Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a...

43
Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Monetary Union Matteo Cacciatore HEC Montréal Giuseppe Fiori North Carolina State University Fabio Ghironi § University of Washington, CEPR, EABCN, and NBER July 25, 2015 Abstract This paper addresses the consequences of product and labor market deregulation for monetary policy in a two-country monetary union with endogenous product creation and labor market fric- tions. We show that when regulation is high in both countries, optimal policy requires signicant departures from price stability both in the long run and over the business cycle. The adjust- ment to market reform requires expansionary policy to reduce transition costs, but deregulation reduces static and dynamic ineciencies, making price stability more desirable once the transition is complete. International synchronization of reforms can eliminate policy tradeos generated by asymmetric deregulation. JEL Codes : E24; E32; E52; F41; J64; L51. Keywords : Market deregulation; Monetary union; Optimal monetary policy. For helpful comments, we thank Giancarlo Corsetti, two anonymous referees, Javier Bianchi, Betty Daniel, Antonia Díaz, Andrea Ferrero, Francesco Giavazzi, Alexandre Jeanneret, Athanasios Orphanides, Paolo Pesenti, Alex Twist, and participants in seminars and conferences at Banco de España-Banque de France Conference on “Structural Reforms in the Wake of Recovery: Where Do We Stand?”, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Bo˘ gaziçi University-CEE 2012 Annual Conference, CEPR ESSIM 2013, Deutsche Bundesbank, European Central Bank, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Florida State University, Johns Hopkins University-SAIS, Magyar Nemzeti Bank, NBER IFM November 2012, NBER SI 2013 “Macroeconomics Within and Across Borders,” North Carolina State University, Rutgers University, SED 2012, Shanghai Macroeconomics Workshop 2014, Société Canadienne de Science Économique, University of Bonn, University of California-Riverside, University of Oxford, UQAM, University of Surrey, University of Virginia, University of Washington, and West Coast Workshop on International Finance and Open Economy Macroeconomics 2013. We are grateful to Jonathan Hoddenbagh and Tristan Potter for outstanding research assistance. Remaining errors are our responsibility. Ghironi thanks the NSF for nancial support through a grant to the NBER. Work on this paper was done while Ghironi was a Visiting Scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. The support of this institution is also acknowledged with gratitude. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reect those of the CEPR, the NBER, the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, or Federal Reserve policy. Institute of Applied Economics, HEC Montréal, 3000, chemin de la Côte-Sainte-Catherine, Montréal (Québec), Canada. E-mail: [email protected]. URL: http://www.hec.ca/en/profs/matteo.cacciatore.html Department of Economics, North Carolina State University, 2801 Founders Drive, 4102 Nelson Hall, Box 8110, Raleigh, NC 27695-8110, U.S.A. E-mail: g[email protected]. URL: http://www.giuseppeori.net. § Department of Economics, University of Washington, Savery Hall, Box 353330, Seattle, WA 98195, U.S.A. E-mail: [email protected]. URL: http://faculty.washington.edu/ghiro.

Transcript of Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a...

Page 1: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a Monetary

Union∗

Matteo Cacciatore†

HEC Montréal

Giuseppe Fiori‡

North Carolina State University

Fabio Ghironi§

University of Washington,

CEPR, EABCN, and NBER

July 25, 2015

Abstract

This paper addresses the consequences of product and labor market deregulation for monetary

policy in a two-country monetary union with endogenous product creation and labor market fric-

tions. We show that when regulation is high in both countries, optimal policy requires significant

departures from price stability both in the long run and over the business cycle. The adjust-

ment to market reform requires expansionary policy to reduce transition costs, but deregulation

reduces static and dynamic inefficiencies, making price stability more desirable once the transition

is complete. International synchronization of reforms can eliminate policy tradeoffs generated by

asymmetric deregulation.

JEL Codes: E24; E32; E52; F41; J64; L51.

Keywords: Market deregulation; Monetary union; Optimal monetary policy.

∗For helpful comments, we thank Giancarlo Corsetti, two anonymous referees, Javier Bianchi, Betty Daniel, AntoniaDíaz, Andrea Ferrero, Francesco Giavazzi, Alexandre Jeanneret, Athanasios Orphanides, Paolo Pesenti, Alex Twist, and

participants in seminars and conferences at Banco de España-Banque de France Conference on “Structural Reforms in the

Wake of Recovery: Where Do We Stand?”, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Bogaziçi University-CEE

2012 Annual Conference, CEPR ESSIM 2013, Deutsche Bundesbank, European Central Bank, Federal Reserve Bank of

Boston, Florida State University, Johns Hopkins University-SAIS, Magyar Nemzeti Bank, NBER IFM November 2012,

NBER SI 2013 “Macroeconomics Within and Across Borders,” North Carolina State University, Rutgers University,

SED 2012, Shanghai Macroeconomics Workshop 2014, Société Canadienne de Science Économique, University of Bonn,

University of California-Riverside, University of Oxford, UQAM, University of Surrey, University of Virginia, University

of Washington, and West Coast Workshop on International Finance and Open Economy Macroeconomics 2013. We

are grateful to Jonathan Hoddenbagh and Tristan Potter for outstanding research assistance. Remaining errors are our

responsibility. Ghironi thanks the NSF for financial support through a grant to the NBER. Work on this paper was

done while Ghironi was a Visiting Scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. The support of this institution is also

acknowledged with gratitude. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect

those of the CEPR, the NBER, the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, or Federal Reserve policy.†Institute of Applied Economics, HEC Montréal, 3000, chemin de la Côte-Sainte-Catherine, Montréal (Québec),

Canada. E-mail: [email protected]. URL: http://www.hec.ca/en/profs/matteo.cacciatore.html‡Department of Economics, North Carolina State University, 2801 Founders Drive, 4102 Nelson Hall, Box 8110,

Raleigh, NC 27695-8110, U.S.A. E-mail: [email protected]. URL: http://www.giuseppefiori.net.§Department of Economics, University of Washington, Savery Hall, Box 353330, Seattle, WA 98195, U.S.A. E-mail:

[email protected]. URL: http://faculty.washington.edu/ghiro.

Page 2: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

“I would argue that our current monetary stance in fact makes accelerating structural

reforms desirable, because it brings forward their positive demand effects.” Mario Draghi,

“Structural Reforms, Inflation and Monetary Policy,” Sintra, May 22, 2015.

1 Introduction

The wave of crises that began in 2008 reheated the debate on market deregulation as a tool to improve

economic performance. Calls for removal, or at least reduction, of regulation in goods and labor

markets have been part of the policy discussions on both sides of the Atlantic.1 The argument is that

more flexible markets would foster a more rapid recovery from the recession generated by the crisis

and, in general, would result in better economic performance. Deregulation of product markets would

accomplish this by facilitating producer entry, boosting business creation, and enhancing competition;

deregulation of labor markets would do it by facilitating reallocation of resources and speeding up the

adjustment to shocks. Results in the academic literature support these arguments, but they do not

address the consequences of market deregulation for the conduct of macroeconomic policy.2 Important

questions remain open for researchers and policymakers: What is the optimal macroeconomic policy

response to the dynamics triggered by goods and labor market reform? How does deregulation affect

the tradeoffs facing policymakers in the long-run and over the business cycle?

This paper addresses these questions from the perspective of monetary policy in a monetary union.

We study how deregulation that increases flexibility in product and/or labor markets affects the long-

run inflation target of the welfare-maximizing central bank of a monetary union; how the central bank

responds to the transition dynamics generated by the deregulation; and how deregulation affects the

conduct of optimal monetary policy over the business cycle. We do this in a two-country, dynamic,

stochastic, general equilibrium (DSGE) model of a monetary union with endogenous product creation

subject to sunk costs as in Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2012)–BGM below–and search-and-matching

frictions in labor markets as in Diamond (1982a,b) and Mortensen and Pissarides (1994)–DMP below.

The model contains the most parsimonious set of ingredients that allow us to capture key empirical

1The title on the front page of the February 18, 2012 issue of The Economist (“Over-regulated America”) and the

discussion of increasing regulation of U.S. product markets are indicative of the attention to the issue in the United States.

In August of 2011, then European Central Bank President Jean-Claude Trichet and President-to-be Mario Draghi took

the then unprecedented step of addressing a letter to the Italian government making market deregulation a condition for

the central bank’s intervention in support of Italian government bonds. Calls for structural reforms have since become a

constant in President Draghi’s press conferences and speeches, in those of many other policymakers, and in commentary

in the media. Structural reforms are part of the conditionality imposed on Greece by its creditors in the Greek debt

crisis. In the United States, Lawrence Summers called for “bold reform” of the U.S. economy as a key remedy to “secular

stagnation” (“Bold Reform Is the Only Answer to Secular Stagnation,” Financial Times, September 8, 2014).2See, for instance, Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003), Cacciatore and Fiori (2010), Dawson and Seater (2011), Fiori,

Nicoletti, Scarpetta, and Schiantarelli (2012), Griffith, Harrison, and Macartney (2007), and Messina and Vallanti (2007).

1

Page 3: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

features of product and labor market regulation and reform as well as the narrative by policymakers.

Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry costs (by cutting “red tape”). In

labor markets, deregulation is modeled as a reduction of unemployment benefits and employment

protection (captured by the workers’ bargaining power). We introduce nominal rigidities in the form

of costly price and wage adjustment. We calibrate the model using parameter values from the literature

and to match features of macroeconomic data for Europe’s Economic and Monetary Union (EMU),

and we show that the model successfully reproduces several features of EMU’s business cycles when

the union’s central bank follows an interest rate rule that reproduces the historical behavior of the

European Central Bank (ECB).

We find that regulation in goods and labor markets has significant effects on optimal monetary

policy. In the presence of high market regulation, it is optimal to deviate from price stability in the

long run and over the business cycle. Structural reforms that make product and/or labor markets more

flexible have three consequences for policy: First, the optimal response to deregulation is expansionary,

with a beneficial effect on welfare during the transition relative to the historical policy behavior (which,

in turn, approximates a policy of price stability). Second, when the effects of deregulation are fully

materialized, price stability is more desirable both in the long run (a lower optimal inflation target)

and over the business cycle (smaller optimal deviations of inflation from target). Third, international

synchronization of market reforms is beneficial, as it removes additional policy tradeoffs induced by

heterogeneous market regulation in the monetary union.

The intuition for our results is straightforward. The initial steady state with high regulation in

goods and labor markets is characterized by too high markups and too low job creation. Moreover,

regulation makes cyclical unemployment fluctuations too volatile, which amplifies their welfare cost.

The Ramsey policymaker uses positive long-run inflation (in the ECB’s current target range) to

mitigate long-run inefficiencies, and (s)he uses departures from price stability over the cycle to stabilize

job creation (at the cost of more volatile product creation). Total welfare gains from optimal policy

are not negligible: Implementing the optimal policy increases welfare by approximately 05 percent of

annual steady-state consumption under the historical rule.

Deregulation (even asymmetric across countries) reduces real distortions in goods and labor mar-

kets. Since the benefits take time to materialize, the Ramsey central bank expands monetary policy

more aggressively than the historical ECB to generate lower markups and boost job creation along

the transition.3 Once the beneficial effects of reforms have fully materialized, there is less need of

3 In the case of joint product and labor market deregulation in one country, the welfare gain from the Ramsey-optimal

policy (relative to historical policy) over a three-year horizon is 04 percent of annual pre-deregulation steady-state

consumption in the country that deregulates and 075 percent in the other.

2

Page 4: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

positive long-run inflation to close inefficiency gaps, and price stability over the cycle is less costly

for economies that deregulated their markets. The welfare benefits of optimal policy depend on the

union-wide pattern of deregulation. Asymmetric deregulation introduces a new policy tradeoff for the

Ramsey central bank, because optimal policy must strike a balance between countries that differ in the

desirability of price stability both in the long run and over the cycle. The welfare cost of this additional

tradeoff is not negligible: Ramsey-optimal cooperative monetary policies for national central banks

operating under a flexible exchange rate improve welfare by 014 percent of steady-state consumption

relative to the Ramsey-optimal policy in the monetary union with asymmetric market characteris-

tics. Internationally synchronized reforms remove this tradeoff, resulting in larger welfare gains from

optimal policy: Market reforms are beneficial for welfare under both historical and Ramsey-optimal

policy, but they are more beneficial if monetary policy is chosen optimally, and the benefit increases

if reforms are synchronized.

Before discussing how our paper contributes to the literature, we note what the paper does not

do. While the recent crises have re-heated the debate on market reform, this debate pre-dates the

crises (for instance, Blanchard and Giavazzi’s, 2003, seminal article). Therefore, we do not cast our

exercise in terms of a crisis response–in which deregulation may be implemented as part of the

response to a crisis–and our results on monetary policy do not provide a lens to interpret many ECB

actions during Europe’s sovereign debt crisis.4 Moreover, we abstract from optimal regulation, fiscal

policy considerations (including fiscal aspects of market regulation), and strategic interactions between

policymakers, and we assume full commitment in all our policy exercises, including full commitment

to permanent deregulations. (The assumption of commitment in our analysis of monetary policy is

standard practice in the literature on Ramsey-optimal policy.) We also abstract from distributional

consequences of reforms. While these are important topics for future research, our choices were

motivated by the goal of obtaining a set of intuitive, benchmark results.

Our paper contributes to a large and varied literature on the macroeconomic consequences of

product and labor market regulation and reform. One strand of this literature focuses mostly on the

long-run consequences of market reforms, without addressing the transition dynamics from short- to

long-run effects in general equilibrium. Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) and Hopenhayn and Rogerson

(1993) are seminal contributions in this vein.5 Another strand of research investigates the dynamic

effects of market deregulation, including transition dynamics and business cycle implications of reforms.

4The zero lower bound on interest rates is among the concerns for current monetary policymaking in the Euro Area.

We verified that this constraint never binds in our exercises.5Other contributions include Alessandria and Delacroix (2008), Ebell and Haefke (2009), and Felbermayr and Prat

(2011).

3

Page 5: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Our closest antecedent in this vein of work is Cacciatore and Fiori (2010), who study, both theoretically

and empirically, the dynamic consequences of market deregulation in a real business cycle model with

search and matching frictions and endogenous product creation. To the best of our knowledge, our

study is the first attempt to investigate how market deregulation affects the conduct of monetary policy

in a model that features the product and labor market dynamics at the heart of policy debates.6

Explicit modeling of product and labor market dynamics differentiates our exercise from some

recent analyses of the interaction between structural reforms and monetary policy. Eggertsson, Ferrero,

and Raffo (2014) argue that the deflationary effects of product and labor market reforms can exacerbate

the zero-lower-bound problem.7 Andrés, Arce, and Thomas (2014) study the consequences of market

reforms in an environment of debt deleveraging All these papers do not feature producer entry dynamics

and DMP labor market frictions. They treat reforms as exogenous reductions in price and wage

markups, which “automatically” have deflationary consequences. Gerali, Notarpietro, and Pisani

(2015) show that investment dynamics affect the response of inflation to exogenous markup reductions.

Product and labor market deregulations have inflationary effects in our model, as increased business

creation and a higher value of job matches put upward pressure on wages.

By incorporating a dynamic model of product creation over the business cycle, our paper also

contributes to the recent literature that studies how endogenous entry and product variety affect

business cycles dynamics in closed and open economies. Bergin and Corsetti (2008, 2013), Bilbiie,

Fujiwara, and Ghironi (2014), Cacciatore and Ghironi (2012), Faia (2012), and Lewis (2013) analyze

optimal monetary policy in models with endogenous producer entry, while Chugh and Ghironi (2015)

focus on optimal fiscal policy in the BGM framework. We contribute to this literature by studying

how a determinant of producer entry–regulation–impacts the conduct of monetary policy.

We share the finding of optimal deviations from price stability with several existing studies. Ab-

stracting from market regulation, our model features well-understood channels through which positive

inflation reduces static and dynamic distortions.8 In the long run, positive inflation in product prices

is optimal when the benefit of product variety to consumers falls short of the market incentive for

6Sibert and Sutherland (2000) study how the incentives of policymakers to undertake costly labor market reforms

depend on the international monetary regime (noncooperative monetary policy versus a monetary union). Thomas and

Zanetti (2009) focus on the positive implications of labor market regulation for inflation volatility. On the consequences

of labor market regulation for business cycle volatility in a model with nominal rigidity, see also Zanetti (2011).7See also Fernández-Villaverde, Guerrón-Quintana, and Rubio-Ramírez (2011).8Notice that our results imply that the classic Friedman rule–setting nominal interest rates to zero at all times and

under all circumstances–is never optimal. We share this result with the vast majority of the New Keynesian literature

with nominal rigidity. In the benchmark New Keynesian model with price stickiness as in Calvo (1983) and Yun (1996) or

Rotemberg (1982), the Friedman rule is inefficient because price stickiness in itself implies the optimality of zero inflation

under commitment (which in turn implies equality of real and nominal interest rates). In our model, the balance of

distortions facing the Ramsey central bank implies departure from the Friedman rule in the form of an optimal, positive

inflation rate.

4

Page 6: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

product creation under flexible prices, as in Bilbiie, Fujiwara, and Ghironi (2014). In the short run,

optimal deviations from price stability arise because of the presence of both price and wage rigidity

(as in Erceg, Henderson, and Levin, 2000, and Thomas, 2008), steady-state distortions induced by

(exogenous) monopoly power of firms with endogenous labor supply (as in Benigno and Woodford,

2005, and Faia, 2009), and incomplete international financial markets (as in Corsetti, Dedola, and

Leduc, 2010).9 Our work adds to this literature along two dimensions. First, we show that market

regulation constitutes a hitherto mostly unexplored motive for non-zero optimal inflation, both in

the long-run and over the business cycle: The level of market regulation matters for the quantitative

importance of the distortions discussed above in generating departures from price stability.10 Second,

we show that optimal departures from short-run price stability also emerge as the optimal monetary

policy response to market deregulation.

By allowing for asymmetries between countries in our monetary union, we contribute also to the

study of optimal monetary policy in economies with potentially heterogeneous regions or sectors.11

Finally, an important insight of our analysis in the European context is that the beneficial effects of

structural reforms may come at the cost of weaker current accounts, at least initially. While market

reforms are generally viewed as a way to improve competitiveness and rebalance external positions in

European policy debates and some academic literature (for instance, Corsetti, Martin, and Pesenti,

2013), explicit consideration of the transition dynamics highlights a worsening of the external balance

among the possible transition costs of reforms.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 describes

monetary policy. Section 4 discusses the distortions and inefficiency wedges that characterize the

market economy and presents intuitions on policy tradeoffs and optimal policy. Section 5 studies the

consequences of market regulation and reform for the optimal inflation target and the optimal monetary

policy response to market deregulation. Section 6 addresses the consequences of deregulation for the

conduct of monetary policy over the business cycle. Section 7 concludes.

9Short-run departures from price stability arise also in Arseneau and Chugh’s (2008) sticky-wage DMP model with

exogenous government spending and Ramsey-optimal monetary and tax policy. Government spending alone has been

shown to imply deviations from short-run price stability in several studies. See Adão, Correia, and Teles (2003), Khan,

King, and Wolman (2003), and Woodford (2003, Ch. 6.5).10Our result that price stability is costly in highly regulated economies is consistent with Blanchard and Galí’s (2010)

findings on the consequences of labor market imperfections for optimal monetary policy. Bilbiie, Fujiwara, and Ghironi

(2014) discuss the consequences of product market regulation for optimal inflation, but price stability is (nearly) optimal

over the business cycle in their model.11Aoki (2001) and Benigno (2004) focus on heterogeneity in nominal rigidity.

5

Page 7: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

2 The Model

We model a monetary union that consists of two countries, Home and Foreign. Foreign variables are

denoted with a superscript star. We use the subscript to denote quantities and prices of a country’s

own goods consumed domestically, and the subscript to denote quantities and prices of exports. We

focus on the Home economy in presenting our model, with the understanding that analogous equations

hold for Foreign. We abstract from monetary frictions that would motivate a demand for cash currency

in each country, and we model our monetary union as a cashless economy following Woodford (2003).

Each economy in the union is populated by a unit mass of atomistic households, where each

household is an extended family with a continuum of members along the unit interval. In equilibrium,

some family members are unemployed, while others are employed. As common in the literature, we

assume that family members perfectly insure each other against variation in labor income due to

changes in employment status, so that there is no ex post heterogeneity across individuals in the

household (see Andolfatto, 1996, and Merz, 1995).

Household Preferences

The representative household in the Home economy maximizes the expected intertemporal utility

function

P∞=

−[() − ()], where ∈ (0 1) is the discount factor, is a consumption

basket that aggregates domestic and imported goods as described below, is the number of employed

workers, and denotes hours worked by each employed worker. Period utility from consumption,

(·), and disutility of effort, (·), satisfy the standard assumptions.The consumption basket aggregates bundles and

∗ of Home and Foreign consumption va-

rieties in Armington form with elasticity of substitution 0: =

∙(1− )

1

−1

+ 1

∗−1

¸ −1,

where 0 1. A similar basket describes consumption in the Foreign country. In each country’s

consumption basket, 1 − is the weight attached to the country’s own output bundle. Therefore,

preferences are biased in favor of domestic goods whenever 12. The consumption-based price

index that corresponds to the basket is given by =h(1− )

1− +

∗1−

i 11−. Departures of

from 12 induce deviations from purchasing power parity in our model, implying 6= ∗ (except

in a symmetric steady state).

Following BGM, the number of consumption goods available in each country is endogenously

determined. Denote with Ω and Ω∗ the overall numbers of Home and Foreign goods over which the

preference aggregators and ∗ are defined. At any given , only subsets of goods Ω ⊂ Ω andΩ∗ ⊂ Ω∗ are actually available for consumption at Home.

6

Page 8: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

We assume that the aggregators and ∗ take a translog form following Feenstra (2003a,b).

As a result, the elasticity of substitution across varieties within each sub-basket and ∗ (and

∗ and in the Foreign consumption basket) is an increasing function of the number of goods

available. The translog assumption allows us to capture the pro-competitive effect of goods market

deregulation on (flexible-price) markups. As shown in BGM and Cacciatore and Fiori (2010), lower

entry barriers in production of goods result in increased entry, a larger number of available goods,

and–by inducing higher substitutability–lower markups.12 13

Translog preferences are characterized by defining the unit expenditure function (i.e., the price

index) associated with the preference aggregator. Let () be the price of a variety produced and

sold at Home, and ∗(∗) the price of a variety ∗ produced in the Foreign country and exported to

Home. The unit expenditure function on the basket of domestic goods is given by:

ln =1

2

µ1

− 1

¶+1

Z∈Ω

ln ()

+

2

Z∈Ω

Z0∈Ω

ln ()(ln ()− ln (0))0

where 0, is the total number of Home products available at time , and is the mass of Ω.

The unit expenditure function on the basket of imported goods ∗ is instead given by:

ln ∗ =1

2

µ1

− 1

¶+

1

Z∗∈Ω∗

ln ∗(∗)∗

+

2∗

Z∗∈Ω∗

Z∗0∈Ω∗

ln ∗(∗)(ln ∗(

∗)− ln ∗(∗0))∗∗0

where ∗ is the total number of Foreign products available at time , and ∗ is the mass of Ω∗.14

12As argued in BGM, a demand-, preference-based explanation for time-varying, flexible-price markups is empirically

appealing because the data show that most entering and exiting firms are small, and much of the change in the product

space is due to product switching within existing firms, pointing to a limited role for supply-driven competitive pressures

in markup dynamics.13Translog preferences have been found to have appealing empirical properties in a variety of contexts. BGM show that

translog preferences and endogenous producer entry result in markup dynamics that are remarkably close to U.S. data.

Bergin and Feenstra (2000, 2001) find that a translog expenditure function makes it possible for macro models to generate

empirically plausible endogenous persistence by virtue of the implied demand-side pricing complementarities. Rodríguez-

López (2011) obtains plausible properties for exchange rate pass-through, markup dynamics, and cyclical responses of

firm-level and aggregate variables to shocks. For a review of applications of the translog expenditure function in the

trade literature, see Feenstra (2003b).14Since we will abstract from producer heterogeneity and endogenous determination of the range of traded consump-

tion varieties, the total number of Home (Foreign) varieties available to Home (Foreign) consumers will also be the

number of varieties imported by Foreign (Home). This will imply (Ω) = (Ω), (Ω) = (Ω),

7

Page 9: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Production

In each country, there are two vertically integrated production sectors. In the upstream sector, per-

fectly competitive firms use labor to produce a non-tradable intermediate input. In the downstream

sector, monopolistically competitive firms purchase intermediate inputs and produce the differentiated

varieties that are sold to consumers in both countries. This production structure greatly simplifies the

introduction of labor market frictions in the model.

Intermediate Goods Production

There is a unit mass of intermediate producers. Each of them employs a continuum of workers. Labor

markets are characterized by search and matching frictions as in the DMP framework. To hire new

workers, firms need to post vacancies, incurring a cost of units of consumption per vacancy posted.

The probability of finding a worker depends on a constant-return-to-scale matching technology, which

converts aggregate unemployed workers, , and aggregate vacancies, , into aggregate matches,

= 1− where 0 and 0 1. Each firm meets unemployed workers at a rate

≡. As in Krause and Lubik (2007) and other studies, we assume that newly created matches

become productive only in the next period. For an individual firm, the inflow of new hires in + 1

is therefore , where is the number of vacancies posted by the firm in period . In equilibrium,

= .

Firms and workers separate exogenously with probability ∈ (0 1).15 Separation happens onlybetween firms and workers who were active in production in the previous period. As a result the

law of motion of employment, (those who are working at time ), in a given firm is given by

= (1− )−1 + −1−1.

As Arsenau and Chugh (2008), we use Rotemberg’s (1982) model of nominal rigidity and assume

that firms face a quadratic cost of adjusting the hourly nominal wage rate, . The real cost of

changing the nominal wage between period − 1 and is 22 per worker, where ≥ 0 is in unitsof consumption, and ≡ (−1) − 1 is the net wage inflation rate. If = 0, there is no cost

of wage adjustment. We present an alternative version of the model which allows for nominal wage

(Ω∗) = (Ω∗), and (Ω∗) = (Ω∗). Ghironi and Melitz (2005) introduce heterogeneity and endoge-nous determination of the traded set in an international macroeconomic model with C.E.S. Dixit-Stiglitz preferences.15Endogenous separation would require the introduction of worker heterogeneity. In principle, this would make it

possible to study the consequences of reductions in firing costs as in Cacciatore and Fiori (2010). However, introducing

worker heterogeneity in the presence of nominal wage stickiness would pose a complicated technical challenge. While

abstracting from these ingredients is a limit in the light of policy debates and recent reforms (for instance, in Italy), we

conjecture based on Cacciatore and Fiori’s results that the additional complication would not alter our main messages.

8

Page 10: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

indexation in an Online Appendix–henceforth, referred to simply as Appendix.16

The representative intermediate firm produces output = , where is exogenous aggregate

productivity. The assumption of a unit mass of intermediate producers ensures that is also the

total output of the intermediate sector. We assume that and ∗ follow a bivariate (1) process

in logs, with Home (Foreign) productivity subject to innovations (∗ ). The diagonal elements of

the autoregressive matrix Φ, Φ11 and Φ22, measure the persistence of exogenous productivity and are

strictly between 0 and 1, and the off-diagonal elements Φ12 and Φ21 measure productivity spillovers.

The productivity innovations and ∗ are normally distributed with zero mean and variance-covariance

matrix Σ∗ .

Intermediate goods producers sell their output to final producers at a real price in units of

consumption. Intermediate producers choose the number of vacancies, , and employment, , to

maximize the expected present discounted value of their profit stream:

∞X=

µ −

− −

22

where denotes the marginal utility of consumption in period , subject to the law of motion of

employment. Future profits are discounted with the stochastic discount factor of domestic households,

who are assumed to own Home firms.

Combining the first-order conditions for vacancies and employment yields the following job creation

equation:

=

½+1

∙(1− )

+1+ +1+1+1 − +1

+1+1 −

22+1

¸¾ (1)

where +1 ≡ +1 is the one-period-ahead stochastic discount factor. The job creation

condition states that, at the optimum, the vacancy creation cost incurred by the firm per current

match is equal to the expected discounted value of the vacancy creation cost per future match, further

discounted by the probability of current match survival 1− , plus the future profits from the time-

match. Profits from the match are the difference between the future marginal revenue product from

the match and its wage cost, including nominal wage adjustment costs.

Wage and Hours The nominal wage is the solution to an individual Nash bargaining problem,

and the wage payment divides the match surplus between workers and firms. Due to the presence of

nominal rigidity, we assume that bargaining occurs over the nominal wage rather than the real wage,

16Available at http://faculty.washington.edu/ghiro.

9

Page 11: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

following Arseneau and Chugh (2008), Gertler, Sala, and Trigari (2008), and Thomas (2008). With

zero costs of nominal wage adjustment ( = 0), the real wage that emerges would be identical to the

one obtained from bargaining directly over the real wage. This is no longer the case in the presence

of adjustment costs.

We relegate the details of wage determination to the Appendix. We show there that the equilibrium

sharing rule can be written as = (1 − ), where is the equilibrium bargaining share

of firms, is worker surplus, and is firm surplus (see the Appendix for the expressions). As in

Gertler and Trigari (2009), the equilibrium bargaining share is time-varying due to the presence of

wage adjustment costs. Absent these costs, we would have a time-invariant bargaining share = ,

where is the weight of firm surplus in the Nash bargaining problem. Importantly, wage rigidity

implies that is procyclical, and its steady-state level is an increasing function of wage and product

price inflation.

The bargained wage satisfies:

=

µ()

+

¶+ (1− )

µ −

22

¶+

½+1+1

∙(1− )(1− )− (1− − )(1− +1)

+1

¸¾ (2)

where () + is the worker’s outside option (the utility value of leisure plus an unemployment

benefit ), and is the probability of becoming employed at time , defined by ≡ . With

flexible wages, the third term in the right-hand side of this equation reduces to (1− )

¡+1+1

¢,

or, in equilibrium, (1− ) . In this case, the real wage bill per worker is a linear combination–

determined by the constant bargaining parameter –of the worker’s outside option and the marginal

revenue product generated by the worker (net of wage adjustment costs) plus the expected discounted

continuation value of the match to the firm (adjusted for the probability of employment). When wages

are sticky, the current wage bill reflects also expected changes in bargaining shares.

As common practice in the literature, we assume that hours per worker are determined by firms and

workers in a privately efficient way to maximize the joint surplus of the employment relation, +.

(See, among others, Thomas, 2008, and Trigari, 2009.) Maximization yields a standard intratemporal

optimality condition for hours worked that equates the marginal revenue product of hours per worker

to the marginal rate of substitution between consumption and leisure: = , where is

the marginal disutility of effort.

10

Page 12: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Final Goods Production

In each country, there is a continuum of monopolistically competitive final-sector firms, each of them

producing a different variety.17 Final goods are produced using domestic intermediate inputs, and

they are sold domestically and abroad.18

Absent trade costs, and since all goods are traded in the model, the law of one price holds, implying

that: () = () and = , where and are the maximum prices that Home producer

can charge in the Home and Foreign markets while still having positive market share. Differently

from Bergin and Feenstra (2001), translog preferences do not imply pricing-to-market in our model.

This happens because producers face the same elasticity of substitutions across domestic and export

markets when all goods are traded.19 The only difference implied by translog preferences relative to

the C.E.S. case is that the symmetric elasticity of substitution is not constant, but it varies in response

to changes in the number of competitors.

As shown in the Appendix, total demand for final Home producer can be written as:

() + () = ln

µ

()

()

µ

¶− h(1− )

+

i

where and ∗

denote aggregate demand of the final consumption basket at Home and abroad,

recognizing that aggregate demand of the final basket in each country includes sources other than

household consumption. Aggregate demand in each country takes the same Armington form as the

country’s consumption basket, with the same elasticity of substitution 0 between demand sub-

bundles of Home and Foreign products ( and ∗ at Home, and ∗ and in Foreign), which

take the same translog form as the sub-bundles in consumption. This ensures that the consumption

price index and the price sub-indexes for the translog consumption aggregators in each country are

also the price index and sub-indexes for aggregate demand of the final basket and sub-bundles.

We introduce price stickiness by following Rotemberg (1982) and assuming that final produc-

ers must pay a quadratic price adjustment cost Γ() ≡ 2()()(() + ())2, where

17Following the convention in BGM, Ghironi and Melitz (2005), and much macroeconomic literature, we refer to an

individual final-good producer as a firm. However, as discussed in BGM and Ghironi and Melitz (2005), final-sector

productive units in the model are best interpreted as product lines at multi-product firms whose boundaries we leave

unspecified by exploiting continuity. In this interpretation, producer entry and exit capture the product-switching

dynamics within firms documented by Bernard, Redding, and Schott (2010).18We do not assume separate productivity shocks in the final production sector, which implies that marginal production

cost in this sector is simply . However, if we re-cast intermediate-sector firms as the “labor-intensive” departments of

(integrated) final-sector firms, measures the effectiveness of labor in final goods production.19See the Appendix for the proof. The absence of trade barriers from our model is consistent with the operation of

the European Union’s Single Market. Transition to the euro narrowed price dispersion across country markets (Martin

and Méjean, 2013), supporting the law of one price as a reasonable first approximation to reality.

11

Page 13: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

≥ 0 determines the size of the adjustment cost (prices are flexible if = 0) and () ≡(()−1()) − 1.20 (In the Appendix, we also consider the case of price indexation.) When

a new final-good firm sets the price of its output for the first time, we appeal to symmetry across

producers and interpret the − 1 price in the expression of the price adjustment cost as the notionalprice that the firm would have set at time − 1 if it had been producing in that period. An intuitionfor this simplifying assumption is that all producers (even those that are setting the price for the first

time) must buy the bundle of goods Γ() when implementing a price decision.21

Total real profits are given by () =h()

³1− 2()2

´ −

i(() + ()). All

profits are returned to households as dividends. Firms maximize the expected present discounted

value of the stream of current and future real profits:

∞X=

[(1− )]− () (). Future

profits are discounted with the Home household’s stochastic discount factor, as Home households are

assumed to own Home final goods firms. As discussed below, there is a probability ∈ (0 1) that eachfinal good producer is hit by an exogenous, exit-inducing shock at the end of each period. Therefore,

discounting is adjusted for the probability of firm survival.

Optimal price setting implies that the (real) output price () ≡ () is equal to a markup

() over marginal cost : () = (). The endogenous, time-varying markup () is given

by () ≡ () [(()− 1)Ξ], where () = − ln (() + ()) ln () denotes the

price elasticity of total demand for variety , and:

Ξ ≡ 1−

22 ()

+

()− 1

⎧⎨⎩ (() + 1)()

h+1 (1− ) (+1() + 1)+1()

+1()

()

³+1()++1()

()+()

´i⎫⎬⎭

There are two sources of endogenous markup variation in our model: First, translog preferences

imply that substitutability across varieties increases with the number of available varieties. As a

consequence, the price elasticity of total demand facing producer increases when the number of

20The total real adjustment cost can be interpreted as the bundle of goods that the firm needs to purchase when

implementing a price change. The size of this bundle is assumed to be larger when the size of the firm (measured by its

revenue) increases.21As noted in Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2008a), this assumption is consistent with both Rotemberg (1982) and

our timing assumption below. Specifically, new entrants behave as the (constant number of) price setters in Rotemberg,

where an initial condition for the price is dictated by nature. In our framework, new entrants at any time who start

producing and setting prices at + 1 are subject to an analogous assumption. Moreover, the assumption that a new

entrant, at the time of its first price decision, knows what will turn out to be the average Home product price last period

is consistent with the assumption that entrants start producing only one period after entry, hence being able to observe

the average product price during the entry period. Symmetry of the equilibrium will imply −1 () = −1∀. Bilbiie,Ghironi, and Melitz (2008a) show that relaxing the assumption that new price setters are subject to the same rigidity

as incumbents yields significantly different results only if the average rate of product turnover is unrealistically high.

12

Page 14: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Home producers is larger. Second, price stickiness introduces an additional source of markup variation

as the cost of adjusting prices gives firms an incentive to change their markups over time in order to

smooth price changes across periods. When prices are flexible ( = 0), only the first source of markup

variation is present, and the markup reduces to ()(()− 1).Given the law of one price, the real export price (relative to the Foreign price index ∗ ) is given

by () ≡ ()∗ = ()

∗ = () = (), where is the consumption-based

real exchange rate: ≡ ∗ .

Producer Entry and Exit Prior to entry, final sector firms face a sunk entry cost in units of

intermediate input.22 Sunk entry costs reflect both a technological constraint () and administrative

costs related to regulation (), i.e., ≡ +. In every period , there is an unbounded mass

of prospective entrants in the final goods sector in each country. Prospective entrants are forward-

looking and form rational expectations of their future profits in any period subject to the

exogenous probability of incurring an exit-inducing shock at the end of each period. Following

BGM and Ghironi and Melitz (2005), we introduce a time-to-build lag in the model and assume that

entrants at time will start producing only at + 1. Prospective entrants compute their expected

post-entry value , given by the expected present discounted value of the stream of per-period profits

: =

P∞=+1 [ (1− )]− () . Entry occurs until firm value is equalized to the entry

cost, leading to the free entry condition = .23 Our assumptions on exit shocks and the timing

of entry and production imply that the law of motion for the number of producing Home firms is given

by = (1− )(−1 +−1).

Household Budget Constraint and Intertemporal Decisions

The representative household can invest in two types of assets: shares in mutual funds of final-sector

and intermediate-sector firms and a non-contingent, internationally traded bond denominated in units

of the common currency.24 Investment in the mutual fund of final-sector firms in the stock market is

the mechanism through which household savings are made available to prospective entrants to cover

their entry costs. Since there is no entry in the intermediate sector (and, therefore, no need to channel

resources from households for the financing of such entry), we do not model trade in intermediate-

22This assumption replicates the assumption in BGM and Ghironi and Melitz (2005) that the same input is used to

produce existing varieties and create new ones.23This condition holds as equality in each period as long as the mass of new entrants is always positive. We

verified that this is the case in our exercises.24For simplicity, we assume extreme home bias in equity holdings and rule out international trade in firm shares. See

Hamano (2015) for a version of the Ghironi-Melitz (2005) model with international trade in equities.

13

Page 15: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

sector equity explicitly, but simply assume that the profits of intermediate sector firms are rebated to

households in lump-sum fashion.25

Let be the share in the mutual fund of Home final-sector firms held by the representative

household entering period . The mutual fund pays a total profit in each period (in units of currency)

that is equal to the total profit of all firms that produce in that period, . During period , the

representative household buys +1 shares in a mutual fund of + firms (those already operating

at time and the new entrants). Only a fraction 1− of these firms will produce and pay dividends attime +1. Since the household does not know which firms will be hit by the exogenous exit shock at

the end of period , it finances the continuing operation of all pre-existing firms and all new entrants

during period . The date price of a claim to the future profit stream of the mutual fund of +

firms is equal to the nominal price of claims to future profits of Home firms, .

Let +1 denote nominal bond holdings at Home entering period + 1. To induce steady-state

determinacy and stationary responses to temporary shocks in the model, we follow Turnovsky (1985)

and, more recently, Benigno (2009), and we assume a quadratic cost of adjusting bond holdings

(+1)2 2 (in units of Home consumption). This cost is paid to financial intermediaries whose

only function is to collect these transaction fees and rebate the revenue to households in lump-sum

fashion.

The Home household’s period budget constraint is:

+1 +

2

µ+1

¶2+ + +1 ( +) =

(1 + ) + ( + ) + + (1− ) + +

+

where is the nominal interest rate on the internationally traded bond, is a lump-sum transfer

(or tax) from the government, is the lump-sum rebate of the cost of adjusting bond holdings

from the financial intermediaries, and is the lump-sum rebate of profits from intermediate goods

producers.26 We use the timing convention in Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) for the nominal interest

rate: +1 is the interest rate between and + 1, and it is known with certainty in period .

25As long as the wage negotiated by workers and firms is inside the bargaining set (and, therefore, smaller than or equal

to the firm’s outside option), the surplus from a match that goes to the firm is positive, even if intermediate producers

are perfectly competitive. Since all workers are identical, the total surplus of the intermediate sector is positive, and so

is the profit rebated to households.26 In equilibrium,

= − (1− ) ,

=

2

+1

2, and

=

− −

22

14

Page 16: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Let +1 ≡ +1 denote Home real bond holdings. Euler equations for bond and share holdings

are:

1 + +1 = (1 + +1)

£+1(1 + +1)

−1¤ and = (1− )

£+1 (+1 + +1)

¤

where ≡ (−1) − 1 is net consumer price inflation. As expected, forward iteration of theequation for shares and absence of speculative bubbles yield the expression for firm value used in

the free entry condition above.27 We present the details of the symmetric equilibrium of our model

economy in the Appendix, and we limit ourselves to presenting the law of motion for net foreign assets

below.

Net Foreign Assets and the Trade Balance

Bonds are in zero net supply, which implies the equilibrium condition +1+∗+1 = 0 in all periods.

We show in the Appendix that Home net foreign assets are determined by:

+1 = (1 + ) + −∗

where1 + ≡ (1 + ) (1 + ) denotes the real interest rate. The change in net foreign assets

between and + 1 is determined by the current account: +1 − = ≡ + , where

is the trade balance: ≡ −∗

∗.

3 Monetary Policy

We compare the Ramsey-optimal conduct of monetary policy to a representation of historical behavior

for the central bank of our model EMU, captured by a standard rule for interest rate setting in the

spirit of Taylor (1993), Woodford (2003), and much other literature.

Data-Consistent Variables and Historical Monetary Policy

The ECB has a mandate of price stability defined in terms of a (harmonized) index of consumer price

inflation. Since we will calibrate the model to features of EMU, we specify historical interest rate

setting for our model ECB as a rule in which policy responds to movements in a country-weighted

average of CPI inflation and GDP gaps relative to the equilibrium with flexible wages and prices.

27We omit the transversality conditions that must be satisfied to ensure optimality.

15

Page 17: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

In the presence of endogenous producer entry and preferences that exhibit “love for variety,” an

issue concerns the empirically relevant variables that enter the theoretical representation of historical

policy. As highlighted by Ghironi and Melitz (2005) and BGM, the welfare-consistent aggregate price

index can fluctuate even if product prices remain constant. In the data, however, aggregate price

indexes do not take these variety effects into account.28 To resolve this issue, we follow Ghironi and

Melitz (2005) and BGM and introduce the data-consistent price index ≡ Ω1(−1) , where Ω is

an adjustment for product variety defined by:

Ω ≡ (1− ) exp

à −

2

!+ exp

Ã∗ −∗

2∗∗

!

where exp() denotes the exponential of to avoid confusion with the notation for firm value.

Multiplication of the welfare-consistent price index by Ω1(−1) removes unmeasured, pure variety

effects and delivers a price index that is closer to available CPI data.29 Given any variable in units

of consumption, we then construct its data-consistent counterpart as ≡ Ω1

−1 . (Additional

details are in the Appendix.)

Given data-consistent price indexes and GDPs for Home and Foreign, we assume the following

interest rate rule to describe historical policy:

1 + +1 = (1 + )h(1 + )

¡1 +

¢ ³

´ i1− (3)

where ≡

∗1− is data-consistent, union-wide CPI inflation, and

∗1−

is the

data-consistent, union-wide GDP gap. Since Home and Foreign have identical size, we set = =

05.30

Table 1 summarizes the key equilibrium conditions of the model, including the policy rule (3). We

rearranged some equations appropriately for transparency of comparison to the planner’s optimum

described below, which we will use to build intuition for the tradeoffs facing the Ramsey policymaker.

28There is much empirical evidence that gains from variety are mostly unmeasured in CPI data, as documented most

recently by Broda and Weinstein (2010).29See also Feenstra (1994).30Benigno (2004) shows that the optimal inflation target for the central bank of a monetary union should attach a

larger weight to inflation in the country where nominal rigidity is more pervasive. We abstract from differences in nominal

rigidity across countries in our exercise, which is consistent with setting = 05 in the absence of asymmetries. We

explore below the consequences of optimally determining and in the presence of asymmetries in market regulation.

16

Page 18: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Ramsey-Optimal Monetary Policy

The Ramsey central bank maximizes aggregate welfare under the constraints of the competitive econ-

omy. Let Λ1 Λ20 be the Lagrange multipliers associated with the equilibrium conditions in Table

1 (excluding the interest rate rule).31 The Ramsey problem consists of choosing Λ1 Λ20∞=0 and

∗ ∗ ∗

∗+1

∗+1 +1 +1∞=0

to maximize:

0

∞X=0

∙1

2( ()− ()) +

1

2( (∗ )− ∗ (

∗ ))

¸(4)

subject to the constraints in Table 1 (excluding the interest rate rule).32

As common practice in the literature, we write the original non-stationary Ramsey problem in

recursive stationary form by enlarging the planner’s state space with additional (pseudo) co-state

variables. Such co-state variables track the value to the planner of committing to the pre-announced

policy plan along the dynamics.

4 Inefficiency Wedges and Policy Tradeoffs

The Ramsey planner uses its policy instrument (the interest rate) to address the consequences of a

set of distortions that exist in the market economy. To understand these distortions and the tradeoffs

they create for optimal policy, it is instructive to compare the equilibrium conditions of the market

economy summarized in Table 1 to those implied by the solution to the first-best, optimal planning

problem. This allows us to define inefficiency wedges for the market economy (relative to the planner’s

optimum) and describe Ramsey policy in terms of its implications for these wedges.

We relegate the details of the planning problem and the analytical derivation of the inefficiency

wedges to the Appendix. Table 2 summarizes the equilibrium conditions for the efficient allocation,

and Table 3 summarizes the distortions that characterize the decentralized economy.

31We assume that the other variables that appear in the table have been substituted out by using the appropriate

equations and definitions above.32 In the primal approach to Ramsey policy problems described by Lucas and Stokey (1983), the competitive equilibrium

is expressed in terms of a minimal set of relations involving only real allocations. In the presence of sticky prices and

wages, it is impossible to reduce the Ramsey planner’s problem to a maximization problem with a single implementability

constraint.

17

Page 19: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Inefficiency Wedges

Our model features several sources of distortion: Some are familiar ingredients in New Keynesian

macroeconomics; Others arise from our microfoundation of product and labor market dynamics and

frictions. The distortions affect five margins of adjustment and the resource constraint for consumption

output:

Product creation margin: Several distortions impinge on the product creation margin in

each country. Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2008b) show that time-variation of markups is ineffi-

cient. In our model, the markup is time-varying because of translog preferences and sticky prices.

We summarize this source of inefficiency with the distortion effect Υ ≡¡−1

¢ − 1. More-

over, both price stickiness and translog preferences imply that the (time-varying) net markup is

not aligned with the benefit of product variety to consumers, resulting in the misalignment effect

Υ ≡ −1³1− 1 − 22

´− 1(2). These distortions are at work in Bilbiie, Fujiwara,

and Ghironi (2014)–BFG below. The product creation margin in our model is distorted also by the

existence of a non-technological component, , of the overall entry cost, , which results in the

regulation distortion Υ ≡ .33 The distortions Υ, Υ, Υ combine into a wedge Σ that

differentiates the Euler equation for product creation in the market economy from the corresponding

equation in the planner’s optimum.

Job creation margin: A wedge Σ similarly results from several distortions that affect each

economy’s job creation margin. Monopoly power distorts the job creation decision by inducing a

suboptimally low return from vacancy posting, captured by Υ ≡ (1) − 1. Failure of the Hosioscondition (for which equality of the firm’s bargaining share and the vacancy elasticity of the matching

function is necessary for efficiency in the absence of other distortions) is an additional distortion in

this margin, measured by Υ ≡ − .34 The distortion Υ is affected both by the flexible-wage

value of the bargaining share (, which can be different from ) and the presence of wage stickiness,

which makes the equilibrium bargaining share endogenous to inflation. Moreover, sticky wages distort

job creation also by affecting the outside option of firms through the additional term Υ ≡ 22.

Finally, unemployment benefits increase the workers’ outside option above its efficient level: Υ ≡ .

33Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2008b) and Chugh and Ghironi (2015) consider the case = − and discussthe determination of optimal product creation subsidies in a first- or second-best environment, respectively. We focus

on the consequences of an exogenous deregulation that reduces non-technological barriers to entry, abstracting from the

issue of optimal entry subsidies (or taxes).34 In the presence of other distortions, the basic, flexible-wage Hosios condition = must be adjusted to include

an appropriate additional term in order to deliver efficiency in job creation. We are grateful to Sanjay Chugh and

Guillaume Rocheteau for clarifying this point. For simplicity of exposition and consistency with much literature (for

instance, Arseneau and Chugh, 2012), we simply refer to the condition = as the Hosios condition below.

18

Page 20: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Labor supply margin: With endogenous labor supply, monopoly power in product markets

induces a misalignment of relative prices between consumption goods and leisure, resulting in the

wedge Σ ≡ Υ+1, which is time-varying because of translog preferences and sticky prices. Except

for translog preferences, this is the distortion that characterizes standard New Keynesian models

with monopolistic competition, which typically assume C.E.S. Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) preferences. This

distortion is at work also in BFG. The prescription of price stability that arises from many New

Keynesian models in which price stickiness is the only cause of markup variation can be interpreted

as a prescription of smoothing the dynamics of the wedge Σ.

Cross-country risk sharing margin: Incomplete markets imply departures from efficient risk

sharing across countries resulting in the wedge Σ ≡ (∗) . This wedge is affected also

by the costs of adjusting bond holdings, which introduce the distortion Υ ≡ +1 and its Foreign

mirror image in the Euler equations for Home and Foreign holdings of bonds.35

International relative price margin: As long as the model does not satisfy the conditions

such that a fixed exchange rate is optimal, monetary union distorts real exchange rate dynamics by

removing adjustment through the nominal exchange rate: −1 =³1 + ∗

´ (1 + ).

36 This

distortion cannot be summarized into an analytically defined wedge because the planned economy

does not feature nominal rigidity. (As a consequence, Table 3 does not include an expression for this

distortion.)

Consumption resource constraint: Sticky wages and prices and “red tape” imply diversion

of resources from consumption and creation of new product lines and vacancies, with the distortions

Υ ≡ 22, Υ ≡ 22, and Υ combining into a wedge Σ .

The market allocation is efficient if and only if all the distortions are eliminated and the associated

inefficiency wedges are closed at all points in time.37

Tradeoffs and Intuitions for Optimal Policy

The Ramsey central bank optimally uses its leverage on the economy via the sticky-price and sticky-

wage distortions, trading off their costs (including the resource costs) against the possibility of address-

ing the distortions that characterize the market economy under flexible wages and prices. Although

35The standard risk sharing condition under complete markets implies ∗ = κ, where κ is a constant of

proportionality that captures asymmetries in the initial steady-state position of the two economies. Under assumption

of zero initial net foreign assets and symmetric countries, it is κ = 1, implying the expression we are assuming for the

risk sharing wedge.36With flexible exchange rates, it would be −1 =

1 + ∗

[(1 + )−1], where is the nominal ex-

change rate (units of Home currency per unit of Foreign currency).37Given our definitions of distortions and wedges, this implies Σ = Σ = Σ = Σ = 1 and Σ = 0.

19

Page 21: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

the model features multiple distortions, several of them have the same qualitative implications for

optimal policy. Therefore, for any given level of market regulation, the Ramsey central bank actually

faces a small number of policy tradeoffs–with intuitive implications for optimal policy–both in the

long run and over the business cycle.

Optimal Monetary Policy in the Long Run

It is immediate to verify that long-run inflation in product-level and consumption prices is always

symmetric across countries regardless of symmetry or asymmetry of the calibration. This result

follows from the presence of a common nominal interest rate in the monetary union, the steady-state

Euler equations of households, and the expressions of price indexes: 1 + = 1 + = (1 + ) =

1 + ∗ = 1 + ∗. Moreover, wage inflation is always equal to producer price inflation: = .

To begin understanding policy incentives in the long run, notice that a symmetric long-run equi-

librium with constant endogenous variables eliminates some distortions: A constant markup removes

the markup variation distortion from the product creation margin (Υ = 0); The risk-sharing dis-

tortion of incomplete markets is eliminated in the deterministic steady state, and constant, zero net

foreign assets eliminate the effect of bond adjustment costs, so that Σ = 1; Finally, symmetry also

eliminates the international relative price distortion of monetary union by implying = 1.

All the remaining steady-state distortions but the costs of wage and price adjustment require

a reduction of markups. As discussed in Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2008b) and BFG, translog

preferences imply that the steady-state, flexible-price markup is higher than the benefit of product

variety to the consumer. Ceteris paribus, this results in suboptimal product creation. Smaller net

markups contribute to realigning the firms’ incentive for product creation and the consumers’ benefit

from variety. Moreover, a smaller markup narrows the wedge in labor supply and results in increased

vacancy posting by firms. A decrease in steady-state markups can be achieved by means of positive

net inflation. At the same time, since = , positive inflation implies a departure from the

Hosios condition (the steady-state level of rises above ), increasing the bargaining power of firms.

Compared to the zero inflation outcome, a positive long-run inflation rate can reduce the inefficiency

wedges in product creation (Σ), job creation (Σ), and labor supply (Σ). However, the Ramsey

authority must trade the beneficial welfare effects of reducing these distortions against the costs of

non-zero inflation implied by allocating resources to price and wage changes and by the departure

from the Hosios condition.

20

Page 22: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Optimal Monetary Policy over the Business Cycle

Stochastic fluctuations in aggregate productivity modify the policy tradeoffs facing the Ramsey au-

thority by reintroducing the distortions eliminated by symmetry and absence of time variation in

steady state. Moreover, Ramsey-optimal long-run policy does not close the remaining steady-state in-

efficiency wedges completely. Thus, the Home and Foreign economies fluctuate around a steady state

where markups and unemployment are inefficiently high. As a result, shocks trigger larger fluctuations

in product and labor markets (in both economies) than in the efficient allocation: Both producer entry

and unemployment are suboptimally volatile.

What are the policy tradeoffs facing the Ramsey central bank over the business cycle? First,

as in steady state, there is a tension between the beneficial effects of manipulating inflation and its

costs. Second, there is a tradeoff between stabilizing price inflation (which contributes to stabilizing

markups) and wage inflation (which stabilizes unemployment) in the country affected by a shock.

Therefore, it is impossible to stabilize unemployment and markups jointly. Third, there is a tension

between stabilizing the Home and Foreign economies in response to asymmetric shocks.

These three policy tradeoffs explain why a policy of price stability can be suboptimal: Under this

policy, wage inflation is too volatile, and markup stabilization correspondingly too strong. Following

fluctuations in aggregate productivity, sticky wages and positive unemployment benefits generate real

wage rigidities, i.e., a positive (negative) productivity shock is not fully absorbed by the rise (fall) of

the real wage, affecting job creation over the cycle. Higher Home productivity pushes the real wage

above its steady-state level, as the real value of existing matches has increased. Under a policy of

price stability, the effect of wage stickiness is magnified, since the real wage becomes even more rigid.

Firms post too many vacancies and, in equilibrium, nominal wage adjustment costs are too large.38

5 Optimal Inflation and the Monetary Policy Response to Market Deregulation

How does market deregulation affect optimal monetary policy? Structural policy changes pose a set

of challenges for the central bank. First, reforms have permanent effects that may alter the optimal

long-run inflation target. Second, monetary policy can shape the dynamic adjustment to the new

long-run equilibrium. Third, deregulation affects the way economies respond to aggregate shocks,

with consequences for the optimal conduct of monetary policy over the business cycle. Finally, new

policy tradeoffs emerge for the central bank if deregulation is asymmetric across members of the

38Notice, however, that a policy that completely stabilizes wage inflation is also suboptimal. In this case, there would

be too much inflation and markup volatility, and the response of unemployment would be too small.

21

Page 23: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

monetary union, raising the question of desirability of coordinated reforms.

In this Section, we study the optimal monetary policy response to market deregulation during

the transition dynamics and in the long run. In the next Section, we consider monetary policy over

the business cycle. We use numerical illustrations to substantiate the general intuitions presented

in the previous Section. We calibrate the model to match quarterly Euro Area macroeconomic data

from 1995:Q1 to 2013:Q1. In the Appendix, we present a detailed description of our calibration,

which is assumed symmetric across countries. Following standard practice, we set parameter values

so that the model replicates long-run features of the data in the zero-inflation steady state. We

show in the Appendix that the model successfully replicates several features of the Euro Area business

cycle, including (at least qualitatively) moments that represent a traditional challenge for international

business cycle models. The Appendix also presents a summary of results obtained from a sensitivity

analysis on the values of several key parameters. Our results are robust to the alternative calibrations

we consider.

In our exercises, we assume that both countries start at high levels of regulation and consider

a joint reduction in goods and labor market regulation. (The cases of separate product and labor

market reforms are presented in the Appendix. Many results are qualitatively similar to the case of

comprehensive product and labor market reform we focus on here.) We study both symmetric and

asymmetric reforms across the two members of the monetary union.39 Product market deregulation

is modeled as a permanent decrease of regulatory barriers to product creation, . Labor market

reform is instead a permanent reduction of unemployment benefits, , and employment protection,

proxied by the workers’ bargaining power parameter 1− as in Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003). We

treat deregulations as unanticipated, permanent policy shocks that are fully implemented in the impact

period.40 Market reforms change the levels of the relevant parameters from the initial Euro-Area-based

calibration to the levels for the U.S. economy, a standard benchmark for flexible markets. Details are

in the Appendix.41

39 It could be argued that the scenario in which both countries start at high levels of regulation and one of them

deregulates captures features of the dynamics after Germany’s labor market reforms initiated by then Chancellor Gerhard

Schröder in 2003. The current debate in Europe would have the countries with rigid markets catch up with Germany.

Our model does not capture the tax reductions that were part of the German experience. We also explored the scenario

in which Foreign deregulates its markets starting from a situation in which Home’s markets are already flexible. The

dynamics of the Foreign country in that case are very similar to those of the Home country described below. Details are

available on request.40Deregulations involving changes in legislation are likely anticipated by the time they happen, and deregulations

may be implemented over time. However, our assumption is a useful benchmark in the absence of information on the

duration of parliamentary debates, legislative processes, and implementation periods. We present results on anticipated

deregulations in the Appendix.41Notice that there is no presumption that the U.S. market regulation levels we use should be optimal for the Euro

Area (or for the United States, for that matter). The optimal design of product and labor market regulation and reform

is a first-order issue, which also raises the question of strategic interactions between government (regulators) and the

22

Page 24: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Given the large size of the deregulation shocks, we compute the responses to these shocks without

relying on local approximations by using the Newton-type algorithm first proposed by Laffargue (1990).

The details of the algorithm can be found in Juillard (1996). In all the figures below, the impulse

responses of the inefficiency wedges that we plot show the percent changes of the wedge deviations

from efficiency.

Asymmetric Market Deregulation

As shown in Table 4, the optimal long-run target for net inflation under the high regulation sce-

nario of our historical calibration is indeed positive and equal to 115 percent–in the range of the

ECB’s mandate. (Inflation results in Table 4 are annualized.) Table 5 shows that the welfare gains

from implementing the Ramsey-optimal inflation target in the high-regulation steady state amount to

approximately 035 percent of steady-state consumption.42

The finding of an optimal positive long-run inflation is in contrast with the prescription of near

zero inflation delivered by the vast majority of New Keynesian models. While the costs of inflation

outweigh the benefits of reducing other distortions in those models, this is no longer the case with a

richer microfoundation of product and labor markets.43 Importantly, the result of a positive Ramsey

inflation target is not an “automatic” consequence of assuming a form of nominal rigidity that implies

long-run non-neutrality of money. As shown in BFG, the same form of price stickiness implies a

zero Ramsey-optimal inflation target in the sticky-price BGM model if preferences take the C.E.S.

Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) form that is common in the New Keynesian literature. The additional distortions

introduced in our model imply the optimality of positive long-run inflation. Moreover, consistent with

results in BFG, Table 4 shows that the optimal long-run inflation target increases up to 231 percent in

the presence of both price and wage indexation as commonly introduced in the literature. The reasons

for this result are twofold: First, indexation lowers the welfare cost associated with a given long-run

inflation rate (steady-state adjustment costs are decreasing in indexation rates). Second, indexation

central bank. We leave this issue for future research. Results in Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2008b) and Chugh and

Ghironi (2015) provide initial insights into optimal product market policy in the BGM model.42We measure the welfare gains from the Ramsey policy by computing the percentage increase in consumption that

would leave households indifferent between policy regimes. Implementing the optimal policy implies transition dynamics

as the Home and Foreign economies adjust to the new steady state with a positive inflation target. Welfare under the

optimal policy accounts also for these transition dynamics. There are no transition dynamics under the historical policy

as there is no change in steady-state inflation from the initial level of zero. Note that our results are not sensitive to the

choice of (identical) initial conditions for the state variables. Additional details on our welfare computations are in the

Appendix.43A similar result arises in BFG’s closed economy model with a Walrasian labor market and flexible wages. Cacciatore

and Ghironi (2012) show that labor market frictions and sticky wages are sufficient to generate significant departures

from zero optimal long-run inflation under flexible exchange rates.

23

Page 25: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

requires larger inflation to achieve a given change in long-run markup and bargaining power of firms.44

Consider now a joint reduction in barriers to firm entry, unemployment benefits, and worker

bargaining power in the Home economy. To understand the optimal monetary policy response to

Home deregulation, it is useful first to inspect the dynamic adjustment and new long-run equilibrium

under historical policy. We present impulse responses for selected variables in Figure 1, where solid

lines show the responses for the historical policy case.45 The reduction in barriers to entry at Home

boosts product creation and results in increased investment.46 Under financial autarky, this would

require households to cut consumption and increase savings to finance the expansion in entry: Since

we are holding exogenous productivity constant, expansion of entry after deregulation requires higher

saving under financial autarky, as noted by Ghironi and Melitz (2005). With an open capital account,

increased entry can also be financed by borrowing from abroad. As a result, the deregulating economy

runs a current account deficit during the first part of the transition.47 Consumption rises on impact

at Home as part of the external borrowing is used to increase current consumption in anticipation of

higher permanent future income. Producer entry boosts job creation, lowering unemployment, and

wages increase as increased business creation in the downstream sector translates into higher labor

demand in intermediate input production. Lower unemployment benefits and worker bargaining have

a moderating effect on wage dynamics, further increasing firms’ vacancy posting and employment.

In contrast to models where product and labor market reform takes the form of exogenous markup

cuts without underlying micro-level dynamics, Home deregulation has an inflationary effect, which

erodes markups on impact. Financial and trade linkages imply significant spillovers to the Foreign

economy along the transition. As Foreign consumers invest at Home, Foreign consumption falls,

and unemployment rises. The dynamics of relative production costs generated by relative firm entry

and job creation imply that Home’s terms of trade ( ≡ ∗) improve in response to the

deregulation, with a negative wealth effect abroad.48

In the second part of the transition, the larger number of available domestic products lowers

44The 231 percent inflation target refers to the case in which the degree of price and wage indexation is set equal to

05, consistent with the empirical evidence discussed in the Appendix. Notice that, while indexation tends to increase the

optimal inflation rate, the relationship is not monotonic. For instance, with full price indexation but no wage indexation,

the optimal inflation target is 119 percent. The optimal target is similar when considering full wage indexation without

price indexation. Intuitively, the equalization of price and wage inflation in steady state dampens the incentive of the

Ramsey authority to increase inflation in the presence of asymmetric degrees of indexation between product prices and

nominal wages.45Responses of variables we mention but do not show, as well as responses of other variables, are available on request.46The measure of investment in our model is ≡ .47The current account initially deteriorates across all asymmetric deregulation scenarios we consider. Policymakers and

academic literature (for instance, Corsetti, Martin, and Pesenti, 2013) often refer to market reforms as a way to improve

competitiveness and rebalance external positions. Our results show that the beneficial effects of structural reforms may

come at the cost of weaker current accounts at least initially.48Home terms of trade appreciation also conflicts with the implications of exogenous markup cuts.

24

Page 26: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

markups at Home, boosting GDP, consumption and job creation. In turn, the Foreign economy

recovers due to increased demand for its products at Home.

How do the responses to deregulation change under the Ramsey-optimal policy? The optimal

policy case is represented by the dashed lines in Figure 1. The responses of inflation rates show

that the Ramsey policy is more expansionary than the ECB’s historical behavior, though inflation

rates remain well within reasonable limits. More aggressive monetary policy expansion generates

higher consumption and lower unemployment in the first two years after the reform. The Ramsey

allocation initially induces smaller product creation by increasing inflation, i.e., reducing the real

present discounted value of entry. This happens because the economy starts from a situation in

which markups are too high and incumbents are too small (in the notation introduced for distortions

above, Υ 0 and Υ 0). However, the Ramsey planner anticipates that the new long-run

equilibrium will feature lower markups, a larger number of producers of more significant size, and

higher aggregate employment. Therefore, the optimal policy reduces markups, boosts incumbent

firm size, and increases employment at Home in anticipation of these long-run effects. Consistent

with Draghi (2015), monetary policy that is more expansionary than historical “brings forward” key

beneficial effects of market reforms. Relative to historical policy, the Ramsey-optimal policy reduces

the job creation wedge Σ during the transition to the new long-run equilibrium. By contrast, the

product creation wedge Σ, is temporarily widened.49 The widening of Σ happens because the

short-run increase in inflation reduces the incentive of prospective entrants to take advantage of lower

non-technological barriers to entry.50

Employment, GDP, and consumption in the Foreign, rigid economy are also favorably affected

by the Ramsey policy on impact due to the larger demand for Foreign goods in the deregulating

economy. The optimal policy reduces the job creation wedge during the transition also in Foreign.

The product creation wedge falls on impact, but then increases, associated with lower product creation

in the relatively less attractive business environment during much of the transition. Finally, notice

that both Home and Foreign benefit from improved risk-sharing under the Ramsey-optimal policy,

i.e., the inefficiency wedge Σ is reduced at each point in time relative to the historical policy.

As time passes, the differences between Ramsey policy and historical rule vanish, at least in the

49The impulse responses of inefficiency wedges show the percent variations of the wedge deviations from efficiency. For

a given wedge Σ with efficient level equal to 1, we plot the response of (|Σ − 1|− |Σ − 1|) (|Σ − 1|). We considerabsolute values because what matters is the deviation from efficiency (be it positive or negative).50Bilbiie, Ghironi, and Melitz (2008b) and Chugh and Ghironi (2015) show that it is optimal to tax entry in the

benchmark BGM model with translog preferences. However, this does not imply that a reduction in entry should reduce

the inefficiency wedge in product creation in our scenario of multiple distortions and a non-optimized change in entry

barriers.

25

Page 27: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

deregulating economy. In the long run, Home deregulation reduces (or leaves virtually unaffected) all

Home and Foreign inefficiency wedges with the exception of cross-country risk-sharing. The optimal

long-run inflation target remains positive but is smaller than under high regulation.

To understand this result, it is useful to inspect how deregulation affects inefficiency wedges in the

long run. First, recall that the markup is constant in steady state, implying Υ = 0. Moreover, under

the assumption of long-run zero net inflation, Υ = Υ = 0, and the Hosios condition implied by

our calibration of the initial, historical position ensures that = = , so that Υ = 0. Finally,

product market regulation does not change the value of unemployment benefits, leaving Υ unaffected.

The zero-inflation steady state features two additional distortions that are affected by regulation and

inflation: the misalignment between the consumers’ benefit from variety and the profit incentives for

new entrants, Υ = (− 1)− 1 (2), and the monopoly power distortion in labor supply and jobcreation, Υ = (1)− 1.51

As barriers to entry fall, the steady-state number of products in the economy increases. With

zero net inflation, the fall in markups due to higher substitutability is larger than the reduction

in the consumers’ incremental benefit from variety, since Υ = −1 ¡22¢ 0. It follows

that lower regulatory costs reduce the misalignment between benefit from variety and incentives for

product creation. Moreover, the reduction in markups also reduces the distortion Υ,since Υ =

−1 ¡2¢ 0. Intermediate input producers have stronger incentives to post vacancies, households

have stronger incentives to supply effort, and employment and hours become closer to the respective

efficient levels.

Changes in labor market regulation directly affect two distortions: The reduction in unemployment

benefits brings the workers’ outside option closer to the (real) costs of labor effort, lowering real wages

and stimulating vacancy posting. The increase in the firms’ bargaining power, instead, implies that

is now greater than the elasticity of matches to vacancies, , a departure from the Hosios condition. In

our second best environment, the rigid, distorted steady state features suboptimally low job creation:

The increase in brings employment closer to the social optimum. Thus, the job creation wedge is

smaller even if the Hosios condition is violated post-deregulation.52

The combination of these product and labor market effects of reform reduces the need for positive

51Notice that a long-run widening of Σ relative to the initial level of 1 does not imply that there is a larger

incomplete markets distortion in the new steady state (which features zero net foreign assets like the initial one).

Asymmetric deregulation introduces a long-run structural asymmetry between Home and Foreign. This implies that the

risk sharing wedge around the new steady state should be redefined as Σ ≡ (∗) (κ), where κ reflectsthe effect of the long-run asymmetry between the two economies. But the new, post-deregulation steady state remains

efficient along the risk sharing margin because of the absence of any uncertainty in steady state.52Put differently, the economy is getting closer to the job creation outcome under the adjusted Hosios condition for a

distorted economy mentioned above.

26

Page 28: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

long-run inflation to bring the economy closer to the efficient outcome. Long-run responses under the

Ramsey-optimal policy are very similar to those under the historical rule because the reduction in

product and job creation wedges dominates the Ramsey central bank’s incentives and results in such

lower steady-state optimal inflation. As shown in Table 4, the optimal inflation target falls to 097

percent. With both price and wage indexation, the reduction in the optimal inflation target implied

by structural reform is even larger, as optimal long-run inflation falls from 231 to 194 percent.

Table 5 shows that market reform is highly beneficial for the deregulating country already under the

historical policy, as welfare gains amount to 740 percent of steady-state consumption at Home. There

is a modest prosper-thy-neighbor effect, as welfare rises by approximately 045 percent of steady-

state consumption in Foreign.53 While the welfare gains from implementing the optimal inflation

target under high regulation are sizable, the gains from implementing the optimal policy response to

deregulation are positive but not large for the reforming country (the relative gain is approximately

005 percent of steady-state consumption). In other words, welfare gains from optimal policy along

the transition and in the new steady state have little impact on the lifetime effect of the reform on

Home welfare, which is dominated by the reduction of long-run inefficiency wedges generated by the

deregulation. The welfare gain from the Ramsey response to reform is small also in Foreign, but more

significant than in Home: Market distortions are still in place in the rigid economy, and welfare gains

from optimal policy along the transition and non-zero long-run inflation are more significant at 025

percent of steady-state consumption. These results are consistent with the fact that a policy of near

price stability is relatively more desirable for more flexible economies.54

International Synchronization of Reforms

Since long-run inflation rates are equalized across countries, the Ramsey authority can choose only

one steady-state inflation target for both countries in the monetary union. Thus, with asymmetric

deregulation, optimal monetary policy must trade off asymmetric desirability of inflation across coun-

tries associated with cross-country heterogeneity in real rigidities: While flexible product and labor

markets at Home call for less inflation, the rigid member of the monetary union still benefits from a

relatively higher long-run inflation target. To investigate this issue further, we consider an alternative

53Market deregulation improves welfare at Home and abroad across all the exercises we perform. However, it is

important to notice that the welfare effects of the reforms are not clear-cut ex ante : Although each individual form of

regulation is distortionary in the model, it is the interaction of regulatory and other distortions with monetary policy

that determines the welfare outcome in our second-best environment.54As we show in the Appendix, joint reform of product and labor markets is more beneficial than deregulation of

individual markets, even if there is some substitutability across reforms, since the welfare gain is smaller than the sum

of the gains from individual reforms. This result is consistent with the empirical evidence in Fiori, Nicoletti, Scarpetta,

and Schiantarelli (2012).

27

Page 29: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

monetary policy arrangement between Home and Foreign: a flexible exchange rate with independent

monetary policies. (The details of this alternative model are presented in the Appendix.) We then

compute the Ramsey-optimal equilibrium with cooperative monetary policies, which, in contrast to

the monetary union scenario, features two policy instruments–one for each economy–and allows for

long-run differences in inflation rates. As shown in Table 4, the optimal policy results in optimal

inflation differentials between Home and Foreign when regulation is asymmetric.55 In the benchmark

case of no price and wage indexation, the optimal inflation target is 076 percent at Home (the flexible

economy), and 114 percent in Foreign. Relative to the Ramsey central bank of the monetary union,

Ramsey-optimal cooperative policies increase welfare by an additional 006 percent of steady-state

consumption.56 57

Symmetric market deregulation across countries could therefore further improve policy tradeoffs for

the central bank of the monetary union. To address this issue, we consider the scenario in which both

countries undertake deregulation of goods and labor markets. Tables 5 summarizes the results. The

reduction in optimal long-run inflation is larger with symmetric deregulation–the optimal inflation

target falls to 075 percent (151 percent with price and wage indexation). From a welfare perspective,

the addition of Foreign deregulation has a small impact on the gain from optimal monetary policy

relative to historical behavior for Home, although Home benefits more significantly from Foreign

deregulation for given monetary policy regime. Foreign gains significantly from deregulation for given

monetary policy, with smaller gains from Ramsey-optimal policy relative to the historical policy, as

expected.

6 Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy over the Business Cycle

Market deregulation affects domestic and international adjustment to aggregate shocks. As a result,

it alters the policy tradeoffs facing the central bank over the business cycle. In this section, we study

these effects and evaluate their consequences for policy.

Figure 2 (dashed lines) shows impulse responses to a one percent Home productivity increase under

the Ramsey-optimal policy in the presence of high regulation in Home and Foreign. Solid lines present

the responses under the historical policy, explained in detail in the Appendix.58

55By contrast, when the steady state is symmetric, there is no difference between the optimal inflation target in the

currency union and the optimal inflation target implied by the Ramsey-cooperative policies under flexible exchange rates.

This is the case since, as discussed above, symmetric regulation implies identical real rigidities in Home and Foreign.56For additional comparison, the Appendix presents also results on the welfare effects of reform under a policy of strict

price stability (around the optimal target).57The welfare calculations include transitions dynamics following the asymmetric Home deregulation. We do not report

impulse responses for brevity. They are available upon request.58The shock has persistence 0999 and zero cross-country spillover as in the benchmark calibration described in the

28

Page 30: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

The Ramsey authority generates a smaller increase in wage inflation and a larger departure from

price stability (disinflation) at Home relative to the historical rule (which implements a policy of

near price stability, defined as zero deviation of inflation from trend). Historical ECB behavior (and

price stability) result in positive employment comovement across countries. In contrast, the Ramsey

authority pushes unemployment rates in opposite directions by engineering wage disinflation rather

than inflation in the Foreign country and a reduction in Foreign firms’ bargaining share. Opposite

responses of employment across countries under the optimal policy are consistent with a standard effi-

ciency incentive to shift production to the more productive economy. In the Home country, producers

have a weaker incentive to post vacancies as more stable wage inflation implies that their effective

bargaining power rises by less than under the historical policy. Trade linkages and risk sharing imply

positive comovement of GDP and consumption across countries under both historical and optimal

policies. While the standard New Keynesian prescription of price stability amounts to a prescription

of procyclical monetary policy, with expansion in response to favorable productivity shocks to mimic

the flexible-price equilibrium, optimal policy in our monetary union with multiple distortions is more

countercyclical than historical behavior.59

Asymmetric Market Deregulation

Figure 3 contrasts the effects of a one percent Home productivity shock before and after Home product

and labor market deregulation under the historical policy rule. When barriers to entry are relaxed, the

economy fluctuates around a steady state with a larger number of firms, smaller markups, and smaller

producer-level profits. Therefore, the present discounted value of entry varies by less (in percentage of

the steady state) in response to aggregate disturbances, dampening markup fluctuations and product

market dynamics. In addition, labor market flexibility makes job creation less responsive to shocks:

Lower unemployment benefits and smaller worker bargaining power imply that adjustment takes place

increasingly through the real wage, reducing job flows over the cycle.

These effects imply that the employment response to shocks is also muted. Computing the second

moments of business cycles in the post-deregulation environment shows that volatility and persistence

of output and employment fall in the reforming country, but the effect on Foreign dynamics and

international business cycles is very small.60 (See the Appendix for details.)

Appendix. The same assumptions on shock size, persistence, and spillover apply also to Figures 3 and 4 below.59 In the standard New Keynesian model, higher inflation is associated with a falling markup. The contemporaneous

occurrence of falling inflation and markups in our model is a result of labor market frictions that induce marginal costs

to rise in the impact period of expansionary shocks. It follows that markups must fall to ensure falling output prices.60Cacciatore, Ghironi, and Stebunovs (2015) and Stebunovs (2008) find that bank market integration has business

cycle volatility consequences similar to those of product market deregulation by lowering financial barriers to producer

29

Page 31: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

The welfare cost of business cycles falls significantly in the more flexible economy–by approxi-

mately 30 percent (Table 5)–while it falls only slightly in the rigid country. This is explained by the

fact that Home markups are less volatile with a flexible product market, resulting in less volatile em-

ployment. In contrast, the welfare costs of business cycles in the Foreign economy are not significantly

affected since they remain dominated by domestic rigidities.

Turning to the Ramsey-optimal policy, Figure 4 shows that the Ramsey authority becomes less ag-

gressive, as deregulation–even asymmetric–ameliorates domestic and international policy tradeoffs.

At Home, more flexible product and labor markets dampen volatility for the same reasons as under

historical policy. Moreover, stabilization of cyclical fluctuations at Home requires less Foreign wage

deflation because Home demand for Foreign goods is higher to begin with, and the resource shifting

effect of Ramsey policy is mitigated.61

Table 5 shows that deregulation narrows the welfare gap between historical and Ramsey-optimal

policy at Home. The welfare gain from Ramsey policy increases slightly in the country that remains

rigid.62 The intuition is straightforward: The flexible economy has less need of an active policy that

addresses distortions. The focus of Ramsey-optimal activism correspondingly shifts toward the rigid

country, which therefore gains more from optimal policy. To substantiate this intuition, we consider

a constrained Ramsey problem in which the monetary authority maximizes the welfare of agents

subject to the constraints represented by the competitive economy relations and the historical rule

for interest rate setting. Our interest is in determining the optimal weights and that define

the relative focus of the monetary authority in stabilizing Home inflation and output gap relative to

Foreign–recall that the union-wide CPI inflation and GDP gap that appear in the historical interest

rate rule are given by: ≡

∗1− and

∗1−

. Concerning the response coefficients

that also appear in the historical rule–, , and –we consider two scenarios: In the first one,

we keep , , and at their calibrated values. In the second one, we determine , , and

optimally jointly with the weights and .63 In both scenarios, the optimized rule features a

more aggressive response to Foreign output gap fluctuations (which reduces the inefficient volatility of

entry.61The 05 percent approximate increase in welfare from implementing optimal monetary policy under high regulation

reported in the Introduction is the sum of the long-run welfare gain (035) and the gain from reduction in business cycle

volatility (017, obtained as the difference between the cost of business cycles under historical policy, 094, and the cost

of business cycles under optimal policy, 077).62 In the Appendix, we show that deregulation of product or labor market alone has similar implications. However,

deregulation of both markets accomplishes the most significant moderation of Home’s aggregate fluctuations, and the

welfare cost of business cycles under the historical policy is lowest. The welfare gain from Ramsey-optimal policy is

correspondingly minimized. At the same time, however, the welfare gain from optimal policy is further magnified in the

rigid country.63We search across a grid of parameter values for the values that minimize the welfare cost of business cycles in (4).

We perform the search over the range [0 10] for each parameter, with fineness equal to 001.

30

Page 32: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Foreign unemployment) and to deviations of Home inflation from trend (which reduces the inefficient

volatility of Home markups).64 Importantly, when the weights and and the response coefficients

, , and are jointly optimized, the welfare cost of business cycles is very similar to that implied

by the Ramsey-optimal policy.

Stabilization Policy and International Coordination of Reforms

To what extent can coordination (i.e., synchronization) of market reforms improve policy tradeoffs

over the business cycle? Over the cycle, optimal policy is relatively less aggressive for the flexible

country compared to the rigid one. When the two economies are simultaneously hit by similar shocks,

inflation stabilization may be too strong (weak) in the flexible (rigid) country. To address this issue,

we consider again the flexible-exchange rate model discussed in the previous Section and compute the

welfare cost of business cycles implied by Ramsey-optimal cooperative monetary policies. Consistent

with the intuition above, Table 5 shows that the welfare cost of business cycle falls in both Home and

Foreign relative to the optimal policy in the monetary union scenario: Ramsey-optimal cooperative

policies with a flexible exchange rate yield an additional welfare gain of 008 percent of steady-state

consumption (the sum of the gains in Home and Foreign).65 The flexible Home economy benefits

relatively more. This happens because, as discussed above, asymmetric regulation shifts the focus of

Ramsey-optimal activism toward the rigid country in the monetary union. Other things equal, this

results in inefficient stabilization in the flexible economy. The existence of two optimally designed

policy instruments removes this tradeoff.

Our analysis thus suggests that the requirement of convergence toward flexible regulation of product

and labor markets across countries should be part of the criteria to be met to join (or form) a currency

union. Importantly, symmetric levels of regulation are not sufficient per se. The requirement is

that market regulation be symmetric and flexible across members of the currency union. This is the

case since, as noted above, both countries need monetary policy activism to stabilize unemployment

fluctuations when regulation is symmetric and rigid. Since there is a tension between stabilizing the

Home and Foreign economies in response to asymmetric shocks, the availability of a single monetary

policy instrument results in negative cross-country spillovers over the cycle.66

64Specifically, in the first case, we find = 1 and = 025. In the second scenario, we find = 1 and = 025,

together with = 0, = 25, and = 05.65For brevity, we do not present impulse responses. They are available upon request.66As shown in Table 5, when regulation is symmetric and rigid, the optimal cooperative policy under flexible exchange

rates results in an additional welfare gain equal to 01 percent of steady-state consumption (relative to the Ramsey-

optimal policy in the monetary union). The gain falls to 006 percent of steady-state consumption when both countries

have deregulated their markets.

31

Page 33: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

To conclude, we find that there are gains from international coordination of reforms due to improved

stabilization of aggregate fluctuations. In particular, synchronized reforms eliminate the heterogeneous

needs of inflation stabilization in rigid and flexible countries. In the long run, the reduction in inflation

is larger with symmetric deregulation. From a welfare perspective, the addition of Foreign deregula-

tion has a small impact on the gain from optimal monetary policy relative to historical behavior for

Home, although Home benefits more significantly from Foreign deregulation for given monetary policy

regime. Foreign gains significantly from deregulation for given monetary policy, with smaller gains

from Ramsey-optimal policy relative to the historical policy, as expected.

7 Conclusions

We studied the implications of structural reforms for the conduct of optimal monetary policy in a mon-

etary union. A key message of the paper is that high levels of regulation in goods and labor markets

generate sizable static and dynamic distortions that call for active monetary policy in the long run

and over the business cycle. Expansionary monetary policy can reduce transition costs and front-load

the benefits of reforms by generating lower markups and stimulating job creation in the aftermath of

deregulation. This finding provides support for the narrative of policymakers (Draghi, 2015, among

others) and for the recurrent argument in policy discussions that supply-side policies should be accom-

panied by active policies supporting aggregate demand (see, for instance, Barkbu, Rahman, Valdés,

and Staff, 2012). However, once the economies in the monetary union have reached the new long-run

equilibrium, real distortions in product and labor markets are reduced, and the need for inflation to

correct market inefficiencies correspondingly mitigated. There is an important international dimension

of deregulation, as asymmetric product and labor market reforms across countries can generate new

policy tradeoffs for a welfare maximizing monetary authority. Coordination of reforms can mitigate

these tradeoffs.

From a methodological standpoint, a contribution of this paper was to clarify the importance of

explicitly modeling micro-level product and labor market dynamics in analyses of the macroeconomic

and policy implications of structural reforms.

References

[1] Adão, B., I. Correia, and P. Teles (2003): “Gaps and Triangles,” Review of Economic Studies 70:699-713.

[2] Alessandria, G., and A. Delacroix (2008): “Trade and the (Dis)Incentive to Reform Labor Mar-kets: The Case of Reform in the European Union,” Journal of International Economics 75:151-166.

32

Page 34: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

[3] Andolfatto, D. (1996): “Business Cycles and Labor-Market Search,” American Economic Review86: 112-132.

[4] Andrés, J., Ó. Arce, and C. Thomas (2014): “Structural Reforms in a Debt Overhang,” mimeo,University of Valencia and Banco de España.

[5] Aoki, K. (2001): “Optimal Monetary Policy Responses to Relative Price Changes,” Journal ofMonetary Economics 48: 55-80.

[6] Arsenau, D. M., and S. K. Chugh (2012): “Tax Smoothing in Frictional Labor Markets,” Journalof Political Economy 120: 926-985.

[7] Arsenau, D. M., and S. K. Chugh (2008): “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy with CostlyWage Bargaining,” Journal of Monetary Economics 55: 1401-1414.

[8] Ascari, G., N. Branzoli, and E. Castelnuovo (2011): “Trend Inflation, Wage Indexation, andDeterminacy in the U.S.,” Quaderni di Dipartimento #276 (10-11), University of Pavia.

[9] Backus, D. K., P. J. Kehoe, and F. E. Kydland (1992): “International Real Business Cycles,”Journal of Political Economy 100: 745-775.

[10] Backus, D. K., P. J. Kehoe, and F. E. Kydland (1994): “Dynamics of the Trade Balance and theTerms of Trade: The J Curve?” American Economic Review 84: 84-103.

[11] Barkbu, B., J. Rahman, R. Valdés, and Staff (2012): “Fostering Growth in Europe Now,” IMFStaff Discussion Note 12/07.

[12] Barseghyan, L., and R. DiCecio (2011): “Entry Costs, Industry Structure, and Cross-CountryIncome and TFP Differences,” Journal of Economic Theory 106: 1828-1851.

[13] Baxter, M. (1995): “International Trade and Business Cycles,” in Grossman, G. M., and K.Rogoff, eds., Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 1801-1864.

[14] Baxter, M., and D. D. Farr (2005): “Variable Factor Utilization and International BusinessCycles,” Journal of International Economics 65: 335-347.

[15] Benigno, P. (2004): “Optimal Monetary Policy in a Currency Area,” Journal of InternationalEconomics 63: 293-320.

[16] Benigno, P. (2009): “Price Stability with Imperfect Financial Integration,” Journal of Money,Credit and Banking 41: 121-149.

[17] Benigno, P., and M. Woodford (2005): “Inflation Stabilization and Welfare: The Case of a Dis-torted Steady State,” Journal of the European Economic Association 3: 1185-1236.

[18] Bergin, P. R., and G. Corsetti (2008): “The Extensive Margin and Monetary Policy,” Journal ofMonetary Economics 55: 1222-1237.

[19] Bergin, P. R., and G. Corsetti (2013): “International Competitiveness and Monetary Policy:Strategic Policy and Coordination with a Production Relocation Externality,” mimeo, Universityof California, Davis and Cambridge University.

[20] Bergin, P. R., and R. C. Feenstra (2000): “Staggered Price Setting and Endogenous Persistence,”Journal of Monetary Economics 45: 657-680.

[21] Bergin, P. R., and R. C. Feenstra (2001): “Pricing-to-Market, Staggered Contracts, and RealExchange Rate Persistence,” Journal of International Economics 54: 333-359.

[22] Bernard, A. B., J. Eaton, J. B. Jensen, and S. Kortum (2003): “Plants and Productivity inInternational Trade,” American Economic Review 93: 1268-1290.

[23] Bernard, A. B., S. J. Redding, and P. K. Schott (2010): “Multi-Product Firms and ProductSwitching,” American Economic Review 100: 70-97.

33

Page 35: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

[24] Bilbiie, F. O., I. Fujiwara, and F. Ghironi (2014): “Optimal Monetary Policy with EndogenousEntry and Product Variety,” Journal of Monetary Economics 64: 1-20.

[25] Bilbiie, F. O., F. Ghironi, and M. J. Melitz (2012): “Endogenous Entry, Product Variety andBusiness Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy 120: 304-345.

[26] Bilbiie, F. O., F. Ghironi, and M. J. Melitz (2008a): “Monetary Policy and Business Cycles withEndogenous Entry and Product Variety,” in Acemoglu, D., K. S. Rogoff, and M. Woodford, eds.,NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2007, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, pp. 299-353.

[27] Bilbiie, F. O., F. Ghironi, and M. J. Melitz (2008b). “Monopoly Power and Endogenous ProductVariety: Distortions and Remedies.” NBER WP 14383.

[28] Blanchard, O. J., and P. A. Diamond (1989): “The Beveridge Curve,” Brookings Papers onEconomic Activity 20: 1-76.

[29] Blanchard, O. J., and F. Giavazzi (2003): “Macroeconomic Effects of Regulation and Deregulationin Goods and Labor Markets,” Quarterly Journal of Economics CXVIII: 879-907.

[30] Blanchard, O. J., and J. Galí (2010): “Labor Markets and Monetary Policy: A New KeynesianModel with Unemployment,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2: 1-30.

[31] Broda, C., and D. E. Weinstein (2010): “Product Creation and Destruction: Evidence and PriceImplications,” American Economic Review 100: 691-723.

[32] Cacciatore, M. (2014): “International Trade and Macroeconomic Dynamics with Labor MarketFrictions,” Journal of International Economics 93: 17-30.

[33] Cacciatore, M., and G. Fiori (2010): “The Macroeconomic Effects of Goods and Labor MarketsDeregulation,” mimeo, HEC Montréal and North Carolina State University.

[34] Cacciatore, M., and F. Ghironi (2012): “Trade, Unemployment, and Monetary Policy,” mimeo,HEC Montréal and Boston College.

[35] Cacciatore, M., F. Ghironi, and V. Stebunovs (2015): “The Domestic and International Effectsof Interstate U.S. Banking,” Journal of International Economics 95: 171-187.

[36] Calvo, G. A. (1983): “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework,” Journal of MonetaryEconomics 12: 383-398.

[37] Card, D.(1994): “Intertemporal Labor Supply: An Assessment,” in Sims, C., ed., Advances inEconometrics, Sixth World Congress, Cambridge University Press, New York, NY.

[38] Chugh, S. K., and F. Ghironi (2015): “Optimal Fiscal Policy with Endogenous Product Variety,”CEPR DP 10674.

[39] Collard, F., and H. Dellas (2002): “Exchange Rate Systems and Macroeconomic Stability,” Jour-nal of Monetary Economics 49: 571-599.

[40] Corsetti, G., L. Dedola, and S. Leduc (2010): “Optimal Monetary Policy in Open Economies,”in Friedman, B., and M. Woodford, eds., Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3B, Elsevier,Amsterdam, pp. 861-933.

[41] Corsetti, G., P. Martin, and P. Pesenti (2013): “Varieties and the Transfer Problem,” Journal ofInternational Economics 89: 1-12.

[42] Dawson, J. W., and J. J. Seater (2011): “Federal Regulation and Aggregate Economic Growth,”mimeo, Appalachian State University and North Carolina State University.

[43] Diamond, P. A. (1982a): “Wage Determination and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium,” Review ofEconomic Studies 49: 217-227.

[44] Diamond, P. A. (1982b): “Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilibrium,” Journal ofPolitical Economy 90: 881-894.

34

Page 36: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

[45] Dixit, A. K., and J. E. Stiglitz (1977): “Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diver-sity,” American Economic Review 67: 297-308.

[46] Draghi, M. (2015): “Structural Reforms, Inflation and Monetary Policy,” Introductory Speech,ECB Forum on Central Banking, Sintra, May 22, 2015.

[47] Ebell, M., and C. Haefke (2009): “Product Market Deregulation and the U.S. EmploymentMiracle,” Review of Economic Dynamics 12: 479-504.

[48] ECB (2002): “Labor Market Mismatches in the Euro Area,” European Central Bank.

[49] Eggertsson, G., A. Ferrero, and A. Raffo (2014): “Can Structural Reforms Help Europe?” Journalof Monetary Economics 61: 2-22.

[50] Erceg, C. J., D. W. Henderson, and A. T. Levin (2000): “Optimal Monetary Policy with StaggeredWage and Price Contracts,” Journal of Monetary Economics 46: 281-313.

[51] Faia, E. (2009): “Ramsey Monetary Policy with Labor Market Frictions,” Journal of MonetaryEconomics 56: 570-581.

[52] Faia, E. (2012): “Oligopolistic Competition and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Journal of EconomicDynamics and Control 36: 1760-1774.

[53] Feenstra, R. C. (1994): “New Product Varieties and the Measurement of International Prices,”American Economic Review 84: 157-177.

[54] Feenstra, R. C. (2003a): “A Homothetic Utility Function for Monopolistic Competition Models,without Constant Price Elasticity,” Economics Letters 78: 79-86.

[55] Feenstra, R. C. (2003b): Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence, Princeton Univer-sity Press, Princeton, NJ.

[56] Felbermayr, G., and J. Prat (2011): “Product Market Regulation, Firm Selection, and Unem-ployment,” Journal of the European Economic Association 9: 278-317.

[57] Fernández-Villaverde, J., P. A. Guerrón-Quintana, and J. Rubio-Ramírez (2011): “Supply-SidePolicies and the Zero Lower Bound,” NBER WP 17543.

[58] Fiori, G., G. Nicoletti, S. Scarpetta, and F. Schiantarelli (2012): “Employment Outcomes andthe Interaction between Product and Labor Market Deregulation: Are They Substitutes or Com-plements?” Economic Journal 122: F79-F104.

[59] Flinn, C. J. (2006): “Minimum Wage Effects on Labor Market Outcomes under Search, Bargain-ing, and Endogenous Contact Rates,” Econometrica 74: 1013-1062.

[60] Gerali, A., A. Notarpietro, and M. Pisani (2015): “Structural Reforms and Zero Lower Bound ina Monetary Union," Temi di Discussione 1002, Bank of Italy.

[61] Gerdesmeier, D., and B. Roffia (2003): “Empirical Estimates of Reaction Functions for the EuroArea,” ECB WP 206.

[62] Gertler, M., L. Sala, and A. Trigari (2008): “An Estimated Monetary DSGE Model with Unem-ployment and Staggered Nominal Wage Bargaining,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40:1713-1764.

[63] Gertler, M., and A. Trigari (2009): “Unemployment Fluctuations with Staggered Nash WageBargaining,” Journal of Political Economy 117: 38-86.

[64] Ghironi, F., and M. J. Melitz (2005): “International Trade and Macroeconomic Dynamics withHeterogeneous Firms,” Quarterly Journal of Economics CXX: 865-915.

[65] Griffith, R., R. Harrison, and G. Maccartney (2007): “Product Market Reforms, Labour MarketInstitutions and Unemployment,” Economic Journal 117: 142-166.

35

Page 37: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

[66] Haltiwanger, J., S. Scarpetta, and H. Schweiger (2008): “Assessing Job Flows Across Countries:The Role of Industry, Firm Size and Regulations,” NBER WP 13920.

[67] Hamano, M. (2015): “International Equity and Bond Positions in a DSGE Model with VarietyRisk in Consumption,” Journal of International Economics 96: 212-226.

[68] Hobijn, B., and A. Sahin (2009): “Job-Finding and Separation Rates in the OECD,” EconomicsLetters 104: 107-111.

[69] Hopenhayn, H. and R. Rogerson (1993): “Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A General Equi-librium Analysis,” Journal of Political Economy 5: 915-38.

[70] Juillard, M. (1996): “Dynare: A Program for the Resolution and Simulation of Dynamic Modelswith Forward Variables through the Use of a Relaxation Algorithm,” CEPREMAP WP 9602.

[71] Khan, A., R. G. King, and A. L. Wolman (2003): “Optimal Monetary Policy,” Review of EconomicStudies 70: 825-860.

[72] Krause, M. U., and T. A. Lubik (2007): “The (Ir)Relevance of Real Wage Rigidity in the NewKeynesian Model with Search Frictions,” Journal of Monetary Economics 54: 706-727.

[73] Laffargue, J.-P. (1990): “Résolution d’un Modèle Macroéconomique avec Anticipations Ra-tionnelles,” Annales d’Economie et de Statistique 17.

[74] Lewis, V. (2013): “Optimal Monetary Policy and Firm Entry,” Macroeconomic Dynamics 17:1687-1710.

[75] Lucas, R. E. Jr., and N. L. Stokey (1983): “Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy in an EconomyWithout Capital,” Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 55-93.

[76] Martin, J., and I. Méjean (2013): “Price Dispersion and the Euro: Micro Heterogeneity andMacro Implications,” International Review of Economics and Finance 26: 70-86.

[77] Messina, J., and G. Vallanti (2007): “Job Flow Dynamics and Firing Restrictions: Evidence fromEurope,” Economic Journal 117: 279-301.

[78] Merz, M. (1995): “Search in the Labor Market and the Real Business Cycle,” Journal of MonetaryEconomics 36: 269-300.

[79] Mortensen, D. T., and C. A. Pissarides (1994): “Job Creation and Job Destruction in the Theoryof Unemployment,” Review of Economic Studies 61: 397-415.

[80] Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff (1995): “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux,” Journal of PoliticalEconomy 103: 624-660.

[81] OECD (2004): Employment Outloook, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

[82] Petrongolo, B., and C. A. Pissarides (2006): “Scale Effects in Markets with Search,” EconomicJournal 116: 21-44.

[83] Pissarides, C. A. (2003): “Company Startup Costs and Employment,” in Aghion, P., R. Fryd-man, J. Stiglitz, and M. Woodford, eds., Knowledge, Information, and Expectations in ModernMacroeconomics: In Honor of Edmund S. Phelps, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp.479-504.

[84] Rotemberg, J. J. (1982): “Monopolistic Price Adjustment and Aggregate Output,” Review ofEconomic Studies 49: 517-531.

[85] Sibert, A., and A. Sutherland (2000): “Monetary Union and Labor Market Reform,” Journal ofInternational Economics 51: 421-435.

[86] Stebunovs, V. (2008): “Finance as a Barrier to Entry: U.S. Bank Deregulation and BusinessCycles,” mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

36

Page 38: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

[87] Taylor, J. B. (1993): “Discretion vs. Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester ConferenceSeries on Public Policy 39: 195-214.

[88] Thomas, C. (2008): “Search and Matching Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy,” Journal ofMonetary Economics 55: 936-956.

[89] Thomas, C. and F. Zanetti (2009): “Labor Market Reform and Price Stability: An Applicationto the Euro Area,” Journal of Monetary Economics 56: 885-899.

[90] Trigari, A. (2009): “Equilibrium Unemployment, Job flows and Inflation Dynamics,” Journal ofMoney, Credit and Banking 41: 1-33.

[91] Turnovsky, S. J. (1985): “Domestic and Foreign Disturbances in an Optimizing Model of ExchangeRate Determination,” Journal of International Money and Finance 4: 151-171.

[92] Weber, A. (2000): “Vacancy Durations–A Model for Employer’s Search,” Applied Economics32: 1069-1075.

[93] Woodford, M. (2003): Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy, Prince-ton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

[94] Yun, T. (1996): “Nominal Price Rigidity, Money Supply Endogeneity, and Business Cycles,”Journal of Monetary Economics 37: 345-370.

[95] Zanetti, F. (2011): “Labor Market Institutions and Aggregate Fluctuations in a Search andMatching Model,” European Economic Review 55: 644-658.

0.5

37

Page 39: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

TABLE 1: MODEL SUMMARY

1 = (1− )h exp

³−

2

´i1−+

h

∗ exp

³∗−∗2∗∗

´i1−(1)

1 = (1− )h∗ exp

³∗−∗2∗∗

´i1−+

hexp

³−

2

´i1−(2)

= (+)+³+1

1− −

´ (3)

∗ ∗∗= ∗ (

∗+

∗)+

³∗+11− −∗

´∗ (4)

= (1− )−1+−1−1 (5)

∗= (1− )∗−1+∗−1

∗−1 (6)

1 = (1− )

n+1

+1

h+1

+1

+

³1− 1

+1−

22

´(+1 + +1)

io(7)

1 = (1− )

n∗+1

∗+1

h∗∗+1

∗+1∗

+∗∗

³1− 1

∗+1−

2∗2

´³∗+1 + ∗+1

´io(8)

1 =

n+1

h(1− )

+1+

³+1+1+1 − +1

+1+1 −

22+1

´io(9)

1 =

n∗+1

h(1− )

∗∗+1

+∗

³∗+1

∗+1

∗+1 −

∗+1∗+1

∗+1 − 2∗2+1

´io(10)

=

³()

+ ´+ (1− )

¡ −

22

¢+

n+1+1

h(1− )(1− )− (1− − )(1− +1)

+1

io (11)

∗∗

∗ = ∗³(∗ )∗

+ ∗´+ (1− ∗)

¡∗∗ ∗ −

2∗2

¢+

n∗+1∗+1

h(1− )(1− ∗)− (1− − ∗ )(1− ∗+1)

∗∗+1

io (12)

= (13)

∗∗ = ∗∗ (14)

(1 + ) =

−1−1 (1 + ) (15)¡1 + ∗

¢=

∗ ∗

∗−1∗−1

³1 + ∗

´(16)

1 + +1 = (1 + )h(1 + )

³1 +

´ ³

´ i1−(17)

1 + +1=(1 + +1)

³+1

11++1

´(18)

1− +1=(1 + +1)

³∗+1

11+∗

+1

´(19)

−1=1+∗1+

(20)

+1 =1+1+

+ −∗

∗ (21)

Note: ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗

are the 21 endogenous variables determined by these equations. Other variables that

appear in the table are determined as described in the text.

38

Page 40: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

TABLE 2: SOCIAL PLANNER

1 = (1− )h exp

³−

2

´i1−+

h

∗ exp

³∗−∗2∗∗

´i1−(1)

1 = (1− )h∗ exp

³∗−∗2∗∗

´i1−+

h1 exp

³−

2

´i1−(2)

= ( + ) +³+1

1− −

´ (3)

∗ ∗∗ = ∗ (

∗ + ∗) +

³∗+11− −∗

´∗ (4)

= (1− )−1 + (1− −1)1− −1 (5)

∗ = (1− )∗−1 + (1− ∗−1)1− ∗−1 (6)

1 = (1− )

n+1

+1

h+1

+ 12+1

(+1 + +1)io

(7)

1 = (1− )

n∗+1

∗+1

h∗+1∗

+ 12∗+1

³∗+1 + ∗+1

´io(8)

1 =

n+1

h

³+1+1+1 − (+1)

+1

´+ [1− − (1− ) +1]

+1

io(9)

1 =

½∗+1

∙∗

µ∗+1

∗+1

∗+1 −

(∗+1)∗+1

¶+£1− − (1− ) ∗+1

¤ ∗∗+1

¸¾(10)

= (11)∗∗

= ∗∗ (12)

=∗

(13)

Note: ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ are the 13 endogenous variables

determined by these equations. Other variables that appear in the table are determined

as described in the text.

TABLE 3: DISTORTIONS

Υ ≡ −1− 1 time-varying markup∗, product creation

Υ ≡ −1³1− 1

22

´− 1

2misalignment between markup and benefit from variety∗, product creation

Υ ≡ regulation costs, product creation, resource constraint

Υ ≡ 1− 1 monopoly power and time-varying markup∗, job creation and labor supply

Υ ≡ − failure of the Hosios condition∗∗, job creationΥ ≡ unemployment benefits, job creation

Υ ≡ ∗

incomplete markets, risk sharing

Υ ≡ +1 cost of adjusting bond holdings, risk sharing

Υ ≡ 22 wage adjustment costs, resource constraint and job creation

Υ ≡ 22 price adjustment costs, resource constraint

∗ From translog preferences and sticky prices.∗∗ From sticky wages and/or 6= .

39

Page 41: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

Table 4: OPTIMAL LONG-RUN INFLATION

Trend Inflation

Status Quo Asymmetric Symmetric

Home Foreign Home Foreign Home Foreign

No Indexation

Ramsey MU 1.15 1.15 0.97 0.97 0.75 0.75

Ramsey Coop 1.15 1.15 0.76 1.14 0.75 0.75

Price Indexation ( = 1)

Ramsey MU 1.19 1.19 0.97 0.97 0.71 0.71

Ramsey Coop 1.19 1.19 0.72 1.17 0.71 0.71

Wage Indexation ( = 1)

Ramsey MU 1.10 1.10 1.01 1.01 0.91 0.91

Ramsey Coop 1.10 1.10 0.92 1.09 0.91 0.91

Price and Wage Indexation ( = = 05)

Ramsey MU 2.31 2.31 1.94 1.94 1.51 1.51

Ramsey Coop 2.31 2.31 1.53 2.29 1.51 1.51

Note: Ramsey MU ≡ Optimal Policy in the Monetary Union;

Ramsey Coop ≡ Optimal Cooperative Policy With A Flexible Exchange Rate;

Asymmetric ≡ Home Country Product and Labor Market Reform;

Symmetric ≡ Home and Foreign Country Product and Labor Market Reform.

Table 5: WELFARE EFFECTS OF REFORMS

Market Reform ∆Welfare

Hist Ramsey MU Ramsey Coop

Home Foreign Home Foreign Home Foreign

Status Quo 0.35 0.35 0.35 0.35

Asymmetric 7.40 0.45 7.45 0.70 7.49 0.72

Symmetric 7.78 7.78 7.83 7.83 7.83 7.83

Welfare Cost of Business Cycles

Hist Ramsey MU Ramsey Coop

Home Foreign Home Foreign Home Foreign

Status Quo 0.94 0.94 0.77 0.77 0.72 0.72

Asymmetric 0.62 0.93 0.54 0.74 0.49 0.71

Symmetric 0.62 0.62 0.52 0.52 0.49 0.49

Note: Hist ≡ Historical Monetary Policy;

Ramsey MU ≡ Ramsey-Optimal Policy in the Monetary Union;

Ramsey Coop ≡ Ramsey-Optimal Cooperative Policy With Flexible Exchange Rate;

Asymmetric ≡ Home Country Product and Labor Market Reform;

Symmetric ≡ Home and Foreign Country Product and Labor Market Reform;

∆Welfare ≡ Welfare change.

40

Page 42: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

10 20 30 40

4

5

6

7

C

10 20 30 40

­0.50

0.5

11.5

2C*

10 20 30 40

­5

­4

­3

­2

­1

0U

10 20 30 40

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0U*

10 20 30 40­40

­20

0

20

40

NE

10 20 30 40­9­8­7­6­5­4­3

µ

10 20 30 40

­4

­3

­2

­1

0µ*

10 20 30 400

0.5

1

1.5

πd

10 20 30 400

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

πd*

10 20 30 40

­30

­20

­10

0

NE*

10 20 30 40­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0

CA

10 20 30 40

­20

0

20

40ΣPC

10 20 30 400

10

20

30

40

ΣPC*

10 20 30 40

­70

­60

­50

­40ΣJC

10 20 30 40

­25

­20

­15

­10

­5

ΣJC*

Figure 1. Home product and labor market reform, historical policy (continuous lines) versus Ramsey-optimal policy

(dashed lines). Responses show percentage deviations from the high-regulation steady state under historical policy

(zero steady-state inflation). Unemployment and inflation are in deviations from the steady state.

10 20 30 40 500.65

0.70.75

0.80.85

0.90.95

C

10 20 30 40 50­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05

C*

10 20 30 40 50

­0.4

­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

U

10 20 30 40 50

0

0.05

0.1

0.15U*

10 20 30 40 500.5

11.5

22.5

33.5

NE

10 20 30 40 50­0.2

­0.1

0

0.1

0.2µ

10 20 30 40 50

­0.1

0

0.1

0.2

µ*

10 20 30 40 50­0.25

­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

πd

10 20 30 40 50­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05πd

*

10 20 30 40 50

­1

­0.5

0

NE*

10 20 30 40 50

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05

CA

10 20 30 40 50­1

012345

ΣPC

10 20 30 40 50­1

012345

ΣPC*

10 20 30 40 50­5

­4

­3

­2

­1

ΣJC

10 20 30 40 50

0

0.5

1

1.5

ΣJC*

Figure 2. Home productivity shock with high regulation, historical policy (continuous lines) versus Ramsey-optimal

policy (dashed lines). Responses show percentage deviations from the respective steady state. Unemployment and

inflation are in deviations from the steady state.

Page 43: Market Deregulation and Optimal Monetary Policy in a ...faculty.washington.edu/ghiro/CacciatoreFioriGhiroJIE.pdf · Deregulation of product markets reduces the size of sunk entry

10 20 30 40 500.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

C

10 20 30 40 500.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08C*

10 20 30 40 50

­0.4

­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

0U

10 20 30 40 50

­0.025­0.02

­0.015

­0.01­0.005

0U*

10 20 30 40 50

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

NE

10 20 30 40 50­0.16

­0.14

­0.12

­0.1

­0.08

µ

10 20 30 40 50

­0.06­0.05­0.04­0.03­0.02­0.01

0

µ*

10 20 30 40 50­0.05

­0.04

­0.03

­0.02

­0.01

0

πd

10 20 30 40 50­0.04

­0.02

0

0.02

0.04

πd*

10 20 30 40 50

­1

­0.5

0

NE*

10 20 30 40 50

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05

CA

10 20 30 40 50­0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

ΣPC

10 20 30 40 50

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

ΣPC*

10 20 30 40 50

­8

­6

­4

­2

ΣJC

10 20 30 40 50­0.4

­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

0

ΣJC*

Figure 3. Home productivity shock, historical policy with high regulation (continuous lines) versus low regulation

(dashed lines). Responses show percentage deviations from the zero-inflation steady state. Unemployment and inflation

are in deviations from the steady state.

10 20 30 40 500.6

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

C

10 20 30 40 50­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05

C*

10 20 30 40 50­0.25

­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

U

10 20 30 40 500

0.05

0.1

0.15U*

10 20 30 40 500.5

11.5

22.5

3

NE

10 20 30 40 50­0.2

­0.1

0

0.1

0.2

µ

10 20 30 40 50

­0.1

0

0.1

0.2

µ*

10 20 30 40 50­0.25

­0.2­0.15

­0.1­0.05

00.05

πd

10 20 30 40 50­0.2

­0.15

­0.1

­0.05

0πd

*

10 20 30 40 50

­0.4

­0.2

0

0.2

NE*

10 20 30 40 50

­0.1

­0.05

0

0.05

CA

10 20 30 40 50­2

02468

ΣPC

10 20 30 40 50­1

012345

ΣPC*

10 20 30 40 50

­5

­4

­3

­2

ΣJC

10 20 30 40 500

0.5

1

1.5

ΣJC*

Figure 4. Home productivity shock, Ramsey-optimal policy with high regulation (continuous lines) versus low

regulation (dashed lines). Responses show percentage deviations from the Ramsey steady state. Unemployment and

inflation are in deviations from the steady state.