Migration between Ghana’s Rural and Urban Areas

download Migration between Ghana’s Rural and Urban Areas

of 42

Transcript of Migration between Ghana’s Rural and Urban Areas

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    1/42

    Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas:

    The Impact on Migrants Welfare

    Louis Boakye-Yiadom*

    Andrew McKay**

    September 2006

    *

    Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]. PhD student, Department of Economics andInternational Development, University of Bath, UK.**

    Professor, Department of Economics and International Development, University of Bath, UK.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    2/42

    2

    Abstract

    This paper examines the impact on migrants welfare of migration between rural

    and urban sectors, using data from Ghana. Employing a consumption measure of

    welfare and a model that corrects for selectivity bias, the analysis also captures factors

    influencing migration decisions. Our findings highlight the importance of anticipated

    welfare gains and personal attributes in migration decisions. We also find support for

    the positive selectivity of urban-to-rural migrants. In addition, estimates of migration

    gains suggest that although some migrants incur welfare losses, migration increases

    on average the welfare of migrants, but would reduce the mean welfare of non-

    migrants if they were to migrate. Finally, the average welfare increment derived by

    rural-to-urban migrants is proportionately much higher than what accrues to their

    urban-to-rural counterparts.

    JEL Classification:O15; O18; I31; R23

    Keywords:Migration; rural-to-urban; urban-to-rural; welfare; selectivity bias

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    3/42

    3

    1. Introduction

    Over the years, the relevance of migration, the rationale for migrating, and the policy

    response to migration patterns and magnitudes have dominated academic and policy

    discussions. Ever since the seminal work of Ravenstein (1885), numerous studies

    have explored various aspects of this pervasive phenomenon. The diversity of

    disciplinary perspectives e.g., demography, economics, and geography of the

    studies attests to migrations intriguing and complex nature. Many studies address

    issues relating to the rationale for migrating (see Sjaastad, 1962; Todaro, 1969; and

    Lucas and Stark, 1985), migration patterns (see Ravenstein, 1885; and Lee, 1966), or

    the determinants of migration (for example, Caldwell, 1968; and Hay, 1980). Others,

    however, examine the welfare impacts of these population movements (for example,

    Falaris, 1987; and Litchfield and Waddington, 2003). Migration studies can,

    nevertheless, be broadly categorised into two, namely, those focusing on internal

    migration, and the set of studies examining migration across national borders, with the

    latter body of studies somewhat dominating in volume.

    Clearly, international migration has immense significance for many countries. For

    typical developing countries especially those in sub-Saharan Africa however,

    internal migration is of equal, if not, greater importance. Given that the rural-urban

    categorization is the major spatial grouping in sub-Saharan African countries, and that

    urbanisation in these countries is on the rise, it is hardly surprising that rural-to-urban

    migration has dominated the countries internal migration research. The present study

    augments the developing countries migration literature by examining for Ghana

    both rural-to-urban and urban-to-rural migration.

    The main purpose of this paper is to determine the impact of Ghanas inter-sectoral

    migration1on migrants welfare. In pursuit of this, we also explore migration patterns

    and factors that influence migration decisions. Within the context of migration

    between rural and urban areas, our main research questions are as follows:

    1We use inter-sectoral migration to refer to migration between rural and urban sectors.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    4/42

    4

    i) What are the major influences on migration decisions?ii) What is the impact of migration on migrants welfare?

    The studys analysis consists of the use of both descriptive statistics and econometric

    modelling. In the next section, we discuss some salient issues emerging from the

    literature. The third section consists of comments relating to data, and a list of

    relevant definitions. Migration patterns and a profile of migrants are presented in

    section four. The empirical modelling of migrations impact on migrants welfare is

    the focus of the fifth section, whilst section six discusses the results of the empirical

    analysis. We summarise and conclude in the seventh section.

    2. Relevant insights from the migration literature

    General literature

    A major challenge in the estimation of migrants income gains is the determination of

    what they would have earned if they had not migrated. Even though several methods

    for estimating migrants income gains have been identified in the literature (see

    Lucas, 1997), two approaches seem to dominate. These methods are the application of

    migration dummies in earnings (or income) functions, and the estimation of separate

    income equations for migrants and non-migrants.

    The application of migration dummies (in income functions) has been employed by

    Yap (1976) in a study of rural-to-urban migration and urban underemployment in

    Brazil. Using census data, Yap estimated income functions to compare the incomes of

    migrants with those of non-migrants residing in migrants areas of origin; this was

    done for three rural areas (origins of migration) corresponding to the three major

    regions in Brazil. For each rural area, the income gain to migrants (from that area)

    was estimated by pooling observations on rural non-migrants, rural-to-rural migrants,

    and rural-to-urban migrants. The regressors for Yaps income functions included

    education level, age group, sex, race, and migration status, with each regressor

    represented by a set of dummy variables. In particular, there were four dummy

    variables for migration status, namely, rural non-migrant (omitted), rural-to-rural

    migrant, recent rural-to-urban migrant, and less recent rural-to-urban migrant.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    5/42

    5

    Yaps (1976) results suggest that rural-to-urban migrants derived significant income

    benefits from migration, and that no significant income gains accrued to rural-to-rural

    migrants. In spite of the fact that Yaps approach is insightful, it does not capture

    convincingly the incomes migrants would have earned if they had not migrated. As

    Lucas (1997) points out, there are concerns about Yaps assumption that the returns to

    education and other estimated coefficients are identical in both origin and destination

    localities. Lucas further observes that Yaps approach is potentially problematic

    because of the possible correlation of the migration dummies with unobserved

    attributes distinguishing migrants from non-migrants.

    The issue of the counterfactual as it relates to migrants incomes has often been

    addressed by estimating separate income equations for migrants and non-migrants

    (see, for example, Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980; Pessino, 1991; and Tunali, 2000).

    Such methods typically incorporate an adjustment for selectivity bias by employing

    techniques such as Lees (1978) two-step method, an approach that is commonly

    known as Heckmans (1979) two-step procedure. For the sake of illustration, let on

    and off describe the different sets of observations corresponding to individuals who

    take a particular decision (such as, the decision to migrate), and those who do not,

    respectively. Then, in brief, the Heckman two-step method entails deriving selectivity

    variables from a probit (decision) regression, and inserting these variables into income

    OLS regressions for the on and off samples. This approach yields consistent

    estimates for the truncated that is, the on and off income regressions (see Lee,

    1978; and Heckman, 1979). It is worth noting, however, that this popular two-step

    method assumes that the error terms in the probit and OLS regressions are normally

    distributed; a violation of this assumption might result in failure to detect selectivity

    in the OLS regressions (see Lee, 1982).

    Using data from Peru, Pessino (1991) applied Heckmans two-step procedure to

    estimate wage equations for movers and stayers in three regions; Lima, other urban,

    and rural localities. The regressors used in the study captured attributes, such as, work

    experience, education, and marital status. Even though Pessino did not find evidence

    in support of selectivity amongst movers in any of her samples, she found positive

    selectivity amongst stayers in Lima, and negative selectivity amongst stayers in rural

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    6/42

    6

    areas. In other words, Pessinos evidence suggests that Lima stayers earned more than

    movers would have earned if they had stayed, but contrary to expectations rural

    stayers earned less at their location than movers would have earned if they had stayed.

    In a more recent study, Agesa (2001) contributes to the discourse on rural-urban

    migration by applying the Heckman two-step technique to Kenyan rural and urban

    data. Agesas approach is, essentially, identical to that of Nakosteen and Zimmer

    (1980); after using the two-step method to estimate migrant and non-migrant income

    equations, these equations are then used to generate an urban-rural income gap

    variable for inclusion in a migration structural equation. Regressors for the migration

    (decision) and income equations include indicators (or proxies) for personal attributes

    and human capital. In addition to obtaining a positive and statistically significant

    coefficient for the urban-rural income gap variable, Agesas findings suggest that

    those rural workers more likely to gain from migrating to the urban sector are those

    who migrate. Other studies that have analysed the migration-income link using

    corrections for selectivity bias include Falaris (1987; for Venezuela), Lanzona (1998;

    for rural Philippines), and Tunali (2000; for Turkey).

    The Ghana literature

    Even though migration in Ghana has attracted very few econometric analyses, the

    available studies lend some support to the view that migration enhances migrants

    welfare. Using data from two waves of the Ghana Living Standards Survey (GLSS),

    Litchfield and Waddington (2003) employ multivariate analyses to investigate the

    impact of migration on welfare. They used standard OLS regressions (of equivalised

    household consumption expenditure) and migration dummies to determine whether

    migrants are better off than non-migrants. Poverty probits were also used to examine

    the impact of migration on the likelihood of being poor.

    Litchfield and Waddington observe, that even though the OLS regressions suggest

    migrants have a higher standard of living than non-migrants, the migration premium

    seemed to have halved between 1991/92 and 1998/99. The poverty probit for 1991/92

    showed migrants having a lower probability of being poor (that is, relative to non-

    migrants), but that for 1998/99 did not indicate any statistically significant difference

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    7/42

    7

    in the probabilities of being poor between migrants and non-migrants. It must be

    noted that Litchfield and Waddington found an apparent zero welfare-gap (that is,

    between migrants and non-migrants) when the analysis was extended to non-monetary

    indicators of welfare. It is worth mentioning, however, that the absence of a correction

    for selectivity bias implies that the parameter estimates of the studys linear

    regressions are likely to be inconsistent, a limitation the authors acknowledge. Given

    the paucity in the context of the Ghana literature of rigorous quantitative analyses

    of migration, the study by Litchfield and Waddington is, nevertheless, an important

    contribution.

    The incorporation of a correction for selectivity bias is a key aspect of a recent

    econometric migration study (Migration and Household, 2004). The study explores

    in the context of Ghanas Volta Basin the determinants of the migration decision,

    placing particular prominence on the role of income in migration decisions. In

    accounting for the fact that migrants are non-randomly selected from the population,

    the study utilises Heckmans procedure for selectivity bias correction. A major result

    of the analysis is the evidence found for expected income gains in influencing

    migration decisions. Furthermore, evidence was found to suggest that incomes of

    migrant households are higher than those of their non-migrant colleagues. Since the

    studys geographical focus was very localised, its findings cannot be generalised for

    the entire country. Notwithstanding this limitation, the results and more importantly

    the methodology employed constitute a valuable addition to the Ghana migration

    literature.

    3. Data and Definitions

    The 1991/92 and 1998/99 Ghana Living Standards Surveys (GLSS) constitute the

    data source for the descriptive analysis, whilst the econometric analysis employs the

    latter surveys data2.The Ghana Living Standards Surveys are a series of nationally

    representative household surveys, the first of which was carried out in 1987/88. The

    1991/92 and 1998/99 surveys, being the third and fourth in the series, are often

    2Owing to a difference in questionnaire design with respect to the migration section between the

    two surveys, the 1991/92 data do not permit a precise identification of migrants (as defined in thisstudy). We consequently employ the 1991/92 data in the descriptive analysis only, and confine the

    econometric analysis to the 1998/99 data.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    8/42

    8

    referred to as GLSS3 and GLSS4, respectively. Apart from the demographic

    information collected in the surveys, the GLSS data cover various aspects of living

    conditions, such as, consumption, education, health, housing, employment, and

    migration. The comprehensive coverage aside, the statistical methods employed in the

    surveys make the GLSS data, presumably, the most widely used survey data on living

    conditions in Ghana.

    At this point, it is pertinent to address issues relating to the definition of a migrant, as

    used in our study. Given that our empirical analysis is mainly based on GLSS4 data, it

    is instructive to identify some definitions proposed by the GLSS4 Report. The

    definitions all relating to persons aged 15 years or more are as follows (GSS,

    2000):

    In-migrant: a person born outside current place of residence;

    Return-migrant: a person born at current place of residence, but who had lived

    elsewhere for at least one year, and returned to place of birth;

    Migrant: an in-migrant or a return-migrant;

    Non-migrant: a person born at current place of residence, and who has never lived

    elsewhere for a period lasting, at least, one year.

    Whilst the above definitions seem appropriate, it is worth noting that they do not

    capture the phenomenon of seasonal migration. Consequently, there is a chance of

    classifying many seasonal migrants as non-migrants. This limitation is closely related

    to the data collected in the survey. In other words, the surveys data do not permit an

    examination of seasonal migration. As a result, the migration-related definitions used

    in the present study similarly do not address this limitation.

    A second problem with the above definitions relate to the importance placed on

    birthplace. For example, the definition of an in-migrant can inappropriately classify

    certain persons as in-migrants, as might occur with persons who have always lived in

    a rural locality, but were born in a nearby town (possibly, the district capital). In

    Ghana (and most likely, in many other developing countries), it is not uncommon for

    expectant women to deliver their babies outside their localities of residence. This may

    occur in cases where rural residents give birth in nearby towns owing to inadequate

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    9/42

    9

    health facilities in their own localities. An expectant woman may also deliver outside

    her residential locality simply because of a decision to be with the mother just before

    delivery, presumably to facilitate the transfer of knowledge and skill in the nursing of

    babies. In the cited and similar instances, the nursing mother typically returns (with

    her child) to her usual place of residence, where the child may live permanently or

    until he or she becomes an adult. Furthermore, circumstances unrelated to baby

    delivery may result in children moving (along with their parents or guardians) to some

    other locality and residing there permanently. Thus, a desirable feature of migrant-

    related definitions is the capacity for dealing with problems posed by the strict linkage

    of migrant status to place of birth.

    In the light of the preceding discussion, the following definitions are proposed:

    In-migrant: an adult (aged at least 15 years) born outside current place of residence,

    and who was, at least, six years old at the time of moving to current place of

    residence;

    Return-migrant: an adult born at current place of residence (or who moved to

    current place of residence before sixth birthday) and who has lived elsewhere for

    more than one year and returned to current place;

    Migrant: an in-migrant or a return-migrant;

    Non-migrant: an adult who has lived at current place of residence since birth (or

    before sixth birthday), and has never moved and lived elsewhere for more than one

    year.

    4. Migration Patterns and Profile of Migrants

    The available data lend support to the prevalence of migration in Ghana, since a

    sizable proportion of the population are migrants or have migrated at some point in

    their lives. In 1991/92, 54 percent of Ghanas population were migrants (that is, either

    in-migrants or return-migrants), whereas the migrant share of the population in

    1998/99 was 50 percent (see Table 4.1).

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    10/42

    10

    Table 4.1: Extent of migration in Ghana; 1991/92 and 1998/99

    Migrant status

    Share (%) of population

    (1991/92)

    Share (%) of population

    (1998/99)

    In-migrant 37.57 34.70

    Return-migrant 16.51 15.08Non-migrant 45.91 50.22

    Total 100.00 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92 and

    1998/99.

    In terms of an origin-destination classification, the data suggest that rural-to-rural and

    urban-to-rural forms of population movement dominate Ghanas internal migration.

    For example, in 1991/92, 17.1 percent of Ghanas population were rural-to-ruralmigrants and 15.5 percent were urban-to-rural migrants, whereas urban-to-urban and

    rural-to-urban migrants constituted 12.4 percent and 4.9 percent, respectively (see

    Table 4.2). The pattern of internal migration in 1998/99 was not very different from

    that of 1991/92; urban-to-rural migrants accounted for 16.6 percent of the population,

    whilst rural-to-rural and urban-to-urban migrants represented 14.4 percent and 10.9

    percent of the population, respectively. As reflected in Table 4.2, the rural-to-urban

    migrant share (4.5 percent) of the population was the lowest (that is, amongst internal

    migrants) in 1998/99. On the whole, and in both survey years, the migrant category

    with the lowest proportion of the population was foreign-to-urban migrants, followed

    by foreign-to-rural migrants. It is important to note, however, that in both 1991/92 and

    1998/99, the majority of persons migrating to Ghana from other countries were

    return-migrants (see Tables A1 and A2 in the Appendix).

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    11/42

    11

    Table 4.2: Distribution of types of migrants in Ghana; 1991/92 and 1998/99

    Migrant Category

    Proportion (%) of

    population; 1991/923

    Proportion (%) of

    population; 1998/99

    Urban-to-urban 12.40 10.94

    Urban-to-rural 15.48 16.55Rural-to-urban 4.90 4.47

    Rural-to-rural 17.11 14.42

    Foreign-to-urban 1.78 1.28

    Foreign-to-rural 2.18 2.12

    Non-migrant 46.15 50.22

    Total 100.00 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92 and

    1998/99.

    The characteristics of migrants have been fairly similar between 1991/92 and

    1998/99. With regard to the gender distribution of migrants, females had a higher

    share than males in each of the survey years. In 1991/92, 53.6 percent of migrants

    were females, whereas the corresponding proportion in 1998/99 was 53.8 percent. It is

    worth pointing out, that in 1991/92, even though female migrants outnumbered their

    male colleagues, the migration rate amongst males (54.4 percent) was slightly higher

    than the rate (53.8 percent) amongst females (see Table A3 in the Appendix). In

    1998/99, however, the migration rate amongst females (50 percent) was higher than

    that of males (49.53 percent).

    An examination of Table 4.3 shows that the majority of Ghanas migrants are less

    than forty years old, and that little change occurred in migrants age distribution

    between 1991/92 and 1998/99. In each of the two survey years, migrants aged

    between fifteen and forty-five years accounted for more than 60 percent of the

    migrant population. It must be stressed though, that whilst this age distribution is not

    surprising, it appears to be largely due to a generally large share of young persons in

    Ghanas population. This point is supported by the fact that amongst the non-migrant

    population, the young still dominates (see Table 4.3).

    3Information on migrants previous place of residence was missing for 0.5% of migrants.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    12/42

    12

    Table 4.3: Age distribution of migrants and non-migrants; 1991/92 and 1998/99

    Age group (in

    years)

    Share (%)

    amongst

    migrants;

    1991/92

    Share (%)

    amongst

    migrants;

    1998/99

    Share (%)

    amongst non-

    migrants;

    1991/92

    Share (%)

    amongst non-

    migrants;

    1998/99

    15 age < 25 18.64 17.38 47.95 43.12

    25 age < 35 24.92 24.69 20.07 21.29

    35 age < 45 21.41 22.16 11.84 14.30

    45 age < 55 16.90 16.24 8.66 9.04

    55 age < 65 9.83 9.52 5.11 5.61

    Age 65 8.29 10.01 6.36 6.63Total 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92 and

    1998/99.

    The main reasons for migrating as indicated by migrants are generally similar in

    the two surveys. In 1991/92, other family reasons was the response category that

    accounted for the largest share (42.8%) of reasons for migrating. This was followed

    by marriage, own employment, spouses employment, other, schooling, and

    drought/war in that order. In 1998/99, other family reasons was again the response

    category accounting for the largest share (46%) of reasons for migrating. The second

    most cited reason in 1998/99 was own employment, with marriage, other, spouses

    employment, schooling, and drought/war following in that order.

    While broad similarities were evident in the cited reasons for migrating, it is worth

    highlighting some gender-related differences. For males, and in both 1991/92 and

    1998/99, own employment accounted for the second largest share of reasons for

    migrating. In the case of females, however, own employment ranked sixth and fourth

    in 1991/92 and 1998/99, respectively. For both 1991/92 and 1998/99, males

    accounted for more than 80 percent of persons who migrated because of own

    employment. Furthermore, in each of the two survey years, marriage accounted for

    the second highest share of reasons for female migration, whereas for males, it ranked

    sixth. In each of 1991/92 and 1998/99, females again had a huge share (more than 90

    percent) of persons who migrated because of marriage. Another insightful observation

    relates to migration induced by spouses employment. In GLSS3, females constituted

    about 60 percent of persons who migrated because of spouses employment; thecorresponding figure for GLSS4 was much higher (81.8 percent).

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    13/42

    13

    On the whole, other family reasons was the most cited reason for migrating,

    irrespective of gender and age group. This notwithstanding, it accounted for a

    particularly high share of reasons amongst persons aged less than twenty-five years

    (but, at least fifteen years old); the shares were 60.1 percent in 1991/92, and 73.3

    percent in 1998/99. Amongst this same age group (that is, fifteen-to-twenty years)

    in both survey years schooling was the second most stated reason for migrating, an

    unsurprising result.

    In order to obtain a rough measure of living standards across migrant status, we

    examine for both rural and urban sectors the mean consumption welfare for in-

    migrants, return-migrants, and non-migrants. To this end, we define an individuals

    consumption welfare as the total consumption expenditure per adult equivalent of that

    individuals household, measured in real terms. In 1991/92, return-migrants had the

    highest mean consumption welfare, followed by in-migrants and non-migrants, in that

    order. In 1998/99, in-migrants had the highest mean consumption welfare, with no

    other clear pattern emerging (see Tables A5 and A6 in the Appendix).

    A comparison of the mean consumption welfare of internal migrants indicates that

    urban-to-urban migrants had the highest consumption welfare in each of the two

    survey years, with rural-to-urban, urban-to-rural, and rural-to-rural migrants following

    in that order (see Table 4.4). Furthermore, in both 1991/92 and 1998/99, urban non-

    migrants had, on the average, a higher level of consumption welfare than urban-to-

    rural migrants, whilst rural non-migrants had a lower level of consumption welfare

    than rural-to-urban migrants.

    Table 4.4: Mean consumption welfare of internal migrants; 1991/92 and 1998/99

    Migrant category 1991/92 1998/99

    Urban-to-urban 1,845,521.8 1,994,174.1

    Urban-to-rural 1,104,548.5 1,206,615.9

    Rural-to-urban 1,637,388.2 1,632,757.1

    Rural-to-rural 1,017,758.9 1,067,828.3Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92 and

    1998/99.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    14/42

    14

    5. Modelling of Migrations Impact on Migrants Welfare

    This section outlines a general model for estimating the impact of migration on

    migrants welfare, since only a slight modification is required to extend the analysis to

    the specific cases of rural-to-urban migration and urban-to-rural migration. The basic

    modelling strategy follows very closely Lee (1978) and Nakosteen and Zimmer

    (1980), and is summarised as follows:

    1. A simultaneous estimation of the following three equations:

    a) A migration decision equation, defined over both migrants and non-migrants;b) A welfare equation for migrants; andc) A welfare equation for non-migrants.

    2. The use of the two welfare equations and data on both migrants and non-migrants

    to estimate the average impact of migration on migrants welfare.

    a) Theoretical Framework

    Sjaastads (1962) human capital framework constitutes the theoretical underpinning

    for the model employed. By viewing migration as an investment in human capital,

    Sjaastad suggests that prospective migrants aim to maximise the present value of the

    net gains resulting from locational change. For any potential migrant, suppose the

    present value of the migration generated net gain is given by:

    m

    T

    ntmtm Cdt-pt

    eWW(t)PV -]-[0= (1)

    where

    Wmtrepresents anticipated welfare at mth prospective destination locality at time t;

    Wntrepresents anticipated welfare at origin locality at time t;

    Cmdenotes a one-time cost4of migrating to locality m;

    T: duration of migration status;

    p: implicit discount rate.

    4Even though costs associated with migration are not incurred once, recurring costs of locational

    change are subsumed in the welfare measure.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    15/42

    15

    The individual does not migrate ifPVm0 for all m;

    The individual migrates, if there exists an m for whichPVm> 0, and where this

    condition is satisfied by more than one prospective destination, the individual selectsthe destination yielding the maximumPVm.

    In order to adapt the above theoretical framework for empirical analyses, we

    (following Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980) make the following assumption:

    At any given time, individual i will choose to migrate if the anticipated welfare gain

    exceeds the corresponding migration costs.

    This implies that at any given time, an individual will migrate if his/her proportionate

    welfare gain exceeds the migration costs, as a proportion of welfare. Thus, denoting

    the individuals migration costs (as a proportion of welfare) by Qi, individual iwill

    migrate if:

    [(WmiWni)/Wni] Qi> 0, (2)

    and will not migrate if:

    [(Wmi Wni)/Wni] Qi 0, (3)

    where

    Wmidenotes individual is welfare as a migrant; and

    Wnidenotes individual is welfare as a non-migrant.

    It may be argued that the costs of migration depend on individual attributes (for

    example, age, sex, and marital status) and community-level characteristics, such as

    the cost of living and the unemployment rate. Thus, the decision to migrate as

    indicated in inequalities (2) and (3) may be expressed as a function of (anticipated)

    welfare gains, individual attributes, and community characteristics. In the tradition of

    similar methodologies (see, for example, Lee, 1978; and Nakosteen and Zimmer,

    1980), we adopt a linear functional form for the migration decision equation as

    follows:

    Individual imigrates if:

    Ii = 0+ 1[(Wmi- Wni)/Wni] + .Gi i> 0, (4)

    and does not migrate if

    Ii = 0+ 1[(Wmi- Wni)/Wni] + .Gi i 0, (5)

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    16/42

    16

    where

    1: Coefficient of the welfare gain variable

    Gi: Vector of variables representing appropriate individual and community

    characteristics: Vector of coefficients of the variables in Gi:

    i: An error term; and

    0: A constant term

    It is also reasonable to postulate that an individuals welfare level depends on

    personal characteristics (such as educational attainment) and community attributes

    (for example, the availability of socio-economic amenities). An individuals welfareequation can consequently be expressed as a function of variables representing

    individual and community characteristics. Invoking the argument of Lee (1978) that

    (LnWmi-LnWni) and (Wmi- Wni)/Wniare approximately equal, the empirical model is

    specified below, with the welfare equations formulated in logarithmic form:

    =Ii 0+ 1(LnWmi-LnWni) + .Gi- i

    LnWmi= am+ m.Xi+ mi

    LnWni= an+ n.Xi+ ni

    where

    Ii is not observed, but we rather observe

    Ii= 1 if Ii> 0, andIi= 0 if Ii

    0;

    LnWmi: log of migrant welfare

    LnWni: log of non-migrant welfare

    Xi:Vector of variables representing relevant individual and community characteristics

    m: Migrant vector of coefficients of the variables inXi

    n: Non-migrant vector of coefficients of the variables inXi

    i, mi, and niare all Normally distributed error terms with zero mean and constant

    variance;

    All other variables retain their definitions.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    17/42

    17

    The observed variables in the model are the limited dependent variables, Wmiand Wni,

    the dichotomous migration decision variable Ii, and the variables contained in vectors

    Gi,andXi. In general, the ordinary least squares (OLS) technique is inappropriate for

    estimating the welfare equations due to its failure to account for selectivity bias (see

    Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980; and Lee, 1978). As a result, we employ Lees (1978)

    proposed solution5; the welfare equations are modified by incorporating appropriate

    selectivity variables, and adding error terms with zero means. It is worth

    emphasising that even though the variables contained in GiandXirepresent individual

    and community characteristics, the two vectors need not contain identical variables.

    b) Estimation procedure

    In order to estimate all the parameters of the model, the following estimation

    technique is used:

    i. Probit estimation of the reduced-form migration decision equation

    The regressors in this equation consist of the exogenous variables in all the three

    structural equations. Fitted values ( i ) obtained from this (first) stage are used to

    construct variables u1iand u2i, where:

    u1i= -f ( i ) /F( i )is the selectivity variable for the migrant welfare equation;

    u2i=f ( i )/ [1-F( i )] is the selectivity variable for the non-migrant welfare

    equation;

    f: the density function of a standard normal random variable; and

    F: the cumulative distribution function of a standard normal random variable.

    ii. Insertion of u1iand u2iinto the appropriate welfare equations and estimating the

    welfare equations by OLS

    Estimates obtained using the above two-step procedure are known to be consistent

    (see Lee, 1978).

    5As noted earlier, this technique is often referred to as the Heckman two-step method.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    18/42

    18

    iii. Probit estimation of the structural migration decision equation

    In this step, the consistent parameter estimates of the welfare equations are used to

    obtain fitted values of the logarithm of welfare, which are in turn, used to compute

    estimates of (LnWmi-LnWni). Together with other exogenous variables, the estimates

    of (LnWmi-LnWni) are inserted into the structural decision equation to obtain the

    probit estimates of the structural migration decision equation.

    c) Determination of migrations impact on migrants welfare

    In order to estimate migrations impact on migrants welfare, we employ simulations

    of counterfactual scenarios, coupled with the estimation of an index of welfare gain

    due to migration. This is accomplished by computing an index of welfare differential

    between migration and non-migration scenarios as follows:

    For any sub-group () of the entire sample, letN() be the corresponding population

    size;

    Then, for any sub-group (), the average proportionate welfare increment attributable

    to migration may be expressed as:

    =

    i Wni

    WniWmi

    Ng

    )(

    1

    Where, Wmiand Wni individual is welfare levels as a migrant, and as a non-

    migrant, respectively are proxied by their corresponding fitted values for cases

    where they are unobserved.

    6. Empirical Results

    a) Introductory note and discussion of regressors

    In applying the described model to an analysis of migration between Ghanas rural

    and urban sectors, a number of adjustments are made. These adjustments stem from

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    19/42

    19

    an explicit recognition of two separate migratory movements, namely, urban-to-rural

    migration and rural-to-urban migration. Two separate analyses are consequently

    carried out, one for each migratory movement. It should be noted also, that a migrant

    as used in the outlined analytical model is equivalent to an in-migrantas defined

    earlier. Furthermore, we employ a consumption measure of welfare, where, an

    individuals consumption welfare is defined as the total consumption expenditure per

    adult equivalent of that individuals household, measured in real terms.

    For the analysis of urban-to-rural migration, the three structural equations consist of a

    migration decision equation (defined over a pooled sample of urban non-migrants and

    urban-to-rural in-migrants), a welfare equation for urban-to-rural in-migrants, and a

    welfare equation for urban non-migrants. Similarly, in analysing rural-to-urban

    migration, the relevant structural equations comprise a migration decision equation

    (defined over a pooled sample of rural non-migrants and rural-to-urban in-migrants), a

    welfare equation for rural-to-urban in-migrants, and a welfare equation for rural non-

    migrants.

    The entire data contained 14,196 observations on persons aged 15 years or more. The

    set of regressors for each of the two migration status equations includes variables for

    highest educational attainment, age group, marital status6,location, and (anticipated)

    welfare gain. The choice of these variables is informed by theory and by a preliminary

    analysis that explored various combinations of regressors. In particular, in order to

    ensure that the parameters of the structural (migration) decision equation are

    identified, the welfare equations contain at least one exogenous variable that is

    excluded from the structural migration equation (Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980).

    On a priori grounds, we expect education to have a positive impact on rural-to-urban

    migration, and to have a negative effect on urban-to-rural migration. With regard to

    age, the literature suggests that young adults tend to have a higher propensity to

    migrate than the elderly. It is therefore expected that the tendency to migrate amongst

    lower age groups will be higher than that of higher age groups. The impact (on

    migration) of anticipated welfare gain is expected to be positive; an expectation

    6Here, what is used is a variable that places emphasis on whether (or not) a person has always been

    single.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    20/42

    20

    rooted in both theoretical and intuitive considerations. Finally, apart from serving as

    control variables, the locational variables can provide spatial-related insights into

    population movements between rural and urban localities.

    Theory and preliminary data examination were again crucial in the selection of

    regressors for the welfare equations. Most of the regressors were common to all four

    welfare equations. These common regressors include variables for highest educational

    attainment, employment category, selectivity, and location, as well as variables that

    capture household characteristics, such as size, access to pipe-borne water for

    drinking, and the use of electricity for lighting. In the analysis of urban-to-rural

    migration however, a gender variable and regressors for other household

    characteristics were included7(see Table 6.1 for a list of variables used in the

    analysis).

    7An initial analysis suggested the relevance of these regressors is confined to the urban-to-rural model.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    21/42

    21

    Table 6.1: List of regressors for the econometric analysis

    Variable Definition

    hhsize Household size

    agegp1 1 if 15 age (in years) < 25, 0 otherwise

    agegp2 1 if 25 age (in years) < 35, 0 otherwiseagegp3 1 if 35 age (in years) < 45, 0 otherwiseagegp4 1 if 45 age (in years) < 55, 0 otherwiseagegp5 1 if 55 age (in years) < 65, 0 otherwiseagegp6 (the omitted category) 1 if age (in years) 65sex1 1 if male, 0 otherwise

    mar5 1 if never married, 0 otherwise

    hiedq1 (the omitted category) Dummy for highest educational qualification; 1 if no

    educational qualification, 0 otherwise

    hiedq2 Dummy for highest educational qualification; 1 ifMSLC/BECE, 0 otherwise

    hiedq3 Dummy for highest educational qualification; 1 if

    vocational, commercial, O or A levelhiedq4 Dummy for highest educational qualification; 1 if T/T,

    nursing, or Tech/Prof, 0 otherwise

    hiedq5 Dummy for highest educational qualification; 1 if

    University degree holder, 0 otherwise

    hiedq6 Dummy for highest educational qualification; 1 if

    unspecified qualification, 0 otherwise

    empcat1 (the omitted category) 1 if unemployed, 0 otherwise

    empcat2 1 if employed in agriculture, 0 otherwise

    empcat3 1 if employed in industry, 0 otherwise

    empcat4 1 if employed in services, 0 otherwise

    empcat5 1 if unspecified employment category, 0 otherwise

    farmliv1 1 if household owns/operates a farm, keeps livestock, or is

    engaged in fishing, 0 otherwisefoodpr1 1 if household is engaged in food processing, 0 otherwise

    othbus1 1 if household is engaged in some other non-farm business,

    0 otherwise

    pbw1 1 if household drinks pipe-borne water, 0 otherwise

    eg1 1 if households main lighting source is electricity or

    generator

    ez1 (the omitted category) Dummy for ecological zone; 1 if Coastal, 0 otherwise

    ez2 Dummy for ecological zone; 1 if Forest, 0 otherwise

    ez3 Dummy for ecological zone; 1 if Savannah, 0 otherwise

    reg1 Regional dummy; 1 if Western, 0 otherwise

    reg2 Regional dummy; 1 if Central, 0 otherwise

    reg3 Regional dummy; 1 if Greater Accra, 0 otherwisereg4 Regional dummy; 1 if Eastern, 0 otherwise

    reg5 Regional dummy; 1 if Volta, 0 otherwise

    reg6 Regional dummy; 1 if Ashanti, 0 otherwise

    reg7 Regional dummy; 1 if Brong Ahafo, 0 otherwise

    reg8 Regional dummy; 1 if Northern, 0 otherwise

    reg9 Regional dummy; 1 if Upper West, 0 otherwise

    reg10 (the omitted category) Regional dummy; 1 if Upper East, 0 otherwise

    diflnWh Estimated migrant-non-migrant gap in log of welfare

    sel selectivity variable

    _cons Constant term

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    22/42

    22

    b) Factors influencing urban-to-rural migration

    The results of the analysis (see Table 6.2) generally conform to a priori expectations.

    The significant and positive coefficient of diflnWh (the welfare gap variable)

    suggests that the anticipated welfare gain is a major influence on urban-to-rural

    migration decisions in Ghana. The results further show, that in comparison with their

    colleagues who are (or have ever been) married8,urban residents who have never

    been married are less likely to migrate to rural areas. This finding is contrary to what

    one might expect, given the perception that persons who are less encumbered will be

    more likely to migrate. This notwithstanding, it is possible that the result is a

    reflection of a tendency for unmarried migrants to marry within a few years after

    migrating. In this connection, it is worth noting that almost 60 percent of all in-

    migrants in the entire sample have lived at their current place of residence for at least

    ten years. Thus, it is plausible that most of those migrants who had never been

    married at the time of migrating had experienced a change in marital status by the

    time of the survey.

    The role of education in urban-to-rural migration decisions is insightful. The evidence

    suggests that the attainment of education beyond the vocational, commercial,

    Ordinary (O), or Advanced (A) level tends to reduce the probability of migrating

    from an urban area to the rural sector. This evidence is not surprising; it is common

    knowledge that persons with higher levels of education tend to have a preference for

    settling in urban areas, and have a better chance (relative to the less educated) of

    finding employment in urban centres. Our findings further suggest, that urban

    residents in the Upper East Region are more likely (relative to their counterparts in

    other Regions, except the Upper West) to migrate to rural areas. Given that the Upper

    East Region is one of the poorest in Ghana, this finding is reasonable.

    8Marriage, as used here, includes informal or loose unions.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    23/42

    23

    c) Factors influencing consumption levels

    With regard to living standards that is, in terms of consumption of urban-to-rural

    in-migrants, there is strong support for a negative effect of household size on welfare.

    The results show a strong negative association between household size and the

    welfare of urban-to-rural in-migrants. Moreover, the magnitude of this link between

    household size and welfare is the same for both urban-to-rural in-migrants and urban

    non-migrants.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    24/42

    24

    Table 6.2: Results of the urban-to-rural migration model

    welf1: OLS welfare regression for urban-to-rural in-migrants

    welf0: OLS welfare regression for urban non-migrants

    probit: Probit regression for the pooled sample of urban non-migrants and urban-to-

    rural in-migrants

    ---------------------------------------------------------Variable welf1 welf0 probit

    ---------------------------------------------------------sex1 -0.06** -0.10***

    (0.03) (0.02)hhsize -0.10*** -0.09***

    (0.01) (0.00)

    hiedq2 0.14*** 0.09*** -0.05(0.03) (0.02) (0.06)hiedq3 0.27*** 0.31*** 0.09

    (0.07) (0.03) (0.10)hiedq4 0.43*** 0.28*** -0.27**

    (0.08) (0.05) (0.13)

    hiedq5 1.20*** 0.46** -2.13***(0.27) (0.22) (0.48)

    hiedq6 0.23 0.00 -0.52(0.31) (0.16) (0.47)

    empcat2 0.17*** 0.02(0.06) (0.04)

    empcat3 0.21*** 0.07**(0.07) (0.04)

    empcat4 0.26*** 0.04(0.06) (0.03)

    empcat5 -0.07 0.10(0.11) (0.06)

    farmliv1 0.00 -0.07**(0.05) (0.03)

    foodpr1 -0.06 -0.06**

    (0.04) (0.03)othbus1 0.05 0.09***

    (0.03) (0.02)pbw1 -0.13* 0.06

    (0.07) (0.04)eg1 0.14** 0.36***

    (0.06) (0.04)ez2 0.18*** 0.04 0.33***

    (0.06) (0.04) (0.09)ez3 0.13 -0.01 -0.18

    (0.08) (0.06) (0.14)reg1 (Western) 0.77*** 0.25** -1.22***

    (0.15) (0.12) (0.25)

    reg2 (Central) 0.65*** -0.19 -2.22***(0.15) (0.12) (0.27)

    reg3 (Gt. Accra) 0.75*** 0.35*** -1.29***(0.16) (0.12) (0.25)

    reg4 (Eastern) 0.45*** 0.05 -1.09***(0.14) (0.11) (0.24)

    reg5 (Volta) 0.67*** -0.01 -1.87***(0.15) (0.11) (0.25)

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    25/42

    25

    Table 6.2: continued

    ---------------------------------------------------------Variable welf1 welf0 probit

    ---------------------------------------------------------

    reg6 (Ashanti) 0.69*** 0.23** -1.43***(0.15) (0.11) (0.25)

    reg7 (B.-Ahafo) 0.57*** 0.18* -1.43***(0.14) (0.11) (0.24)

    reg8 (Northern) 0.25 0.12 -1.16***(0.15) (0.10) (0.23)

    reg9 (Upper West) -0.02 0.10 0.56**(0.15) (0.12) (0.24)

    sel -0.33*** -0.02(0.10) (0.07)

    agegp1 0.18(0.13)

    agegp2 0.19*

    (0.11)agegp3 0.15

    (0.11)agegp4 0.22*

    (0.12)agegp5 0.09

    (0.13)mar5 -0.46***

    (0.08)diflnWh 3.41***

    (0.13)_cons 13.31*** 14.11*** 2.01***

    (0.21) (0.12) (0.27)

    ----------------------------------------------------------Number of obs. 1360.00 2720.00 4080.00R-squared 0.39 0.46Adj. R-squared 0.38 0.45F-statistic 30.53 81.80Pseudo R-squared 0.38

    Chi-squared 1974.61----------------------------------------------------------

    Legend: * p

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    26/42

    26

    As expected, strong support is found amongst both urban-to-rural in-migrants and

    urban non-migrants for a welfare-enhancing role of education. In both welfare

    equations, virtually all the education dummies have significantly positive effects on

    welfare. The results further suggest that being employed (whether in agriculture,

    industry, or services) enhances the welfare of urban-to-rural in-migrants, with the

    services sector generating the biggest impact. In comparison with urban-to-rural in-

    migrants, urban non-migrants specific employment sector appears to be less

    important in influencing welfare. Nevertheless, working in the industrial sector exerts

    a positive effect on the welfare of urban non-migrants.

    The results also suggest that having electricity (or a generator) for lighting enhances

    the welfare of both urban-to-rural in-migrants and urban non-migrants. This finding is

    tenable, given the health hazards associated with some other forms of lighting. An

    intriguing finding of our analysis is the apparent higher welfare of females relative to

    males. This finding holds for both welfare equations. In other words, it does appear

    that female urban-to-rural in-migrants are slightly better off than their male

    counterparts, and also, that the welfare of male urban non-migrants is lower (on

    average) than that of their female counterparts. It must be stressed however, that this

    result is not conclusive, since the welfare measure is equal for all members of a given

    household, irrespective of gender.

    Another notable finding of this study relates to self-selectivity. For the urban-to-rural

    welfare equation, the coefficient of the selectivity variable (sel) is statistically

    significant and negative. This provides support for the positive selectivity of urban-to-

    rural in-migrants. Other results relating to urban non-migrants are worth noting; all

    things being equal, individuals whose households are engaged in an agricultural or

    food processing enterprise are likely to have lower levels of welfare relative to those

    whose households are not engaged in these activities. On the other hand, the results

    suggest that an urban non-migrants welfare tends to be enhanced by the households

    ownership of some other business.

    All things being equal, urban-to-rural in-migrants living in the Upper East Region

    tend to have lower welfare levels than their colleagues in every other Region, with the

    exception of the Upper West and Northern Regions. This finding reflects the

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    27/42

    27

    relatively low standards of living in the three northern (that is, Northern, Upper West,

    and Upper East) Regions of Ghana (see GSS, 2000). Roughly similar results, but to a

    much lesser degree, are found for urban non-migrants; living standards amongst urban

    non-migrants residing in the Upper East Region tend to fall below those of their

    counterparts in the Western, Greater Accra, Ashanti, and Brong-Ahafo Regions9.

    Urban-to-rural in-migrants located in the forest ecological zone also tend to have

    higher living standards than their coastal zone counterparts, a result that is apparently

    linked to the concentration of cocoa farming in the rural Forest ecological zone (see

    Coulombe and McKay, 2003).

    d) Welfare-gain from urban-to-rural migration

    The average proportionate welfare gap between in-migrant and non-migrant scenarios

    is very informative. On the whole, migration has a positive impact on the welfare of

    urban-to-rural in-migrants, as they incurred (on average) a 27.7 percentage welfare

    gain (see Table 6.3). Further examination shows that 56.3 percent of urban-to-rural in-

    migrants gained from migrating, their average gain being 72.2 percent. These findings

    suggest that although gains are not guaranteed from urban-to-rural migration,

    participants often benefit considerably.

    A similar simulation for urban non-migrants shows that if they were to migrate to the

    rural sector, they would incur a 30.5 percent welfare loss on average. As shown in

    Table 6.3, migrating to the rural sector would leave the overwhelming majority (83.2

    percent) of urban non-migrants un-rewarded. Indeed, amongst the three categories of

    individuals shown in the Table, only urban-to-rural in-migrants gain from migration.

    Whilst the findings summarised in Table 6.3 are not a direct test for selectivity bias,

    they lend support to the notion that migrants and non-migrants are often non-

    randomly selected from the population. Migrants tend to be those who have a better

    chance (compared with non-migrants) of gaining from migration.

    9The coefficients of the other regional dummies were not statistically significant.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    28/42

    28

    Table 6.3: Migration-generated welfare gains; urban-to-rural migration

    (selectivity bias adjusted)

    Number of

    persons

    Mean

    percentage

    welfare gain

    Percentage

    with welfare

    gain

    Percentage

    without

    welfare gainUrban-to-rural

    in-migrants

    1,360 27.66 56.25

    (Mean % gain

    = 72.23)

    43.75

    (Mean % loss

    = 29.64)

    Urban non-

    migrants

    2,720 -30.49 16.84

    (Mean % gain

    = 48.68)

    83.16

    Mean % loss =

    (46.52)

    Urban-to-rural

    in-migrants

    and urban non-

    migrants

    4,080 -11.10 29.98

    (Mean % gain

    = 63.41)

    70.02

    (Mean % loss

    = 43.00)

    Since our findings are based on a correction for selectivity bias, it is worth indicating

    the outcome of an analysis that does not make such an adjustment. In the absence of a

    correction for selectivity bias, the analysis of welfare-gains (that is, from urban-to-

    rural migration) produces considerably different results from that shown in Table 6.3

    (see Table A7 in the Appendix). In failing to correct for selectivity bias, the analysis

    generally shows gains from urban-to-rural migration for all categories of individuals

    considered. It would be recalled from our discussion of the welfare regression

    estimates for urban-to-rural in-migrants that there is evidence for the positive

    selectivity of urban-to-rural in-migrants. Thus, failure to correct for selectivity bias

    leads to an overestimation of migrant welfare, and consequently, to an overestimation

    of gains from urban-to-rural migration.

    e) Factors influencing rural-to-urban migration

    Many of the results from the analysis of rural-to-urban migration conform to that of

    the urban-to-rural analysis. The findings provide strong support for the importance

    in rural-to-urban migration decisions of anticipated welfare gains, as reflected by

    the performance of the variablediflnWh (see Table 6.4). The results further point to

    an absence of a strong influence of age in rural-to-urban migration decisions.Compared with rural dwellers who are (or have ever been) married, rural residents

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    29/42

    29

    who have never been married are less likely to migrate to the urban centres. As

    suggested earlier, it might be misleading to draw strong conclusions from this finding,

    owing to the long duration of stay at current residence of most in-migrants in our

    sample.

    In comparison with rural residents whose educational attainment is either lower than

    MSLC/BECE10or unspecified, rural dwellers with MSLC/BECE (that is, as their

    highest educational attainment) are less likely to migrate to urban centres. Similarly,

    rural dwellers with the highest educational attainment being vocational, commercial,

    O, or A level, are less likely to migrate to the urban sector, that is, relative to the

    reference group (those with a lower-than-MSLC/BECE or with an unspecified

    educational attainment). Although the underlying reasons for these findings are

    unclear, the significant and positive coefficient of hiedq5 (the dummy for the

    holding of a university degree) provides strong support for a tendency for university

    graduates to settle in urban centres. Our results further show that the Upper East

    Regions rural residents are less likely (compared to their counterparts in other

    Regions) to migrate to urban centres. Considering the Upper East Regions status as

    one of the poorest in Ghana, this finding is consistent with the view that very poor

    individuals or households are often unable to invest in migration.

    f) Factors influencing consumption levels

    One of our robust results is the strong support established for a negative relationship

    between welfare and household size. This relationship exhibits similar orders of

    magnitude amongst in-migrants and non-migrants. All other things being equal, rural-

    to-urban in-migrants whose households drink pipe-borne water enjoy a higher level of

    welfare, relative to their counterparts lacking this amenity. Furthermore, the results

    for both welfare equations suggest that living standards are enhanced by the use of

    electricity (or a generator) for lighting. The welfare equations for both rural non-

    migrants and rural-to-urban in-migrants further reflect a high and positive link

    between education and welfare. This positive association between education and

    10

    MSLC is the Middle School Leaving Certificate (no longer awarded), and the BECE is the BasicEducation Certificate Examination. Each of these represents the highest qualification at the basic

    education level.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    30/42

    30

    welfare conforms to a priori expectations, and highlight the need to attach immense

    importance to education in national development policies.

    Table 6.4: Results of the rural-to-urban migration model

    welf1: OLS welfare regression for rural-to-urban in-migrants

    welf0: OLS welfare regression for rural non-migrants

    probit: Probit regression for the pooled sample of rural non-migrants and rural-to-

    urban in-migrants

    ----------------------------------------------------------

    Variable welf1 welf0 probit----------------------------------------------------------hhsize -0.09*** -0.07***

    (0.01) (0.00)hiedq2 0.11** 0.04** -0.18**

    (0.05) (0.02) (0.08)hiedq3 0.34*** 0.14*** -0.51***

    (0.08) (0.04) (0.15)hiedq4 0.35*** 0.20** -0.09

    (0.09) (0.09) (0.19)hiedq5 0.30 0.94** 1.74***

    (0.34) (0.37) (0.67)empcat2 -0.14* 0.00

    (0.07) (0.02)empcat3 0.06 0.06

    (0.09) (0.05)

    empcat4 0.09 0.08**(0.07) (0.03)

    empcat5 0.02 -0.07*(0.14) (0.04)

    othbus1 0.07 0.12***(0.05) (0.02)

    pbw1 0.34*** 0.05(0.11) (0.03)

    eg1 0.38*** 0.11***(0.08) (0.03)

    ez2 0.24*** 0.11*** -0.58***(0.08) (0.02) (0.10)ez3 0.05 0.21*** 0.64***

    (0.11) (0.04) (0.15)reg1 (Western) 0.46*** 1.03*** 6.87***

    (0.13) (0.05) (0.46)reg2 (Central) (dropped) 0.81*** 7.31***

    (0.05) (0.48)reg3 (Gt. Accra) 0.51*** 1.00*** 7.76***

    (0.16) (0.08) (0.46)reg4 (Eastern) 0.20 0.76*** 7.36***

    (0.16) (0.04) (0.45)reg5 (Volta) -0.02 0.89*** 8.07***

    (0.14) (0.05) (0.47)reg6 (Ashanti) 0.23 0.91*** 7.70***

    (0.16) (0.05) (0.46)

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    31/42

    31

    Table 6.4: continued

    ----------------------------------------------------------Variable welf1 welf0 probit

    ----------------------------------------------------------reg7 (B.-Ahafo) 0.32* 0.74*** 6.87***

    (0.17) (0.04) (0.45)reg8 (Northern) 0.16 0.37*** 6.48***

    (0.20) (0.04) (0.44)reg9 (Upper West) 0.36 0.15*** 3.78

    (0.49) (0.05) (.)sel -0.03 0.12

    (0.11) (0.08)agegp1 -0.26*

    (0.15)agegp2 -0.20

    (0.13)agegp3 0.19

    (0.12)

    agegp4 0.18(0.13)

    agegp5 0.21(0.15)

    mar5 -0.43***(0.12)

    diflnWh 3.23***(0.14)

    _cons 13.56*** 13.13*** -8.00***(0.35) (0.05) (0.47)

    ----------------------------------------------------------Number of obs. 523.00 4447.00 4970.00R-squared 0.54 0.35

    Adj. R-squared 0.52 0.34F-statistic 25.63 97.58Pseudo R-squared 0.41chi-squared 1374.95----------------------------------------------------------Legend: * p

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    32/42

    32

    With the exception of being employed in the agricultural sector (which is negatively

    linked to welfare), the specific sector of ones employment exerts no significant

    impact on the welfare of rural-to-urban in-migrants. In the case of rural non-migrants,

    being employed in the services sector relative to being jobless is positively

    associated with a higher level of welfare. Rural non-migrants whose households are

    engaged in business enterprises (other than agricultural or food processing ventures)

    have higher welfare levels compared with those whose households do not engage in

    such activities.

    g) Welfare-gain from rural-to-urban migration

    On the basis of our results, rural-to-urban migration is generally very rewarding for

    rural-to-urban in-migrants. By migrating to urban localities, rural-to-urban in-

    migrants increased their welfare by 46.3 percent, on average (see Table 6.5). This

    percentage increment is considerably higher than that of their urban-to-rural

    counterparts (see Table 6.3). Furthermore, the majority (68.5 percent) of rural-to-

    urban in-migrants gained by migrating, the mean welfare-gain of the gainers being

    80.1 percent. For the minority (31.6 percent) of rural-to-urban in-migrants who did

    not gain, the average welfare-loss was 26.9 percent. Interestingly, our findings

    suggest that for most rural dwellers, rural-to-urban migration is not necessarily

    profitable. As shown in Table 6.5, if rural non-migrants were to migrate to urban

    areas, they would incur, on average, a welfare-loss of 2 percent, and 38.4 percent of

    such migrants would gain.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    33/42

    33

    Table 6.5: Migration-generated welfare gains; rural-to-urban migration

    (selectivity bias adjusted)

    Number of

    persons

    Mean

    percentage

    welfare gain

    Percentage

    with welfare

    gain

    Percentage

    without

    welfare gainRural-to-urban

    in-migrants

    523 46.30 68.45

    (Mean % gain

    = 80.05)

    31.55

    (Mean % loss

    = 26.92)

    Rural non-

    migrants

    4,447 -1.97 38.36

    (Mean % gain

    = 55.52)

    61.64

    (Mean loss =

    37.75)

    Rural-to-urban

    in-migrants

    and rural non-

    migrants

    4,970 3.11 41.53

    (Mean % gain

    = 59.77)

    58.47

    (Mean % loss

    = 37.13)

    For the purpose of comparison, Table A8 (in the Appendix) shows welfare-gains from

    rural-to-urban migration when no correction is made for selectivity bias. As can be

    seen, although the two sets of results are different, the disparities are not as large as

    those found for the urban-to-rural analysis. This gives credence to the lack of

    significance of the selectivity variables in the welfare regressions for rural-to-urban

    in-migrants and rural non-migrants (see Table 6.4). The results in Table 6.5 do

    suggest however, that rural residents who migrate to the urban areas tend to be those

    individuals who have a better chance of reaping a welfare-gain.

    h) Impact of return-migration on migrants welfare

    Our multivariate analysis has so far focused on in-migrants. Given the availability of

    data on return-migrants, it is instructive to investigate the impact of migration on the

    welfare of persons who have returned to their origin localities after engaging in either

    urban-to-rural or rural-to-urban migration. Thus, as an ancillary exercise, welfare

    regressions (with return-migrant dummies) are used to examine the impact of

    migration on the welfare of those return-migrants whose previous form of migration

    was urban-to-rural or rural-to-urban. We therefore estimate the following two welfare

    equations:

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    34/42

    34

    i) urbwelf: OLS welfare equation for a pooled sample of urban non-migrantsand rural-to-urban return-migrants (that is, urban-to-rural-to-urban

    migrants);

    ii) rurwelf: OLS welfare equation for a pooled sample of rural non-migrantsand urban-to-rural return-migrants (that is, rural-to-urban-to-rural

    migrants);

    In each of the two equations, the sample consists of non-migrants and return-migrants

    residing in the same locality. This feature non-existent in samples for our main

    model facilitates the use of dummy variables for return-migrant status. The dummy

    variables are defined as follows:

    du1: 1 if urban-to-rural-to-urban migrant, 0 if urban non-migrant;

    dr1: 1 if rural-to-urban-to-rural migrant, 0 if rural non-migrant.

    Table 6.6: Impact of inter-sectoral migration on return-migrants welfare

    -------------------------------------------Variable urbwelf rurwelf

    -------------------------------------------du1 -0.03

    (0.05)

    sex1 -0.09*** -0.02(0.02) (0.01)

    hhsize -0.09*** -0.08***(0.00) (0.00)

    hiedq2 0.09*** 0.05***(0.02) (0.02)

    hiedq3 0.31*** 0.11***(0.03) (0.04)

    hiedq4 0.29*** 0.23***

    (0.05) (0.07)hiedq5 0.45** 0.63**

    (0.22) (0.30)hiedq6 0.00 0.06

    (0.16) (0.15)empcat2 0.02 -0.01

    (0.03) (0.02)

    empcat3 0.07** 0.07*(0.03) (0.04)

    empcat4 0.03 0.09***(0.02) (0.03)

    empcat5 0.09 -0.06*(0.06) (0.04)

    farmliv1 -0.07** -0.02(0.03) (0.03)

    foodpr1 -0.05** -0.03(0.02) (0.02)

    othbus1 0.10*** 0.12***(0.02) (0.02)

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    35/42

    35

    Table 6.6: continued

    -------------------------------------------Variable urbwelf rurwelf

    -------------------------------------------pbw1 0.06** 0.03

    (0.03) (0.02)eg1 0.36*** 0.14***

    (0.03) (0.02)ez2 0.05 0.08***

    (0.04) (0.02)ez3 0.01 0.17***

    (0.06) (0.03)reg1 (Western) 0.27** 1.03***

    (0.11) (0.05)reg2 (Central) -0.18 0.78***

    (0.11) (0.05)reg3 (Gt. Accra) 0.38*** 1.12***

    (0.11) (0.06)

    reg4 (Eastern) 0.08 0.74***(0.10) (0.04)

    reg5 (Volta) -0.00 0.91***(0.11) (0.04)

    reg6 (Ashanti) 0.25** 0.92***(0.11) (0.04)

    reg7 (B.-Ahafo) 0.19* 0.78***(0.11) (0.04)

    reg8 (Northern) 0.12 0.40***(0.10) (0.03)

    reg9 (Upper West) 0.11 0.18***(0.11) (0.04)

    dr1 0.05**

    (0.02)_cons 14.07*** 13.25***

    (0.11) (0.05)-------------------------------------------Number of obs. 2839.00 5437.00R-squared 0.46 0.37

    Adj. R-squared 0.45 0.37F-statistic 85.07 114.00

    -------------------------------------------Legend: * p

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    36/42

    36

    Our findings generally conform to those of the main model. The strong negative link

    between household size and welfare is confirmed. The strength of this link is about

    the same in both urban and rural areas (see Table 6.6). The positive welfare impact of

    education is given further support in both rural and urban samples. In urban areas,

    industrial sector workers tend to have a significantly higher level of welfare than the

    unemployed, whereas in the rural areas it is the services sector workers who are

    significantly better off than the unemployed. The results further highlight regional

    welfare disparities, especially in rural areas; the three northern Regions (Northern,

    Upper West, and Upper East) are shown to have the lowest rural welfare levels, whilst

    the Greater Accra and Western Regions have the highest rural welfare levels.

    We now focus attention on the coefficients of the return-migrant dummies, which are

    the main variables of interest. Even though the coefficient of du1 (the return-

    migrant dummy for the urban sample) has a negative sign, it is not statistically

    significant, thus providing little insight into the welfare impact of migration on return-

    migrants. The coefficient of dr1 (the return-migrant dummy for the rural sample),

    on the other hand, is positive and significant, with a p-value of 0.015. This provides

    evidence in support of return-migrants (that is rural-to-urban-to-rural migrants) being

    better off than rural non-migrants. This finding is consistent with our earlier result

    suggesting that rural-to-urban migration is, on average, very profitable for participants

    (see Table 6.5).

    7. Conclusion

    This paper has examined the impact of migration between rural and urban sectors

    on migrants welfare, using data from Ghanas 1998/99 Living Standards Survey.

    Employing a consumption measure of welfare and a model that corrects for selectivity

    bias, the analysis has also highlighted factors influencing migration decisions between

    Ghanas rural and urban areas.

    Our findings underscore the importance of anticipated welfare gains and personal

    attributes in migration decisions. We also find support for the positive selectivity of

    urban-to-rural migrants. In addition, estimates of migration gains suggest that

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    37/42

    37

    although some migrants incur welfare losses, migration enhances on average the

    welfare of migrants, but would reduce the mean welfare of non-migrants if they were

    to migrate. Finally, the average welfare increment derived by rural-to-urban migrants

    is proportionately much higher than what accrues to their urban-to-rural counterparts.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    38/42

    38

    Appendix

    Table A1: Distribution of migrant type by in- or return-migrant status; 1991/92

    Share (%) of

    in-migrants

    Share (%) of

    return-migrants Total

    Urban-to-urban 74.10 25.90 100.00

    Urban-to-rural 58.75 41.25 100.00

    Rural-to-urban 85.30 14.70 100.00

    Rural-to-rural 77.13 22.87 100.00

    Foreign-to-urban 44.68 55.32 100.00

    Foreign-to-rural 44.78 55.22 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92.

    Table A2: Distribution of migrant type by in- or return-migrant status; 1998/99Share (%) of

    in-migrants

    Share (%) of

    return-migrants Total

    Urban-to-urban 81.25 18.75 100.00

    Urban-to-rural 59.58 40.42 100.00

    Rural-to-urban 83.02 16.98 100.00

    Rural-to-rural 75.51 24.49 100.00

    Foreign-to-urban 50.29 49.71 100.00

    Foreign-to-rural 33.46 66.54 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1998/99.

    Table A3: Extent of migration, by gender; 1991/9211

    Sex Non-migrant share

    (%) of population

    Migrant share (%)

    of population

    Row Total

    Male 45.60

    45.79

    54.40

    46.38

    100.00

    Female 46.19

    54.21

    53.81

    53.62

    100.00

    Column Total 100.00 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92.

    11For each cell in the Table, the first value represents the row percentage, whereas the second

    represents the column percentage.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    39/42

    39

    Table A4: Extent of migration, by gender; 1998/9912

    Sex Non-migrant share

    (%) of population

    Migrant share (%)

    of population

    Row Total

    Male 50.47

    46.70

    49.53

    46.22

    100.00

    Female 50.00

    53.30

    50.00

    53.78

    100.00

    Column Total 100.00 100.00Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1998/99.

    Table A5: Mean consumption welfare (in constant cedis) across migrant status

    and locality of residence; 1991/92

    Migrant status Urban Rural

    In-migrant 1,779,164.7 1,049,810.4

    Return-migrant 1,984,938.8 1,104,967.7

    Non-migrant 1,541,151.7 870,465.35Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1991/92.

    Table A6: Mean consumption welfare (in constant cedis) across migrant status

    and locality of residence; 1998/99

    Migrant status Urban RuralIn-migrant 2,085,238.2 1,341,066.6

    Return-migrant 1,848,170.6 1,215,428.4

    Non-migrant 1,892,204.3 1,053,309.6Source: Authors computation using data from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, 1998/99.

    12For each cell in the Table, the first value represents the row percentage, whereas the second

    represents the column percentage.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    40/42

    40

    Table A7: Migration-generated welfare gains; urban-to-rural migration

    (selectivity bias unadjusted)

    Number of

    persons

    Mean

    percentage

    welfare gain

    Percentage

    with welfare

    gain

    Percentage

    without

    welfare gainUrban-to-rural

    in-migrants

    1,360 30.88 57.87

    (Mean % gain

    = 74.56)

    42.13

    (Mean loss =

    29.17)

    Urban non-

    migrants

    2,720 11.86 46.36

    (Mean % gain

    = 60.84)

    53.64

    (Mean % loss

    = 30.48)

    Urban-to-rural

    in-migrants

    and urban non-

    migrants

    4,080 18.20 50.20

    (Mean % gain

    = 66.13)

    49.80

    (Mean % loss

    = 30.11)

    Table A8: Migration-generated welfare gains; rural-to-urban migration

    (selectivity bias unadjusted)

    Number of

    persons

    Mean

    percentage

    welfare gain

    Percentage

    with welfare

    gain

    Percentage

    without

    welfare gain

    Rural-to-urban

    in-migrants

    523 36.93 63.67

    (Mean % gain= 73.32)

    36.33

    (Mean % loss= 26.85)

    Rural non-

    migrants

    4,447 4.82 42.86

    (Mean % gain

    = 59.37)

    57.14

    (Mean % loss

    = 36.09)

    Rural-to-urban

    in-migrants

    and rural non-

    migrants

    4,970 8.20 45.05

    (Mean % gain

    = 61.44)

    54.95

    (Mean % loss

    = 35.45)

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    41/42

    41

    Bibliography

    Agesa, R.U. (2001). Migration and the Urban to Rural Earnings Difference: A

    Sample Selection Approach,Economic Development and Cultural Change,

    Vol. 49, No. 4, pp. 847-865.

    Caldwell, J.C. (1968). Determinants of Rural-Urban Migration in Ghana,

    Population Studies: A Journal of Demography, 22(3).

    Coulombe, H. and A. McKay (2003), Selective Poverty Reduction in a

    Slow Growth Environment: Ghana in the 1990s, Paper Prepared for the

    World Bank, Human Development Network.

    Falaris, E.M. (1987). A nested logit migration model with selectivity,International

    Economic Review, Vol. 28, No. 2, pp. 429-443.

    Ghana Statistical Service (GSS) (2000), Ghana Living Standards Survey Report of the

    Fourth Round (GLSS 4), Accra, Ghana.

    Hay, M.J. (1980). A Structural Equations Model of Migration in Tunisia,Economic

    Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 28, No. 2, pp. 345-358.

    Heckman, J.L. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error,Econometrica,

    Vol. 47, No. 1, pp. 153-161.

    Lanzona, L.A. (1998). Migration, self-selection and earnings in Philippine rural

    communities,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 56, pp. 27-50.

    Lee, E.S. (1966). A Theory of Migration,Demography, Vol.3, No.1, pp.47-57.

    Lee, L.-F. (1978). Unionism and wage rates: a simultaneous equations model with

    qualitative and limited dependent variables,International Economic Review,

    Vol. 19, No. 2, pp. 415-433.

    Lee, L.-F. (1982). Some Approaches to the Correction of Selectivity Bias, The

    Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 49, No.3, pp. 355-372.

    Litchfield, J. and H. Waddington (2003), Migration and Poverty in Ghana: Evidence

    from the Ghana Living Standards Survey, Sussex Migration Working Paper

    no. 10. Sussex Centre for Migration Research.

    Lucas, R.E.B. and O. Stark (1985). Motivations to Remit: Evidence from Botswana,

    Journal of Political Economy, 93 (5), pp. 901-918.

    Lucas, R.E.B. (1997). Internal Migration in Developing Countries. In M.R.

    Rosenzweig and O. Stark (eds.),Handbook of Population and Family

    Economics, Vol. 1B.

  • 8/13/2019 Migration between Ghanas Rural and Urban Areas

    42/42

    Migration and Household Income Differentials in the Volta Basin of Ghana: A

    Sample Selection Approach, http://economics.ca/2004/papers/0199.pdf,

    accessed on 29 December, 2004.

    Nakosteen, R.A. and M. Zimmer (1980). Migration and Income: The Question of

    Self-Selection, Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 46, Issue 3, pp. 840-851.

    Pessino, C. (1991). Sequential migration theory and evidence from Peru,Journal of

    Development Economics, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 55-87.

    Ravenstein, E.G. (1885). The Laws of Migration,Journal of the Royal Statistical

    Society, Vol.44, pp.420-23.

    Sjaastad, L.A. (1962). The Costs and Returns of Human Migration, The Journal of

    Political Economy, Vol. 70 (Supplement).

    Todaro, M.P. (1969). A Model of Labour Migration and Urban Unemployment in

    Less Developed Countries,American Economic Review, 59, pp.138-149.

    Tunali, I. (2000). Rationality of migration,International Economic Review, Vol. 41,

    No. 4, pp. 893-920.

    Yap, L.Y.L. (1976). Rural-urban migration and urban underemployment in Brazil,

    Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 3, No. 3, pp. 227-243.

    http://economics.ca/2004/papers/0199.pdfhttp://economics.ca/2004/papers/0199.pdf