: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 15

a. Strengths of Federalism

1.Little Centralized Leadership

2.Increases Participation (offers more offices/chances for citizens to participate in holding/selecting offices)

Page 62: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 16

3. Increases Policy Responsiveness - more decisions are made locally

4. Encouraging Policy Innovation-States are viewed as “laboratories of

democracy”

Page 63: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 17

b. Weaknesses of Federalism

1. Obstructing National Policies –

e.g., protected slavery (might be “responsive” to a local area that desired slavery but definitely not “fair” to slaves)

Page 64: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 18

2. Allows Great Inequalities between

States (fairness?)

3. Confusion: In a crisis what level of government is responsible?

4. Representation: citizens typically are better informed about national than local issues – local decisions more favor the advantaged

Page 65: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 19

F. While Liberty (through Private Property) was Written into the Constitution, a Bill of Rights was Not. Why?

Page 66: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 20

III. Interpretation and Change Under the Constitution

A. Flexibility – The Minnesota Moratorium Act

1. Fairness?

Page 67: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 21

B. Formal Amendment

C. Judicial Review

1. Marbury v. Madison (1803)

Page 68: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government - 22

D. Informal Change – Reinterpreting the Same Words

1. Heart of Atlanta Motel (1965)

2. Fairness?

Page 69: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Structure of Government – 23

IV. National Supremacy

A. McCulloch v. Maryland (1819)

Page 70: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 1

I. California’s Constitution Contains Over 6 Times as Many Words as the U.S. Constitution

A. California Constitution is Frequently Amended

Page 71: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 2

1. U.S. Constitution is Difficult to Amend whereas the California Constitution is Easy to Amend

2. Only 8% of California Voters Need to Sign Petition to put a Constitutional Amendment on the Ballot

Page 72: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 3

3. A Constitutional Initiative only Needs a Majority Vote to Pass

B. Focus of the U.S. Constitution is on the Structure of Government and the Fundamental Law

Page 73: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 4

C. By Contrast, the California Constitution details both Law and Policy (e.g., K-12 Spending Formula)

D. Constitutional Restrictions have made it Very Difficult to Enact a Budget and Raise Taxes

Page 74: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 5

E. Impact on Representation and Fairness

1. Ease of Amending the California Constitution Increases the Likelihood of Discrimination (e.g., Proposition 8)

Page 75: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 6

2. The Initiative Process itself Makes it Much Easier for Special

Interests to Skew Public Policy in their Interests.

a. Monetary Cost of a Successful Ballot

Initiative

Page 76: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Constitution - 7

b. An Initiative Passed with a Majority Vote can Require a Future 2/3rds Vote to Override it.

1. Effects raising taxes and fees, and hence, the California Budget.

Page 77: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Rights - 1

VI. Civil Rights

A. The UNELECTED Supreme Court

acted BEFORE Popularly

Elected Officials

1. Representation? Fairness?

Page 78: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Rights - 2

2. Proposition 14 – 1964

3. Proposition 8 – 2008

B. Least “Threatening” Civil Rights

Laws Enacted First.

Page 79: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Rights - 3

C. Civil Rights helped trigger a large realignment of voters.

Page 80: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Selection - 1

I. Judicial Appointment

A. Constitutional protections require an independent (non-elected) judiciary

1. The Constitution and public law may not be popular but they must be defended.

B. This is why federal judges are appointed, NOT ELECTED.

Page 81: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Selection - 2

C. It is also why federal judges serve for life

D. Federal judges are appointed not on the basis of the popularity of their views, but on the basis of their ability to think clearly about legal and Constitutional questions

Page 82: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Selection – 3

E. DON’T WRITE THE FOLLOWING STATEMENTS FROM PRESIDENTIAL CANDIDATES. JUST READ THEM AND THINK HOW THEY WOULD CHANGE OUR COURT SYSTEM.

1. “Appointees to the federal bench will not receive lifetime appointment” - Rick Perry

Page 83: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Selection - 4

2. “Sign a bill tomorrow to eliminate the 9th Circuit” (U.S. Court of Appeals)

- Rick Santorum

3. Newt Gingrich has called for impeaching judges, abolishing judgeships and even eliminating courts whose rulings he dislikes.

(Los Angeles Times – 12/20/11 – A21)

Page 84: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Philosophies - 1

I. Judicial Philosophies

A. Preferred Freedoms

1. Court should actively look for

cases where the rights of a

minority may have been violated.

Page 85: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Philosophies - 2

2. If there is a conflict, noneconomic

freedoms are “preferred” over

economic freedoms.

3. To restrict a preferred freedom, the burden of proof is on the

restrictor, who must show a clear and imminent danger.

Page 86: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Philosophies - 3

Free Speech Standards

Violent Overthrow of the Government

Clear and Imminent Danger

Clear and Present Danger

Bad Tendency Doctrine

Page 87: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

B. Judicial Self-Restraint

1. The judiciary should “restrain itself”

from declaring many laws

unconstitutional

Judicial Philosophies - 4

Page 88: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Philosophies - 5

2. Since the constitution doesn’t seem to “prefer” certain freedoms all freedoms are equal.

3. No “fixed” standard for cases involving what some term “preferred freedoms.”

Page 89: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

C. Democratic justices are typically closer to the “Preferred Freedoms”

model than Republican Justices.

D. Since cases often involve conflicting values/points of law, judicial philosophy inevitably becomes important.

Judicial Philosophies - 6

Page 90: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Judicial Philosophies - 7

E. State Courts: Democratic judges are more likely to side with the economically less advantaged party and find a violation of the rights of the accused than Republican judges.

1. Exception: Democrats favor the government in tax cases – Why?

Page 91: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 1

I. Civil Liberties

A. Well-Protected by the Constitution

and the Courts

B. Reduced Somewhat During Popular National Wars

Page 92: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 2

C. Many of the Most Important Cases

Occur During War Periods

D. Free Speech Examples

1. Schenck v. U.S. (1919)

Page 93: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 3

2. Dennis v. U.S. (1951)

3. Tinker v. Des Moines (1969)

Page 94: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 4

E. Freedom of Press Examples

1. Near v. Minnesota (1931)

2. New York Times v. U.S. (1971)

Page 95: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 5

F. Religious Freedom

1. Each religious sect wanted its religion to be the Established Religion

a. This is still what some American religious fundamentalists would like

b. It is the basis of the governments of Saudi Arabia and Iran

Page 96: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 6

2. Above all, each sect’s members feared that if one of the other denominations got control over the government that they would have to obey that other false religion’s laws (this is why they had emigrated to the American colonies)

3. Members of other religions increasingly fear discrimination and loss of rights

Page 97: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 7

4. Most large scale civil wars and civil conflicts today have something to do with religious disputes

5. The second-best solution = no group’s religion gets to be the Established Religion

Page 98: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 8

G. Religious Freedom is so Important that the 1st Amendment Contains Two

Clauses Protecting Religious Freedom

1. Free Exercise Clause

2. Establishment Clause

Page 99: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 9

a. Wall of Separation between

Church and State

1. No connection/relationship between government and religion

Page 100: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 10

c. No-Preference Standard

1. Government and religion can have some relationship as long as all religions are treated equally.

Page 101: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 11

2. Government provided bus rides to religious schools viewed as an aid to education, not religion.

3. Can’t have government officials write prayers or have prayers spoken in class -

denominationally neutral prayer is impossible.

Page 102: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 12

What words would the prayer contain?

Whom to pray to?

Are teachers allowed to use sacred objects: rosaries, prayer rugs?

When to pray?

Individually or in groups?Silently or aloud?

Page 103: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Civil Liberties - 13

3. Los Angeles County Seal/Christian Cross Over a Military Cemetary

Page 104: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Juries - 1

I. Legal Standards Juries Use

A. Criminal Cases – Beyond a

Reasonable Doubt

1. If you think there is an 80% the defendant is guilty you should vote “not guilty” (20% is NOT

beyond a reasonable doubt).

Page 105: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Juries - 2

B. Civil Cases – A Preponderance of

the Evidence

Page 106: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Juries - 3

II. Decision-Making

A. The Missouri Juror – Show me the

evidence

B. The Neighborhood Watch Juror –

Looks for suspicious activity

Page 107: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Juries - 4

III. Jury Service

A. California uses a “one day or one trial” system.

B. Don’t be disappointed if your background disqualifies you from serving on a particular jury .

Page 108: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Preparing for the Exam - 1

1. Be able to answer the study guide

questions on page 10 of the coursepack (www.csulb.edu/~cdennis click on “Courses”)

2. Be able to explain any concept or term on the slides and why that concept or term was important enough to be

discussed.

Page 109: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Preparing for the Exam - 2

3. Be able to “compare and contrast” concepts. For example, what are the similarities and differences between a presidential system and a parliamentary system?

Page 110: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Beginning of Section II

The material for Exam #2 begins with the next slide.

Page 111: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Opinion - 1

I. Public Opinion

A. Economic and Noneconomic

B. Abstract and Specific

Page 112: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 2

1. Basic rule: People give more tolerant

or “democratic" responses in the abstract than they do in the specific.

C. Liberal and Conservative

1.Relative not Absolute Definitions

Page 113: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 3

2. Liberal - greater commitment to reducing economic inequality and maintaining economic

security/greater support for the noneconomic freedom to differ

Page 114: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 4

3. Conservative – greater individual free choice-less commitment

to equality in economics/less commitment to the freedom to differ in noneconomics

Page 115: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 5

D. If Asked Their Political Orientation

Conservatives Outnumber Liberals

Two to One.

1. Symbolic Conservatism (they say they’re “conservative”) but

Operational Liberalism (support greater government spending on education, health care, etc.)

Page 116: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 6

2. Conservatives have, with much success, attempted to switch the notion of an “elite” from an economic elite (which politically hurts conservatives) to a cultural elite (which politically helps conservatives).

a. Sarah Palin/Rick Santorum – the well-educated are “against us”

Page 117: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 7

E. Public support for greater government spending on social welfare programs moves opposite the partisanship of the president (e.g., public support for more government spending on environmental protection increases under Republican presidents because the public feels the Republicans aren’t very environmentally oriented).

Page 118: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 8

F. Citizens Often Hold Competing Values Such as Freedom and Equality (e.g., desiring both tax cuts and increased government services)

1. Public opinion can often be easily manipulated.

Page 119: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 9

G. Public Opinion is Individually Irrational but Collectively Rational

 

1. Most people don’t follow politics

closely and aren’t well-informed.

However, a small group of voters are well-informed and this means that

overall opinion moves in a rational manner.

Page 120: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 10

H. Political Parties and Voters - Specific Issue Positions – “Four-Celled

Diagram”

The Voters:

Economic - Liberal/

Noneconomic -Conservative

Page 121: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 11

Democratic Party:

Economic – Liberal/

Noneconomic – Liberal

Page 122: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 12

Republican Party:

Economic – Conservative/

Noneconomic – Conservative

 

Page 123: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 13

Libertarians –

Economic – Conservative/

Noneconomic – Liberal

Since political support is often based upon intolerance, libertarianism will have difficulty building much mass support.

Page 124: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 14

I. Relationship Between Socioeconomic Status (SES) and Political Opinions

1. Socioeconomic Status - income, education and occupational status

Page 125: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 15

2. Economic Issues – Negative Association - As SES increases

support for liberal positions decreases

Page 126: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 16

3. Noneconomic Issues - Positive

Association – As SES increases

support for liberal positions increases

Page 127: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 17

4. Typically, a party will “frame” an issue as an issue they “own.” Democrats would frame universal health care

as either security for workers losing insurance and/or fairness, while the Republicans would frame universal health care as either a tax increase and/or the size and scope of government (i.e., “big government”).

Page 128: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 18

a. Republicans are perceived as better able to handle foreign policy and defense issues, reducing taxes, controlling inflation, reducing government spending, reducing crime and promoting moral values than Democrats.

Page 129: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 19

b. Conversely, Democrats are perceived as better able to handle social

welfare policies and/or “fairness” issues such as protecting Social Security, improving health care, helping the poor, supporting public schools, reducing unemployment, solving farm problems, and protecting the environment than Republicans.

Page 130: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 20

J. Public Support for the Bush Tax Cuts

A. 40% of the benefits go to the wealthiest 1% of households

(annual income above $370,000) – this is equal to the

amount received by the poorest

70% of households COMBINED!

   

Page 131: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 21

1. 75% of households LOSE under the Bush Tax Cuts  

a. Mean Cut - $1,199

Median Cut - $217

2. People Overly Upwardly Identify (19% thought they were in the top 1%)

Page 132: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 22

B. Those FAVORING greater government spending more FAVORED the Bush Tax Cuts - SEE THE

CONTRADICTION?

1.Similarily half of California voters think the state’s budget could

be reduced 20% WITHOUT reducing services.

Page 133: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion - 23

C. The MORE One Thinks Their OWN Tax Burden is Too High the MORE they SUPPORT the Bush Tax Cuts - SEE THE CONTRADICTION?

D. The Public Simply Doesn’t Connect the Bush Tax Cuts to Either Other Public Policies (services cutbacks, higher interest rates) or Inequality.

Page 134: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion on Income Inequality - 1

The next several slides show what groups in the United States, Japan and Sweden

think is the actual and fair degree of income inequality between an executive and an auto worker.

Page 135: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion on Income Inequality – 2 – United States

Perceived Fair

Income Income

Republicans 13.2/1 11.3/1

Democrats 15.4/1 8.2/1

Page 136: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion on Income Inequality – 3 - Japan

Perceived Fair

Income Income

Conservative 7.1/1 5.4/1

Party

Left Parties 10.3/1 3.7/1

Page 137: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Public Opinion on Income Inequality – 4 - Sweden

Perceived Fair

Income Income

Conservative/ 2.2/1 2.1/1

Center Party

Left Party 3.2/1 1.9/1

Page 138: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 1

I. Political Participation

A. Types of Political Participation

Page 139: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 2

B. Who Participates?

1. Basic rule: while voting is positively related to socioeconomic status (SES) non-voting forms of political participation are even more strongly positively related to socioeconomic status.

Page 140: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 3

C. “60-30-10” Diagram

1. SES Composition of the Highest Participating One-Fifth of Adult Americans

Page 141: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 4

Highest 1/3 SES - 60%

Middle 1/3 SES - 30%

Lowest 1/3 SES - 10%

Page 142: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 5

D. Consequences

 

1.Message Received: Too Economically Conservative

and Socially Liberal

Page 143: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 6

E. Comparison

1. Only In India was the Relationship between SES and Participation as Strong as in the U.S.

Page 144: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Participation - 7

F. Why?

1. Relative Absence of Class-Related

Politics in the U.S.

2. Relative Lack of Work Organizations/Unions in the U.S.

Page 145: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 1

I. Why Political Parties are Important

A. Provide Candidates for Office

1. Importance of opposing candidates – even in lopsided elections

Page 146: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 2

B. Provide Policy Alternatives

1. Election should provide a referendum on policy

2. Information Reduction Device for Voters

Page 147: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 3

2008 Presidential Candidates

L= AFL-CIO (Labor)

E = League of Conservation Voters (Environment)

Page 148: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties – 3 (continued)

DON’T WRITE DOWN THE NUMBERS THAT APPEAR ON THE NEXT SEVERAL SLIDES. I’M ONLY INTERESTED IN WHAT THE NUMBERS MEAN – THE PATTERN OF THE NUMBERS - NOT THE NUMBERS THEMSELVES.

Page 149: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 4

Democratic

Edwards Clinton Obama

L E L E L E

 

97% 88% 94% 87% 98% 86%

2004 Democratic Ave. LCV – 85%

Page 150: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 5

Republican - 2008

McCain Thompson

L E L E

  17% 24% 8% 6%

2004 Republican Ave. LCV – 10%

Note: McCain Changed Virtually Every Moderate Position to Appease the Republican base: Bush Tax Cuts, Off Shore Drilling, etc.

Page 151: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties – 5 (Continued)

Republican - 2012

Gingrich Santorum Paul Ryan

L E L E L E L E

 10% 29% 13% 0% 18% 30% 14% 24%

NOTE: Gingrich’s record became consistently less environmental over time. In 1995 the LCV called the Gingrich-led legislative agenda “an environment train wreck.”

Page 152: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties – 5 (Continued)

Republican - 2016

Rubio

L E

  11% 9%

Page 153: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 6

C. Accountability

1. G. H. W. Bush–No New Taxes Pledge

2. Republicans in California after Republican defections in the

state legislature over 2009 budget

 

Page 154: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 7

3. Most Party Platform Pledges are Honored

Page 155: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 8

I. Political Party Systems

Cadre Mass Membership

Where All other Wealthy

Found: U.S. Democracies

Page 156: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 9

Goal: Winning Greater Emphasis on

Standing for

Something Different

than the Opposition

Traits: Few Dues Many Dues

Paying Members Paying Members

 

Page 157: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 10

Little Public Much Public

Education Education

Policy

Flexibility High Low

Page 158: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 11

II. Why the U.S. Developed a Cadre rather than a Mass Membership Party System

A. "Absolutist Individualism" – to make the individual as self-reliant as is

practically possible

B. Little for the Political System to do

Page 159: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 12

III. Why the U. S. Has Such a Strong

Commitment to Absolutist Individualism

A. Great Wealth

Page 160: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 13

B. Frontier Experience

1. Self-Sufficiency

 

2. Ease of Owning Property

 

Page 161: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 14

3. Basic rule: government actions to help the poor often involve some

reduction in property rights

4. Zoning

Page 162: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 15

C. Agrarian Experience

1. Difficult to Organize Farmers

Page 163: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 16

D. Ethnic Diversity

1. Basic Rule: A society strongly divided on racial, ethnic or religious lines is more difficult to divide on social

class lines

Page 164: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties - 17

E. Lateness of the Industrial Revolution

 

1. Strong Commitment to Absolutist Individualism Prior to Industrialization

 

2. Reliance on “Craft” Unions

Page 165: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 1

I. Voting Behavior

 

A. Realigning Election

 

B. Current Division between the Parties is Quite Close

 

Page 166: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 2

II. The Republican Coalition

A. White Evangelicals – Moral Decline

B. Deep South – Civil Rights

Page 167: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 3

C. Country Folk – Culture

D. Exurbia – White Flight

Page 168: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 4

E. Young Blue Collars Boys – White

Men Without College Degrees

F. Blue Collar Old Men – Social Security can cause defections

Page 169: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 5

G. Privileged Men – Noneconomic liberalism of this group can cause defections

Page 170: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 6

III. The Democratic Coalition

A. African-Americans – Civil Rights plus

Economic Need

1. Republican support eroded once

Civil Rights involved government

regulation of business

Page 171: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 7

B. Hispanics – Similar Calculus to African-Americans

C. Well-Educated Women – Relatively Liberal both Economically and Socially (support Affirmative Action – Abortion Rights and Gun Control)

Page 172: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 8

D. Secular Warriors – Don’t Go to Church and Don’t Own Guns

E. Cosmopolitan States (large, diverse populations)

Page 173: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 9

F. Union Families

IV. Contested Groups – Typically Economically Liberal and Socially Conservative

A. Catholics

Page 174: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 10

B. Single Women – Economically

Vulnerable

C. Young Voters – Tend to be Relatively

Liberal but Don’t Vote as Much

Page 175: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 11

I. Question – If poor people disproportionately vote Democratic and richer people disproportionately vote Republican, why do Democratic Presidential candidates win the richer states and Republican Presidential candidates win the poorer states?

Page 176: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 12

Page 177: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 13

Page 178: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior – 14 - Race is Half the Story

Page 179: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 15

I. Voting and the Culture War

A. The culture war is fought by the wealthy, in part, because their economic needs are met.

B. The wealthy have sufficient money to move to an area that is culturally suitable for them.

Page 180: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 16

I. The Issue Positions/Ideology of Today’s Voters More Accurately Reflect the Views of Their Party than during the 1950-1980 period.

A. During the 1960-1980 period the message from party elites became more consistent

within each party.

Page 181: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 17

B. Two Fundamental Causes

1. Reaction to the Civil Rights movement – the South becomes much more Republican

2. Political losses by business cause it to spend much more on lobbying for a message of low

taxes and regulation

Page 182: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 18

C. As the cues from party officeholders become more similar within each party, there are fewer voters whose issue positions/ideology don’t fit their political party (i.e., liberal Republicans and conservative Democrats).

Page 183: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 19

1. Independent voters who “lean” toward a party typically behave as partisans (i.e., hold opinions similar to their party and vote for that party).

2. If faced with a conflict between their ideology and their party, most

voters change their ideology to fit their party rather than vice versa.

Page 184: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 20

D. All these factors, plus the greater turnout rate among partisans, have caused campaigns to increasing focus on activating their “base” rather than appealing to independent voters.

Page 185: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Voting Behavior - 21

E. All of these factors greatly increase the “cost” to politicians of compromising with the opposition party (e.g., you may get a primary election challenge within your party).

Page 186: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Noneconomic Party Differences- 1

I. Left (Non-Communist)/Right (Non-Fascist) on Noneconomic Issues

A. Right

1. Maintain Traditional Social

Relationships/Regime

Maintenance

Page 187: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Noneconomic Party Differences- 2

2. Freedom of Expression

3. Increase Civil Rights and Liberties

Page 188: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Noneconomic Party Differences- 3

B. Left

1. Freedom of Expression

2. Increase Civil Rights and Liberties

Page 189: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Noneconomic Party Differences- 4

3. Maintain Traditional Social

Relationships/Regime Maintenance

Page 190: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 1

I. Congress – Perspectives

A. Executive Dominated

1. President Sets the Agenda

Page 191: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 2

2. Unity

3. Expertise

4. Governor has Line-Item Veto

5. Term Limits for California Legislature have reduced it’s willingness to change the governor’s budget

Page 192: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 3

B. High Level of Political Polarization

1.Cohesion within each party has increased and the distance between the parties has widened.

Page 193: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 4

2. 2008 Presidential Contender Scores on Labor/Environment

3. California Legislature: Support for the Chamber of Commerce:

Republicans 80%-100%

Democrats 0% - 20%

Page 194: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 5

4. Compromise can bring a Primary

Challenger

5. Reasons for 1-4

a. Electoral Coalitions of Parties have

become more Dissimilar

Page 195: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 6

b. Increasing Income Inequality

c. Civil Rights Era brings Less Tolerant Voters into Republican Party

Page 196: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 7

C. “Anticipated” Public Opinion, Not “Current” Public Opinion Matters Most

1. Traceability

2. Closing Military Bases

Page 197: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 8

3. Incentive: take actions with immediate positive payoffs (e.g., tax cuts) and avoid actions which have negative short-term effects (e.g., gas tax increases) but positive long-term effects (cleaner environment).

Page 198: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 9

4. Particular vs. General Benefits

a. Those Who Don’t Get Cancer because of Reduced

Pollution Won’t Know it

b. Fairness?

Page 199: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 10

D. Responsiveness Without Responsibility

1. Doing what voters want “now” but

without explaining “long-term”

harm.

2. California: term limits shield legislators from long-term consequences

Page 200: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 11

E. State Legislators Think Public Opinion Is More Conservative Than It Is.

1. On average, conservative state

legislators over-estimated constituency conservatism by 20% while liberal state legislators substantially overestimate constituency conservatism but by a smaller margin.

Page 201: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 12

F. Congress Often Legitimates Governmental Decisions.

1. Panama Canal Treaty

Page 202: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 13

G. Incremental Decision-Making

 

 

1. Budgets

Page 203: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 14

H. Political Activity and the Popularity of Congress

1. Public dislikes conflict – which is the very essence of politics

2. Don’t See Supreme Court Justices Arguing on T.V.

Page 204: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 15

I. Congressional Elections

1. Referendum on President

2. Unpopular Incumbent leads to

Better Challenger

Page 205: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 16

3. As the issue bases of partisan attachments have increased there has been less

opportunity for Congressmen to receive “personal vote.”

4. Fewer Competitive Districts

Page 206: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 17

5. Less Turnover in Congress

6. Big Republican Win in 2010 Yielded No Republican Gains

in California Legislature

Page 207: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 18

II. Representation and Fairness

A. Since the Primary Election is Often More Important than the General Election and Primary Voters are More Extreme, Representation Can be Harmed.

Page 208: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 19

2. Politically, it can be Advantageous for a Legislator to Vote in the

Direction Favored by a Small, Extreme, But Vocal Minority Who Cast their Votes on the Issue rather than Vote in the Direction of Majority Public Opinion.

Page 209: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 20

B. Since You Often Need 60 of the 100 Senators to Vote “Yes” and Each State Receives Two Senators, Small States Can Have Disproportionate Influence.

Page 210: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 21

I. Partisan Differences in the U.S.

Congress

 

A. 95% Direction Rule

B. 40% Difference Rule

Page 211: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 22

C. Policy Areas – least to greatest

partisan difference

1. Civil Liberties

2. International Involvement

Page 212: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Congress/California Legislature - 23

3. Agricultural Assistance

4. Social Welfare

5. Government Management of the

Economy

Page 213: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Preparing for the Exam - 1

1. Be able to answer the study guide

questions on page 11 of the coursepack (www.csulb.edu/~cdennis click on “Courses”)

2. Be able to explain any concept or term on the slides and why that concept or term was important enough to be

discussed.

Page 214: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Preparing for the Exam - 2

3. Be able to “compare and contrast” concepts or ideas. For example, compare and contrast cadre and mass membership political parties.

4. What’s related to what? For example, as a person’s income increases does their probability of voting increase or decrease?

Page 215: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Beginning of Section III

The material for Exam #3 begins with the next slide.

Page 216: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1A

DON’T WRITE DOWN ANY OF THE MATERIAL OVER THE NEXT 220 SLIDES. ALL OF IT IS IN THE COURSEPACK. JUST LISTEN TO THE DISCUSSION!

Page 217: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1B

I. Policy Orientation of This Discussion

A. Since the U.S. has the weakest social safety net and highest level of income inequality of any wealthy democracy the obvious comparison is to the other wealthy democracy that have stronger social safety nets and less income inequality than we do.

Page 218: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1C

B. I know that isn’t “comforting.” We naturally want to think of our nation as “best” on all criteria. Realistically, this is impossible. A nation that has the lowest taxes won’t have the least inequality. The United States ranks high on some social programs (e.g., higher education) but not on income security and reducing inequality.

Page 219: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1D

C. If I were teaching this class in a nation with a very strong social safety net and much less income inequality (e.g., Sweden), I would compare it to nations that have less strong social safety nets and greater income inequality (e.g., Canada and Great Britain with moderately strong social safety nets and the U.S. with a very social safety net).

Page 220: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 1E

D. Therefore, while I will touch on proposals to weaken the U.S. safety net, the vast bulk of the discussion ahead will focus on what other wealthy democracies do to reduce income equality, how well these policies work and what the U.S. could do in this regard while still preserving our freedoms and improving our political system.

Page 221: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 2

I. Incentives of the Two Major Political Parties

A. Unemployment has a large impact which disproportionately falls on low and middle-income voters.

1. Nonmonetary costs of unemployment

Page 222: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 3

B. The poorest 80% of American households are relatively unaffected by inflation. However, inflation has a greater adverse impact on the richest 20% of American households.

Page 223: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 4

C. Marginal Substitution Rate

Democrats Independents Republicans

.90 2.0 1.5

Page 224: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 1

I. Macroeconomic Theory

A. Neoclassical

1. The free market was assumed to yield full employment (i.e.,

no/low unemployment) and to grow without limitation and to correct any imbalances that might develop

Page 225: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 2

2. Since the higher one’s income the greater the percentage of their income they save/invest and the smaller percentage of their income they spend, the greater the share of income the rich possessed the greater the investment, and hence, economic innovation/growth.

Page 226: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 3

3. By this view, a major goal of macroeconomic policy was to keep the costs of production low (e.g., low wages – through the absence of labor unions, a low minimum wage, low taxes, little government regulation of business, etc.) in order to increase profits and investment.

4. Couldn’t explain the Great Depression

Page 227: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 4

B. Keynesianism

1. If the non-rich lacked sufficient money to purchase goods, the economy would not reach its’

full potential because businessmen would not open new business,

or expand current ones, if they felt they could not sell the resulting products or services.

Page 228: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 5

2. This meant that middle and lower-income groups, who spend a greater share of their income than upper income groups, need to have a significant share of the national income (through a minimum wage, labor unions, etc.).

Page 229: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 6

3. If economic demand was insufficient, Keynes argued that the government should increase its’ spending and be willing to run large deficits (i.e., spend more money than it receives in taxes).

4. If both inflation and unemployment are high (late 1970s & early 1980s) –

trouble.

Page 230: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory – 7A

C. The aforementioned difficulties of Keynesian economics, plus the renewed political strength of a Republican Party whose ideology was similar to neoclassical economics, resulted in a rebirth of neoclassical economics under several different names.

Page 231: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory – 7B

D. Corporate profits were 25% to 30% higher at the official end of the Great Recession than they were before it started (2007). Meanwhile, wages as a share of national income fell to 58%. That’s the lowest wage share had been since it began to be recorded after World War II.

Page 232: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory – 7C

If wages were at their postwar (World War II) average of 63%, U.S. workers would earn an extra $740 (billion) this year (2012) or about $5,000 per worker. That’s a lot of consuming power.”

Page 233: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 8

D. Supply-Side Economics - Ronald Reagan 1981 & Newt Gingrich 2012

1. Like Neoclassical Economics – much more concerned with reducing impediments to supply (high labor costs, taxes and regulations) than in stimulating demand.

Page 234: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Macroeconomic Theory - 9

2. Tax Cuts DON’T pay for themselves.

3. Gregory Mankiw – supply-side

economics devised by “charlatans and cranks”

E. Relationship between the philosophy/self-interest of both major political parties and the economic theory they use.

Page 235: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 5

D. Recent research by political scientists shows that all income groups up through the 95th percentile (i.e., all but the richest 5% of households – today those earning about $200,000, or less, per year) gain under the Democrats relative to the Republicans. However, the poor gain at a greater rate under the Democrats.

Page 236: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 6

E. Our Current Situation

1. Tremendous loss of consumer demand due to the collapse of real estate

2. Government needs to replace this lost demand – i.e., NOT cutback

Page 237: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 7

3. 300 billion dollars of stimulus will reduce the unemployment rate by 1%. The Obama Stimulus Plan was approximately 775

billion dollars spread over two years. Given the composition of the Obama Stimulus Plan (e.g., tax cuts – which have low stimulative value) it is equivalent to about 510 billion dollars of stimulus rather than 775 billion dollars.

Page 238: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 8

This means that, due to the Obama Stimulus Plan, the unemployment rate, while high, is about 1.7 percentage points lower that it would have been without the plan (510/300 = 1.7).

Page 239: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 9

4. Many economists think that the federal government needs to do two things to improve the economy: (1) provide a larger stimulus than the Obama Stimulus Plan; and (2) more strongly regulate the financial markets (to avoid the bad loans that precipitated our current problems). This is difficult for the Republican Party: their ideology conceives of government as “the problem,” not “the solution.”

Page 240: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 10

Income Inequality in Wealthy Democracies

in the Mid-1980s – Percentage Distribution

Japan Sweden U.S.

Richest

20% 37.5% 41.7% 42.0%

Poorest

20% 8.7% 7.4% 5.0%

2009 >>> 3.9%

Page 241: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11A

Richest Richest Richest

Year 10% 1% ½ of 1%

1920 39.0% 14.8% 11.1%

1970 32.6% 9.0% 6.3%

2008 48.2% 21.0% 16.9%

SHARES FOR THE RICHEST 1% AND ½ OF 1% ARE ABOUT TWICE AS HIGH AS IN EUROPE

Page 242: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11B

U.C. Berkeley Economist Emmanuel Saez’s comments on the reasons for increase income inequality in the U.S.:

“…The changes in income concentration are just too abrupt and too closely correlated with policy developments for the standard story about pay equaling productivity to hold everywhere.

Page 243: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11C

Between 1971 and 2007, U.S. hourly wages, adjusted for inflation, rose by 4%. (That’s not 4% a year; it’s 4% over 36 years!) during those same decades, productivity increased by 99% - that is, it nearly doubled. In other words, the average worker’s productivity rose 25 times more than his pay. Los Angeles Times, May 14, 2013, page A11).

Page 244: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

That is, if pay is equal to productivity, you would think that deep economic changes in skills would evolve slowly and make a gradual difference in the distribution—but what we see in the data are very abrupt changes. Basically all western countries had very high levels of income concentration up to the first decades of the 20th century

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11D

Page 245: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11E

and then income concentration fell dramatically in most western countries following the historical narrative of each country. For example, in the United States the Great Depression followed by the New Deal and then World War II. And I could go on with other countries.

Page 246: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11F

Symmetrically, the reversal—that is, the surge in income concentration in some but not all countries—follows political developments closely. You see the highest increases in income concentration in countries such as the United States and the United Kingdom (Great Britain),

Page 247: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11G

following precisely what has been called the Reagan (Republican President from 1981-1988) and Thatcher (Conservative Party Prime Minister of Great Britain from 1979-1990) revolutions: deregulation, cuts in top tax rates, and policy changes that favored upper-income brackets.

Page 248: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11H

You don’t see nearly as much of an increase in income concentration in countries such as Japan, Germany, or France, which haven’t gone through such sharp, drastic policy changes.

Page 249: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy: 11I

Apportioning the 12 percentage Increase in the Share of Income Going to the Top 1% - 1976-2008 (8.9% to 20.9%)

Tax Reductions – 45%

Political Polarization – 28%

Unexplained - 26%

Conservative tax changes and the increased conservatism of the Republican Party have had a large impact on inequality.

Page 250: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 12

If you include government transfers and subtract taxes from 1979 to 2006, the richest 1% of households had a 256% increase income while middle-income households (40th-60th percentiles) had a 21% increase and low-income households (1st-20th percentiles) only an 11% increase. In the United States today, the richest 1% of households have over 1.5 times as much income as the entire poorest 40% of households combined.

Page 251: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Changes in California - 1

In California, between 1987 and 2009, more than 33% of the income gains went to the richest 1% of Californians, and almost 75% went to the richest 10% while the bottom 90% received just over 25% of the growth in incomes. During the last two decades, the average income of the richest 1% of Californians increased by more than 50%,

Page 252: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Changes in California - 2

after adjusting for inflation, while the average income of the middle fifth (i.e., the 40th – 60th percentiles) decreased by 15%. In 2009, the average income of the richest 1% of Californians was $1.2 million – more than 30 times that of Californians in the middle fifth. California’s income gap is wider than most other states.

Page 253: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 13

Americans in the poorest 10% had a living standard 22% below low-income Finns, 24% below low- income Dutch and 15% below low-income Italians. However, the wealthiest 10% of Americans had incomes 50% higher than the wealthiest 10% in the other OECD nations (Great Britain, France, Canada, Japan, Australia and New Zealand).

Page 254: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy -14

One fundamental reason the poor in the U.S. have a lower standard of living than in several other nations is that, after taxes, the U.S. transfers only about one-third the percentage of income to the poorest 20% of households (1.5%) as does the average (4.2%) of the world’s wealthy democracies.

Page 255: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Analysis from the World Bank Publication, “Social Safety Nets and Target Assistance: Lessons from the European Experience,” Chris de Neubourg, et. al.

While the average American has a higher living standard than the average resident in the other countries, this does not hold for the entire spectrum of the income distribution. Despite the higher aggregate and average standard of living in the United States, people in the lower deciles of the income distribution are far worse off in US than poorer persons or households in Europe, if compared to the median income of their own country. (p. 5)

Page 256: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 15

The median Swedish family has a living standard roughly comparable with that of the median U.S. family: wages are, if anything, higher in Sweden, and a higher tax burden is offset by public provision of health care and generally better public services. As you move further down the income distribution, Swedish living standards are much higher than in the U.S.: at the 10th percentile (poorer than 90% of the population) the Swedish living standard is 60% higher than in the U.S.

Page 257: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 16

In this light it is worth noting that approximately 38% of the benefits from the Bush Tax Cuts go to the richest 1% of the households (i.e., the same households who have been receiving a much higher share of personal income over the past 40 years). The richest 1% of U.S. households receive more money from the Bush Tax Cuts than the entire poorest 70% of U.S. households combined (roughly households with annual incomes of about $90,000 or less).

Page 258: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 17

Wealth is a storehouse of assets: trusts, stocks, bonds, etc. whereas income is what you live on over a short period – say, a year. As the following statistics will make clear: Wealth is even more unequally distributed than income. In the United States the wealthiest 1% of households have over 33% of the national wealth while the poorest 50% of households have approximately 7% of the national wealth.

Page 259: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 18

A rather large amount of research tells us the following: (1) Americans vastly overestimate their chances of becoming rich; (2) vastly underestimate the degree of income inequality (i.e., do not think the wealthy are as wealthy as the actually are); and (3) have a difficult time connecting public policy to economic outcomes (e.g., not that many see the Bush Tax Cuts as a tremendous redistribution to the wealthy).

Page 260: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 19

Currently, wealth in America is distributed as follows: the richest 20% of households (percentiles 81-100) have approximately 84% of the wealth, the next richest 20% (i.e., percentiles 61-80) have approximately 11%, the middle quintile (i.e., percentiles 41-60) have approximately 4%, the next poorest 20% (i.e., percentiles 21-40) have approximately .2% (two tenths of 1%) and the poorest quintile (i.e., percentiles 1-20) have approximately .1% (one tenth of 1%).

Page 261: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 20

Americans do desire a less unequal distribution of wealth. Recently, two scholars tried an interesting experiment.

Not being told what nations had what distribution of wealth, Americans were offered three choices: (1) the current American distribution of wealth;

Page 262: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 21

(2) perfect equality (i.e., each quintile getting an equal – 20% - share of the wealth); or (3) the current Swedish distribution of wealth (the richest 20% of households approximately 36% of the wealth, the next richest 20% approximately 21% of the wealth, the middle quintile approximately 18% of the wealth, the next poorest 20% approximately 15% of the wealth and the poorest quintile approximately 11% of the wealth).

Page 263: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 22

The results were as follows: 47% chose Sweden’s distribution, 43% chose perfect equality while only 10% chose the current American distribution. Additionally, American’s are less satisfied with their lives than citizens in a number of European countries that have less per capita income, but much stronger safety nets/less income inequality than the U.S.

Page 264: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–22A

I.How Should We Measure “Well-Being”?

A. If someone spends $1,000 on diabetes medicine it counts as part of GDP. However, wouldn’t the same person have a better life if they didn’t have diabetes but spent $750 on a computer? Since $1,000 is greater than $750, in this example GDP would be higher for diabetes oriented spending than for buying a computer.

Page 265: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–22B

B. GDP (Gross Domestic Product) only measures the monetary value of the economy. It tells nothing about how the money is used or any non-monetary value (national health, the functioning of the political system, job security and measures of community well-being).

Page 266: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–22C

C. Typically, on such indicators, the United States ranks lower than the high tax and strong welfare state countries of Northern Europe (e.g., Norway, Sweden, Denmark, Finland, and the Netherlands).

Page 267: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 23

Mobility is NOT that high in the U.S.

If you compare the eventual income of two children from different families, on average, the child from the richer family receives an annual income that is higher than the child from the poorer family by approximately 30%-40% of the difference in the incomes of their parents.

Page 268: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 24

A child from a family that made $100,000 per year would, on average, out earn a child from a family that made $25,000 by approximately $25,000 per year (the difference in their parents incomes was $75,000 – i.e., $100,000 - $25,000 = $75,000; 33% of $75,000 = $25,000). Thus, if later in life the child of the poorer family was earning $25,000 per year and the child of the richer family was earning $50,000 per year, you could say that the difference was entirely due to background.

Page 269: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 25

Put another way: children born into the poorest 20% of households have approximately a 42% chance of ending up in the poorest 20% themselves, a 24% chance of ending up in the next poorest 20% and only a 6% chance of ending up in the richest 20%.

Page 270: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 26

Father’s and Son’s incomes in the U.S. correlate at about .43 (correlation ranges from 0 to 1.0 so this is a moderate correlation), and is higher in the U.S.

(i.e., less mobility) than in Sweden, Norway, Finland, France, Spain, Germany, and Canada.

Page 271: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 27

The Bush Tax Cuts reveal a very pertinent fact about economic policy: there is often a great difference between programs that help the non-wealthy acquire wealth versus policies that protect the wealth of those who already have it. What is good for one group is not necessarily good, and often harmful, for the other group. Approximately 75% of American household lose under the Bush Tax Cuts.

Page 272: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 28

Consider how the Bush Tax Cuts affect mobility from low to high-income groups. First, by repealing the estate tax and reducing other taxes on high-income individuals, the Bush Tax Cuts give the wealthy more wealth to leave their heirs. Obviously, this makes it more difficult for most of you to try to amass more wealth than the heirs of the currently very wealthy due to the fact these heirs will be given such a tremendous head start on you.

Page 273: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 29

Second, by reducing the revenue of the federal government, the Bush Tax Cuts will all but require reductions in programs that help low and middle-income people ascend the economic ladder (e.g., the Pell Grant Program for poor college students, health care for the poor, job training, public transportation, etc.).

Page 274: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 30

The Bush Tax Cuts are one of the very least effective, and most costly, methods of stimulating the economy and, ultimately, reducing unemployment. As economic research indicates: lower-income households spend a higher percentage of each additional dollar they receive than higher-income households.

Page 275: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 31

For example, a household with a $40,000 annual income will spend a higher percentage of each additional dollar it receives than a household with a $200,000 annual income. This is because lower-income households have greater unmet needs than higher-income households (e.g., replacing a worn out car).

Page 276: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 32

By showering more money on the richest 1% of households (i.e., households with incomes above $370,000) than on the entire poorest 70% of households combined, the Bush Tax Cuts place the most money in the hands of those least likely to spend it. Contrast this with the items on the next slide – favored by Democrats.

Page 277: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 33

The following indicates how much additional economic activity occurs per dollar spent: extending unemployment compensation - $1.60; payroll tax reduction - $1.09; and extending the Bush Tax Cuts - $.35 (i.e. for each dollar given to tax payers through the Bush Tax Cuts, we only receive 35 cents of additional economic activity – only a fourth as much per dollar spent as on unemployment compensation – i.e., $.35 is about ¼ of $1.60).

Page 278: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 34

Since all income groups will save some percentage of the money they receive (i.e., lower-income households will save some money, just not as a great percentage as higher-income households), having the government directly spend money is more stimulative than tax cuts.

Page 279: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 35

If the government both taxes and spends a large share of the economy won’t we end up with more equal slices of a smaller pie (or a pie that isn’t growing as fast as it otherwise would)? While this is an important point, the evidence in favor of it is NOT compelling.

Page 280: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36A

Tax rates as a percentage of the economy are much lower in the U.S. than in most wealthy democracies:

U.S. – 32.2%, Canada – 38.3%,

Great Britain – 41.2%, Germany – 44.6%,

Italy – 47.8%, Sweden – 50.9%,

France – 52.9% and Denmark – 57.4%.

Source: OECD as reported in NY Times

11/16/14

Page 281: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36B

Federal Taxes as a percentage of our economy are lower today than they have been in over 60 years.

1951- 16.1 % (before Medicare enacted)

1971 – 17.3%

2001 – 19.5%

2011 – 15.4%

Page 282: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36C

Effective Tax Rates on Income of

$100,000 in 2012

Nation Income Tax Social Security

U.S. – 26.0% 18.7% 7.3%

G. Brit.- 31.4% 24.1% 7.3%

Sweden- 36.3% 36.3% 0%

France – 42.0% 20.0% 22.0%

Germany-43.8% 28.3% 15.5%

Page 283: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–36D

Government Mandated Paid Annual Leave and Paid Days of Vacation

U.S. - 0

Great Britain - 20

Sweden - 25

German - 30

France - 31

Page 284: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 37

From 1990-2005 per capita (i.e., per person - to adjust for differences in population size between nations) growth rates were as follows: U.S. - 85%, Netherlands – 86%, Norway – 134%, France – 60%, Australia – 91%, Canada – 69%, Denmark – 80%, United Kingdom – 111%. Since 1980, per capita real G.D.P. (Gross Domestic Product) – which is what matters most for living standards - has risen at about the same rate in America and in the E.U.(U.S. - 1.95%, E.U. - 1.83%).

Page 285: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 38

As economist Peter Lindert of the University of California at Davis put it, “No matter how you torture the data, there is no negative relationship between a commitment to the welfare state and the growth rate in how well off we are.” While taxes may reduce the willingness of some to work as hard, many of the purposes for which tax dollars are spent (e.g., education, infrastructure, etc.) increase the growth rate. One of the reasons the Nordic countries (Norway, Sweden, Denmark and Finland) spend about TWICE the percentage of GDP (3%-4%) on research and development as the U.S.

Page 286: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 39

In light of the Obama Health Care Plan, let me mention the following: EVERY nation in the world rations health care. For example, would you pay an additional $200 per month for health care in order to prolong the life of terminally ill patients an average of 3 months? If “yes,” how about $400 per month? Once you say “no” (i.e., refuse to pay), you are rationing health care.

Page 287: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 40

Let me offer the following question: Would you prefer to have a government panel – typically headed by physicians – make the necessary rationing decisions or would you rather have a for-profit insurance company make them? That’s the choice we actually have.

Page 288: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 41

Government policies do have important affects on the rationing decisions that all health care systems must make. For example, cigarette taxes reduce cigarette smoking. Economists have found that a 10% increase in the cost of cigarettes reduces smoking by about 3%-4%. Thus, cigarette taxes reduce the amount of smoking which, in turn, reduces the onset of a large number of adverse health consequences (e.g., cancer, heart attack, stroke, etc.).

Page 289: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 42

Many of those who claim the Obama Health Care Plan will lead to government rationing of health care to the elderly are the same individuals/groups who oppose government regulations (e.g., soda taxes, meat taxes, restaurant menu labeling requiring disclosure of calories, fat, sodium, etc.) which would greatly reduce adverse health consequences (e.g., obesity) which, in turn, would leave more money for the health care needs of senior citizens.

Page 290: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 43

Broad-based government programs, such as Medicare (a government health care program for senior citizens), have two big cost saving advantages over a completely free market social insurance system: (1) compulsion – i.e., requiring everyone to buy health insurance lowers the cost because the cost of the “expensive” individuals (e.g., those likely to be ill) is spread over a large group (e.g., the healthy) and;

Page 291: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 44

(2) administrative cost (e.g., the typical private health insurer spends about 10% of its outlays on administrative costs, weeding out sick people, etc. whereas the government run Medicare program spends between 2%-3% of its budget on administrative costs).

Page 292: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 45

The preceding are two of the major reasons why the #1 ranked (by the World Health Organization) French health care system spends only a little more than half as much money per person as the 37th ranked U.S. health care system (France - $4,690, U.S. - $8,895).

Page 293: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 46

Government run programs such as Medicare aren’t the same as government ownership of productive assets. Medicare doesn’t own hospitals or employ doctors, it contracts with privately owned hospitals and private physicians.

Page 294: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 47

I should also mention that government programs such as Medicare and Medicaid (a government run health care program for the poor) currently pay substantially more of our nation’s health care costs (approximately 47%) than private insurance (approximately 35%).

Thus, we can’t “get the government out of health care.”

Page 295: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 48

It should also be mentioned that the democracies of Western Europe are, in the main, NOT socialist nations. Socialism means that the government owns the modes of production and distribution. For example, socialism in the U.S. would mean that the government would own the major fast food outlets (e.g., McDonalds, Wendy’s etc.).

Page 296: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 49

Considerations about the size of government on personal freedom are complicated. Equating the size of government with personal freedom often involves equating private property with personal freedom. This is difficult.

Page 297: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 50

For example, would most Californians have more freedom if the beaches were sold to private individuals or if the State of California operates them? Additionally, if state taxes were reduced taxpayers would have a greater freedom of choice in spending their money.

Page 298: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 51

However, if these state tax cuts resulted in higher fees for U.C. and CSU students fewer students would attend college. Not attending college would reduce both the future incomes and occupational choices of the individuals who did not attend college due to the budget reductions resulting from the state tax cuts. In short, it would reduce their future freedom. So, would such a state tax cut result in a “net” gain or loss in freedom?

Page 299: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 52

A relatively small loss in freedom for a large group of people (requiring each person to purchase health insurance) will provide a much larger amount of freedom (to make all the decisions living people can make) for a smaller group of people (the unhealthy). If so, has the amount of freedom either increased or decreased? It’s not so easy to answer! You would have to balance the loss of many small amounts of freedom against a fewer large gains in freedom.

Page 300: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 53

People in the democracies of Western Europe are typically as “free” as Americans. For example, free speech in Great Britain is as great as it is in the United States. Additionally, some Western European nations actually have higher scores on some measures of democracy than the United States. Typically, this occurs because of lower voter turnout and fewer major political parties in the United States.

Page 301: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 54

The “big picture” is that, if we wanted to, our nation could reduce economic inequality significantly and still have an equally vibrant, growing economy with the same level of freedom we currently enjoy. This is really a question of values (i.e., Do we want to?) rather than possibilities (i.e., Could we?)

Page 302: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–55A

Increased redistribution of income and wealth might well improve the functioning of democracy in the United States. What some refer to as “the Debilitating Cycle” is a very important problem: greater income inequality leads to a greater reliance of politicians on campaign contributions from the wealthy, which, can easily cause these same politicians to adopt policies that even more favor the wealthy, which starts the same cycle again.

Page 303: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–55B

Relative to the average American, the very wealthy (net worth of $40 million or more) are: (1) much more concerned about budget deficits; (2) much more favorable to cutting social welfare programs, especially Social Security and health care; (3) are considerably less supportive of an above-poverty-level minimum wage, or having the federal government “see to” or provide jobs for the unemployed;

Page 304: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–55C

(4) much less supportive of providing broad educational opportunities; (5) much less willing to redistributive income to those poorer than themselves; (6) less willing to raise taxes on high income groups (e.g., less supportive of having an estate tax); and (7) are less willing to regulate either the stock market or businesses.

Page 305: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 56

Proposals of the Political PartiesPresident George W. Bush proposed a series of

policies to deal with our nation’s economic future that were collectively referred to as “The Ownership Society.” The idea is that each individual citizen would “own” items that had previously been provided by the government. For example, if each individual citizen can choose how to invest their money in a personal Social Security Account you could say that person “owned” their retirement.

Page 306: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 57

Let’s see how “The Ownership Society” would have changed American health care policy and the degree of health care security American’s have. Former President George W. Bush did not favor requiring all Americans to purchase health insurance. He did favor

(and at his urging Congress did pass) legislation setting up Health Savings Accounts in 2003.

Page 307: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 58

In 2008, an individual could contribute up to $2,400 per year to such an account ($5,800 for a family). The gains from this investment are not taxed and the money could be withdrawn to pay the deductable under a health insurance policy. This is a tax free method of investing for those fortunate enough to have the money to participate. Not surprisingly, those most likely to contribute to Health Savings Accounts are much richer than average.

Page 308: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 59

Look at the relationships between wealth/education and health: (1) more well-educated and higher-income individuals are more likely to value delayed gratification – i.e., foregoing something today for a greater future gain - in this case eating healthier food, maintaining a healthier weight, not smoking, etc. than less well-educated and lower-income individuals; thus,

Page 309: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 60

(2) more well-educated and higher-income individuals are less likely to need medical attention than less well-educated and lower-income individuals; and (3) more well-educated and higher-income individuals are more likely to contribute to Health Savings Accounts than less well-educated and lower-income individuals.

Page 310: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 61

By not requiring people to buy insurance and by allowing people to put money into Health Savings Accounts, higher-income people, who are typically more healthy, are able to remove money that would’ve gone into an insurance pool from which the unhealthy could benefit. Thus, the practical effect of Health Savings Accounts is to reduce the ability to spread medical costs over a larger, healthier, population.

Page 311: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 62

Withdrawing money that a healthier population would have put into an insurance pool and, instead, placing it in the hands of higher-income households means that the costs of health insurance to the less healthy population, disproportionately drawn from middle and low-income households, will increase. All of this works to the advantage of higher- income individuals.

Page 312: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 63

The Ownership Society proposal for education (another tax-free savings plan) has a similar effect to the Health Savings Accounts. Here’s why: (1) higher-income individuals are much more likely to have the necessary money to put into such an account; (2) citizens are more likely to vote in favor of increased taxes for education when they have children in the public education system; and

Page 313: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 64

(3) the money from an Educational Savings Account will either allow more students to afford a private college and/or reduce their need for more funding for state run colleges. For example, the money from the account means they are less likely to need financial aid than other students. Points 1-3 mean that the educational “gap” between students from lower and higher-income households will increase.

Page 314: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 65

Republican Congressman Paul Ryan calls his plan, “The Roadmap for America’s Future.” His plan would: (1) cut federal taxes of the richest 1% of households by 50% (i.e., in half – this is in addition to the tax cuts this group would receive by making the Bush Tax Cuts permanent);

Page 315: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 66

(2) replace some of the lost revenue from the tax cuts for the richest 1% of households with a much more regressive consumption tax on most goods and services (i.e., paid much more by middle and low-income households – families with incomes between $50,000 and $75,000 would face a tax increase of around $900 per year);

Page 316: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 67

(3) freeze discretionary domestic spending (keep in mind that, that after adjusting for inflation and population growth, this would mean a 25% reduction over 10 years in such items as public transportation, etc.); (4) privatize Social Security (i.e., individual accounts) and;

Page 317: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 68

(5) replace Medicare for senior citizens with a voucher (i.e., an amount of money to buy health insurance). Since the Ryan plan doesn’t require all citizens to buy health insurance and includes Health Savings Accounts, health care costs will increase (see previous discussion). These increases would occur at the same time that Ryan wants to reduce Medicare spending. Thus, senior citizens would have much poorer health care under the Ryan plan than currently.

Page 318: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 69

The Ryan plan proposes large cuts in Social Security benefits — roughly 16 percent for the average new retiree in 2050 and 28 percent in 2080 from price indexing alone — and initially diverts most of these savings to help fund private accounts rather than to restore Social Security solvency.”

Page 319: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 70

This is very similar to former President George W. Bush’s proposal for Social Security. Unlike Bush’s Social Security Proposal, the Ryan Plan protects those whose investments result in less income than under the traditional Social Security program. Ryan’s guarantee would encourage seniors to make more risky investments.

Page 320: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 71

Why not gamble on an investment with large possible gain (but also large possible loss) when the federal government insures you against loss?

Page 321: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 72

While the Ryan Plan does include a protection for senior citizen’s whose investments yielded a return lower than what they would have received under traditional Social Security, it is extremely unlikely that this guarantee would be paid in full. Here’s why: Ryan would use government revenues to replace the lost income to senior citizens whose investments performed poorly.

Page 322: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–73A

The cost of this guarantee would be very high. Given the reductions in other programs that would be required to fully fund this guarantee (e.g., in defense, education, environmental protection, etc.) it would be extremely unlikely to be fully realized. The “big picture” is that the current Republican plans, including Mitt Romney’s, are very similar to former President Bush’s plans.

Page 323: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–73B

Regardless of whether one agrees or disagrees with the philosophy of the Republican party, the following conclusion is inescapable: the Republican proposals would make what is already, by far, the weakest social safety net of any wealthy democracy in the world much weaker still while simultaneously increasing the degree of after-tax income inequality in what is already the most economically unequal wealthy democracy in the world.

Page 324: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 74

Which of the following seems more appropriate: (1) As personal economic risk increases, you need the government less? (2) As personal economic risk increases, you need the government more?

Page 325: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 75

The two parties differ widely. The Republican Party approach (i.e., “The Ownership Society” and “The Roadmap for America’s Future”) is to load increased personal economic risk back on the individual (i.e., less governmental guarantees – privatization of Social Security rather than guaranteed benefit levels, giving senior citizens a voucher rather guaranteed Medicare – same with health care for the poor;

Page 326: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 76

reducing taxes on high income earners that can be applied to public services for middle and low-income earners) while the Democratic Party approach is more in favor of using the government to offset increased personal financial risk (e.g., the Obama Health Care Plan – making health care more affordable for middle and low-income earners, increasing the Pell Grant program for low-income college students,

Page 327: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 77

reducing the Bush Tax Cuts, increasing government deficit spending and increasing regulation of financial markets).

Page 328: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 78

Tax rates are NOT highly progressive in the United States. The rich pay a higher percentage of their income in taxes than the poor, but not greatly so. All federal taxes together (i.e., income taxes, Social Security taxes, etc.) take approximately 9.4% of the income of households making $16,000 per year, approximately 20.5% of the income of households making $52,000,

Page 329: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 79

approximately 27.2% of the income of households making $200,000 per year and approximately 34% of households making $18,000,000 per year.

Page 330: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 80

It is very important to mention that federal taxes have been made much LESS progressive over time. To demonstrate the impact of reduced federal tax progressivity consider the following: “In 2000, the richest 1 household in 1,000 (i.e., .1 of 1%) had about 7.3% of total national after-tax income. If the effect of taxes on their income had remained what it was in 1970, they would have had about 4.5% of after-tax national income.

Page 331: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 81

This would be a reduction of approximately 38% in their after-tax income (7.3% - 4.5% = 2.8 and 2.8 is approximately 38% of 7.3). This decrease in federal tax progressivity was prior to the Bush Tax Cuts (which, as previously discussed, overwhelmingly benefit households with very high incomes).

Page 332: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Tax Rates Over Time

Page 333: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 82

State and local taxes are even LESS progressive than federal taxes. Thus, if you add state and local taxes to federal taxes (i.e., to obtain “total taxes”) the tax burden is less favorable to the poor (i.e., less progressive) than for federal taxes alone. State and Local Taxes are a greater percentage of personal income for the poorest 20% of a state’s households than for the wealthiest 1% of a state’s households in virtually every state (all but one).

Page 334: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 83

In California state and local taxes take approximately 11.3% of the income of the poorest 20% of households while taking only 7.2% of the income of the richest 1% of households.

Page 335: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 84

For example, in California, the wealthiest 10% of the taxpayers pay approximately 75% of the state income tax. While true, this argument is misleading for two reasons: (1) the most important consideration is taxes as a percentage of income and not the percentage of a tax borne by a particular income group – thus, if California’s state income tax was only to raise $1 and Steven Spielberg paid that $1 he would have borne 100% of the state income tax burden –

Page 336: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 85

however, $1 would be virtually 0% of his income – thus it’s the percentage of income paid in a tax and not the percentage of a tax that a particular income group pays that is the important consideration; (2) this calculation excludes all taxes except the income tax (e.g., state sales taxes, property taxes, etc.) – when we include all state and local taxes and fees, state and local taxes are a higher percentage of income for the very poor than the very rich.

Page 337: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 86

As a share of personal income, California typically ranks about 18th (out of 50 states) in state and local tax burden with state and local revenues equal to approximately 17% of personal income.

Page 338: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 87

One often hears candidates for state office talking about “runaway” state spending. Adjusting for population growth and inflation, to maintain the same level of service in 2009 that the state of California provided in 1999 state spending would have had to increase by 53%. Over the 1999-2009 period spending by the State of California only increased by 29% (i.e., a 24% REDUCTION in real per capita spending).

Page 339: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 88

Another way of looking at the question of state spending is to take account of both need (i.e., what type of population we have) and state wealth (i.e., our “ability to pay”). By such a measure, California ranked 37th out of the 50 states.

Page 340: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 89

Some state tax increase would IMPROVE the functioning of California’s economy:

(1) tax internet purchases – not taxing them discriminates against bricks and mortar stores;

(2) change business property taxes annually (i.e., not only when the property is sold) - current practice favors those who hold a property longer – harms new businesses;

Page 341: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 90

(3) tax carbon, pollution and oil - from an economic standpoint, the cost of pollution should be taxed to provide the appropriate disincentives to reduce pollution. Currently, California is the only oil producing state that does not have a severance tax on oil.

Page 342: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 91

One factor that would greatly help California’s business climate is a more highly educated workforce. To meet employment needs, the percentage of California’s workforce with at least a bachelor’s degree needs to roughly double over the next 15 years (from approximately 21% to approximately 41%). Tax cuts that result in reduced funding for higher education will not help us meet this critical need.

Page 343: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92A

A final point, California does NOT have a “big bureaucracy.” State and local employees constitute a SMALLER share of California’s population than in approximately 45 of the 50 states.

Page 344: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92B

HOMELESSNESS:In 2005, Utah calculated the annual cost of E.R.

visits and jail stays for an average homeless person was $16,670, while the cost of providing an apartment and social worker would be $11,000. Each participant works with a caseworker to become self-sufficient, but if they fail, they still get to keep their apartment.”

Due to drug and alcohol use shelters are much

less beneficial than individual apartments.

Page 345: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92C

Will poor people make better decisions if they have greater economic security (e.g., guaranteed housing, food, medical care, etc.) or less economic security? The evidence we have is lopsidedly on the side that says poor people will make better decisions (e.g., decisions concerning employment, health, etc. that involve current sacrifice but have greater

Page 346: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92D

long-term benefits) under conditions of greater rather than lesser security. In reviewing a recent study by an economist and psychologist, Tina Rosenberg notes, “Worrying about money when it is tight captures our brains. It reduces our cognitive capacity — especially our abstract intelligence,

Page 347: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92E

which we use for problem-solving. It also reduces our executive control, which governs planning, impulses and willpower. The bad decisions of the poor, say the authors, are not a product of bad character or low native intelligence. They are a product of poverty itself. Your natural capability doesn’t decrease when you experience scarcity.

Page 348: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy–92F

But less of that capacity is available for use. If you put a middle-class person into a situation of scarcity, she will behave like a poor person.”

Page 349: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 93

Why Not Policies that Would More Help Middle and Low-Income Households?

While both our strong commitment to absolutist individualism and the framework of our political system (e.g., the separation of powers), make it difficult for the government to pass laws, there are important changes in the balance of domestic political power that have taken place over the past 40 years that make it even more difficult for the federal government to act on

Page 350: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 94

behalf of the interests of middle and low-income citizens.

In a “nutshell,” here’s what happened: (1) after suffering a large number of political defeats through the 1960s under both political parties, during the mid-1970s business groups (the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, the National of Manufacturers, the National Federation of Independent Business, etc.)

Page 351: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 95

decided to invest tremendous amounts of money both in lobbying members of Congress and contributing to political campaigns; (2) the relative strength of the counter-weight to business, labor unions, declined precipitously (in 1954 – 32% of the workforce was unionized - today only 13%), and with it a tremendous loss in both political information supplied to middle and low- income households and political participation by these citizens

Page 352: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 96

(i.e., unions contacting their membership with information on political issues, the membership then contacting elected officials); (3) the interest groups that have formed on the political left have dealt more with the concerns/interests of well-educated higher income voters rather than the working class (i.e., environmentalism, women’s rights and gay rights do not deal with the distribution of the tax burden,

Page 353: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 97

subsidies for low-wage workers or extending governmental provided health care); (4) due to the increased share of income going to the rich and greatly increased campaign costs – Democrats have had to turn more to business and upper-income groups for campaign contributions; and (5) due to factors 1-4, the political position of business has become much more advantaged relative to labor.

Page 354: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 98

Think of the political consequences of policy philosophies such as The Bush Tax Cuts, The Ownership Society and The Roadmap for America’s Future. All of these policies accomplish three goals of many (but not all) conservative leaders: (1) they shift the distribution of the tax burden away from taxing investments (i.e., money made with money – income sources primarily of very high-income households)

Page 355: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy – 99

toward higher taxes on labor (i.e., taxes more paid by income from wages and salaries – the principle sources of income for the poorest 90%, or more, of households - by relying on consumption taxes); (2) reduce the amount of money redistributed to middle and low-income groups through public programs (e.g., mass transit, job retraining, guarantees for Social Security, Medicare, etc.); and

Page 356: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –100

(3) increase the size of the federal deficit to the point that future Democratic Administrations will have difficulty in undertaking programs primarily benefitting middle and low-income households. For example, notice how difficult it is for Obama to get the necessary funding to implement his health care plan due to the size of the federal deficit (greatly swelled by the Bush Tax Cuts).

Page 357: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –101

The political consequences of the above mentioned policies significantly reduce the incentive for low and middle-income people to participate in the political process (e.g., vote) because they will perceive that government is not that helpful to them (i.e., their taxes will increase and the value of their government benefits will decrease). So, why invest time and effort in politics?

Page 358: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –102

This protects high-income households from future adverse political events. Thus, if increasing income inequality might cause low and middle-income people to desire income redistribution, make it difficult for the government to accomplish this and reduce the incentives for low and middle-income people to get involved in the political process.

Page 359: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –103

What could we do? The basic answer is to undo the changes of the past 40 years. While any proposed “reforms” would spark opposition from those who do well under the current system, I’ll mention two possible changes that would greatly alter the political landscape in a direction much more favorable to middle and low-income groups. First, make it easier for workers to unionize.

Page 360: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –104

Canada offers a compelling lesson. According to the survey evidence, American workers are as favorable to unionization as Canadian workers. However, over the past 40 years, the gap between the percentage of the Canadian workforce that is unionized and the percentage of the U.S. workforce that is unionized has steadily increased (Canada: 1960 - 32%, 2000 – 32%| U.S.: 1960 - 31%, 2000 – 13%).

Page 361: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –105

Without a lengthy discussion, the differences over time are mostly attributable to differences in public policies governing the unionization process. Not surprisingly, this was one of the earliest results of increased business political strength: make it more difficult for workers to unionize.

Page 362: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –106

The second change would be to enact Yale Law Professor Bruce Ackerman’s “Patriot Dollars” proposal for campaign financing: have the federal government give each voter an ATM valued at $50 for each federal election cycle (i.e., every two years). This money could only be used for campaign contributions (i.e., all unused money would be returned to the federal government – “yes” it could be done – i.e., the technology to ensure this does exist).

Page 363: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –107

A voter could give their contribution to one, or a series, of candidates. By not limiting how much individuals, businesses or unions contribute, this policy would not be invalidated by the Supreme Court. The Supreme Court has ruled that restricting how much an individual, or group, can contribute violates their free speech (i.e., money equals speech). Since Professor Ackerman’s proposal does not limit speech, it is constitutional.

Page 364: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Political Parties, Income Inequality and Public Policy –108

By greatly increasing the amount of campaign money available, Professor Ackerman’s proposed policy would reduce the tremendous monetary advantage of both business and the wealthy.

Page 365: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Lessons from Canada - 1

Currently, the federal deficit (i.e., the difference between what the federal government receives in taxes and what it spends) is approximately 10% of GDP. Rather than the painful cuts to the poor (food programs, medical care, job training, etc.) and education, we could eliminate the ENTIRE deficit by

Page 366: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Lessons from Canada - 2

having U.S. taxes as a percentage of GDP equal Canadian taxes as a percentage of GDP (U.S. taxes would increase from 27% of GDP to 37%). Next to the United States, Canada has one the VERY WEAKEST social safety nets of the wealthy democracies. Thus, Canada is NOT a “high tax, big welfare state” nation. However, Canadian taxes represent 10% more of GDP than in the United States. We are a very LOW tax nation.

Page 367: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Rationale for Budget Austerity

In voting in favor the Ryan Budget, Representative Tim Walberg (R-Michigan) said, “They understand in my district: We’re broke. If we don’t deal with this, we lose the social safety net.” One could ask, “Why can’t the wealthiest democracy in the world guarantee to it’s citizens the same social welfare protections (universal health care, greater income support, etc.) that all other wealthy democracies guarantee their citizens”?

Page 368: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

U.S. & Canada – Taxes and Spending as a Percent of GDP

U.S. Canada

Taxes 27% 37%

Health Care 16% 10%

W. Health Org. Rank 37th 30th

Defense 4.7% 1.1%

It’s not that we “can’t afford” to provide a better social safety net but rather we tax much less and spend much more on health care and defense. Defense spending in Great Britain and France is approx. 2.5% of GDP.

Page 369: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Areas to Reduce Spending

If you’re thinking of areas to reduce federal spending consider defense. U.S. military spending is about 4.7% of GDP. U.S. military spending is approximately 46.5% of the military expenditures of the ENTIRE WORLD. To put this in perspective the second highest spending nation, China, spends about 6.6% of the military expenditures of the entire world. The next largest spenders are France (4.2%), Great Britain (3.8%) and Russia (3.5%).

Page 370: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 1

Even the comparatively weak U.S. safety net still helps. In the current recession, the U.S. Census Bureau estimates that the combination of unemployment insurance, food stamps and tax credits for the working poor lifted the incomes of between 3 to 5 MILLION U.S. households above the poverty line. Now think of the human cost of reducing the funding for these programs.

Page 371: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 2

The most important fundamental change is to realize that a more activist government will be necessary. If present economic trends continue (e.g., small increases in hourly wages for most middle and low-income workers, reduced employer provided health care and less generous and secure private sector retirement benefits),

Page 372: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 3

the obvious “solution” is to have the federal government provide the benefits that the private sector use to provide. This means having the federal government supplement wages (i.e., to provide cash payments to those who work but earn little), provide a health care benefits package to all citizens similar to Canada and Western Europe, provide child care/day care to working mothers and increase the amount of money Social Security provides to retirees.

Page 373: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 4

Concerning Social Security remember:

1.It Is LESS GENEROUS than similar programs in other wealthy democracies;

2. For TWO-THIRDS of the retired population it provides OVER HALF of their income and for ONE-THIRD of the retired population over 90% of their income;

Page 374: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 5

3. Is an “INSURANCE” against poverty for the elderly and income loss due to

disability – to do this it MUST have

GUARANTEED benefits;

4. As “INSURANCE” against poverty and disability it is NOT comparable to a risk-laden 401k plan;

Page 375: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 6

5. Future shortfalls in necessary revenues can EASILY be accomplished by having ALL income subject to the Social Security tax;

6. Future support for Social Security would be GREATLY weakened if ALL

elderly did NOT receive benefits.

Page 376: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 7

One of the primary difficulties the United States faces in confronting growing inequality and poverty “head on” is the following core set of beliefs about poverty: (1) poverty is the fault of the victim; (2) economic growth will greatly reduce poverty; (3) government intervention will increase poverty. Each of these beliefs, at best, is “suspect. ”

Page 377: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 8

Greater economic growth does reduce the poverty rate in the U.S. However, what this means is that the U.S. poverty rate (typically around 17% of households - Great Britain and Canada around 12%, and the Scandinavian countries – Norway, Sweden and Denmark – around 6.5%) fluctuates around a much higher average than in other wealthy democracies and even at it’s lowest level, is much higher than most all other wealthy democracies.

Page 378: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 9

The “big picture”: the main reason that the U.S. has a much higher poverty rate than the vast bulk of wealthy democracies is that we don’t spend nearly as much of our economy in the following programs as do other wealthy democracies on income transfers (i.e., direct cash payments to either the unemployed or the working poor and the elderly) and do not providing comprehensive health insurance and childcare to all.

Page 379: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 10

Wage Subsidy: Assuming a minimum wage of $8 per hour, here’s how such a plan might operate: a worker earning the minimum wage of $8 per hour would receive a $4 per hour subsidy from the federal government (i.e., their “total wage” would be $12 per hour - $8 per hour from their employer plus $4 per hour from the federal government = $12 per hour) with the subsidy decreasing by 10% for each additional dollar per hour they earned.

Page 380: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 11

This plan does NOT increase unemployment because employers are NOT required to pay their employees more. Far from discouraging work and rewording laziness, the wage subsidy plan encourages work by making work pay more (i.e., the normal wage plus the value of the wage subsidy). The more work “pays”, the more leisure “costs” (i.e., each hour you don’t work costs you more when income per hour is higher than when it is lower). Since you have to work, this isn’t “welfare.”

Page 381: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 12

Furthermore, by making work pay more, and increasing the cost of not working in a legitimate occupation (e.g., selling drugs), the wage subsidy plan will reduce government expenditures by reducing the occurrence of two circumstances which increase government costs: (1) crime (by offering more money for being employed in non-criminal employment) and; (2) teen pregnancy (by increasing the cost of not working – having children typically reduces the hours a mother can or will work).

Page 382: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Reaction to the Wage Subsidy Plan

When a senior economic advisor to former President George W. Bush was asked about the wage plan he replied, “that’s the type of thing we’d do if we were serious.”

Page 383: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Value of Education

It is very important to mention the tremendous impact education has on earnings. In 1975 those with a bachelor’s degree out earned those with a high school diploma by approximately 60%. By 2008 this differential rose to approximately 100%. Unfortunately, the United States ranks 12th in the percentage of 25 to 34 year olds with at least an associate’s degree.

Page 384: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 11

In addition to the wage subsidy, other programs that would greatly benefit low and middle-income earners are: universal childcare, fully funding the Obama Health Care plan and the “Patriot Dollars” campaign finance plan.

Page 385: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 12

In all high-income countries, the parents’ socioeconomic status shapes a child’s educational and earnings prospects, but much less so in Sweden than elsewhere and much more so in the United States. In Sweden, even a child growing up in relative poverty has almost the same education and earnings prospects as a child growing up at the top on the income curve.

Page 386: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 13

Sweden’s distinction lies not in its support for public education, which is roughly matched by other countries, but in its public support for families and their children from the earliest age, even before formal schooling. All of Sweden’s families have access to affordable high-quality day care, which is publicly provided.

Page 387: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 14

This enables mothers to work without leaving their children behind in an unsafe environment. Female heads of household, a group marked by a high rate of poverty in the United States, are not poor in Sweden. Remarkable, their poverty in Sweden, is only 4 percent, compared with the United States, where the Census Bureau recorded a 30 percent poverty rate in 2009. Similarly, all of Sweden’s children are afforded high-quality preschooling.

Page 388: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 15

The annual costs of these programs are:

1. wage subsidy ($150 billion)

2. universal childcare ($150 billion)

3. Obama Health Care Plan ($96 billion)

4. Patriot Dollars ($4 billion)_______

Total Annual Cost: $400 billionNote: wage subsidy costs over time are

likely to be much lower than listed above

Page 389: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 16

Paying for the these programs:

1. Allowing the Bush Tax Cuts to expire

will bring in approximately $363 billion

per year.

2. Ackerman and Alstott’s Wealth Tax - a 2% annual wealth tax on households owning more than $7.2 million in assets (the richest ½ of 1% of households) would bring in at least $70 billion dollars per year – France, Norway and Switzerland have this

Page 390: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 17

If repealing the Bush Tax Cuts and instituting Ackerman and Alstott’s wealth tax seems “too hard” on the wealthy, consider the following: (1) the wealthy did very well, as did the economy as a whole, under the tax rates that would be in effect if the Bush Tax Cuts were allowed to expire (i.e., economic growth was greater under the higher tax rates of the Clinton Administration than during the Bush Administration);

Page 391: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 18

(2) over the 1980-2008 period 98% of the income gains went to the richest 10% of American households (i.e., exactly those that gained, by far, the most under the Bush Tax Cuts); (3) the share of income going to the richest 1% of American income earners more than doubled between 1970 and 2010 (from about 7% to over 18% of personal income);

Page 392: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 19

(4) reducing the concentration of income and wealth at the top of the income distribution would likely improve the performance of our democracy by reducing the previously discussed “debilitating cycle” (i.e., where the increasingly concentration of income and wealth among the very rich increases the reliance of politicians on campaign contributions from the very rich which, in turn, leads politicians to enact policies which further advantage the very rich);

Page 393: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 20

(5) many of the very rich inherited their wealth which rewards “luck” (you can’t pick your parents/grandparents) not “merit”; and

Page 394: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 21

(6) much of the income of very wealthy citizens was made possible by taxpayers. For example, while Henry Ford made a fortune from developing the Ford automobile, he wouldn’t have been successful unless taxpayers and/or government provided roads/highways, street lights, a public education system to provide an educated workforce to design, build and sell Ford cars, and a highway patrol to keep the highways safe.

Page 395: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 22

Similarly, would Bill Gates and Steve Jobs have been able to amass vast fortunes without the research and development provided by the National Science Foundation (an agency of the federal government which provided many of the protocols used for the internet) and the public school system to train the designers and builders of computers?

Page 396: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 23

In all of these cases, it is misleading to say that these individuals achieved their success “alone”, or without government help. Since taxpayers provided much of the requirements for their success, doesn’t it seem reasonable to suggest that taxpayers were investors in these projects and, as such, should reap the rewards of their investment (through tax payments)?

Page 397: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 24

Even if all of the preceding policy and tax changes were adopted, by comparison to the other wealthy democracies of the world the U.S. Social Safety net would still be “weak” and taxes would still be “very low.” It’s not “big government.”

Page 398: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net - 25

We could more than save the annual $400 billion cost of these programs by switching to a Canadian or European style health care system.

Page 399: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

The Social Safety Net – 26

If we adopted a European Health Care system taxes would increase, but this would be more than offset by the savings. For example, if your taxes increase by $100 per month, but your take-home pay increases by $200 per month (due to either less money deducted by your employer for health insurance) or your medical expenses decrease by $200 per month (by reducing the amount you have to pay out of your own pocket for health expenses), your standard of living would increase by $100 per month.

Page 400: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 1

There are good reasons to think that the government budget is too small in a democracy. First, consider the power of advertising. Isn’t the purpose of the tremendous amount of advertising private companies buy to get you to spend money on their product rather on an alternative use of the same money (e.g., higher taxes to provide government benefits)?

Page 401: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 2

Second, there is ample evidence that the public does not have a good sense of not only the benefits other citizens derive from government programs, but of the value they themselves derive from government programs. The percentage of people who (a) benefit from various government programs, and

Page 402: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 3

(b) claim in response to a government survey that they 'have not used a government social program’ are as follows: Home Mortgage Interest Deduction (a huge benefit for home owners) – 60%, Student Loans – 53.3%, Child and Dependent Tax Credit – 51.7%, Earned Income Tax Credit – 47.1%, Pell Grants – 43.1%, Medicare – 39.8% and Food Stamps – 25.4%.

Page 403: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 4

Third, many of those who most benefit from government programs vote the least frequently. As discussed in both class and the readings, lower income citizens disproportionately benefit from government social welfare programs. Additionally, lower income citizens vote less frequently than middle and upper income citizens.

Page 404: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 5

Fourth, many upper income individuals might prefer a greater government effort to help the poor if they thought they might be poor in the future. It doesn’t take much “courage” to favor low taxes and oppose government spending to help the poor when the person in question, either by their current economic position (upper income) or a realistic assessment of their future economic position (e.g., being born into a wealthy family, being close to completing medical school, etc.)

Page 405: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 6

strongly suggests that they aren’t likely to become poor. Would this same individual be as likely to oppose government programs for the poor if they did NOT know (or have a pretty good idea) of their future economic position?

Page 406: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 7

So, wouldn’t the obvious political incentive be for politicians to provide lower government benefits to the poor than would be provided if the poor voted in proportion to their strength in the population?

Page 407: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 8

A person’s political philosophy is likely to their willingness to spend money to reduce income inequality. If you are political liberal, you probably viewed the programs I mentioned previously (the wage subsidy, universal child care, the Obama Health Care Plan and the Patriot Dollars campaign finance reform) favorably.

Page 408: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 9

However, if you are liberal you have to face the question of how far you would go (i.e., how much of your money would you spend) to reduce income inequality?

Page 409: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 10

If you are politically conservative, a reasonable question to ask is: What are you trying to “conserve”? On the one hand you could answer that you were trying to conserve freedom and since taxes reduce a person’s freedom to spend their money as they please, then the government should be very small and taxes very low and, hence, you would probably not support the programs I mentioned previously.

Page 410: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 11

That’s certainly a philosophically defensible position. It could be useful, however, to consider the following two questions: (1) Is freedom the only value that matters? (i.e., inequality, poverty, the performance of democracy – think back to the discussion of the “debilitating cycle” - don’t matter much);

Page 411: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 12

(2) Does a small government actually deliver the most freedom? For example, would increase if: (1) the State of California sold off public beaches to private citizens and; (2) if taxes were reduced but fewer students could go to college and hence suffer a reduction in career choices later in life?

Page 412: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Size of Government - 13

A second answer to the question of what you are trying to conserve might be as follows: an America where the benefits of economic growth and technological change are widely shared, such as occurred between the end of World War II (1945) and the early 1970s (i.e., where economic growth was high and the share of income going to very high income groups decreased substantially). If this is what you are trying to conserve, then the programs previously mentioned could be quite beneficial to your goal.

Page 413: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 1

Mitt Romney, the 2012 Republican Presidential nominee, said the following: “We have a very ample safety net, and we can talk about whether it needs to be strengthened or whether there are holes in it. But we have food stamps, we have Medicaid, we have housing vouchers, we have programs to help the poor.”

Page 414: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 2

Now the reaction to Romney’s comments from Washington Post editorial writer Marc Thiessen. “So Romney is fine with an entire class of Americans being permanently on food stamps, Medicaid, housing vouchers and other government welfare programs? His solution for our fellow citizens trapped in poverty and dependency is to find holes in the safety net and repair them? That is not conservatism.

Page 415: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 3

That is liberalism. The left judges compassion by how much money we spend, which is why the liberal project is to strengthen the safety net and grow the nanny state. The conservative project is to help people escape the safety net. Conservatives seek to create an opportunity society where we can lift people out of lives of dependency.

Page 416: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 4

That is liberalism. The left judges compassion by how much money we spend, which is why the liberal project is to strengthen the safety net and grow the nanny state. The conservative project is to help people escape the safety net. Conservatives seek to create an opportunity society where we can lift people out of lives of dependency.

Page 417: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 5

We are not okay with having millions of Americans trapped in poverty and living on the dole. We are not okay with multiple generations trapped in government welfare. We believe in a society where the poor have opportunities for advancement.

Page 418: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 6

We want them to have the education and skills they need to find good jobs, get off public assistance and to move up to the middle class and beyond-as far as their ambition and ability will take them.”

Page 419: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 7

First, our economy does not, and will not, generate sufficient jobs to employ all of the poor who want to work. The Great Recession, which began in late 2007, caused the economy to lose 8 million jobs. According to the nonpartisan Congressional Budget Office, the unemployment rate is NOT expected to get as low as even 5% by 2016.

Page 420: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 8

Put another way, for the nine year period from 2007 through 2016, the unemployment rate would be high enough to leave several million job seekers without employment. How could these people be expected to work over this period when the jobs simply aren’t available?

Page 421: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 9

Furthermore, as explained very early in this writing, Republican/Conservative Administrations and politics weight reducing inflation more highly than Democratic/Liberal Administrations. Think back to the Obama Stimulus plan’s effect: unemployment was 1.7% lower than it otherwise would have been.

Page 422: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 10

As much research by political scientists and economists has found, more liberal administrations typically produce lower unemployment and higher inflation than conservative administrations (see earlier discussion and sources cited therein). So, the policies of the very philosophy Thiessen favors actually produces less employment, and hence, less opportunity for the poor than more liberal administrations/politicians.

Page 423: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 11

If the growth rate in the economy appeared to be high enough to actually employ all those who wanted to work, the inflation rate would move into, as policymakers see it, a danger zone. What would happen is that as economic growth exceed about 4% per year the federal reserve would raise interest rates, making borrowing more costly and, thus, ultimately reducing the economic growth rate and employment.

Page 424: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 12

Since the Great Recession started, millions of Americans cannot find work and the economy will not likely grow sufficiently to employ them for many years, if ever.

Page 425: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 13

Second, many jobs simply do not provide the level of compensation necessary to provide workers with a standard of living that Americans would consider “decent.” Working 40 hours per week, 50 weeks per year, at $9 per hour translates into an income of $18,000 per year. Most such jobs do not come with either health care or retirement benefits.

Page 426: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 14

Think of your family living on such an income. Is this how you want low wage workers to live? The very government programs Thiessen refers to are the only bulwark such low workers have against living on an income that does not adequately provide even the “essentials” of life. Think back to the discussion of the wage subsidy program.

Page 427: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 15

Take the food stamp program. Food stamps only provide approximately 70% of the money necessary to provide what the U.S. Department of Agriculture says is a nutritionally adequate diet Over three times as many households that receive food stamps had at least one worker than relied solely on government assistance.

Page 428: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 16

Finally, each $1 spent on the food stamp program generates $1.72 in economic activity. Think back to the previous discussion of how much economic activity per dollar spent was generated by other programs that benefit the poor (e.g., extending unemployment compensation - $1.60; payroll tax reduction - $1.09 or the wage subsidy program) versus

Page 429: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 17

the economic stimulation per dollar of the Bush Tax Cuts ($.35). Thus, the food stamp program helps generate the very economic activity that helps reduce the unemployment rate.

Page 430: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 18

Generations of the same family could not be on cash welfare for entire lifetimes because each person is restricted to 5 years. Second, Mitt Romney supports the previously discussed Ryan Budget, which will require large reductions in what is, by far, the weakest social safety net of any wealthy democracy in the world.

Page 431: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 19

No other wealthy democracy has pursued the type of system Thiessen desires. Third, the Ryan Budget, will require large spending reductions in exactly the types of programs (e.g., education) that would make the poor/unemployed more competitive in today’s labor market.

Page 432: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Thiessen’s Comments - 20

Fourth, the previously discussed wage subsidy plan increases the incentive for people to work because it “makes work pay more” for low-income workers than it current does. Thus, if we adopted such a plan, it would use government programs to increase, not decrease, work effort.

Page 433: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Wage Subsidy: Assuming a minimum wage of $8 per hour, here’s how such a plan might operate: a worker earning the minimum wage of $8 per hour would receive a $4 per hour subsidy from the federal government (i.e., their “total wage” would be $12 per hour - $8 per hour from their employer plus $4 per hour from the federal government = $12 per hour) with the subsidy decreasing by 10% for each additional dollar per hour they earned.

Thiessen’s Comments - 21

Page 434: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Conclusions - 1

Budget Waste/Fraud: One of the most important findings from the study of citizen attitudes toward government programs is this: people typically think that unpopular spending programs (e.g., welfare and foreign aid) makeup a much larger share of the budget than they actually do. In studies I read many Americans think that welfare and foreign aid each account for 10%, or more, of federal spending. Actually, welfare and foreign aid each account for less than 1% of federal spending.

Page 435: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Conclusions - 2

The error rate in the food stamp program is 2% (92% of the money goes to the beneficiaries). Since one-third of those eligible for food stamps do not receive them, we spend much less on food stamps than we would if fraud were completely eliminated and everyone who was eligible for foods stamps participated.

Page 436: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Conclusions - 3

Eliminating politicians “pet projects” (e.g., “earmarks” – the famous “bridge to nowhere”) are .1% of GDP (i.e., one tenth of one percent). The “big picture” is that we will not meaningfully reduce the budget deficit by eliminating “waste, fraud and abuse.” Waste, fraud and abuse simply aren’t large enough to have a discernible impact on budgets.

Page 437: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Conclusions - 4

The ingenuity of capitalism’s “creative destruction” means that business CANNOT pursue social goals/values over profitability. Thus, the very strength of capitalism is a prime reason why it can be argued that a strong social safety net is absolutely necessary.

Page 438: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Conclusions - 5

None of this is to say that our current policies are “wrong” or that the conservative vision of low taxes, high levels of inequality and a low degree of economic security are “wrong.” However, if we want to provide greater economic security and reduce income inequality in America, there are very viable options to both our current policies and conservative proposals.

Page 439: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 1

I. Partisan Difference on Health Care

A. Medicare – 1965

1. Presidential History

a. Truman

Page 440: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 2

1. Due to absolutist individualism, Truman shifts from universal plan

to Medicare

b. Eisenhower

c. Kennedy

Page 441: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 3

d. Johnson

1. 1964 election aids passage

2. Fewer than 30% of

congressional Repubicans

vote for Medicare

Page 442: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 4

2. Interest Groups – Medicare

For Against

AFL-CIO AMA

NFU AFBF

(small farmers) (large farmers)

Page 443: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 5

For Against

CCUS

(business)

NAM

(business)

Blue Cross

Page 444: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 6

Note: (1) the relative wealth difference between the “for” and “against” groups; (2) “for” groups support Democrats while “against” groups support Republicans

Page 445: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 7

3. Ramifications

a. Virtually impossible to repeal

b. America lags well behind other

wealthy democracies in both the time of adoption and the scope

of coverage

Page 446: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 8

c. Incremental attempts to increase coverage can make it difficult

to eventually cover everyone

B. Clinton – 1994

1. Expansion of coverage again

attempted by Democrats opposed by Republicans

Page 447: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 9

2. Almost identical interest group alignment as on Medicare

C. Obama – 2009

1. Democrats try to expand coverage while Republicans oppose

Page 448: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 10

2. If fully implemented, would reduce

uninsured rate from about 17%

to about 3%.

Page 449: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 11

Rudy Giuliani: “The American way is not single-payer, government controlled anything. That’s a European way of doing something; that’s frankly a socialist way of doing something.” “That’s why when you hear Democrats in particular talk about single-mandated health care, universal health care, what they’re talking about is socialized medicine.”

Page 450: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 12

“That is where Hillary Clinton, Barack Obama and John Edwards are taking you,” he said, “You have got to see the trap. Otherwise we are in for a disaster. We are in for Canadian health care, French health care, British health care.”

(“Giuliani Seeks to Transform U.S. Health Care Coverage,” Marc Santora, New York Times, August 1, 2007)

Page 451: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 13

II. Comparison of U.S. and Foreign Health Care Systems

Per Capita WHO

Spending  Ranking

U.S. $5,711 37th

France $3,048 1st

Canada $2,998 30th

U.K. $2,317 18th

Page 452: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 14

A. Why do the others do better at lower

cost?

1.Require Everyone to Buy Insurance

a. adverse selection if people

aren’t required to buy

insurance

Page 453: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 15

b. Need a strong minimum benefits package-must

shift costs to the healthy

2. Single-Payer Plans have much Lower

Administrative Costs

3. Government Bulk Buying of Medicine

Page 454: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 16

4. Pay Doctors Less

Question: If we are measuring “wait times” for a procedure should we start when your physician recommends the procedure or when it is medically advisable? Remember 18% of Americans don’t have a physician and Americans see doctors less frequently than in Europe/Canada. U.S. “wait times” are longer than frequently stated.

Page 455: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 17

A thought: Isn’t there a tension between opposing government regulation of behavior with health consequences (e.g., cigarette taxes, soda taxes, meat taxes, etc.) and believing in personal responsibility? The least regulatory, or “smallest government,” may not be the government that most fosters personal responsibility. Especially when personal irresponsibility imposes costs on others (i.e., people whom my costly actions shouldn’t harm).

Page 456: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 18

Not only do all other wealthy democracies in the world cover all their citizens for health care, even poorer nations are moving in this direction: (1) China has a 3-year initiative that will cover 90% of it’s population; (2) Mexico just completed an 8-year drive for universal coverage; and (3) in Thailand, where per capita GDP is one-fifth of America’s, 99% of the population has health insurance.

Page 457: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Health Care - 19

Dr. Julio Frenk, Dean of the Harvard School of Public Health: “As countries advance, they are realizing that creating universal healthcare systems is a necessity for long-term economic development.” This is leaving America behind.

“We are really an outlier,” said David DeFerranti, a former World Bank vide president. (source for last two slides, Los Angeles Times, May 12, 2012)

Page 458: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 1

I. Why it is Difficult for the California Legislature to Adopt a Budget

 

A. Public Expectations

Page 459: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 2

1. 50% of California Voters thought that State Spending

Could be Reduced 20% Without Reducing Services

Page 460: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 3

2. Voter Backed Initiatives Mandate Spending and Reduce the Options of the Legislature

a. Among the 24 states that permit initiatives, California is the only one that does NOT permit the legislature to amend or repeal them.

Page 461: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 4

B. Two-Thirds Vote of Both Houses of the California Legislature is

Required to Raise Taxes and Many Fees

1. Only 7 States Require This

Page 462: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 5

2. The Majority Party Typically Holds Less Than 2/3rds of the Legislature

3. Very Different Party Coalitions Reduce Chance of Republican Support for Tax/Fee Increases

Page 463: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 6

C. Most Legislative Districts are Not Politically Competitive

1. Greater Socioeconomic Difference Between Counties Over Time

Page 464: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 7

2. Real Election is Often in the Primary

3. Compromising with the Opposition Party Could Lead to a Primary Challenger

Page 465: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 8

D. As the Distribution of Income has Become Much Less Equal in California, the Policy Differences Between the Two Major Political Parties have Noticeably Increased.

Page 466: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 9

1. This Reduces the Ability to Achieve Compromise

E. About the Only Policy Area Californians are Willing to Cut is Prisons

1. Don’t Want to Cut Education – Which is a Big Budget Item

Page 467: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 10

1. Voter Backed Initiatives Require Long Prison Sentences

2. Think of the Public Outrage if We

Released Prisoners Early Who

Then Committed Crimes.

Page 468: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 11

II. California’s Structural Budget Deficit is Approximately 15 Billion Dollars.

A. The Structural Deficit is about 10%-15% of the Size of the Budget

Page 469: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 12

B. Solutions: Short-Term

1. Formula from the Past: Temporary Tax Increases and Spending Cuts

Page 470: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 13

C. Long-Term

1. Spending Cuts Alone Won’t

Work

a. Firing ALL State Workers Paid from the General Fund

would save about

9.2 billion

Page 471: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 14

(California Currently Ranks 46th in State Employees as a Percentage of the Population – Not “Big Government!)

b. Eliminating ALL funding for CSU and UC would only save 5.4 billion.

Page 472: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 15

c. Eliminating the ENTIRE Cal Works Welfare Program would save 3 billion.

d. Closing ALL Prisons would save

9 billion.

Page 473: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 16

D. Public Employees

1. Government typically pays LESS

than the private sector for comparable work.

2. Top Government Officials are paid MUCH less than Private Sector.

Page 474: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 17

3. State Workers in California are Typically Paid More than in Most States.

a. However, 50% of the difference is due to the higher cost of living in California.

Page 475: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 18

4. Pensions

a. Few State Workers can Retire at

age 50!

b. Pensions were one of the few politically accepted ways of increasing compensation.

Page 476: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 19

c. Thus, if we reduce pensions, then we owe state workers the pay they gave up in order to get better pension benefits.

Page 477: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 20

E. Revenue Increases Will be Needed

1. Overturn the 2/3rds Vote

Needed to Raise Taxes and

Fees

a. Representation/Fairness –

majority vote needed

Page 478: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 21

2. Taxes are NOT High or Very Progressive in either the United States as a whole or in California

a. Tax rates as a percentage of the economy are much lower in the U.S. than in most wealthy democracies: U.S. - 27%, Canada – 34%, Germany – 35%, Great Britain – 37%, Italy – 41%, France – 44% and Sweden - 51%.

Page 479: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 22

b. Federal Taxes - All federal taxes together (i.e., income taxes, Social Security taxes, etc.) take approximately 9.4% of the income of households making $16,000 per year, approximately 20.5% of the income of households making $52,000, approximately 27.2% of the income of households making $200,000 per year and approximately 34% of households making $18,000,000 per year.

Page 480: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 23

It is very important to mention that federal taxes have been made much LESS progressive over time. To demonstrate the impact of reduced federal tax progressivity consider the following: In 2000, the richest 1 household in 1,000 (i.e., .1 of 1%) had about 7.3% of total national after-tax income. If the effect of taxes on their income had remained what it was in 1970, they would have had about 4.5% of after-tax national income.

Page 481: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 24

C. State and local taxes are even LESS progressive than federal taxes. Thus, if you add state and local taxes to federal taxes (i.e., to obtain “total taxes”) the tax burden is less favorable to the poor (i.e., less progressive) than for federal taxes alone. State and Local Taxes are a greater percentage of personal income for the poorest 20% of a state’s households than for the wealthiest 1% of a state’s households in virtually every state.

Page 482: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 25

In California state and local taxes take approximately 11.3% of the income of the poorest 20% of households while taking only 7.2% of the income of the richest 1% of households.

Page 483: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 26

In California, the wealthiest 10% of the taxpayers pay approximately 75% of the state income tax. While true, this argument is misleading for two reasons: (1) the most important consideration is taxes as a percentage of income and not the percentage of a tax borne by a particular income group – thus, if California’s state income tax was only to raise $1 and Steven Spielberg paid that $1 he would have borne 100% of the state income tax burden –

Page 484: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 27

however, $1 would be virtually 0% of his income – thus it’s the percentage of income paid in a tax and not the percentage of a tax that a particular income group pays that is the important consideration; (2) this calculation excludes all taxes except the income tax (e.g., state sales taxes, property taxes, etc.) – when we include all state and local taxes and fees, state and local taxes are a higher percentage of income for the very poor than the very rich.

Page 485: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 28

F. Some state tax increases would IMPROVE the functioning of California’s economy and raise revenue:

a. tax services – no economic rationale for not taxing them

Page 486: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 29

b. change business property taxes annually (i.e., not only when the property is sold) - current practice favors those who hold a property longer – harms new businesses;

Page 487: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 30

c. tax carbon, pollution and oil - from an economic standpoint, the cost of pollution should be taxed to provide the appropriate disincentives to reduce pollution. Currently, California is the only oil producing state that does not have a severance tax on oil.

1. New “Cap and Trade” System.

Page 488: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 31

G. State Spending Has NOT kept pace

with either Inflation/Population or Personal Income

1. Adjusting for population growth and inflation, to maintain the SAME level of service in 2009 that the state of California provided in 1999 state spending would have had to

increase by 53%. It only increased by 29%.

Page 489: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 32

2. In 1980 California General Fund Expenditures (i.e., state spending) was 7.4% of personal income. For 2009-2010, this figure had dropped to only 5.5%.

Page 490: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

California Budget - 33

3. As a share of personal income, California typically ranks about 18th (out of 50 states) in state and local tax burden with state and local revenues equal to approximately 17% of personal income.

Page 491: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 1

DON’T WRITE DOWN ANY OF THE MATERIAL OVER THE NEXT GROUP OF SLIDES. ALL OF IT IS IN THE LAST 6 PAGES OF THE COURSEPACK. JUST LISTEN TO THE DISCUSSION!

Page 492: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 2

THE FINAL EXAM ESSAY IS TO BE DONE OUTSIDE OF CLASS AND SUBMITTED AT THE TIME OF THE FINAL EXAMINATION. YOU NEED TO SUBMIT A “HARD COPY” OF THE ESSAY WHEN YOU TAKE THE FINAL EXAM. DO NOT EMAIL A COPY TO ME.

Page 493: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 3

Since you will be a voter, a critical topic in this class concerns the choices the political parties offer voters. To examine this in Congress, select an issue that was voted on by either the House of Representatives or the Senate. The vote you choose can be either recent, or from the distant past. Since political party differences can only occur where there is controversy, select a vote where at least 20% of those voting voted on the losing side.

Page 494: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 4

For example, if the vote in the House of Representative is 70 "yes" and 330 "no" the vote was not sufficiently conflictual. However, had the vote been 80-320, 320-80 (or closer) it would have been “okay.” Similarly, if a Senate vote is 82-18, you could not use it. It makes NO difference if the legislation was “passed” or “defeated.”

Page 495: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 5

The source you are required to use is Congressional Quarterly Weekly. You will find instructions for accessing CQ Weekly in the coursepack. If for any reason you cannot access CQ Weekly, there is an alternative website mentioned on the very last page of the coursepack. “Google” your topic (e.g., U.S. Senate voting on health care) to find the date of a vote.

Page 496: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 6

When examining a vote make sure you do not confuse voting "yes" or "no" with supporting the concept. Let me explain. If the legislature is voting on a motion to "table" or "recommit" the legislation, voting "yes" on such a motion is to oppose the actual bill (if the legislature votes to "table" a bill then the bill will not be voted on).

Page 497: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 7

If the bill is not voted on it could not be passed. Therefore, voting "yes" on a motion to "table" the bill has the same effect as voting "no" on the bill itself. Additionally, the word "strike" means to remove (i.e., take out or delete). Finally, “substitute” means to replace part of the legislation (e.g., “substitute” 6 months for 3 months).

Page 498: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 8

You may want to use a vote on an "amendment" to the proposed legislation. Amendments modify (i.e., change) the legislation. Much of the most interesting legislative "action" is on amendments.

Page 499: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 9

This assignment is worth 30 points and a “hard copy” is due (typed) at the time of the final examination. Scores are lowered 10 points per day late (later on the day of the final exam also counts as one day late). NO excuses (e.g., my printer ran out of ink) will be accepted. That’s why you should start EARLY! Assume there will be problems.

Page 500: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 10

Additionally, you CANNOT use a computer malfunction as an excuse to take the final exam later. If you can’t bring a printed copy of the essay at the time of the final exam, your best approach is to email the paper and pay the “10 point penalty.”

Page 501: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 11

The following information is from the two page sample essay that appears in the coursepack. The discussion of “how” to obtain the congressional vote you will use is placed AFTER the sample term paper. Thus, don’t “panic” when you see a sample term in the coursepack and don’t yet have your vote. It’s all explained. Just read the 6 pages!!

Page 502: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 12

Issue and Importance (<<use headings)

 

In order to provide the funds for governmental projects, citizens pay taxes. Since taxes can be a sizeable expenditure for many families and individuals, the question of who bears the tax burden becomes important.

Page 503: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 13

Several years ago the U.S. Senate voted on an amendment offered by Senator Gore (D-Tennessee) that would have raised income taxes on high income groups and reduced proposed increases in taxes that would primarily fall on middle and low income groups (CQ Weekly Report, October 27, 1990, page 3655 – if you are using the internet version you will not have a page number).

Page 504: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 14

The purpose of this paper is to examine how Democratic and Republican senators voted on the Gore Amendment. We shall now develop a hypothesis concerning how we would expect Democratic and Republican senators to vote on the Gore Amendment.

Page 505: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 15

Hypothesis

 

As discussed in class, political issues can typically be thought of as primarily either economic or noneconomic (lecture of 3/30/10 - if you do not "date" your notes, estimate the date). Taxation would clearly be an economic issue.

Page 506: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 16

Furthermore, liberal and conservative political ideologies take very different positions on economic issues. Liberals tend to think the government should try to minimize economic inequality and maintain economic security whereas conservatives value freedom of choice most highly with economic equality being much less important (lecture of 3/30/10).

Page 507: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 17

Additionally, class lecture has stressed that Democratic officeholders are typically more liberal (or less conservative) than Republican officeholders (lecture of 3/30/10). Since the Gore Amendment would raise taxes on high income groups and reduce proposed tax increases on middle and low-income groups, it is probably best classified as a liberal proposal.

Page 508: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 18

As Democratic senators are likely to be more liberal than Republican senators the following hypothesis seems reasonable:

H1 Democratic senators are more

likely to vote in favor of the Gore Amendment than Republican senators. (Note: phrased in probabalistic – i.e., “more likely” and not “certain” terms)

Page 509: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 19

Findings

 

The Gore Amendment was voted on by the United States Senate on October 18, 1990. The amendment was defeated by a vote of 45 to 55 (i.e., 45 senators voted "yes" while 55 senators voted "no" - CQ Weekly Report, October 27, 1990, page 3655).

 

Page 510: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 20

Therefore, the Gore Amendment meets the criteria that at least 20% of those voting voted on the losing side (i.e., 45 out of 100 = 45% and 45% is equal to or greater than 20%).

Page 511: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 21

Among Democratic senators, 67% voted in favor (i.e., "yes") on the Gore Amendment [37-18 and 37/(37+18) = 37/55 = .67]. By contrast, only 18% of the Republican senators voted in favor of the Gore Amendment [8-37 and 8/(8+37) = 8/45 = .18]. (NOTE: you need to calculate percentages and NOT say the vote was “37-18” to “8-37”)

Page 512: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 22

Since Democratic senators were much more likely to vote in favor of the Gore Amendment than Republican senators (67% vs. 18%) the results offer strong support for the hypothesis.

Page 513: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 23

Implications

 

In this section of the paper you need to put your findings in a wider perspective. Thus, are the differences between Democratic and Republican officeholders on the Gore Amendment similar to their differences on other economic issues? If so, what does this tell you about American politics? If not, why?

Page 514: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 24

In the implications section you need to cite pages from the assigned readings. The sample essay contains page numbers from the assigned readings that deal with party differences.

Page 515: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Remember!

1. Do NOT advocate a particular policy or make “value judgments.” Remember, you’re an analyst, NOT an advocate.

2. Do NOT make statements that imply there is only one correct viewpoint (e.g., do NOT say something such as “any rational educated mind …”).

3. Do NOT use the first person or offer opinions (i.e., do NOT say “I think that …” or “I feel that”).

Page 516: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 25

In addition to substance, grammar, and neatness, points will be subtracted from your score for each of the following:

(1) Not calculating the percentage (i.e., NOT the number but the percentage) of Democratic legislators and the percentage of Republican legislators who voted "yes" on the proposal (5 points).

Page 517: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 26

(2) Not citing specific pages from the textbook in the "Implications" section of the paper (5 points).

(3) Not stapling a copy of your vote (i.e., printout a copy of the vote) to your paper (5 points).

Page 518: Political Science 100 Introduction to American Government.

Final Exam Essay - 27

(4) Untyped papers will not be accepted.

(5) You need to STAPLE your paper (i.e,. NO “DOG EARED” PAPERS – this will cost 5 points).

Late papers lose 10 points per day. Essays turned in after the final exam period are counted as one day late.