Overview and analysis of possible transitional...

78
Overview and analysis of possible transitional strategies: Moving from a tightly restricted supply model to an open entry taxi industry Paper prepared for the Victorian Taxi Industry Inquiry October 2011 1 Final draft: 18 October 2011

Transcript of Overview and analysis of possible transitional...

Overview and analysis of possible transitional strategies:

Moving from a tightly restricted supply model to an open entry taxi industry

Paper prepared for the Victorian Taxi Industry Inquiry

October 2011

Jaguar Consulting Pty LtdABN: 56089 615636

1Final draft: 18 October 2011

Summary

Where a move to an open-entry taxi market from a starting point of a high level of supply restriction is contemplated, transition strategies are frequently advanced as constituting more feasible reform paths than an immediate opening of entry. Feasibility in this context has several elements: avoidance or minimisation of the disruptions and costs associated with very large market adjustments, avoidance of economic hardship for existing licence-holders, due to the value of the licence being suddenly eliminated, and avoidance of the political risks associated with these adjustment issues.

Several types of transition strategy can be identified. All can be assessed in terms of two key characteristics: the time that would elapse before an open entry market would be attained and the amount, if any, paid to incumbent licence holders during the transitional period. These two characteristics determine the allocation of the costs and benefits of reform.

Delay in achieving an open entry outcome prolongs the existence of deadweight economic losses due to restricted supply. However, they also continue the transfer from consumers to licence-holders that results from supply restrictions. Hence, longer transition periods involve both higher economic costs and greater transfers from consumers to licence owners. The payment of compensation, or adjustment assistance, to licence-holders similarly involves a transfer of the costs of reform from those who have profited from monopoly rents accruing from supply restrictions to consumers and/or taxpayers. The distribution of the costs of reform is determined by both the amount of such payments and the sources of the funds used.

Consistent with this frame of reference, this paper groups transitional strategies into two types: those that involve immediate moves to open entry, but differ according to the amount of compensation or adjustment assistance paid and those that involve staged releases of licences over a period of time. However, it is important to recognise that these two groups of strategies are not, in practice, distinct. A true open-entry market equilibrium only exists when licences are freely available at a cost no greater than that required to recover administrative and regulatory costs. Thus, models that notionally provide for licences to be freely available but incorporate significant annual licence fees as a means of recouping compensation payments cannot accurately be described as involving immediate open entry. The distinction drawn between the two models centres on the question of whether there is a formal limit on the number of available licences, but the practical implications of two strategies that do and do not involve such limits may differ little in practice.

This paper also briefly discusses strategies that aim to manage the relative scarcity of taxi licences without moving to an open-entry market equilibrium.

The discussion is illustrated, where possible, by practical examples of the use of the reform strategies under discussion. However, most of the reform strategies that have been identified by policy-makers or in the academic literature have never been adopted in practice. Hence, the discussion of these options is necessarily conducted at a theoretical level. An appendix considers the

2Final draft: 18 October 2011

experiences of five OECD countries that have moved from a restricted entry model to an open entry model of taxi industry regulation in the past 20 years approximately.

3Final draft: 18 October 2011

Contents

1. Introduction..................................................................................................................................5

2. Immediate opening of entry.........................................................................................................6

2.1. Open entry with full compensation for incumbents..............................................................6

2.2. Immediate open entry with partial compensation..............................................................13

2.3. Immediate open entry with ex gratia payments only..........................................................20

2.4. Immediate open entry with no payments to incumbents....................................................23

3. Staged releases of licences.........................................................................................................24

3.1. Issue of additional licences to existing licence-holders........................................................24

3.2. Open market auction of additional licences........................................................................29

4. Formula-based issue of licences.................................................................................................32

4.1. Description and rationale....................................................................................................32

4.2. Population ratio based formulae.........................................................................................34

4.3. Load factor based formula...................................................................................................35

4.4. Multi-criteria based formulae..............................................................................................36

4.5. Subjective criteria................................................................................................................38

4.6. Discussion............................................................................................................................38

5. Other reform options..................................................................................................................39

6. Easing entry to the hire car industry...........................................................................................42

7. Conclusion...................................................................................................................................46

Appendix 1: Jurisprudence in relation to compensation....................................................................47

Appendix 2: Summary of reform strategies pursued in major jurisdictions........................................49

Appendix 3: Bibliography....................................................................................................................55

Other readings.....................................................................................................................................56

4Final draft: 18 October 2011

1. Introduction

The paper identifies and assesses the merits of a wide range of options for managing transitions from a taxi industry characterised by strong regulatory controls on entry to the taxi industry - such as that currently found in Melbourne - to a regulatory environment free of quantitative restrictions on licence numbers and characterised only by minimum quality standards. Such transitional mechanisms are necessarily also be applicable in a context in which it was proposed to move to a situation in which quantitative restrictions were retained, but substantially eased.

Each transitional strategy is assessed in terms of the following criteria:

Cost to government; Impact on consumers and licence-owners; Time taken for full implementation (estimated); Feasibility assessment (based on practical experience and theoretical assessments, as

required); Assessment of key risks.

Four groups of transitional strategy have been identified. The first involves the immediate removal of overt supply restrictions, combined with various mechanisms to address the impact on incumbent taxi licence-owners and, potentially, lessors. The second involves staged increases in the number of taxi licences. This group of strategies is consistent with both an eventual removal of all supply restrictions and an endpoint based on the retention of (less restrictive) supply constrols.

The third group of transitional strategies is a variant of the second, in that it involves moving to a formula-based approach to licence issue and/or total licence numbers. Finally, a fourth group of transitional strategies consists of indirect approaches to taxi reform, notably involving the encouragement of competition in related markets.

Some strategies discussed have been implemented in the course of reforming taxi regulation in one or more jurisdictions, while others have been adopted in transitions to deregulated markets in other industries. A third group has been proposed in the literature dealing with regulatory reform in the taxi industry but has not, for one reason or another, actually been implemented. Where practical experience with a transitional strategy is available, this will be assessed as far as possible. Where a strategy has not been implemented in practice, a theoretical discussion of its merits and likely feasibility and outcomes is undertaken.

5Final draft: 18 October 2011

2. Immediate opening of entry

Immediate removal of restrictions on the number of taxi licences potentially provides the welfare maximising approach to taxi reform, since the efficiency benefits of an open entry market are obtained without delay. However, different variants of this model have substantially different implications, both in terms of the expected rate of increase in taxi supply and in terms of the incidence of the costs of reform. Thus, several variants of this model are discussed below.

2.1. Open entry with full compensation for incumbents

Description and rationale

Providing full compensation to incumbents is generally taken to mean that the government undertakes to purchase any tradable licences at the ruling market price immediately prior to the announcement of the regulatory reform. Given the lack of transparency found in most taxi markets, there is generally some doubt as to the exact "market price" to be applied. Perhaps in consequence, this option is sometimes formulated in terms of government undertaking to pay an amount equal to the highest price for which a licence has previously traded.

While the translation of a "full compensation" policy into practice is simple in relation to perpetual, freely tradable licences, significant difficulties necessarily arise in the increasingly common circumstances in which various kinds of restricted licences have been issued by government. In particular, where these licences are not tradable, there is no readily established "market price". A plausible approach, in cases in which governments have sold these licences for significant sums is that the licence-holder would be refunded the sum paid1. However, where governments have sold licences for sums that, while substantial, fall short of the capitalised value of the monopoly rents available from the exploitation of the licences, licence-holders will clearly be made worse-off by a "refund-based" buyback2. To this extent, such an approach cannot be said to offer "full compensation". Sales of licences undertaken in Melbourne since 2002 would all fall within this category.

Box 1: The rationale for compensation payments

Soon (1999) argues that the compensation issue is “both a moral and practical one”. Morally, it is possible to argue that licence holders should be compensated for the loss of their licence values, since the government policy change has disproportionately disadvantaged them as a group. However, a strong counter argument is

1 Where annual sums are paid, any compensation would presumably be limited to the unexpired portion of the current year's payment.2 For example, the 10 year unrestricted licences recently auctioned in Melbourne were sold for $180,000, to be paid in instalments of $18,000 per annum, indexed to the CPI. By contrast, assignment fees are currently around $30,000 per annum. Hence, the successful bidders will receive windfall gains in terms of potential monopoly rents from exploitation of the licence of around $12,000 per annum. This group of licence owners would not, therefore, be fully compensated by a refund-based buyback payment.

6Final draft: 18 October 2011

that purchasers of an intangible asset that derives its value entirely from a particular government policy stance must be presumed to be aware of the risk that changes in the government policy position may reduce, or even eliminate, the value of the asset. Policy changes (or, perhaps more correctly, policy stasis) have substantially increased the value of these assets in the past: in fact, licence holders have generally achieved high rates of return which should, arguably, be seen as reflecting the inherently high level of risk associated with the investment3. Symmetry would seem to argue that, just as licence holders have been able to reap windfall gains from past government policy choices without these being confiscated, so they must expect to bear windfall losses due to other policy choices.

A particular Australian perspective on this issue can be derived from the experience of implementing legislative reforms under the National Competition Policy. The approach to the losers from reform advocated by the National Competition Council and generally adopted by State and Federal Governments was that there would not be a presumed right to compensation for economic losses due to pro-competitive reform. However, adjustment assistance was made available where it was concluded that there were net social benefits in so doing. In virtually all cases in which it was paid, this adjustment assistance amounted to only a relatively small proportion of the economic losses from reform. Had taxi reforms been widely implemented under the auspices of the NCP process, there would have been a strong presumption in favour of the adoption of this approach4. A broadly similar approach was ultimately taken in Ireland, following the failure of legal action seeking compensation for lost licence values (see below). The Irish Government ultimately provided for payments to be made to incumbent licence-holders who could demonstrate that they were suffering financial hardship as a result of the move to an open-entry taxi market.

A further argument against compensation is that payments based on the full, pre-reform market value of licences would be so large in total that virtually the whole of the available benefits of reform would be transferred to the former incumbent producers. Considered alternatively, the whole of the costs of reform would be borne by the taxpayer. Some individuals who are taxpayers but who make little or no use of taxis would almost certainly be worse off as a result of reforms in which full compensation is paid. Moreover, the political difficulty of arguing for such payments suggests that paying compensation may reduce the feasibility of reform, rather than enhancing it.

At a practical level, Soon argues that:

Reform is less likely to be disruptive if affected interests can be “bought off”. Though New Zealand succeeded in deregulating its taxi industry without any compensation, it did so in an extraordinary period when many other reforms took place.

This argument may, however, be unduly pessimistic. New Zealand is not the only jurisdiction with high pre-reform licence values to have removed supply restrictions immediately without paying compensation: as noted elsewhere, Ireland also followed this path in 2000 despite Dublin licence values being little lower than Melbourne licence values at the time of reform.

Does paying compensation remove political opposition to reform?

While incumbents would clearly prefer to obtain compensation, rather than not, it is less clear that the promise of compensation would substantially eliminate opposition to reform from this quarter. From the viewpoint of licence-holders, the maximum amount of compensation likely to be payable by a reformist government will not exceed the immediately realisable value of the licence. In a context in which licence values have historically risen rapidly, licence-holders can be expected to prefer the prospect of continued gains to a compulsory buy-out at existing prices.

3 The major risk involved inevitably being that of deregulation.4 As noted elsewhere, the Northern Territory – as the one jurisdiction to reform the taxi industry under the NCP program – did not adopt this approach. However, this may be explained by the fact that the NT reforms occurred in the early days of the NCP legislative reform program, prior to this general approach to compensation/adjustment assistance being developed and clearly enunciated.

7Final draft: 18 October 2011

Cost to government

The cost to government of full compensation based schemes is extremely large in jurisdictions, such as Victoria, where persistent regulatory failure has led to very large imbalances between supply of, and demand for, licences and, hence, very high licence values. At an average licence value of $500,000, buyback of even the 3,100 unrestricted licences on issue in Melbourne would cost around $1.55 billion, while additional expenditures would be required to buy back many or most of the remaining licences - almost 2,000 in number.

The prohibitive nature of these costs has frequently led to consideration of options for recovery or part or all of the buyback expenditure. Most commonly, it is proposed that a substantial licence fee be imposed on an annual basis, either for a fixed period or until a certain proportion of the buyout cost has been retrieved. This option was adopted in practice in the Northern Territory in the context of its National Competition Policy-based reforms in 1999. In Darwin, where $95,000 had been paid per licence in compensation, the annual fee imposed was $16,000. The government initially stated that this fee was to be removed following recoupment of the compensation costs, estimated to occur in seven to eight years.

A plausible alternative approach to recouping buyout costs might be to impose a consumer levy, in the form of a fare surcharge. Thus, for example, a 10% fare surcharge could be collected by the ATO in parallel with the GST/BAS system. Two potential benefits of such an option are that it provides greater transparency for consumers regarding the cost and financing of the payment of compensation and that it may have a lesser impact in limiting entry to the industry in the early years after supply restrictions are removed.

Impact on licence-owners

A full compensation largely insulates licence owners from the cost of reform, if considered in the static sense. However, opposition to reform is likely to remain, even under such an option. A key reason for this opposition lies in the opportunity costs involved: licence owners lose the opportunity to continue with an investment that has historically generated high and stable annual returns5. In addition, there may be concerns as to whether full compensation will actually be paid in a timely fashion.

The Northern Territory reforms constitute a practical example of a case where reform was strongly opposed by licence-owners despite full compensation being paid at the outset. This opposition was maintained after the opening of the entry and ultimately led to the reforms being reversed.

Impact on consumers

5 ESC (2005) found that assignment values had been stable at 7-8% over the long term. In addition, the real value of taxi licences rose by 76% in the 15 years to 2004, or an average of 4% per annum. Thus, total real returns to a passive investment averaged 11-12% over the period, compared with a long-term average of around 9% for the stock market - a market which demonstrates substantially higher volatility in terms of annual returns.

8Final draft: 18 October 2011

Consumers theoretically obtain maximum benefit from any strategy based on immediate removal of entry restrictions, since both the deadweight losses and the transfers to producers associated with licence-owners exploiting monopoly rents available in a restricted-entry market are immediately eliminated.

However, where governments seek to recover substantial costs incurred in making compensation payments to incumbents via hypothecated charges, much lower consumer benefits will be obtained in the medium term. Most obviously, where a substantial annual taxi licence fee is imposed in order to recoup these compensation payments, the rate of entry can be expected to be lower than otherwise, since the licence fee constitutes a substantial additional operating cost. The major practical example of this dynamic is the case of the Northern Territory in 1999-2000, where entry rates were substantially below those experienced in New Zealand following the opening of the market due to the requirement for all licence-holders to pay a $10,000 annual fee. It was initially anticipated that this fee would remain in place for around eight years, during which time entry rates would necessarily remain substantially lower than would be the case in the absence of the fee.

Time taken for full implementation

Consistent with the above point, implementation of an open entry policy can only be judged to be complete when any "clawback" mechanism - such as an annual licence fee or consumer surcharge - has been removed. That is, it is only at this point that an equilibrium number of taxi licences will be sought and obtained, as a result of the supply-inhibiting impact of the licence fee being eliminated. Basic arithmetic indicates that attempts to recover fully the costs of a full compensation package will necessarily involve the adoption of such charges over many years.

For example, in the Northern Territory case, it was initially anticipated that the fees were to be levied for around eight years. In the event, the fee remained at the same level for eight years and then, rather than being removed, was increased substantially by the Government: In 2007, the Darwin fee rose from $10,000 to $16,000, with further increases to $18,400 in 2010 being scheduled6,7. Thus, the fees continue to be charged some 13 years after the initial removal of supply restrictions.

That said, the continuation of the high annual fee regime in the Northern Territory, in a context, in which severe supply restrictions have subsequently been re-imposed, appears to constitute a conscious (if not public) policy decision by government to appropriate the monopoly rents created by its regulatory supply restrictions, rather than a view that there remains an actuarial shortfall in recovering the cost of the 1999 buyback.

This, in turn, raises a further issue in relation to attempts to recover the cost of compensation payments. As noted above, removing these payments is a necessary condition for the establishment of a free-entry supply/demand equilibrium in the taxi market. However, establishing a process in which the government receives a substantial annual stream of income from licence-holders

6 http://www.nt.gov.au/transport/taxi/pdf/ballot/09/infopack09.pdf 7 http://www.nt.gov.au/transport/newsroom/2007/pdf/20071205taxilicencefees.pdf#search=%22licence%22

9Final draft: 18 October 2011

necessarily creates a barrier to the further reform that removal of the licence fee implies. That is, having achieved partial reform of the industry at the outset, there is a strong probability that a government will fail to complete the reform process several years later, when this implies foregoing a substantial annual stream of income. As an example, if the Victorian government were to levy a $20,000 annual licence fee to defray the cost of paying compensation to Melbourne licence-holders, the annual revenue from this fee could easily exceed $120 million.

Thus, governments that seek to recover the cost of compensation will not only delay the achievement of the full benefits of reform, they will reduce the likelihood that these benefits will ever be achieved.

Feasibility assessment

The use of compensation strategies is generally promoted on the basis that it renders a rapid or immediate move from a highly restricted environment to an open entry one more feasible. As it is generally accepted that there is no legal requirement to pay compensation8 the relevant notion of feasibility here is clearly a political one. It is arguable that governments will be more inclined to risk major reform, such as open entry to a highly restricted market, if they believe that payment of full compensation will reduce or eliminate negative reactions from incumbents. However, as discussed above, payment of compensation is likely, at best, to limit opposition, rather than removing it altogether.

Moreover, any "feasibility" benefit thus attained must be weighed against the question of the "feasibility" of diverting large quantities of public funds to this purpose. In the current context, payment of full compensation to existing Melbourne licence-holders would cost at least $1.5 billion9. A budget allocation of this magnitude to be used as a transfer to a group that has both profited greatly from government regulatory restrictions over a long period and provided a service widely regarded as being of unacceptably low quality would clearly be politically controversial at best.

That the option of funding full compensation from general revenue is essentially infeasible is made clear by reference to the history of compensation payments in the context of industry reform in Australia. Where compensation to incumbents has been paid, this has usually been funded through some form of industry levy, whether paid in the first instance by consumers or producers10.8See: Abelson (2010). Court actions in Ireland (three cases), the United States and the United Kingdom have all resulted in decisions that the reduction or destruction of taxi licence values via regulatory change does not constitute a "taking" of private property and therefore does not give rise to an obligation on governments to compensate licence-holders. Economic analysis concurs: for example, Sidak & Spulber (1998) set out four conditions for the recovery of stranded costs and explicitly exclude taxi licence-holders from the list of possible appellants for compensation, arguing that the “irreversible investment cannot consist solely of a franchise right to receive supracompetitive returns.” See: Sidak, J. G., & Spulber, D.F: Deregulatory Takings and the Regulatory Contract, Cambridge, 1998. Cited in Koehler, B (2004). Regulating Supply in Taxi Markets. City University, London. nttp://www.unicataxibologna.it/studi_economici/City%20University%20of%20London%20-%20Regulating%20Supply%20in%20Taxi%20Market.pdf9 $500,000 x 3,100 permanent licences = $1.55 billion. The question of whether any compensation would be payable to the holders of the various classes of restricted licences that have been created would also need to be considered. Compensation payments to at least some of this group would be a likely outcome and would necessarily further increase the total costs involved. 10For example, the $1.29 billion dairy industry adjustment scheme was funded by a consumer levy. See: http://www.daff.gov.au/agriculture-food/meat-wool-dairy/dairy/history_of_government_involvement_in_the_dairy_indus

10Final draft: 18 October 2011

Even if a model involving partial or total recovery of this amount from future licence fees were promoted, significant controversy would remain likely, with the implications in terms of delayed realisation of the full benefits of reform doubtless being prominent in the discussion.

A key perspective on the feasibility of a "full compensation" approach to opening entry to the taxi market is found in the fact that the Northern Territory circa 1999 is the only currently known example of this strategy having been adopted in practice anywhere in the world. The following box provides details of the NT experience.

Box 2: Taxi reform gone wrong: the experience of the Northern Territory

The Northern Territory Government was the only Australian government to remove entry restrictions on its taxi industry as part of the National Competition Policy reforms. It removed restrictions in January 1999 and paid compensation to incumbent licence holders based on the highest licence sale price observed prior to the reform. However, annual licence fees were implemented in an attempt to recoup the cost of the compensation package. In Darwin, where $95,000 had been paid per licence in compensation, the annual fee was $16,000. This fee was to be removed following recoupment of the compensation costs, estimated to occur in seven to eight years.

The high annual fee restricted entry to levels substantially lower than those experienced in New Zealand and Ireland. Nonetheless, the industry complained strongly of an overcrowded market and low rates of return to both existing and new entrants. This, plus some conduct related complaints led, the government to respond by re-imposing a “temporary” cap on licence numbers as soon as November 2001. The “temporary” cap was twice extended and has now been made permanent, with a maximum of 11.1 taxis per 10,000 population being allowed (NCC (2003), p 2-19) – a level similar to that ruling in other Australian capitals characterised by major supply restrictions and very high licence prices and only about one third of that found in New Zealand’s open taxi market. The annual licence fee continues to be paid, almost 13 years after the initial reforms and, indeed, has been substantially increased in recent years. There is no indication that it is now intended to be other than permanent.

Thus, the net impact of taxi reform in the Northern Territory appears to have been an initial transfer of approximately A$100 million to incumbent licence holders, followed by the adoption of a system that will see the monopoly rents from restricting entry to the taxi market accrue in perpetuity to the government, rather than being appropriated by licence-holders. While the latter is a preferable outcome to the pre-reform situation, the market position of consumers is now essentially unchanged from that obtaining before the reform process began, with the exception that the use of an explicit formula to set taxi numbers reduces the risk that relative supply will become even more constrained over time. The Northern Territory experience thus serves as a clear example of the difficulty of embedding open entry reforms in the long-term.

Finally, the position of assignees of taxi licences must be considered. Assignment contracts typically have a three year duration and involve annual payments of at least $24,000 to the licence owner. Immediately moving to open entry would eliminate the monopoly rents that effectively fund these payments. This implies that there is a case for action to be taken to prevent assignees suffering hardship as a result of the reform. One option would be to pre-announce the reform, to take effect,

try

11Final draft: 18 October 2011

say, three years hence. A second would be to legislate to declare all assignment contracts void as from the date on which the open entry takes effect.

Assessment of key risks.

A key risk from any variant of the immediate open entry strategy derives from the size of the adjustment that would be required. The Northern Territory provides an example - albeit one in which the starting point is one of a lesser degree of supply/demand imbalance than that found in Melbourne at present - of the risk of a reform commitment being rapidly reversed due to the political fall-out from a market in a state of adjustment toward a new equilibrium in the medium-term.

Addressing this risk would require a clear understanding on the part of decision-makers of the expected post-reform trajectory of the market and a sustained attempt to communicate this to consumers and the public. The use of legal mechanisms to make early reversal of the reforms difficult to undertake would also merit consideration.

Conclusions

Payment of full compensation to incumbents as a corollary of an immediate move to an open entry market would involve very substantial expenditures and would only be partially effective in removing opposition to reform. The high cost of such payments gives rise to significant questions regarding the feasibility of such an approach. The merits of such an option, in a context in which case law indicates there is no legal requirement to pay compensation, are open to significant question.

Only one jurisdiction (the Northern Territory in 1999) is known to have adopted this approach to reform. It did so in a context of much smaller licence values than those ruling in Melbourne at present. While the reform initially proceeded, it was later reversed. However, this policy reversal is unlikely to have been related to the payment of compensation.

12Final draft: 18 October 2011

2.2. Immediate open entry with partial compensation

Description and rationale

This transitional strategy seeks to tread a compromise path between a full compensation and a zero compensation model. Clearly, numerous variants of a partial compensation model can be developed. At the simplest level, this could involve a determination that a given percentage of the pre-reform market value of the licence, or a given dollar amount per licence, would be paid to all licence-owners. However, a more sophisticated variant of this model would seek to differentiate between owners according to identified criteria and would yield different outcomes for different groups of licence owners. Deighton-Smith (2000) identified several general criteria that can be used to assess claims for compensation in a context in which governments choose to reform regulated industries in ways that will financially disadvantage incumbents. These were:

Whether the owner paid the government for the licence or permit to operate and, if so, how much was paid;

Whether significant additional investments have been made in the asset (or related assets) over time;

What time has elapsed since acquisition of the licence and, by implication, to what extent any investments have been amortised; and

The inherent risk involved in investing in an intangible asset reliant on the continuation of govt policy.

The application of these criteria clearly leads to a conclusion that holders of most taxi licences - including all permanent, transferable licences - have little claim to compensation payments. Those who have recently paid substantial sums to government for restricted licences would, on the other hand, have some claims.

Importantly, Deighton-Smith (2000) also points out that, in the context of the conduct of the National Competition Policy's Legislative Review Program in the 1990s and 2000s, the approach generally recommended by the National Competition Council and adopted by the Federal Government is to reject a "compensation" perspective for incumbents in an industry being reformed in favour of an "adjustment assistance" perspective.

Here too, the arguments for the provision of assistance in the taxi industry context are somewhat limited, particularly since there are virtually no "stranded assets" involved, other than the licence, which is rendered worthless if an immediate open entry policy is adopted. Deighton-Smith (2000) argues:

"...in some cases significant assistance has been provided, while in others it has been much more limited, or even non-existent.

One key consideration in terms of adjustment assistance is that of whether substantial hardship would be likely to result in the absence of such payments. As noted above, for many

13Final draft: 18 October 2011

owners, reductions in taxi-plate values will constitute the reversal of large “paper gains” made on the basis of relatively modest initial investments. However, for others, the possibility of hardship resulting from regulatory decisions that remove taxi-plate value is certainly real. It is most apparent in the case of small investors who have recently allocated a large proportion of their portfolios to the purchase of taxi plates. This “hardship” perspective tends to suggest consideration of the possibility of adopting different approaches to the payment of adjustment assistance, based on recognition of individual circumstances.

It can be expected that arguments would be made that any such discrimination would violate equity principles. However, an understanding of the payments as being “adjustment assistance” suggests that what is acknowledged is not a right of redress against a change in government regulatory policy but, rather, an obligation on the part of government to address particular economic circumstances that could arise as a result. Thus, payments should be regarded as “ex gratia” in nature, rather than as representing compensation in the specific sense.11

Costs to government

Modelling conducted by Deighton-Smith (2000) concludes that the adoption of such a differentiated approach could substantially reduce the cost to government of compensation payments (vis-a-vis the adoption of an across the board full compensation model), while preventing hardship for licence-holders. A number of scenarios were modelled, with the following results:

Purchasing licences for amounts equal to the real value of the initial purchase price would yield a total cost 40% lower than that of a full compensation based approach;

Limiting this buyback to those who had purchased their licences within the previous ten years12 would yield a total cost 55% lower than that of a full compensation based approach;

Applying a "sliding scale" in which 100% of licence purchase price was paid to those who had purchased a licence in the past year, reducing to 50% of licence purchase price for those who had held licences for 10 years or more would also yield a total cost 55% lower than that of a full compensation based approach;

Applying a sliding scale moving from 100% of purchase price in year 1 to 50% in year 6 would yield a total cost slightly more than 60% lower than that of a full compensation based approach.

While these costs are clearly much lower than the cost of paying full compensation in all cases, the amounts involved remain substantial. Applying the above percentages to the currently estimated cost of a full compensation based buyout suggests that costs of at least $620 million and as much as $930 million could still be incurred under such proposals. This inevitably raises the question of whether incurring such costs is likely to be significantly more politically feasible, in practical terms, than the option of paying full compensation. Conversely, this approach implies a broader distribution of the costs of reform, as noted below.

11 Deighton-Smith (2000), pp 15-16.12 This model assumed that no compensation would be paid to those who had held licences for longer than ten years, on the grounds that their initial investments were largely amortised.

14Final draft: 18 October 2011

Impact on licence owners

The different scenarios highlighted above have significantly different impacts on licence owners. In the first scenario, all licence owners receive the inflation adjusted value of their initial investment. Thus, while they incur significant paper losses, the net result of their investment in the taxi industry remains strongly positive, given that assignment prices have consistently averaged 7-8% of the ruling licence value at any given time13. Thus, for example, an investor purchasing a licence in 1997, for approximately half its current nominal value, would have received annual returns initially averaging 7-8% and rising to around 15% per annum (nominal) in recent years.

In the second scenario, long-term licence holders incur substantial paper losses, since they receive no compensation. However, this scenario is predicated on the view that, for those who have held licences for more than a decade, the initial investment in the licence has been substantially amortised via the high rates of return enjoyed in the long period since purchase of the licence.

Scenarios 3 and 4 would imply that many or most licence holders would face losses of some proportion of the value of their initial investment. However, the proportionate losses would be no greater than 50%, while the higher proportionate losses would apply only to long-term licence holders who had had the opportunity to substantially amortise their initial investments. Hence, hardship outcomes would be extremely unlikely, albeit that "paper losses" - i.e. the value of compensation paid compared with the pre-reform value of the licence - would be very large in many cases.

Impact on consumers

The same essential dynamics identified above in relation to full compensation based strategies are likely to apply to these partial compensation approaches. That is, given the need to fund compensation payments that could potentially exceed $1 billion, it is highly probable that governments would seek to recover these expenditures via an industry levy, leading to significant increases in licence-holders' cost functions and lower entry rates than would otherwise occur.

As the amount of compensation paid would be substantially smaller, consumers would clearly bear a significantly lower proportion of the costs of reform. Put alternatively, they would obtain more significant benefits in the short to medium term (if a lower annual fee were charged than under a full compensation option) or would obtain the full benefit of open entry conditions sooner (if the higher fee were charged over a shorter period).

Time taken for full implementation

Were the government to choose to levy a licence fee to recoup the partial compensation payments made, plausible assumptions suggest that a four to ten year period would elapse before the fee

13 This long-term historical relationship appears to have broken down more recently, with lower rates of return being earned. However, there is some indication that the increasing use of covert payments may mean that the apparent decline in returns over-estimates the actual position.

15Final draft: 18 October 2011

could be abolished. For example, were a $20,000 fee to be set - an amount that is somewhat below current assignment rates and thus allows for some degree of entry - annual revenue of $120 - $150 million would be generated14. As noted above, compensation costs under the various scenarios would likely total between $600 million and $1.2 billion. Thus, four to ten years would be required to fully recoup the initial compensation period in nominal terms and slightly longer were the government to seek to recover the present value of the initial payment.

Clearly, this period could be reduced if the government were to choose to fund a proportion of the compensation cost via consolidated revenue, rather than through a hypothecated charge on the industry or its consumers.

Feasibility assessment

The above suggests that it is possible to fund partial compensation payments from a licence fee while still allowing significant consumer benefits to be obtained from year 1, as well as providing for the elimination of the licence fee over the medium term. However, the implications of different partial compensation scenarios for the length of the transition period - and hence the ultimate feasibility of the reform - are significant. Thus, there is a need to focus on limiting compensation expenditure as far as possible and to consider partial funding of the compensation paid from consolidated revenue in order to complete the transition phase as rapidly as possible.

The following is presented as an indicative scenario for a reform path based on partial compensation.

Box 3: Partial compensation scenario analysis

The basis for the payment of compensation is that set out in the third scenario above - i.e. that a "sliding scale" approach to compensation would be adopted, in which 100% of licence purchase price was paid to those who had purchased a licence in the past year, reducing to 50% of licence purchase price for those who had held licences for 10 years or more. As noted above, this would be expected to yield a total cost 55% lower than that of a full compensation based approach15. On the assumption that compensation would only be paid to the owners of the 3,100 perpetual, transferable licences, this implies a total cost of approximately $700 million.

This capital cost is assumed to be recovered by government via an annual licence fee to be payable by all taxi licence-holders. This fee is to be a fixed term measure, with legislation setting a specific date for its abolition. The fee would be set at a level that would allow for significant entry to the industry in the short to medium term. Assignment fees are currently of the order of $24,00016. Hence, it is necessary for the annual fee to be set at a level significantly below this level to achieve this outcome. For simplicity, it is assumed that each of the 4,450 taxi licences yields a monopoly rent of $24,000 per annum. In practice, peak service taxis and, to a lesser extent, WAT will yield smaller rents than perpetual licences, since

14 Assumes approximately a 20-50% increase in the current number of licences due to new entry.15 This is based on the assumptions set out in Deighton-Smith (2000). In particular this relates to the rate of turnover of taxi licences and the rate of increase in taxi licence values. Clearly, should these variables have changed, there will be implications for the cost of the buyout package and the time horizon for the completion of the reform process.16 http://taxiindustryinquiry.vic.gov.au/doi/internet/vehicles.nsf/headingpagesdisplay/about+taxis+and+hire+vehiclesthe+taxi+industry

16Final draft: 18 October 2011

their average revenues are lower. Conversely, it is likely that the presence of hidden payments means that the figure of $24,000 understates true assignment fees to some extent.

On this basis, the total monopoly rent earned in the market annually is $24,000 x 4,450 = $106.8 million. This declines to zero in as the number of taxis licensed reaches 12,000 (i.e. 3 per 1,000, given a population of 4 million). For the sake of simplicity, it is assumed that the value of the monopoly rents available would decline in a linear fashion as taxi numbers increased17.

If taxi numbers were to increase to 5,800, available rents would diminish to approximately $87.7 million. Dividing the former figure into the latter, yields an average monopoly rent per licence of $15,121. If the government were to make taxi licences available at an annual fee of $15,000, approximately 5,800 licences would be demanded in a steady state. Total revenue to the government would be (5,800 x $15,000) = $87 million. If government levied fees at this level for 8 years, the capital value of the initial partial compensation package (i.e. $700 million) would be recouped.

This rough calculation represents only one possible option: higher fees would be associated with lower rates of entry and shorter payback periods, while lower fees would be associated with higher entry rates and longer payback periods. For example, at a fee of $11,000 should be associated with 6,300 licensees, an annual revenue of $70 million and a 10 year pay back period.

It should be emphasised that these calculations are general and imprecise. Two limitations should be noted, but tend to be offsetting in terms of their impact. First, payback periods have been calculated on the nominal value of the compensation package and do not take into account the reduced value of the stream of licence payments over several years (as a result of discounting). Conversely, the analysis is statically based. In practice, at a set licence fee, the number of licences demanded at a given licence fee will increase over time with taxi demand. This is a potentially important factor working in favour of this model, given the relatively high rates of taxi demand observed in recent years and the increase in demand which the initial increase in supply (and hence reduction in waiting times) would bring forth.

On the above analysis, the adoption of a $15,000 fee would lead to an initial increase of at least 1,350, or 30%, in the number of Melbourne taxi licences, while government could recoup the cost of the partial compensation package within eight years.

As noted above, multiple variants of this package are feasible. For example, if government were willing to fund part of the compensation package from consolidated revenue, the delay until open entry was achieved could be reduced. For example, if government were prepared to fund a cost of $260 million from consolidated revenue, the open entry end-point could be achieved within five years.

The above indicates that a transitional strategy based on a partial compensation payment being recouped through annual licence fees over a transitional period prior to open entry being adopted is, at least in the arithmetic sense, feasible. Importantly, the above scenario is based on a total compensation bill that is less than half of the cost of paying full compensation at current market value, while the minimum feasible transition period is approximately eight years. This implies that a full compensation based transition would not be feasible, in the sense that it would not be possible to fully recover the cost of the compensation package over any time horizon18. 17 In practice, the decline in rents per additional licence may diminish over a wide range, due to the increases in taxi demand which would be brought forth by additional supply and consequent reductions in waiting time.18 Given the impact of the discount rate.

17Final draft: 18 October 2011

Identification of key risks

The key risk identified above in respect of the levying of licence fees is that the government will choose to retain this rich source of revenue in perpetuity (estimated at $87 million per annum in the above "base case"), rather than allowing for open entry (i.e. licences priced at administrative cost) after having recouped their initial costs. The prospect of this outcome occurring in practice is heightened by the fact that licence-holders are likely to continue to lobby against policy changes that would lead to further entry to, and competition within, the industry.

Moreover, the risk of the reform transition not being completed as planned must inevitably increase with the length of the transition period: reneging on "old" promises is likely to have lower political cost, given the enhanced potential to argue that circumstances have changed and point to a less restricted industry with, presumably, higher levels of consumer satisfaction than were previously found.

Shorter adjustment periods will be obtained if there is a combination of a rigorous approach to the design of a partial compensation scheme, which would minimise its cost, and the inclusion of a component of funding of the scheme from general revenue, rather than recouping through licence payments. These measures are therefore likely to be critical to the prospects of the reform being completed in the medium term and a true open-entry outcome being achieved.

Conclusions

A key benefit of this option is that it would prevent the adoption of open entry reforms leading to hardship for incumbents. This is likely to be seen as reducing the political risks of reform substantially, relative to an immediate opening of entry with no compensation. The fact that most incumbents would receive a high proportion of their initial investments in government payments would mean that the majority of the public would be likely to see this outcome as generally equitable, where this is unlikely to be the case in respect of a no-compensation approach.

Moreover, the partial compensation option is more feasible than a full compensation option in the sense of its ability to be internally funded - at least to a substantial degree - by the industry within the medium term and be consistent with a move to fully open entry (i.e. licences at administrative cost) within the medium term.

That said, this option would be opposed strongly by incumbents and would, in this respect, yield similar political challenges to a no-compensation based option.

18Final draft: 18 October 2011

2.3. Immediate open entry with ex gratia payments only

Description and rationale

As noted above, it is generally accepted that governments face no legal obligation to pay consultation. Consequently, any decision to make compensation payments, whether full or partial, is a political one. Equally, governments may choose not to compensate members of an industry who have, for the most part, reaped substantial profits over an extended period simply via ownership of a paper asset whose value is supported by no more than government regulatory decisions.

This option was employed in Ireland at the time of the major reform of the taxi industry carried out in the late 1990s. While the initial intention was to make no payments at all to incumbent licence holders, it was subsequently decided to make ex gratia payments available to those who could demonstrate that personal hardship had resulted from the destruction of the former value of their taxi licences. An independent Taxi Hardship Panel was established to review individual applications for ex gratia hardship based payments and make recommendations.

Costs to government

The costs to government of a scheme based on the provision of ex gratia payments to some or all licence holders may vary widely according to both the characteristics of the specific taxi market being opened to competition and the criteria adopted. However, in the Irish case, the costs of the hardship based payment regime adopted were extremely modest.

Payment of full compensation would have been extremely expensive: immediately prior to deregulation there were 2,722 Dublin taxi licences with a value of I£90,000 each. Thus, the cost of buying these licences alone at market prices would have been I£245 million. In addition, there were almost 1,200 licences spread across the rest of Ireland. If the average value of these licences was even one quarter of those of the Dublin licences, additional compensation costs of I£27 million would have been incurred, making a total cost of full compensation of over I£270 million19.

In the event, the Taxi Hardship Panel recommended payments totalling €12.6 million (£9.9 million). In answer to a 2005 Parliamentary question, the Irish Minister for Transport stated that individual payments of between €3,000 and €15,000 had been made - i.e. a maximum of 16.7% of the pre-deregulation value of a Dublin taxi licence. A total of €16,349,000 in hardship payments had been made to 1,412 persons by 200520. The latter figure represents around 36% of the total of around 3,900 licences on issue prior to reform. Although the actual number of pre-reform licence-holders is

19 Barrett, S.D., (2003). Regulatory Capture, Property Rights and Taxi Deregulation: A Case Study. Economic Affairs, December 2003, pp 35-40.20 http://www.transport.ie/viewitem.asp?id=6424&lang=ENG&loc=1858. Note that these figures appear to be final, as the closing date for applications was 30 April 2004.

19Final draft: 18 October 2011

unknown, published discussion of the industry suggests that there were relatively few owners of multiple licences.

The total of €16,349,000 (I£12.9 million approximately) in hardship payments represents less than 5% of the total cost of paying full compensation, as estimated above.

Impact on licence-holders

As Barrett (2003) points out, numerous harms were claimed to have been suffered by licence-holders as a result of the Irish reforms:

"The panel21 reported that ‘amongst the many and varied medical conditions cited as being directly attributable to, or intensified by, liberalisation, were strokes, hypertension, high cholesterol and heart problems, stress, anxiety and panic attacks, depression, asthma, back problems and fatigue’ and that, ‘this by no means purports to be an exhaustive list of ailments.’ (p 38)."

As noted, the Irish context was one in which no compensation at all was initially proposed by Government, with the Taxi Hardship Panel being an ex post response by governments about concerns raised over hardship resulting for some licence-holders. The above perhaps argues in favour of a strategy of making an ex ante announcement of such arrangements. However, it is also notable that the Victorian Essential Services Commission received warnings of similar outcomes and worse (including suicide) in response to a 2005 draft report recommending that the existing hire car licence fee be halved from $66,000 to $33,000.

In financial terms, as noted above, the hardship payments amounted in total to only around 5% of the pre-reform value of licences. Thus, around 95% of the cost of the reform was borne by licence-holders in this case. Individual licence-holders would, in many cases, not only have borne substantial paper losses, but have experienced significant losses when any payment made was measured against the historical cost of their investment.

Impact on consumers

From the consumer perspective, the implications of this option are identical to those of the immediate entry with no compensation option. That is, the deadweight loss to economic welfare associated with the presence of supply restrictions is removed immediately.

Time taken to full implementation

In economic terms, this option is consistent with the immediate achievement of the full benefits of moving to open entry. The completion of the process of determining and distributing hardship payments could, on the Irish experience, take a number of years.

21 i.e. the Taxi Hardship Panel

20Final draft: 18 October 2011

Feasibility assessment

This option arguably ranks significantly more highly than the closely related alternative of immediately moving to an open entry outcome without any payments to incumbents, given that discussion of the impediments to reform frequently focuses on the position of those that have paid the market price for a licence in the recent past. Moreover, the Irish experience suggests that the costs of a carefully designed hardship based approach could be very small in relation to the current licence value, so that it does not create a practical impediment to reform based on the need to divert substantial funds from the budget.

Identification of key risks

From the political perspective, this option entails risks in relation to the ability of incumbents to argue that any hardship based scheme will, in practice, be inadequate to prevent substantial loss and hardship occurring in practice.

Conclusion

This option arguably conceptually belongs at the end of the continuum of "partial compensation" based approaches considered above. That is, while a conceptual distinction is made in this context between "compensation" and "adjustment assistance" made as an ex gratia payment, the common link is that some payment is made to former incumbent licence holders.

21Final draft: 18 October 2011

2.4. Immediate open entry with no payments to incumbents

This option is included for the sake of completion, although it arguably does not constitute a "transitional strategy". It's implications are essentially identical to the above option of moving to immediate open entry with only hardship-based payments being made. The key differences are:

Relatively small costs to consolidated revenue of funding hardship based payments to former incumbent licence-owners are avoided; and

The government faces an additional political risk due to the fact that licence-owners are able to make hardship based arguments against reform proceeding, as well as arguments based on economic loss/uncompensated government "takings".

22Final draft: 18 October 2011

3. Staged releases of licences

A staged move to open entry has been proposed in a number of contexts, primarily as a means of providing a more gradual transition to open market conditions and thereby ameliorating costs for incumbent licence-holders and/or governments. In particular, it is often argued that such approaches have the potential to avoid the imposition of hardship. This option is normally formulated in terms of a program to issue a defined number of licences annually over a set number of years, with licences to become freely available at the end of the transition period. It is generally assumed that, at the completion of the transition period, the pre-existing excess demand for licences will have been largely removed and, with it, the value of licences. Thus, the move to open entry represents a small further adjustment, in practical terms.

From the perspective of the achievement of the efficiency benefits of reducing the extent of supply restrictions, the fundamental consideration in relation to a staged program of licence release is that of the rate and timing of licence releases. From the perspective of the allocation of the costs of reform, the key questions relate to the allocation of the additional licences and the amount, if any, paid to incumbents as compensation or adjustment assistance.

No practical example of the successful adoption of transitional strategies of this type have been identified. Victoria's post-2002 reforms might be regarded as an example of this approach, except that there was no clear statement made, either at the time of the adoption of the strategy or subsequently, to the effect that the ultimate objective was to achieve an open entry taxi-market. That said, it is noted below that objectives of reducing the extent of supply restrictions over time were explicitly stated in 2003. Thus, Victoria itself can be regarded, in part, as a case study.

Given the lack of practical experience with the strategies, the following discussion is based on the findings of researchers who have sought to model its expected impacts. A number of different variants of this model can be identified and are considered in turn below. These are:

Strategies based on the staged release of licences can be divided into two types: those that are based on all additional licences being issued to incumbent licence-holders and those based on making additional licences available in the open market. A further distinction in respect of the latter variant lies in the question of whether the proceeds from auctioning licences are used to partially compensate incumbents for losses of monopoly rents or are retained by governments.

3.1. Issue of additional licences to existing licence-holders

The general approach of confining licence issues to incumbents is proposed on the basis that, while the total monopoly rents available across the taxi industry will decline substantially due to the licence issue, providing the new licences only to incumbents has the effect of ensuring that they continue to profit from the whole of these rents. Thus, this option minimises the losses borne by

23Final draft: 18 October 2011

incumbents, for any given level of licence issue. This is seen as a means of reducing the likelihood that compensation will need to be paid. Indeed, discussions of this option generally presume that compensation will not be paid, albeit that there is no conceptual reason for this to be the case.

Two broad variants of this option can be identified. The first is extremely simple, and involves simply issuing an additional licence to each holder of an existing licence, on a "one for one" basis. This is generally envisaged as a "one off" licence issue. It is usually expected to be followed after a pre-announced period by a move to complete open entry, albeit that it is also conceivable that this approach would be taken without embodying a commitment to an open entry market as the ultimate goal.

The second variant of this option involves issuing an additional "partial licence right" in relation to each licence. This would imply that incumbent licence-holders would be issued a right to, for example, 0.2 licences per licence held. Holders of these rights would be entitled to trade them freely, allowing them to be aggregated into new licence rights. This variant implies that there would be regular - perhaps annual - licence issues. Again, such issues are generally expected to continue until the value of a licence is near zero and an open entry policy can be adopted with little further adjustment to market dynamics.

The implications of these two variants of the model are considered in turn below.

3.1.1. "One for one" issues

This option necessarily implies immediately doubling the number of taxi licences on issue. It is therefore only feasible in a context in which the number of licences currently on issue is significantly less than half of the estimated open market equilibrium number. That is, unless a significant measure of monopoly rent continues to be available to incumbents after the issue of the additional licences, no "staged transition" to an open market is possible.

Given that Melbourne currently has approximately 1.0 - 1.1 licences per 1,000 population, while most open entry markets have more than 3 licences per 1,000 population, the adoption of this option would be consistent with the maintenance of some monopoly rents and, hence, licence value. In this context, it can be assumed that the "one for one" issue would apply only to owners of the 3,100 perpetual, transferable, licences currently on issue. Thus, the impact of adopting this policy would be to increase total licence numbers by around three quarters, from approximately 4,200 to around 7,300.

This means that a one-for-one issue is at least theoretically feasible in the current Melbourne context. If it is assumed that the open-entry equilibrium ratio of taxis to population is approximately equal to 3 per 1,000, the adoption of this policy would be expected to move Melbourne's taxi industry approximately slightly less than half-way toward this open-entry equilibrium.

24Final draft: 18 October 2011

The impact of a "one for one" issue on licence values is, in fundamental terms, determined by two factors. The first is the size of the move toward an open entry equilibrium position that the "one for one" issue would represent. The second is the timing of the announced move to open entry22.

Open entry equilibrium number of taxis

While no open-entry taxi markets are known to have significantly lower taxi ratios than 3 per 1,000 population, several have much higher ratios. Thus, it is possible that the relative size of such a move in the Melbourne context would be smaller than the above estimate implies. The larger the remaining "gap" between the actual number of licences and the open entry equilibrium number, the higher will be the value of licences immediately after the licence issue. The high level of demand increase in the taxi industry relative to population growth in Melbourne in recent years suggests that the true equilibrium ratio may be greater than 3 per 1,000, so that the impact of an initial "one for one" issue may be to move the industry less than half way toward the open entry position.

Timing of the move to open entry

Because the licence value is equal to the (risk adjusted) capitalised value of the expected flow of future monopoly rents available from its exploitation, there is a direct relationship between the number of years delay until the implementation of open entry and the value of the licences. A second factor determining the value of licences is necessarily the credibility of the announcement that an open entry policy will be pursued at the stated time. If this is less than 100%, the licence value will be increased, ceteris paribus.

Assessment of policy merits

The adoption of this policy would, in the short term, lead to a substantial disruption of the market, as a large number of new taxis would be added to the fleet in the short term. In this respect, the initial impact of the policy would be broadly similar to that of an "immediate open entry" option: the number of licences released initially would be broadly similar to that expected in the event of an open entry option that included a significant annual licence fee as a transitional element, although evidently smaller than the number of licences that would be demanded in the absence of such a fee.

The policy can clearly be criticised on equity grounds, in that it provides no opportunity for those outside the industry to benefit from the issue of new licences. However, the primary justification advanced for this strategy is that it will minimise the loss of licence value experienced by incumbents for a given level of new licence issue. Thus, it is promoted with reference to a different conception of equity.

A key benefit of this approach is that, by minimising the loss of monopoly rents experienced by incumbents, it is expected that the need to pay compensation may be averted. However, as

22 A third factor is whether any additional licence issues would occur in the interim. However, it has been assumed above that none would occur.

25Final draft: 18 October 2011

discussed above, the main determinant of the "one off" loss of licence value experienced by incumbents is the timing of the announced future move to an open entry licensing regime.

The 1994 analysis undertaken by Gaunt and Black23 suggests that, were the anticipated move to open entry to occur in fewer than seven years, the impact of this announced change would be at least as great as the impact of the initial licence release. That is, if it is assumed that the equilibrium taxi ratio for Melbourne is around 3 per 1,000 population, a "one for one" issue resulting in an increase in licence numbers from the current 1.0 per thousand to around 1.75 per thousand would, of itself, be expected to reduce licence values to around $300,000. However, if this were accompanied by an announcement that an open entry regime would commence, say, five years hence, the licence value would be expected to fall below $100,00024.

Thus, a government concerned to avoid major windfall losses to incumbents would be expected to find this approach to reform unappealing: a move to open entry that was sufficiently distant as to preserve a substantial proportion of the existing licence value would also be too far distant from the present to be credible. This option therefore seems to have little merit, in practice, in terms of weakening any argument for the payment of compensation.

The option of implementing the initial "one for one" policy, without committing to a future open entry policy might be considered more feasible in this context, as it could see 60% or more of the existing licence value preserved. However, the corollary of this is that the consumer benefit delivered would also be far smaller than that available under open entry. Indeed, the adoption of this policy would do no more than return the taxi licence to population ratio to a level equivalent to that found in several Australian cities in the 1960s. For example, Gaunt and Black find that the licence ratio in Brisbane at this time was around 1.9 per 1,000, compared with the above estimate under the application of this policy in Melbourne of 1.75 per 1,000.

Practical experience with the reform strategy

No example of this option being adopted in practice has been identified. The initial reform proposal developed by the Irish Government was structured broadly along the lines of a "one for one" policy: It was proposed that each licence-holder would receive one additional licence, with a further 500 licences to be made available to all parties in Dublin.

In the event, however, this policy was abandoned prior to implementation. This was the result of the position of strong opposition to the policy adopted by hire-car drivers, who sought access to any new taxi licences to be issued and successfully challenged the legality of the government's policy proposal in the courts25.

23 Gaunt, C. & Black, T. (1994). The Unanticipated Effects of the Industry Commission's Recommendations on the Regulation of the Taxicab Industry. Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp 151-162. 24 The licence value in this case would be equal to the discounted value of the assignment fees that could be obtained over five years, since it would have no value after this time. Given that licence numbers would have increased by 75%, the assignment price would be expected to fall substantially from the current level of around $24,000. 25 Barrett, S.D., (2003). Regulatory Capture, Property Rights and Taxi Deregulation: A Case Study. Economic Affairs, December 2003, pp 35-40.

26Final draft: 18 October 2011

Conclusion

This alternative has been shown to be unlikely to significantly lessen the opposition of incumbent licence-holders to major reform and to have little practicability ability to cushion incumbents from experiencing major losses as part of a move to adopt open entry within a feasible time-period. Moreover, significant opposition to such an option from non-licence-owning parties who seek access to taxi licences would also be anticipated. This would likely include a large proportion of both taxi operators and taxi drivers.

3.1.2. Partial rights issues

Abelson (2010) and others have also highlighted the possibility of using the basic mechanism of issuing additional licences to incumbents to expand supply more slowly, by creating "partial" rights. This would imply that incumbent licence-holders would be issued a right to, for example, 0.2 licences per licence held. Holders of these rights would be entitled to trade them freely, allowing them to be aggregated into new licence rights. The benefit of this option is that it allows for a more flexible approach to be taken to the issue of additional licences.

Thus, whereas the adoption of the "one for one" model would only allow for a major, one-off increase in licence numbers, prior to a possible delayed adoption of fully open entry, this variant allows for smaller numbers of licences to be issued, presumably on a more frequent schedule. For example, holders of "pre-reform" licences might receive a right to 0.2 licences annually until licence values are exhausted - likely to be a period of ten years or more in the Melbourne context. Evidently, this variant of the model more closely resembles the alternative considered below, of auctioning licences on the open market, in terms of the expected trajectory of licence increases over time. In theoretical terms, there is little difference between this option and one involving regular auctions of licences with the proceeds paid to former incumbents: the result in both cases is that incumbents receive partial compensation for their loss of monopoly rents, while these losses are extended over a substantial period of time.

However, as demonstrated above, a key driver of declines in licence values is the timing of the move to open entry. To the extent that this is so, this variant of the option demonstrates the same weakness as that identified above: any relatively short transition to open entry would create a situation in which large losses were incurred over a short period of time and would, as a result, do little to weaken incumbents' "moral" case for compensation.

It is theoretically possible that this option could be combined with a partial compensation payment in respect of the licence value lost, however, this does not appear to have been proposed by advocates of this model.

Practical experience with the reform strategy

No jurisdiction is known to have implemented this transitional strategy.

27Final draft: 18 October 2011

Conclusion

In practical terms, this option is broadly equivalent to the option of auctioning set numbers of licences on a regular basis and using the proceeds to pay partial compensation. Incumbents will receive little benefit from the adoption of this option unless a very long time horizon is adopted.

3.2. Open market auction of additional licences

An alternative to issuing licences without charge to incumbent licence-holders is to auction a pre-determined and clearly advertised number of additional licences on the open market. It is generally assumed that a given number of licences would be auctioned annually, with the long-term evolution of the auction program being established in advance, with the volume of licence issues being calculated to enable a seamless move to an open-entry market within a defined timeframe.. The credibility of this program is essential to maximisation of the revenue from licence sales, since any fear on the part of potential purchasers that actual licence releases could be greater than scheduled will clearly reduce auction receipts substantially.

No example of this model being adopted in practice has been identified. However, Gaunt and Black (1994)26 modelled the application of this model to the Brisbane taxi market, using an assumed seven year transition to an open-entry market. This paper was published in response to the then Industry Commission having recommended such an approach as a feasible reform option in a 1993 report on urban transport.

Importantly, Gaunt and Black concluded that, even were the total value of licence auction receipts to be returned to incumbent licence-holders, the total amount of compensation that could be financed by these means would amount to less than one third of the pre-reform licence value. Gaunt and Black concluded that this model represented a poorly performing approach to reform, since it substantially delayed the achievement of much of the efficiency benefit of reform while delivering only a relatively small amount of compensation to incumbents.

It should be noted, however, that the major determinant of the revenue obtained from licence auctions (and potentially available for redistribution by way of compensation to incumbents) is the time horizon for the move to open entry market conditions. As noted above, Gaunt and Black's calculations were based on a seven year time horizon. A longer time horizon would increase receipts significantly. However, it would simultaneously postpone the capture of the benefits of reform and greatly increase the risk of the reform program being derailed prior to completion due to successful lobbying from incumbents.

Box 4: Montreal taxi licence buy-back27

26 Gaunt, C. & Black, T. (1994). Ibid. 27 Trudel, M (1995). The Fundamentals of Taxi Regulation and the Quebec Experience. Paper presented to the 7th Congress of the European Taxi Confederation, Donostia - San Sebastian, Spain, February 1995

28Final draft: 18 October 2011

The experience of the Montreal licence-buyback, organised and funded by licence-holders in that city between 1985 and 1990 provides a real example that underlines Gaunt and Black's conclusions, albeit that the direction of change is reversed. In that case, licence holders collectively repurchased 25% of the licences on issue in the Montreal taxi market over a 5 year period and retired them from use.

The buybacks occurred at market value and this value rose from $10,000 at the commencement of the program in 1985 to $30,000 at its finish in 1990. By 1995, licence values had increased to $55,000. Thus, industry participants had taken a rational decision to purchase a higher degree of monopoly rents for their existing licences. Remarkably, the buyback was supported by the regulatory authorities, rather than being the subject of legal action by the competition authority, as might be expected.

Arguably, were a "one for one" licence issue to be put into practice, there would be a significant risk of such collective action being taken by incumbents to defeat the purpose of the policy. As demonstrated above, it would be in the interests of incumbents to agree collectively not to either exploit the additional licences granted or to make them available for sale. The apparently highly concentrated nature of the taxi industry, which is characterised by numerous cross-ownership relationships and other interdependencies, suggests a higher likelihood that such action would be feasible than would be the case in most industry contexts.

This risk of action by incumbents to defeat the purposes of a licence issue program theoretically attaches to all variants of progressive licence issue, other than those that are formula based. However, governments would arguably be better placed to take action in response in the context of a progressive licence issue policy, as distinct from a "one off" licence release policy.

Melbourne licence issues - post 2002

The regular licence issue program commenced in Melbourne from 2002 arguably constitutes a case study of this reform option. As noted above, no explicit statement was made to the effect that an open-entry market was the desired endpoint of the reforms. However, a number of official statements identified objectives involving a substantial improvement to existing demand/supply balance. Thus, in 2003 the Victorian Government28 reported to NCC that the program would:

break the link between the provision of taxi services and the value of the taxi licence as an asset;

improve the current demand/supply balance; lead to a gradual decline in the value of taxi licences over time; and prevent future "windfall gains" being obtained by licence-holders.

The report stated that the announced program did not constitute the endpoint of reform and that, should the licence issue program not achieve these stated objectives, additional 24 hour licences would be issued.

http://www.taxi-library.org/qebc0295.htm28 Department of Treasury and Finance (2003). National Competition Policy: Report for the 2003 Assessmenton Victoria’s Implementation of National Competition Policy, pp 91-4. See: www.ncp.ncc.gov.au/docs/Victoria's%20annual%20report%202003.pdf

29Final draft: 18 October 2011

Comparison of these identified objectives with the actual performance of the post 2002 reforms highlights the practical difficulties involved in implementing a progressive licence release option. The first of these is a systematic tendency, particularly in the presence of strong lobbying by incumbents, to systematically underestimate the extent of licence release required in order to achieve a given policy objective. Despite advice to the contrary by the NCC, the Victorian government apparently believed that the issue of 100 licences annually from 2003 to 2008 and 150 licences annually from 2009 to 2014 would be sufficient to achieve the above objectives29. Experience has demonstrated that this is not so. However, a more instructive calculation is based on determining what level of licence release would have been required over the period to achieve the desired goals.

As a starting point, the number of licences required to achieve an open entry market equilibrium can be estimated. The average taxi/population ratio in New Zealand cities, 20 years following deregulation, is in the vicinity of 3.0 and 3.5 taxis per 1000 population, while in Ireland the equivalent ratios are as high as 6.0 per 1,000. Taking the New Zealand ratios as a reasonably conservative estimate and applying this to the current Melbourne population of around 4.0 million suggests an open entry equilibrium number of taxis of between 12,000 and 13,500. Given that there were fewer than 3,500 licences on issue in 2002 (including 3,100 transferable general licences), this implies that between 8,500 and 10,000 licences would need to have been issued over a 12 year period in order to approximate an open entry equilibrium over that time.

This is equivalent to the issue of between 700 and 830 licences per annum, approximately, over a period exceeding a decade. By comparison, programmed issues were to average 125 per annum over the period.

These estimates suggest that, even if a move to an open entry market was never in contemplation, in order to achieve the stated objectives of an improvement in supply/demand balance and a gradual reduction in licence values over the reform period30, it would have been necessary to release around four times as many licences as were called for under the program.

These notional calculations highlight a fundamental feasibility issue in relation to the design and implementation of staged licence issue schemes. Estimates of the number of licences required at the given "endpoint" tend to be based on static analyses or unduly conservative demand growth estimates, while it is politically difficult to convince stakeholders that a tripling in the taxi/population ratio is needed, especially in the face of concerted lobbying to the contrary from stakeholders. As an example of the former dynamic, in the lead-up to the Irish taxi reforms, the Oscar Faber Report prepared for the Irish government in 1998 argued that a fleet of 5900 taxis would be needed after 10

29 While not generally publicly acknowledged, the documentation provided to the NCC stated that at least half of the peak services licences issued in the first six years would, on the 6th anniversary of their issue, be converted to 24 hour licences and replaced by additional peak service licences. This was expected to lead to a total increase of 46 per cent in actual licence numbers. See Department of Treasury and Finance (2003), op. cit., p 7.30 For example, even a modest $10,000 annual reduction in nominal licence values from their $280,000 starting point in 2002 would imply that the 2014 licence value would have been no more than $160,000, or less than one third of its current value. This would appear to imply a taxi fleet of at least 9,500 on the above calculations.

30Final draft: 18 October 2011

years in order to service the Dublin market. In the event, two years after deregulation, 9000 taxis were operating in Dublin, while these numbers have subsequently been maintained.

Conclusions

Staged licence issue programs provide a theoretically feasible means of reducing the impact of reform on licence-holders, by both allowing revenue to be attained by government from licence auctions and redistributed to licence holders as partial compensation and by allowing some monopoly rents to continue to be earned over a number of years. However, the cost of following this path lies in the substantial delay in achieving the majority of the benefits of reform.

More importantly, two systemic issues suggest that the final objective of this strategy is unlikely to be met. First, the licence issue program is likely to be miscalculated, leading to far too few licences being issued, as in the Victorian case post 2002. Second, if the transition period is long enough to substantially smooth the adjustment path for incumbents, it will also lead to a high risk that successful lobbying will lead to its abandonment prior to completion. Another Victorian example, that of the post-Foletta report reforms of the late 1980s, provides a practical example of this risk translating into reality.

4. Formula-based issue of licences

4.1. Description and rationale

The fundamental concern with mechanisms such as those discussed above, which involve determining ex ante the number of licences to be issued annually over a given period, is that they imply a high risk that the underlying objectives of reform will not be achieved. This will occur if the annual licence issued required to achieve the reform objective over the identified period is under-estimated by policy makers during the project design phase. Such under-estimates are highly likely to occur, for several reasons:

A static analysis of the taxi market may be employed, which does not account for increases in demand due to service quality improvements and/or price falls resulting from reform;

Ongoing increases in taxi demand due to factors exogenous to the taxi market are under-estimated (frequently due to inadequate data);

Strong lobbying from incumbents to minimise the extent of additional licence issue.

Moreover, there are impediments to policy-makers correcting these initial under-estimates following initial program implementation. In particular, there is likely to be ongoing lobbying from incumbents to “honour commitments” made to a particular program of licence issue at the outset (i.e. in preference to increasing issues), together with a perceived need to maintain the predictability of the reform program in the interests of “market stability”.

31Final draft: 18 October 2011

The experience of the current (post 2002) Victorian taxi reform program provides a clear example of this dynamic. Advice was provided by the National Competition Council prior to the announcement of the policy indicating that the proposed quantum of licence issues would be insufficient to improve supply/demand balance over time. This was based on analysis of historical demand growth in the market. However, no change was made to the initial proposals in response.

In 2003 the Victorian Government31 reported to NCC on the objectives of the reform program and the “flexibility” said to be contained in it. It indicated that a key objective of the reform was to break the link between the provision of taxi services and the value of the taxi licence as an asset and that the reforms were expected to improve the current demand/supply balance. It also stated that it was expected that taxi licences would gradually decline in value over time as a result and that it would no longer be possible for licence-holders to obtain “windfall gains”. In particular, the report stated that the announced program did not constitute the endpoint of reform and that, should the licence issue program not achieve these stated objectives, additional 24 hour licences would be issued.

In the event, while none of the above objectives was achieved, with licence values almost doubling over the ensuing nine years, no further licences were issued32.

A formula-based licence issue program provides a plausible means of overcoming these systemic problems. The key decision to be made in this context is what criterion or criteria will be used to identify the appropriate number of licences to issue. Several possibilities can be identified, based on both practical experience and theoretical analysis. In terms of practical experience, three OECD countries currently adopt formula-based licence issue programs, as do New South Wales and the Northern Territory. Four of these five jurisdictions adopt a formula based on a single criterion, while the fifth adopts a formula based on multiple criteria. In addition, Bruce Schaller, a former taxi regulator, has adopted an alternative, multi-criteria formula. These options are discussed in turn.

The purpose of a formula-based approach is clearly to provide a decision-rule that consistently provides an appropriate matching of taxi supply and demand. The key benefit of a formula based approach is that the existence of such a rule removes decision-making on taxi licence issue form the arena of subjective political or administrative decision-making and, hence, reduces or eliminates the risk of regulatory capture. However, the formula-based approach will only provide positive outcomes if two conditions hold:

The criterion or criteria used constitute a good proxy for taxi demand (or demand growth); and

the "benchmark" value(s) of the criterion or criteria are appropriately set.

31 Department of Treasury and Finance (2003). National Competition Policy: Report for the 2003 Assessmenton Victoria’s Implementation of National Competition Policy, pp 91-4. See: www.ncp.ncc.gov.au/docs/Victoria's%20annual%20report%202003.pdf32 The “one off” issue of 200 10 year licences and 330 WAT licences that occurred in 2010 appears, in effect, to have largely substituted for the programmed releases of 200 peak period licences during 2010 and 2011, together with the anticipated conversion of 100 peak period licences to full licences over the same period and their replacement with a further 100 peak period licences, as envisaged under the original reform program. When other failures to carry out aspects of the initially announced reforms are taken into account, the total number of licences issued from 2002 to 2011 remains less than that originally envisaged.

32Final draft: 18 October 2011

4.2. Population ratio based formulae

The most commonly used criterion is that of population ratio. This is used in Flanders and Romania, as well as the Northern Territory and some German cities33. Flanders uses a ratio of 1:1,000, in common with the Northern Territory34. However, Romania uses a ratio of 4:1,000.

No information is available as to the reasoning behind the adoption of the 1:1,000 ratio in Flanders. However, it is notable that, when the Northern Territory adopted this ratio in the course of reversing its recently adopted open entry reforms, it chose a ratio that represented the actual pre-reform ratio of taxis to population. This suggests that decision-makers opted to try to revisit the pre-reform state of the industry. Alternatively, the fact that the government chose to continue to capture the available monopoly rents through maintenance of a large annual licence fee can also be seen as providing a strong incentive for it to choose a relatively low ratio, since this would maximise the available rents and, hence, the size of the licence fee that can be charged. Recent significant increases in the fee provide some support for this hypothesis.

In practice, Romania's 4: 1,000 ratio is a legislated national maximum, with local authorities being permitted to impose tighter restrictions35. Notably, the 4: 1,000 ratio is broadly in line with the taxi ratios found in cities characterised by open entry markets. Conversely, the 1: 1,000 ratio adopted in Flanders and in the Northern Territory is broadly equivalent to the minimum ratios found in cities with ad hoc licence issuing arrangements, such as most Australian capitals.

While only a small number of observations are available, it is clear that the outcomes of the adoption of a population ratio based formula can, and do, vary widely. On one view, observation of actual ratios found in open-entry markets should provide a benchmark which would allow decision-makers to determine an appropriate ratio. Observation across many markets with tradeable licences of a clear inverse relationship between licence values and taxi: population ratios might also be thought to provide useful guidance to decision-makers charged with selecting an appropraite ratio. However, the above observations provide no evidence of a "clustering" of outcomes and no real evidence that the actual ratio of taxis per head of population is systematically higher in jurisdictions adopting this criterion as part of a formula based approach than is the case for cities with ad hoc approaches to licence issue.

Thus, the practical performance of this type of formula based approach cannot be judged to be particularly positive. At a theoretical level, the problem may be that the administrative mechanisms put in place have not incorporated any specific decision-rules to be used in determining an appropriate ratio.

More broadly, it is clear that a city's population size provides only a very loose approximation for taxi demand and that the "optimal" ratio of taxis to population is likely to change over time, perhaps

33 Bekken, JT. (2007). Experiences with (de)Regulation in the European Taxi Industry. In OECD/ECMT (2007) (De)-Regulation of the Taxi Industry. See pp 40-41. No information is available on the ratios used in German cities or the rationales for their adoption.34 Strictly speaking, the NT ratio is 1.11 per 1,000.35 In practice, however, there seems to have been relatively little use made of this power by local authorities: according to Barrett, taxi numbers in Romania more than doubled since 1989. See: OECD/ECMT (2007), op. cit., p 136.

33Final draft: 18 October 2011

substantially. The recent history of Melbourne provides an obvious example, with demand growth having substantially exceeded population growth over a long period36. Moreover, regression analysis conducted by Schaller (see below) finds that population is not a significant determinant of taxi demand, once other key variables have been controlled.

In sum, there is no single "optimum" ratio of taxis to population and, consequently, little reason to believe that the adoption of a formula-based approach using this criterion will necessarily yield a positive outcome. While the general rationale for a ratio-based approach is that it can function as a preventative against declining relative supply due to ad hoc decisions being made over time by decision-makers who demonstrate degrees of capture by the industry, the practical experience with this approach, albeit limited, provides little support for it.

4.3. Load factor based formula

One OECD country - South Korea - uses a formula based on the utilisation rate of taxis to determine licence issue decisions. This formula requires that licences be issued where load factors fall below 55% (for cities of more than 500,000), or 50% for smaller cities. In addition, licences will be issued if operation rates of the taxi fleet falls below 80%.

Such criteria, in particular the former, arguably better reflect taxi demand than does a simple population ratio. To the extent that this is so, this option potentially provides a superior decision-rule. In practice, the adoption of this approach does seem to have coincided with a slight decline in the real value of Korean taxi licences and, by implication, an improvement in supply/demand balance. Kang reports that taxi licences were valued at around $65,000 in 1998, whereas OED (2007) reports that the then current value of a licence was in the range A$25 - 65,000 approximately. This broadly static nominal licence value over a decade suggests a significant decline in nominal values over the period, contrary to the experience of most taxi markets with controlled entry.

Given that there is only a single observation of the use of this criterion in practice, it clearly cannot be concluded that this represents a superior approach or that it will systematically perform well in practice. That said, it is clear that load factors constitute a more direct and reliable measure of supply/demand balance than does the taxi/population ratio.

On the other hand, there is clearly room for substantial disagreement as to the specific occupancy rate that should trigger taxi licence issues. From a theoretical perspective, the "optimum" rate is a function of consumer preferences measured on a price/quality continuum. That is, lower occupancy rates are necessarily associated (cet. par.) with lower waiting time, which is a key element of service quality, while also implying higher cost structures. Thus, different populations with different valuations of their waiting time will implicitly prefer different load factors.

36 For example, the Victorian NCP review of taxi legislation found that demand had increased at an average of 3% per annum between the early 1980s and the late 1990s - substantially higher than the rate of population growth. Similarly, the strong post-2002 inflation of taxi licence values, occurring in a context of licence numbers being increased broadly in line with population, implies that this trend has continued.

34Final draft: 18 October 2011

Again, it is not clear how a regulatory authority would go about systematically assessing these consumer preferences and determining an optimum load factor to maintain as a target over time. Unless such a mechanism can be posited, there is no basis for believing that a licence issue formula based on this criterion will systematically achieve good outcomes over time.

4.4. Multi-criteria based formulae

Sydney model

Sydney constitutes the only currently known example of a multi-criteria based formula for licence issue. The Sydney model was adopted very recently, so that there is little possibility of assessing its practical performance over time. However, it can be assessed in terms of a theoretical consideration of the criteria used.

The Sydney model uses ten criteria, as follows:

Table 1: Sydney taxi licence issue formula - criteria used

Key demand driver ComponentsLikely taxi demand (including latent demand) State final demand

Sydney population sizeUnemployment rateSydney airport passenger numbers Total network bookings

Industry viability and sustainability and demand for new licences

Value of licencesPlate lease costs

Performance of existing taxi services Annual average pick up time (mins)Percentage of pickups within 15 minsPercentage of "no cars available"

This formula clearly includes elements of both the "population ratio" and "load factor" based formulae discussed above, while also taking a broader range of factors into account. Some bear a very indirect, or even tenuous relationship to taxi demand: the unemployment rate and Sydney airport passenger numbers arguably fall within this category. Conversely, the "performance of existing taxi services" criteria are clearly directly related to actual service quality, while the "industry viability and sustainability" criteria are direct indicators of relative supply/demand balance, since taxi plate values and assignment rates move directly with expected monopoly rents.

Despite the varying relevance, or importance, of the different criteria, they receive a relatively even weighting in the model: while there are some changes from year to year, eight criteria received the same (10%) weighting in 2011/12, while the unemployment rate received a zero weighting and state final demand a 20% rating.

35Final draft: 18 October 2011

A likely impact of adopting the multi-criteria approach appears to be to reduce the likelihood of large increases in plate numbers occurring in any given year. As an example, licence releases based solely on the values of the performance indicators in 2011/12 would have totalled 5.4% of the fleet, compared with the actual 3.6%.

However, the fundamental issue with the Sydney model is that its starting assumption is that the current number of taxi licences is in some sense optimal and that the purpose of the formula is to maintain this existing level of supply/demand balance over time. Given the clear evidence of excess demand - demonstrated by the $400,000 value of a Sydney licence - this is not a supportable position.

In sum, the Sydney formula is, as demonstrated above, potentially consistent with further declines in service quality but, when its recommendations are considered in the light of the historical record of licence releases in Sydney, it is plausible that it will result in a greater degree of maintenance of current levels of supply/demand balance than would have occurred under a continuation of the former, ad hoc approach to new licence issue.

Schaller37 model

Schaller (2005) modelled taxi demand by conducting regression analysis on six variables, using data from 118 US cities. Schaller argues for the use of three variables to determine taxi demand and, hence, required taxi numbers. These are the number of workers commuting by subway, the number of households with no private vehicles and the number of airport taxi trips.

This conclusion is based on regression analysis conducted on six variables, of which the above three are found to be closely correlated with the observed number of taxis in a range of cities studied. He reports that the results show all three variables as being statistically significant at the 95% confidence interval38. However this, apparently impressive, result is rendered substantially less credible by both a lack of transparency as to his methodology and results and circularity in his argument. He states that:

The predicted number of cabs closely matches the actual number in cities that, based on separate information, appear to have an appropriate number of cabs. (Schaller (2005 ) p 73).[emphasis added]

This statement strongly suggests that the statistically significant results relate only to a handpicked subset of the cities studied. Moreover, Schaller provides little detail on what separate information was used to determine which cities were judged as having “an appropriate number of cabs” and which were judged to have “undersupply” or “oversupply”. Arguably, the “appropriate” number of

37 Bruce Schaller is a former New York City taxi regulator and proponent of restricted entry to taxi markets. See: Schaller, B. (2005), A Regression Model of the Number of Taxicabs in US Cities. Journal of Public Transportation, Vol 8, No 5, 2005.38 Interestingly, Schaller concludes that population is not a determinant of taxi demand, once these three significant variables have been controlled for.

36Final draft: 18 October 2011

cabs may have been defined in a way that would maximize the apparent predictive power of the model. This suspicion is heightened by the fact that Schaller does not even report the number of cities in respect of which the model’s predictions do and do not accord with observed reality, instead relying on a small number of partial observations39.

In sum, there is strong doubt as to the actual predictive performance of Schaller's model, while no city is, to date, known to have adopted it as the basis for determining its licence release program.

4.5. Subjective criteria

Bekken states that:

Subjective criteria are the most common criteria for issuing new licences. In such cases, an authority assesses the need for an increase or decrease in the number of licences. Often these criteria are related to terms such as public need, excess demand, excess driver profits and other societal reasons. The real differences between objective and subjective criteria may be small. To make the decision more “objective”, different studies or investigations may be conducted. Nonetheless, the authority or the politicians will have the last word.40

As this quote suggests, the use of such criteria provides, at best, only minimal guidance to, or constraint on the discretion of, decision-makers in determining what numbers of taxi licences should be issued from time to time. Review of the Transport Act 1983 shows that it sets out a large number of such criteria as the required basis for Ministerial decision-making in relation to licence applications. The dismal performance of the Victorian legislation in this regard underlines the lack of practical utility of such subjective criteria.

4.6. Discussion

Formula-based approaches to licence issue do not constitute "transitional strategies" as such. In fact, they share the characteristic of being based on the maintenance of some form of status quo, whether specified in terms of population ratios, service standards or other criteria. There are therefore 2 concerns with this approach:

While the formula might be used to specify a desired end-point, a transitional strategy is still required if this desired end-point is a significant distance from the current position and

The formula based approach contains an implicit rejection of open entry as the appropriate regulatory position. Hence it is necessarily a 2nd best option that can only (in the best cases) approximate the benefits of that alternative.

39 These are that: The predictions are within 10% of observed numbers in “Denver, Los Angeles, San Diego, St Louis and several smaller cities or counties”; “model predictions are within 7% of the actual number of taxicabs in several jurisdictions that do not regulate the number of taxicabs..[including] Orange County (California), Phoenix, Newark and New York City (the latter three cities including open-entry livery vehicles in the vehicle count”; but “the model predicts 29 to 55%fewer cabs than are actually licensed in Dallas, Houston and Washington DC”; and “the model predicts 79 to 128% more cabs in Boston, Montgomery County (Maryland) and San Francisco”.40 Bekken (2007), op cit, p 42.

37Final draft: 18 October 2011

None of the above practical examples of the use of the formula appears to be predicated on a desire to move toward an approximation of an an open entry taxi market outcome. Rather, they are explicitly based on an objective of maintaining a certain supply/demand balance. Thus, a formula based approach to licence issue that was adopted as a transitional strategy toward achievement of an open-entry market would appear to be unique if implemented.

That said, such an option is clearly feasible. One formula based approach to achieving open entry would involve estimation of the ratio that approximates an open-entry equilibrium, with licence issues programmed so as to achieve steady progress toward achievement of this ratio after a set number of years. Such a model would not necessarily lead to the achievement of a seamless transition to open entry, since the open-entry equilibrium ratio of taxis to population may be under-estimated at the outset. Thus, further significant entry may occur at the end of the transitional phase. However, this does not pose a significant problem for the reform program unless a very substantial under-estimate occurs.

Alternatively, the formula could be based on achieving a certain price-path for taxi licences. As noted above, the Victorian government indicated in 2003 that its intention was to achieve a gradual reduction in licence values over the course of its 12 year reform program. A potential alternative program design would have seen an unlimited number of licences made available each year at a pre-determined price, with this licence price being reduced each year. Thus, given a pre-reform price of around $300,000 and a 12 year time horizon, a price of $275,000 could have been set in year 1, declining by $25,000 annually, until licences were available at administrative cost from year 12 onward. The number of licences to be issued each year would not be pre-determined, but would be dependent on the number of purchasers willing to pay the set price. This approach ensures that sufficient licences are issued to compensate for increases in taxi demand, as well as achieving a degree of progress toward the objective of rebalancing supply and demand.

5. Other reform options

Licence tenure and transferability

Transferability

A significant regulatory change made in many jurisdictions in the 1980s and 1990s, as high taxi licence values arose, was to move to make licences readily saleable. More recently, some commentators have argued that this change should be reversed as a key element in a reform program.

In general, economics recommends that assets should be freely tradable, since this ensures that they flow to their most productive use. In the taxi licence context, the argument for transferability was that, in the presence of supply restrictions, ensuring that those who can exploit licences most

38Final draft: 18 October 2011

efficiently can obtain them will improve service standards. This argument is sound within its own frame of reference, but is arguably rendered nonsensical when it is observed that the basic premise - that taxi licences are in finite supply - is indefensible.

Conversely, it is clear that transferability has contributed to the observed inflation in licence values, for two reasons. First, those who can most efficiently exploit a taxi licence (or other asset) will reap a higher return from it and, as a corollary, will bid a higher price for it. Second, the tradability of licences has meant that expectations of future increases in the capital value of the licence have become a potentially important driver of the market value of the licence. The recently observed decline in the rate of return to licence assignments (i.e. annual assignment price as a percentage of capital value of the licence) provides evidence of this dynamic: the existence of a 12 year reform program with specified rates of licence issue allowed industry participants to calculate the expected impact on relative scarcity over the period, as well as lowering the "risk premium" attaching to licences, since the likelihood of additional, unanticipated licence issues was much diminished by the existence of a long-term program.

Calls to remove licence transferability are generally accompanied by proposals that only licensed drivers should be able to hold licences. These proposals have at least two rationales. First, some believe that the removal of "passive investors" from the industry and a return to active participation by licence-owners is likely to improve service standards. Second, it is argued that such a move could facilitate further reform. Announcing a requirement that only full-time drivers can own licences would, on its own, be expected to lead to a significant one-off reduction in licence values, if the requirement were able to be enforced reliably. It is also expected to lead to a greater focus on the licence as a "tool of trade" rather than a financial asset. If combined with a delayed move to non-transferability, the value of the licence in the short term would decline further.

These two factors are seen as being likely to reduce significantly the extent of opposition to further reforms in the shape of substantial additional licence issues. However, even if these arguments are accepted, removing licence transferability can also have negative implications for reform. In particular it obscures the need for new licence issues, since the market price of the licence is the most reliable gauge of the size of the monopoly rents being earned and, hence, of the degree of relative scarcity. This means that, in the absence of a transparent gauge of relative scarcity, taxi regulators may, in fact, be less likely to expand supply over time, rather than more likely to do so.

Tenure

A significant shift in policy adopted at the time of the 2002 Victorian reforms is the move from issuing permanent, transferable licences to issuing time-limited, non-transferable licences.

It can be speculated that a part of the intention in issuing non-transferable licences was to progressively neutralize licence holders as anti-reform agents, as an increasing proportion of licence-holders became holders of licences with no exchange value. However, any such erosion of the “anti-reform lobby” would:

Only occur in the very long term; and

39Final draft: 18 October 2011

Be limited in extent, since PS licence holders still have substantial incentives to oppose the issue of larger numbers of new licences.

In the context of the 2002 reform package, full implementation would have meant that, even after 12 years, only around 35% of licences would be non-transferable and time limited. If this approach were maintained, the transferable licences would continue to become progressively scarcer (and more valuable, for a given taxi/population ratio) over time. However, the owners of permanent licences would continue to be a powerful lobby for a very long period.

In sum, the issue of whether licences should be perpetual and transferable or time-limited and non-transferable is only relevant in a context in which moving to a free-entry regulatory system has been rejected as a short or medium term policy option. It is therefore a strategy that has to be assessed on second best grounds. Such an assessment reveals that the use of non-transferable licences is as likely to inhibit moves to increase licence numbers in the medium to long term as to favour them.

40Final draft: 18 October 2011

6. Easing entry to the hire car industry

The NCC noted in 2002 that one possible strategy for addressing the undersupply of taxis is to act to favour the expansion of the hire car industry. The distinction between a taxi and a hire car is exclusively the product of regulatory arrangements: the main additional restriction applicable to hire cars, vis-a-vis taxis, is that they are unable to operate in the rank and hail market41. However, in practical terms, hire cars and taxis provide the same service within the pre-booked market, which accounts for approximately 60 per cent of demand in the Melbourne market (Firecone Ventures 2008). Moreover, increasing the supply of hire cars would be expected to lead to some diversion of taxis away from the pre-booked market and toward serving the rank and hail market. By this mechanism, supply in all of these markets could be expected to increase.

A "two track" model, in which there are large numbers of both taxis and hire cars, can be observed in a number of major cities worldwide. Two obvious examples are New York City and London. In both cases, the "hire car" market (called car services in the former and mini-cabs in the latter city) represent a very large proportion of total "taxi" supply. In both cases, this situation has developed in the context of strong entry restrictions to the taxi market proper - albeit that these restrictions are quantitative in the case of New York City, where no new taxi medallion has been issued since 1937, and qualitative in the case of London42.

Licence fee reductions

Melbourne is clearly another city in which strong quantitative controls have existed in the taxi market over a long period, yet the relative size of the hire car sector is substantially smaller than in these two cities: the current number of hire car licences in Victoria as a whole is around 900, compared with over 5,000 taxi licences43. One possible explanation for this difference is that hire car licences have, since 2004, been sold by the government for a fee initially set at $66,000 and subsequently reduced to $60,50044. To the extent that this fee is seen as an impediment to entry to the industry, reductions might be expected to assist in securing greater competition for the taxi industry from the hire car sector.

However, the historical record does not suggest that reductions in the fee would be likely to have a substantial impact. In practice, the hire car fee has fallen significantly since 2004, both in absolute and relative terms, yet entry to the industry has been limited.

Table 2: Changes in Melbourne taxi and hire car values - 2004 to 2011

41 Higher vehicle standards constitute a further additional restriction on hire car operations, although this appears to be of lesser significance to their competitive position in the market.42 Completion of "The Knowledge" typically requires 2 - 4 years' study and requires several, successive examinations to be passed. This represents a significant regulatory barrier to entry. See: http://www.tfl.gov.uk/businessandpartners/taxisandprivatehire/1412.aspx43 Taxi Industry Inquiry (2011). Setting the Scene. P 19.44 Prior to 2004, the licences were available at a nominal cost, subject to satisfaction of a "public interest" test, similar to that historically adopted in relation to taxi licence applications.

41Final draft: 18 October 2011

Taxi licence Hire car licence Hire car licence as % of taxi licence2004 $340,000 $66,000 19.4%2011 $510,000 $60,500 11.8%Change +$170,000 (50%) -$5,500 (-8.3%) -40%

The current fee of $60,500 is currently 8.3% lower in nominal terms than in 2004, while the real value of a hire car licence is currently approximately 25% below its level of 7 years ago45. Moreover, while the value of the hire car licence has fallen, the taxi licence value has grown by around 50% since 200446. Thus, the value of a hire car licence has fallen from 19.4% of the value of a taxi licence in 2004 to around 11.8% of the value of a taxi licence currently. Hire car licences are thus 40% lower, relative to the value of a taxi licence, than seven years ago. Moreover, in recent times, hire car licences have been available at a fee of $40,000 to operators willing to operate hybrid vehicles, implying an even greater decline in licence costs47.

Despite these reductions in both absolute and relative licence fees, the rate of growth in the sector has been relatively low: the current total of approximately 900 hire cars compares with a 2004 total of 53848, indicating that entry has totalled around 360 in seven years, or around 7.6% per annum on average.

These observations suggest there must be some doubt as to the likely effectiveness of a strategy of reducing the hire car licence fee as a means of encouraging greater competition for the taxi industry from this sector.

Removal of other regulatory restrictions

The question of why the hire car sector has been less successful in expanding to compete with the taxi sector than in other cities, such as London and New York City, that are also characterised by severe supply limits in the taxi market, was considered in the ESC's 2004 review of the hire car licence fee. The ESC noted that hire cars had historically focused on the provision of a premium service at higher prices than taxis, particularly to the business and tourism sectors. This was attributed in part to regulatory factors including higher vehicle standards and limits on the minimum period of hire.

However, the ESC noted that a number of these restrictions (including the minimum hire time) had been removed or made less stringent over time. Moreover, the ESC noted evidence that country hire cars in particular had increasingly moved to embrace a price-sensitive "mainstream" market, rather than simply serving a premium market, stating that they:

45 CPI all groups Melboune - June 2011/June 2004 = 175.6/143.9. The current value of the hire car licence is therefore equal to around $49,580 in 2004 dollars, or 25% below its then level of $66,000.46 See ESC (2004) Review of Hire Car Licence Fees: Final Report, p 17. The metropolitan hire car licence fee fell from $66,000 to $60,500 in response to the ESC Report. See also: ESC (2005), p 23 (2004 value of a taxi licence). 47 Moreover, the price of a hybrid vehicle would, in many cases, be lower than that of "traditional" hire cars, as would its operating costs, suggesting further reductions in overall business costs.48 ESC (2004), p 17.

42Final draft: 18 October 2011

"...currently undertake substantial contract based work for the Department of Veterans Affairs (‘DVA’) at prices that are significantly below regulated taxi fares. ...This experience in country areas appears to indicate both that hire cars are economically able to compete directly with taxis and that some elements of the industry are moving toward serving this wider ‘non-premium’ market. This suggests the possibility of a significant further expansion in the market for hire car services over time."49

Thus, the ESC was confident that a reduction in hire car licence fees would lead the industry to provide significantly greater competition to the taxi industry over time. However, the above data indicates that this hope has yet to be realised. While regulatory restrictions on the sector are less substantial than was previously the case, action to further reduce these restrictions might, a priori, be expected to significant in encouraging greater service expansion. The key potential reforms in this regard to be:

Restrictions on vehicle type and age

There is no clear policy reason for hire car vehicle requirements to differ from those applicable to taxis. Removal of the requirement to operate a "premium" vehicle would be expected to have some impact in reducing operating costs. That said, the size of the cost impact would be likely to be relatively modest.

Prohibition on use of taxi ranks

The major regulatory difference between taxis and hire cars is that the latter are prohibited from operating in both the rank and hail markets. While data are scarce, the ESC (2005) reported estimates that these two markets could account for around 50% of the total taxi market. Consideration could be given to allowing hire cars to use taxi ranks, thus opening a significant additional proportion of the taxi industry to competition.

Conclusions

The historical data indicates that a gradual reduction in the real value of hire car licences over a seven year period has been associated with only modest rates of entry, despite the fact that taxi licence values have grown strongly over the same period. This inevitably raises some question as to the effectiveness of licence price reductions as a strategy for enhancing competition for the taxi industry from the hire car sector. Nonetheless, given that licences currently cost over $60,000, it could be expected that a move to issue licences at administrative cost would potentially yield a substantial supply response.

This could be increased further by relaxing other regulatory restrictions on the operation of hire cars, thus enhancing further their potential profitability. A removal of the prohibition on the use of taxi ranks by hire cars would be likely to be the most significant initiative in this regard, though moving to a "level playing field" in terms of vehicle requirements would also have a potential impact.

49 ESC (2004), p 23.

43Final draft: 18 October 2011

Moreover, were a sufficiently strong supply response to be forthcoming, it could be expected that network effects would operate (i.e. hire cars would form larger networks, thus improving their potential response times and making them more competitive in the market for immediate dispatch by phone). This would further enhance their competitive position and bring forth further entry.

Of course, while the value of the hire car licence is considerably smaller than that of the taxi licence, it remains significant. This means that incumbent hire car licence-holders could be expected to lobby strongly against any reduction in its nominal value. A basic problem with using this strategy to improve taxi supply is that there is no policy or equity basis for acting primarily against the interests of incumbent hire car licence-holders rather than taxi licence-holders.

Regardless of this issue, there must be doubt as to the size of the likely supply response to a fall in hire car licence fees and, more specifically, the impact of an increase in supply on competition with the taxi industry. Previous reports50 suggest that, while there is some competition between the two sectors in the business traveller market, much of the activity in the hire car market remains focused on tourism and special events, as has traditionally been the case, rather than on competition with the taxi industry. However, the absence of sound data on industry operators - itself partly a reflection of the atomised nature of the industry - means that this conclusion must be somewhat tentative.

The current relative prices of taxi and hire car licences must be considered in this context: The hire car licence value of $60,500 is little more than one tenth of the size of the taxi licence value, despite the fact that hire cars are able to compete in the 50 - 60% of the taxi market that is accounted for by phone-booked services. Moreover, the proliferation of secondary networks and the improvements in communications technologies in recent years would appear to provide opportunities for businesses to combine both taxis and hire cars in order to meet consumer demand.

Given the above, it appears unlikely that the hire car licence price is itself a major impediment to this sector providing stronger competition to the taxi industry. Nor are there clearly identifiable regulatory impediments: while vehicle standards are higher in the hire car industry, and might reasonably be relaxed, the contribution of these requirements to overall cost structures, and hence to price competitiveness, seems likely to be relatively small.

A strategy of improving the ability of the hire car sector to compete with the taxi industry would need to embrace both a reduction in the licence fee and, perhaps more importantly, a consideration of the nature and extent of current regulatory impediments to such competition. However, a degree of pessimism regarding the potential effectiveness of this course seems justified, based on the apparent failure of this sector to take advantage of the opportunities for greater competition with the taxi sector that have arisen to date.

50 See ESC (2004), NCC (2002).

44Final draft: 18 October 2011

7. Conclusion

A wide range of transitional strategies have been proposed as means of rendering politically and economically more palatable the move from a taxi market that is highly distorted by regulated entry restrictions to an open entry market - or at least one that has a less distorted supply/demand balance. Relatively few of these strategies have been adopted in practice.

This means that the relative merits of these strategies must, to a large extent, be assessed on theoretical grounds. More importantly, however, it means that there is no known example of a taxi market characterised by severe entry restrictions, like Melbourne's, successfully moving to an open entry outcome via gradualist change. While at least six OECD countries have made the move to open entry taxi markets in the last two decades approximately, and several additional countries have open entry conditions in at least some cities, these changes were, in all cases, achieved through immediate reforms and, in all but one case (that of the Northern Territory) without the payment of compensation.

Particularly given the relatively small number of observations involved, this cannot be taken to imply that gradualist reform is impossible. However, the absence of even one successful instance of gradualist reform necessarily casts a major question-mark over the practical feasibility of all of these models. Moreover, the absence of any case in which compensation has been paid (save NT) and the clear jurisprudence indicating that there is no legal requirement for governments to pay such compensation suggest that the inclusion of such elements in a reform strategy is unlikely to enhance feasibility.

45Final draft: 18 October 2011

Appendix 1: Jurisprudence in relation to compensation

While the legal position in different jurisdictions will not be identical, available precedent in this area strongly suggests that no legal obligation to pay compensation would be found to exist. The most extensive jurisprudence on this issue arises from the Irish reforms. Legal challenges to the Irish reforms by licence owners were unsuccessful and ended in clear judicial statements to the effect that there was no legal obligation on governments to pay compensation. Barrett (2003) notes that:

In Irish law there are three judgements that taxi licences do not confer property rights and that the terms under which they are held may therefore be altered without compensation.

The first of these is the decision in Hempenstall v Minister for the Environment (1994) which states:

‘property rights arising in licences created by law … are subject to the conditions created by law and an implied condition that the law may change those conditions. Changes brought about by law may enhance the value of those property rights …, or they may diminish them… But an amendment of the law which by changing the conditions under which a licence is held, reduces the commercial value of the licence cannot be regarded as an attack on the property right in the licence – it is the consequence of the implied condition which is an inherent part of the property right in the licence.’ (cited in Barrett (2003), pp 35-6)

That is, the nature of the “property right” conferred by a regulatory licence is that it is inherently conditional on any future changes to the law that may alter its nature or value. Consequently, such changes do not amount to an abrogation of a property right of the kind that would give rise to a legal right to compensation. This position was subsequently confirmed in two further cases51.

A more recent case from the United States reached the same conclusion, while subtly differing in terms of the reasons advanced. Following the removal of entry restrictions in the city of Minneapolis, judgement was made in August 2007 in the case of Minneapolis Taxi Owners Coalition vs City of Minneapolis52. The plaintiffs’ argument for compensation for the loss of value of their taxi licences was again dismissed. However, in contrast to the Irish cases noted above, the court distinguished between a property right and an “economic interest” and concluded that

“…the license holders do not have a property interest in the value of the taxicab vehicle license on the secondary market because the issuance of the license does not entitle them to that value, nor does it provide for its legal protection. The license allows its holders to drive a taxi in the City. It does not guarantee that the City would indefinitely limit the number of taxi licenses issued. Even under the former ordinance, the City was required to conduct a hearing at least every 24 months to determine whether “public convenience and necessity” warranted additional licenses. (Compl. Ex. E at fmr. sec. 341.270(a)). Furthermore, the City, as a law-making entity, is free to amend ordinances as it sees fit. Like the trucking authority holders in the Rogers Truck Line case, the taxicab vehicle license holders do not have a constitutionally protected freedom from competition.”

51 Humphry and others vs Minister for the Environment (2000) and Gorman, Kearns, and National Taxi Drivers Union v the Minister of State and the Attorney General (2001), a judicial review of the decision in Humphry. See www.bailii.org 52 United States District Court of Minnesota, Civil No. 07-1789 (JMR/FLN).

46Final draft: 18 October 2011

Thus, while the legal context in which compensation decisions are made varies, there appears to be strong case law, derived from several industries and applied to the taxi industry case, establishing that compensation is not payable in respect of losses arising from legislative changes which affect licences or other “property rights” which are established solely via government regulation in the first instance.

47Final draft: 18 October 2011

Appendix 2: Summary of reform strategies pursued in major jurisdictions

Overview

At least six OECD countries have removed quantitative entry restrictions from their taxi regulatory structures since the late 1980s, while open entry has also been implemented on a city by city basis in some countries. In each case, the removal of entry restrictions has occurred via a single reform initiative, rather than through a process of staged reform. In no case was compensation paid to incumbent licence holders. In cases in which licences were tradable prior to the reforms, valuations were generally modest. The exception is that of Ireland, where pre-reform values in the late 1990s reached £90,000 in Dublin (A$300,000 in current dollar terms).

The following provides information on the reform process followed in relation to five of the six countries that now have open entry taxi markets nationally. Data for the Czech republic was not found.

Ireland

The path to reform in Ireland began with a 1992 Interdepartmental Committee report, which recommended gradual liberalisation of the industry. This met with a major industry response, including a blockade of the hometown of the responsible Minister. Dublin City Council approved a recommendation from its taxi and hire car committee to release 200 new licences in 1995, but rescinded this recommendation following further lobbying and a blockade. A similar recommendation from the committee in 1997 also brought forth a blockade.

In 1999, the government proposed to issue 3,100 new licences in Dublin, approximately doubling the existing number of taxis. It was proposed that 2,600 of these licences would be issued to existing licence-holders, with 500 being more widely available. The proposed reservation of most of the new licences to incumbents was strongly opposed by private hackney (i.e. hire car) drivers, who sought access to the industry. A small group challenged the Minister's proposals in the High Court. The challenge argued that the legislative discretion conferred on the Minister in relation to licence issue did not allow him a general right to restrict taxi numbers53. This action was successful, with the Court finding that the Minister had acted ultra vires in restricting licence numbers for reasons unrelated to ensuring that licence-holders could meet required quality standards. In Humphrey v Minister for Environment and Local Government (2000), the court stated:

… the Minister, in restricting the numbers for reasons unrelated to qualitative standards of the vehicles and of drivers has fettered the exercise of the discretion conferred upon him by Section 82 of the 1961 Act. A quantitative restriction not alone affects the rights of citizens to

53 Barry, F. (2009). Politics and Economic Policy-Making in Ireland. Trinity College Dublin. See: http://www.tcd.ie/business/staff/fbarry/papers/Politics%20and%20Economic%20Policymaking%20in%20Ireland%20REVISED%20_3_.pdf

48Final draft: 18 October 2011

work in an industry for which they may be qualified but it also manifestly affects the right of the public to the services of taxis and, indeed, restricts the development of the taxi industry itself.

Regulations which restrict the number of public hire vehicles contradict the very concept of public service. It is, of course, open to the relevant authority to insist on quality as the base or threshold requirement in relation to a vehicle license as well as a drivers license. The 1961 Act does not contemplate the restriction of numbers in order to enforce standards. Moreover, there would appear not to be any criteria in the Act, nor in the regulations, by which a determination should be made on the number of new licenses to be granted.

Given this outcome, the government determined to immediately open entry to the industry. It also determined not to pay compensation to incumbent licence-holders. This decision was subject to court challenge by the incumbent licence-holders, which failed. Barrett (2003)54 comments:

In Irish law there are three judgements that taxi licences do not confer property rights and that the terms under which they are held may therefore be altered without compensation.

The third decision to whcih Barrett refers was an unsuccessful judicial review of the Humphry decision cited above.

Following the failure of the legal action seeking compensation, further lobbying by former incumbent licence-holders led to the government adopting a policy of making ex gratia payments on a hardship basis. A Taxi Hardship Panel recommended payments totalling €12.6 million (£9.9 million). In the event, payments totalling €16,349,000 in hardship payments had been made by 2005, representing less than 5% of the total cost of paying full compensation. Payments were made to 1,412 persons. There were around 3,900 licences on issue prior to reform, although the actual number of licence-holders is unknown. Individual payments ranged between €3,000 and €15,000 .

An additional feature of the Irish reform process is notable: The Oscar Faber Report prepared for the Irish government in 1998 argued that a fleet of 5900 taxis would be needed after 10 years in order to service the Dublin market. In the event, two years after deregulation, 9000 taxis were operating in Dublin (Barrett (2003)) and 10,865 in June 201155. This points to an apparent tendency for formula based estimates of equilibrium taxi numbers of err strongly on the side of underestimation of the true open market equilibrium number of taxis, perhaps in part because of a failure to take into account the positive impact on demand of improved taxi service.

Ireland has maintained its open-entry arrangements, in combination with maximum fare regulation. Further regulatory reforms were implemented after the initial reforms, mainly aiming at strengthening quality regulation. These include the adoption of the Taxi Regulation Act 2003, the

54 These decisions are Hempenstall v Minister for the Environment (1992), Humphry and others vs Minister for the Environment (2000) and Gorman, Kearns, and National Taxi Drivers Union v the Minister of State and the Attorney General (2001), a judicial review of the decision in Humphry. See www.bailii.org. See also: Barrett, S.D., (2003). Regulatory Capture, Property Rights and Taxi Deregulation: A Case Study. Economic Affairs, December 2003, pp 35-40.

55 http://taxiregulation.nationaltransport.ie/for-everyone/statistics/vehicle-licences-county-and-category-2010/

49Final draft: 18 October 2011

establishment of a Commission for Taxi Regulation in 2004 and a national fare structure in 2006. A 2009 review commissioned for the regulatory agency56 found that trip numbers had risen 82 per cent from 1997 - 2008 and that the annual value of reduced consumer waiting time was around €780 million. These consumer benefits were found not to have come at the expense of quality standards, which were rated as being good. Driver incomes were found to have declined slightly (by about 5%) since 2005 and drivers were found to be earning well below the current average industrial wage57. No longer-term driver income comparisons were available. A major shift in relative market share toward taxis and away from hackneys (hire cars) since the opening of entry was observed and it was concluded that the previous regulations had led to a major imbalance, or market distortion. Continued problems in ensuring adequate services for people with disabilities were noted, and it was concluded that there was "no one policy solution" to this problem. The current approaches of providing financial support for purchase of WATs and requiring minimum service standards were found to be appropriate.

The current 2010-2014 regulatory strategy document58 states that the existing regulatory model is consistent with OECD and World Bank best practices and is expected to continue.

New Zealand

The opening of entry to the New Zealand taxi industry was originally intended to occur in concert with the wide ranging reform of land transport regulation conducted in 1983. However, successful lobbying by the industry resulted in the removal of the taxi-related provisions from the 1983 legislation. The legislation created a separate service category called a Passenger Service Vehicle, with few restrictions on the grant of a PSV licence. In 1986 an application for a PSV licence was received by an intending "limousine service" operator. According to Gaunt (1996)59:

"The application was granted. The MOT strongly opposed the granting of the licence to Mr Tarr, claiming that a taxi service was being provided. The MOT appealed as far as the High Court, where it was ruled that the granting of the licence was legal".

The government of the day nonetheless continued to express dissatisfaction with the performance of the taxi industry and sought change "from within the Industry". However, a new Minister instituted a formal review of the industry, leading to proposals for reform being published in 1988 and eventually legislated in 1989.

The new legislation removed both limits on licence numbers and maximum fare regulation, although it did require that maximum fares be notified to the Minister by service providers. The number of

56 Goodbody Economic Consultants (2009). Economic Review of the Small Public Service Vehicle Industry. Commission for Taxi Regulation, Dublin. See: http://www.taxi-library.org/ireland-taxi-economic-review_2009.pdf57 The latter finding is unsurprising, given the essentially unskilled nature of the occupation.58 http://www.nationaltransport.ie/downloads/taxi-reg/strategy-english.pdf59 Gaunt, C. (1996). Taxicab Deregulation in New Zealand. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, Vol 30, No. 1, pp 103-6.

50Final draft: 18 October 2011

taxis operating in major cities increased by almost 200% following deregulation in 198960. According to Morrison (1997):

The 1989 legislation, which removed the quantitative controls (deregulation), has been followed by a tripling of the number of companies in the metropolitan centres and a massive increase in the number of taxi cabs. A much wider range of taxi services now exploit different market segments and offer a wider geographic coverage. These changes have been accompanied by a decline in fares in real, if not nominal, terms.

Soon61 cites examples of service innovation in post-deregulation New Zealand including the introduction of taxi vans and executive cabs, new taxi charge credit systems, more advertising on cabs and tendering for public bus routes by some cab companies.

The immediate removal of quantitative restrictions on licence numbers was achieved in New Zealand without payment of compensation to incumbents, although Soon notes that the context was one of major reform being undertaken throughout the economy over a relatively short period of time. Johnston62 also notes that pre-reform taxi licence values were substantially lower than those current in Australian capitals at present, citing a 1989 figure of around NZ$20,000 (or around NZ$34,000 in current dollar terms).

Open entry conditions have also been maintained to date. In common with the Irish experience, fleet numbers appear to have broadly been maintained at levels near their post-deregulation highs. For example, recent reports state that there are 1,237 taxis in Wellington, or slightly more than 200% more than the 400 comprising the pre-deregulation fleet. Notably, calls for the reintroduction of limits on numbers continue to be heard, over 20 years after deregulation63.

Sweden

The Swedish taxi industry was deregulated by the Transport Policy Act of 1989. Prior to this time there was only one taxi company in each city and municipal councils determined the number of taxi licences that would be issued with reference to their estimates of consumer demand.

The 1989 legislation deregulated both entry and fares. However, operators were required to inform customers about fares prior to trips and cabs were required to be equipped with meters that provided receipts. The taxi association also recommended that fares should be displayed on the exterior of the cab. Previous requirements that cabs be affiliated with radio despatch networks were removed, while government established its own despatch networks to provide competition to the incumbents.

60 According to NCC (2002, p 5-3), the number of taxis operating increased from 2,567 in 1989 to 6,907 in 1998. See: National Competition Council (2002). Assessment Of Governments' Progress In Implementing The National Competition Policy And Related Reforms. NCC, Melbourne (Australia). Available at www.ncc.gov.au61 Soon, J. (1999) Taxi!!: Reinvigorating Competition in the Taxi Market. Issue Analysis, No 7, May 1999, Centre for Independent Studies. 62 Johnston, A. (2000) Taxi Industry Reform: Should There Be Compensation? Agenda, Vol 7, No 2, pp 171-183.63 http://www.stuff.co.nz/dominion-post/news/4598707/Too-many-taxis-Mayor-wants-cap

51Final draft: 18 October 2011

Quality controls were reinforced, with assessments made of competence, economic capacity and character. Compulsory pre-entry training requirements were introduced as, in 1994, were geographical knowledge tests64.

Taxi numbers had experienced little increase in the years immediately prior to deregulation. The result was a rapid increase in numbers immediately following deregulation, with the size of the taxi fleet quickly stabilising at the new higher level. Total taxi numbers in 1995/6 were reported to be 25 per cent higher than in 1989, while waiting times became significantly shorter65.

Fares rose in real terms following deregulation, although significant regional variation was observed. A concern was the ability of monopoly providers to raise prices in some smaller population centres. Several years after deregulation, increasing innovation in pricing structures was observed. In larger towns, central booking offices supplemented the standard tariff with fixed prices for some routes, maximum prices within zones and discounts for certain categories of customers (e.g. women travelling alone). However, some argued that a simpler tariff structure was needed in order to enhance consumers' ability to estimate fares before trips as well as comparing different fare offers66. It is notable that driver authorisations were not initially part of the regulatory system and were only introduced in 1995. The impetus for this step seems to have evolved largely from concerns regarding tax evasion, although drivers with criminal records for violent offences were excluded from the industry.

Singapore

Taxi fares in Singapore were deregulated in 1998, while entry was opened in 2003. According to Chow & Leng67, the result has been a high level of innovation and diversification. They note, in addition, that rigorous regulation of service quality and standards has been retained and that there is a high level of surveillance of the industry to ensure compliance with these quality standards.Regulatory requirements include a provision that operators must notify the regulator of changes in fares a week before they are implemented.

The opening of entry appears to have yielded a substantial supply response: The taxi fleet grew in size from 16,857 in 1996 to 24,446 taxis in 2007, while there are now eight taxi operating companies. Despite this, there is recent evidence that the largest taxi operator has retained a dominant market position and has been able to act as a "price leader" in practice. Thus, concerns regarding the consumer impact of fare deregulation persist, several years after entry to the market was opened68.

64 Kang, CH., (1998). Taxi Deregulation: International Comparison. Institute of Transport Studies, University of Leeds. Available at: http://www.taxi-library.org/kang0898.htm 65 Ljusberg, JE (1998). Deregulation of the Taxi Market: The Swedish Experience. In Improving the Quality of Legislation in Europe (TMC Asser Institut 1998, The Hague). Pp 145-150.66 Ljusberg (1998), op. cit., p 148.67 Chow, K. & Leng, LP (2008). The Evolution of the Taxi Industry in Singapore. Public Transport International, Vol 57, No 2

52Final draft: 18 October 2011

In most cases, taxi drivers rent cabs for a fixed bailment fee, with these agreements being medium-term in nature.

Netherlands

The regulation of the Dutch taxi industry was substantially reformed in 2000, although some changes were subject to staged implementation. According to Bakker (2007)69:

Considering previous negative experiences in other deregulating countries, the Dutch Government chose an implementation strategy consisting of deregulating as well as re-regulating elements. The philosophy was, firstly, to safeguard basic service quality and fair competition, and secondly, to abolish capacity and fare rules.

The Government initially replaced regionally based fare price regulation with a single national maximum fare structure. It abandoned a regionally based licensing system, from 2002 replacing it with a system that allowed any licensed taxi to operate anywhere within the country. Licensing is based on operators, rather than individual vehicles and, since 2002, there has been no restriction on the number of vehicles an operator can employ.

It was initially intended to deregulate fares, but this proposal was abandoned following early experiences of significant fare increases. In the event, the system of nation-wide maximum fares has been maintained.

Taxi numbers increased substantially in all areas of the country following deregulation. However, the pattern of entry differed between markets: Where the rank and hail market dominated (i.e. in major cities) new entrants tended to be small owner drivers. Conversely, where the pre-booked market dominates, entry levels have largely been the result of expansions in the operations of incumbent operators.

Taxi availability increased in most areas, notably at peak times. One dynamic operating has been that operators from rural areas that faced low demand at nights and weekends were, due to the abolition of the regional licensing system, now able to move to service urban centres at these times.

However, the improved supply of taxis has not brought forth the expected increases in patronage. It has been speculated that this may be due to consumer price sensitivity and the failure of the regulator to reduce fares70.

68 Nugroho, A. (2011). Is Taxi Industry Should not Remained as Deregulated Market in Singapore?( sic). See: http://kumpulankaryasiswa.wordpress.com/2011/04/15/is-taxi-industry-should-not-remained-as-deregulated-market-in-singapore/ 69 Bakker, P (2007). Deregulation of the Taxi Industry: Experiences in the Netherlands. In OECD/ECMT (2007), p 65.70 Bekken (2007), op cit, p 51.

53Final draft: 18 October 2011

Appendix 3: Bibliography

Abelson, P (2010). Governance and Economics of the Taxi Industry with Special Reference to Sydney. University of Sydney. Seminar Paper presented to the Economic Society of New South Wales, 14 July 2010.

Barrett, S.D., (2003). Regulatory Capture, Property Rights and Taxi Deregulation: A Case Study. Economic Affairs, December 2003, pp 35-40.

Barry, F. (2009). Politics and Economic Policy-Making in Ireland. Trinity College Dublin. See: http://www.tcd.ie/business/staff/fbarry/papers/Politics%20and%20Economic%20Policymaking%20in%20Ireland%20REVISED%20_3_.pdf

Chow, K. & Leng, LP (2008). The Evolution of the Taxi Industry in Singapore. Public Transport International, Vol 57, No 2

Deighton-Smith, R. (2000). Taxi Reform in Australia. National Competition Council Staff Discussion Paper. NCC, Melbourne, October 2000. www.ncc.gov.au

Department of Treasury and Finance (2003). National Competition Policy: Report for the 2003 Assessment on Victoria’s Implementation of National Competition Policy. Available at www.ncc.gov.au

See ESC (2004) Review of Hire Car Licence Fees: Final Report. Essential Services Commission (Government of Victoria), Melbourne (Australia), June 2005.

Essential Services Commission (2005) Taxi Fare Review: Final Report. Essential Services Commission (Government of Victoria), Melbourne (Australia), June 2005.

Gaunt, C. (1996). Taxicab Deregulation in New Zealand. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, Vol 30, No. 1, pp 103-6.

Gaunt, C. & Black, T. (1994). The Unanticipated Effects of the Industry Commission's Recommendations on the Regulation of the Taxicab Industry. Economic Analysis and Policy, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp 151-162.

Goodbody Economic Consultants (2001). Review of the Taxi and Hackney Market 2001 (Demand and Supply). Goodbody Economic Consultants, Dublin, January 2001.

Humphrey v. Minister for Environment and Local Government [2000] IEHC 149; [2001] 1 ILRM 241 (13th October, 2000) http://www.bailii.org/ie/cases/IEHC/2000/149.html

Johnston, A. (2000) Taxi Industry Reform: Should There Be Compensation? Agenda, Vol 7, No 2, pp 171-183.

Kang, CH., (1998). Taxi Deregulation: International Comparison. Institute of Transport Studies, University of Leeds. Available at: http://www.taxi-library.org/kang0898.htm

54Final draft: 18 October 2011

Ljusberg, JE (1998). Deregulation of the Taxi Market: The Swedish Experience. In Improving the Quality of Legislation in Europe (TMC Asser Institut 1998, The Hague). Pp 145-150.

Nugroho, A. (2011). Is Taxi Industry Should not Remained as Deregulated Market in Singapore?( sic). See: http://kumpulankaryasiswa.wordpress.com/2011/04/15/is-taxi-industry-should-not-remained-as-deregulated-market-in-singapore/

OECD/ECMT (2007) (De) Regulation of the Taxi Industry. Round Table No 133. Transport Research Centre. OECD, Paris, 2007.

Schaller, B. (2005), A Regression Model of the Number of Taxicabs in US Cities. Journal of Public Transportation, Vol 8, No 5, 2005.

Soon, J. (1999) Taxi!!: Reinvigorating Competition in the Taxi Market. Issue Analysis, No 7, May 1999, Centre for Independent Studies.

Taxi Industry Inquiry (2011). Setting the Scene

Trudel, M (1995). The Fundamentals of Taxi Regulation and the Quebec Experience. Paper presented to the 7th Congress of the European Taxi Confederation, Donostia - San Sebastian, Spain, February 1995

United States District Court of Minnesota, Civil No. 07-1789 (JMR/FLN).

Other readings

Ho, LS. (1993). An Optimal Regulatory Framework for the Taxicab Industry. Department of Economics, Chinese University of Hong Kong. http://www.ln.edu.hk/econ/staff/taxi.pdf

Moore, AT., and Balaker, T. (2006) Do Economists Reach a Conclusion on Taxi Deregulation? Economic Journal Watch, Vol 3, No. 1, January 2006, pp 109-132.http://www.econjournalwatch.org/pdf/MooreBalakerDoEconomistsJanuary2006.pdf

Morrison, PS. (1997), Restructuring Effects of Deregulation: The Case of the New Zealand Taxi Industry. Environment and Planning A, Vol 29, No.5, pp 913-928.

OECD (2007). Taxi Services: Competition and Regulation. OECD Policy Roundtables. [Book based on papers presented to the October 2007 roundtable of the OECD Competition Committee on improving competition in taxi services. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/49/27/41472612.pdf

55Final draft: 18 October 2011