Margin Squeeze in theTelecommunications Sector:A · PDF fileMargin Squeeze in...

27
Margin Squeeze in the Telecommunications Sector: A More Economics-based Approach Ramin Silvan GOHARI * A margin squeeze occurs when a vertically integrated company,dominant in the supply of an indispensable upstream input, pursues a pricing policy which prevents downstream competitors from trading profitably,thereby leading to their ultimate exclusion from the downstream market. In the telecommunications sector, where large ex-State firms still enjoy considerable market power, margin squeeze has long been frequent. Interestingly, the United States and the European Union have tackled this problem in considerably different ways. Dismayed by the idea of an antitrust court intervening in a companys price setting, the US Supreme Court held that margin squeeze was exclusively the domain of regulation. Conversely, the Court of Justice of the European Union has endorsed a modern economics-based approach enabling competition authorities to engage in a coherent and verifiable antitrust assessment of the price differentials that potentially amount to a margin squeeze. This paper will argue that (1) the economics-based approach is the right solution in the European context, but that (2) this approach will only lead to convincing results if it includes a rigorous and transparent analysis of the effects on competition and consumers. 1 INTRODUCTION A margin squeeze occurs when a vertically integrated company, which is dominant in the upstream market, supplies an indispensable upstream input to downstream competitors and charges them a price which would not allow equally efficient downstream rivals to trade profitably, thereby leading to their ultimate exclusion from the downstream market. 1 * Trainee at the Swiss Competition Commission as of September 2011; MJur (Oxford); MLaw (Fribourg). I am very grateful to Dr Ariel Ezrachi for his invaluable supervision and guidance throughout the period of this work. I also would like to thank Professor Marc Amstutz,Vasiliki Brisimi, Maria Ioannidou and Viktoria Robertson for many comments and discussions that helped to shape this paper. Finally, I am deeply grateful to the Berrow Foundation and the Marquise de Amodio for their generosity and support.The views expressed are those of the author. 1 Case T-5/97 Industrie des Poudres Sphériques v. Commission [2000] ECR II-3755, para. 178; Case C-280/08 P DeutscheTelekom v. Commission [2010] unreported (DeutscheTelekom [CJEU]), para. 4; Case C-52/09 Konkurrensverket v. TeliaSonera Sverige AB [2011] unreported, para. 32; Pietro Crocioni & Cento Veljanovski, Price Squeezes, Foreclosure and Competition Law, Principles and Guidelines, 4 JNI 28, 39–41(2003); James Kavanagh, Assessing Margin Squeeze under Competition Law, 3 Comp. Law 187, 189 (2004); Robert ODonoghue & Atilano Jorge Padilla, The Law and Economics of Article 82 EC Gohari, Ramin Silvan. ‘Margin Squeeze in the Telecommunications Sector: A More Economics-based Approach’. World Competition 35, no. 2 (2012): 205–232. © 2012 Kluwer Law International BV, The Netherlands World Competition Young Writer's Award 2012

Transcript of Margin Squeeze in theTelecommunications Sector:A · PDF fileMargin Squeeze in...

Margin Squeeze in the TelecommunicationsSector:A More Economics-based Approach

Ramin Silvan GOHARI*

A margin squeeze occurs when a vertically integrated company, dominant in the supply of anindispensable upstream input, pursues a pricing policy which prevents downstream competitorsfrom trading profitably, thereby leading to their ultimate exclusion from the downstream market.

In the telecommunications sector, where large ex-State firms still enjoy considerable marketpower, margin squeeze has long been frequent. Interestingly, the United States and the EuropeanUnion have tackled this problem in considerably different ways. Dismayed by the idea of anantitrust court intervening in a company’s price setting, the US Supreme Court held thatmargin squeeze was exclusively the domain of regulation. Conversely, the Court of Justice of theEuropean Union has endorsed a modern economics-based approach enabling competitionauthorities to engage in a coherent and verifiable antitrust assessment of the price differentialsthat potentially amount to a margin squeeze.

This paper will argue that (1) the economics-based approach is the right solution in theEuropean context, but that (2) this approach will only lead to convincing results if it includes arigorous and transparent analysis of the effects on competition and consumers.

1 INTRODUCTION

A margin squeeze occurs when a vertically integrated company, which isdominant in the upstream market, supplies an indispensable upstream input todownstream competitors and charges them a price which would not allow equallyefficient downstream rivals to trade profitably, thereby leading to their ultimateexclusion from the downstream market.1

* Trainee at the Swiss Competition Commission as of September 2011; MJur (Oxford); MLaw(Fribourg). I am very grateful to Dr Ariel Ezrachi for his invaluable supervision and guidancethroughout the period of this work. I also would like to thank Professor Marc Amstutz, VasilikiBrisimi, Maria Ioannidou and Viktoria Robertson for many comments and discussions that helped toshape this paper. Finally, I am deeply grateful to the Berrow Foundation and the Marquise de Amodiofor their generosity and support.The views expressed are those of the author.

1 Case T-5/97 Industrie des Poudres Sphériques v. Commission [2000] ECR II-3755, para. 178; CaseC-280/08 P Deutsche Telekom v. Commission [2010] unreported (Deutsche Telekom [CJEU]), para. 4; CaseC-52/09 Konkurrensverket v. TeliaSonera Sverige AB [2011] unreported, para. 32; Pietro Crocioni &Cento Veljanovski, Price Squeezes, Foreclosure and Competition Law, Principles and Guidelines, 4 JNI 28,39–41(2003); James Kavanagh, Assessing Margin Squeeze under Competition Law, 3 Comp. Law 187, 189(2004); Robert O’Donoghue & Atilano Jorge Padilla, The Law and Economics of Article 82 EC

Gohari, Ramin Silvan. ‘Margin Squeeze in the Telecommunications Sector: A More Economics-basedApproach’. World Competition 35, no. 2 (2012): 205–232.© 2012 Kluwer Law International BV, The Netherlands

World Competition Young Writer's Award 2012

It is not by accident that the telecommunications sector has been home tomany margin squeeze cases. For decades, telecommunications had been anindustry of monopolies, special rights and subsidies, sheltered from competitionand ideal for the creation of extensive network infrastructures by public utilities.2

It was only in the late 1980s – after similar steps had already been undertaken inthe United States and the United Kingdom – that the European Commissiondeclared its intention to fully liberalize the European telecommunications marketby 1 January 1998.3 Driven by regulatory and antitrust intervention, this processtowards full competition led to lower prices and significant investment by theprivate sector; however, it failed to reduce the dominance of the incumbentcompanies.4 New digital networks have certainly enabled some entrants tocompete profitably in the telephony, internet and television markets.5 Yet, in mostparts of Europe, the success of these entrants is contingent on access to theincumbents’ local loop and broadband infrastructure on equitable terms.6

Determining which access conditions and pricing policies are to beconsidered appropriate is a highly controversial issue which has led tofundamentally dissimilar responses in the United States and Europe.7 Influencedby the Chicago School’s reticence to interfere with price competition, the UnitedStates Supreme Court held that, absent an antitrust duty to deal or predatory

310–312, 320 (Hart Publishing 2006); Einer Elhauge & Damien Geradin, Global Competition Law andEconomics 418f (Hart Publishing 2007); John Vickers, Handbook of Antitrust Economics 421 (PaoloBuccirossi ed., MIT Press 2008).

2 European Commission, ‘Guidelines on the Application of EEC Competition Rules in theTelecommunications Sector’ COM (1991) C233/02, paras. 3, 5;Wolfgang Jauk, The Application of ECCompetition Rules to Telecommunications – Selected Aspects: The Case of Interconnection, 4 Intl. J. Comm.Law & Policy 1, 3f (1999/2000); Jean-Jacques Laffont & Jean Tirole, Competition in Telecommunications 3(MIT Press 2001); OECD Working party on telecommunication and information services policies,‘Developments in Local Loop Unbundling’ (Report, Sept. 2003) (OECD 2003), 6.

3 European Commission, ‘Green Paper on the Convergence of the Telecommunications, Media andInformation Technology Sectors, and the Implications for Regulation – Towards an InformationSociety Approach’ COM (97) 0623 final, 5; Jauk, supra n. 2, at 3–5; Laffont &Tirole, supra n. 2, at 2, 3,18f, 29–34; OECD 2003, supra n. 2, at 6; ICN Working Group on Telecommunications Services,‘Report on Telecommunications Services’ (Report, May 2006) (ICN Report), 3; Jordi Gual & SandraJódar-Rosell, Competition Policy in the EU, Fifty Years on from the Treaty of Rome 237 (Xavier Vives ed.,OUP 2009).

4 Directive 2002/21/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of Mar. 7, 2002 on a commonregulatory framework for electronic communications networks and services (Framework Directive)[2002] OJ L108/33, recital 1; Directive 2009/140/EC of the European Parliament and of the Councilof Nov. 25, 2009 amending Directives 2002/21/EC, 2002/19/EC and 2002/20/EC [2009] OJL337/37,Art. 2(9);William J. Baumol & J. Gregory Sidak, Toward Competition in LocalTelephony 9 (MITPress 1994) ; Gual & Jódar-Rosell, supra n. 3, at 237, 246.

5 ICN Report, supra n. 3, at 6; Gual & Jódar-Rosell, supra n. 3, at 252.6 Wanadoo España v.Telefónica (Case COMP/38.784) unreported July 4, 2007 [2007], para 240; Gual &

Jódar-Rosell, supra n. 3, at 251, 255; ICN Report, supra n. 3), at 5.7 Baumol & Sidak, supra n. 4, at 10, 16; OECD Competition Committee, ‘Competition and Regulation

Issues in Telecommunications’ (Competition Policy Roundtables, Feb. 2002) (OECD 2002), 21.

WORLD COMPETITION206

pricing, an insufficient margin in itself was outside the reach of antitrust law andbelonged to the sole sphere of regulation.8

Europe’s Court of Justice, however, adopted a considerably moreinterventionist approach. Partly endorsing the Commission’s economics- andeffects-based criteria of analysis, it held that margin squeeze was a stand-alonecompetition law claim even in cases when the dominant company was under noregulatory duty to deal.9

This paper will explore the elements of the Commission’s economics-basedapproach to margin squeeze (chapter II); how it was gradually adopted by thedecisional practice in the European Union and how other jurisdictions in Europeand the United States have dealt with margin squeeze cases (chapter III); whatdimensions and contentious questions the use of economic models implies andhow the application of competition law in a regulatory context can be justified(chapter IV); and finally, how the economics- and effects-based approach canbecome the right solution in the European context (chapterV).

2 THE COMMISSION’S MORE ECONOMICS-BASED APPROACH

2.1 INTRODUCTION

While the objectives of European competition law have long been manifold,recent competition policy papers have focused on one main and two derivedgoals: enhancing consumer welfare by protecting competition and allocativeefficiency.10 In this same context, the Commission has introduced a newmethodological approach, capable of putting these objectives into practice.11

The economics- and effects-based approach analyses the actual and potential effectsof dominant firms’ behaviour by relying on economic techniques and empiricalevidence with a view to ensuring ‘that markets function properly and thatconsumers benefit from the efficiency and productivity which result from effective

8 Chapter III.4; Daniel A Crane, linkLine’s Institutional Suspicions, 8 Cato S. Ct. Rev. 111, 113 (2009);Liza Lovdahl Gormsen, A Principled Approach to Abuse of Dominance in European Competition Law 35f(CUP, 2010).

9 Chapter III.1.10 Karel van Miert, A Pragmatic Approach to Europe’s Competition Policy, Frontier-Free Eur. Mthly. Newsltr.

1 (1993); Neelie Kroes, Speech, European Competition Policy – Delivering Better Markets and Better Choices(European Consumer and Competition Day, London, Sept. 2005) (transcript available athttp://www.europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=SPEECH/05/512) accessed Sept. 1,2011, 2;Victoria Mertikopoulou, DG Competition’s Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of theEC Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses: The Proposed Economic Reform from a Legal Point of View, 28 Eur.Compet. L. Rev. 241, 242(2007).

11 Lovdahl Gormsen, supra n. 8, at 185; Marc Amstutz, Basler Kommentar, Kartellgesetz, Art. 7, para. 30(Marc Amstutz & Mani Reinert eds., Helbing Lichtenhahn 2010).

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 207

competition between undertakings’.12 Its often interdependent objectives are (1)to apply Article 102 TFEU13 consistently with competition law in other areaswhere economics had been influential already, (2) to increase the precision ofassessments, (3) to avoid false positives and false negatives and (4) to protectcompetition, not inefficient competitors.14

Quite conversely, a form-based approach declares certain forms of conduct asper se abusive without regard to their possible pro-competitive effects.15

2.2 BEFORE THE PUBLICATION OF THE GUIDANCE PAPER

In 2004, then Commissioner Monti declared that he wanted competition policy tobecome fully compatible with economic learning.16 With regard to Article 102TFEU, however, this process only really began with the submission of a report bythe Economic Advisory Group on Competition Policy (EAGCP) in 2005.

The EAGCP report pointed out the weaknesses of a form-based approachand insisted that the notion of consumer welfare was key to the definition ofcompetitive harm.17 Yet, despite the report’s level of detail, margin squeeze was atbest addressed implicitly.18

In the same year, the Directorate General for Competition published aDiscussion Paper setting out its probable future approach to Article 102 TFEU.19

While the Discussion Paper was generally considered to be less innovative than the

12 European Commission, ‘Guidance on the Commission’s Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings’ (Communication)COM (2009) C45/7 (Guidance Paper),para 5.See also EconomicAdvisory Group on Competition Policy,‘An Economic Approach to Article 82’ (July 2005) http://www.ec.europa.eu/dgs/competition/economist/eagcp_july_21_05.pdf accessed Sept.1, 2011 (hereinafter“EAGCP”),14.

13 ConsolidatedVersion of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union [2008] OJ C115/47.14 EAGCP, supra n. 12, 9;Ariel Ezrachi, The European Commission Guidance on Article 82 EC – The Way in

Which Institutional Realities Limit the Potential for Reform, Oxford Legal Studies Research Paper 27/2009(hereinafter Ezrachi 2009b): 1, 12; Ekatarina Rousseva, Rethinking Exclusionary Abuses in EUCompetition Law 378 (Hart Publishing 2010);Anne C.Witt, The Commission’s Guidance Paper on AbusiveExclusionary Conduct – More RadicalThan It Appears, 10 Eur. L. Rev. 214, 224 (2010).

15 Paul K Gorecki, Form- versus Effects-Based Approaches to the Abuse of a Dominant Position: the Case ofTicketmaster Ireland, 2 J. Compet. L. & Econ. 533, 534, 547 (2006); Ioannis Lianos, Article 82 EC –Reflections on its Recent Evolution 20 (Ariel Ezrachi ed., Hart Publishing 2009).

16 Mario Monti, ‘The EU Gets New Competition Powers for the 21st Century’, ECCPN Special Issue(2004): 1, 4; Nicholas Forwood, The Commission’s “More Economic Approach” – Implications for the Role ofthe Courts, theTreatment of Economic Evidence and the Scope of Judicial Review 1, 1f (Eur. U. Inst. 2009).

17 EAGCP, supra n. 12), 2, 5–7, 12f; Ariel Ezrachi, Article 82 EC – Reflections on Its Recent Evolution 53(Ariel Ezrachi ed., Hart Publishing 2009) (hereinafter Ezrachi 2009a) ; Amstutz, supra n. 11, atparas 28f.

18 EAGCP, supra n. 12, 26f, 43.19 Directorate General for Competition, ‘Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the

Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses’ (2005) http://www.ec.europa.eu/competition/antitrust/art82/discpaper2005.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011 (Discussion Paper).

WORLD COMPETITION208

EAGCP report, it nevertheless reaffirmed the main pillars of an economics-basedapproach and led to the adoption of a Guidance Paper in 2008.20 The DiscussionPaper mentioned margin squeeze cases but applied to them the methodologydeveloped for constructive refusal to supply cases.21

2.3 THE GUIDANCE PAPER

In the Guidance Paper, the Commission laid out its enforcement prioritiesregarding exclusionary practices under Article 102 TFEU and announced that itwould ‘take into account the specific facts and circumstances of each case’ and‘focus on those types of conduct that [were] most harmful to consumers’.22 Asimultaneously published press release reassured the public that the Paper ‘[wassetting] out an economic and effects-based approach’.23

The following paragraphs outline the Commission’s analytical frameworkwith a special focus on margin squeeze in the telecommunications sector.24 It ison the basis of ‘general’ and ‘specific’ factors that the Commission seeks to establishwhether a dominant company forecloses competitors to the detriment ofconsumers.

The general factors used by the Commission make it clear that dominanttelecommunications companies are in a difficult position: they commonly enjoyconsiderable strength on a significant part of the relevant market (position of thedominant undertaking, extent of the conduct), they benefit from scale and scopeeconomies (market conditions) and their competitors generally struggle to gainground in the market (position of competitors).25 Regrettably, the Commissionadds that it will also take into account ‘any other factors’ it considers appropriateand that for certain forms of conduct the ‘anti-competitive effect may be inferred’

20 Discussion Paper, supra n. 19, paras 54–60; Centre for European Policy Studies, Treatment ofExclusionary Abuses under Article 82 of the EC Treaty, Comments on the European Commission’s GuidancePaper (Final Report of a CEPS Task Force 2009) (CEPS), 11; Ezrachi 2009a, supra n. 17, 52; Ezrachi2009b, supra n. 14, 3, 5; Lovdahl Gormsen, supra n. 8, 152.

21 Discussion Paper, supra n. 19, paras 72, 220.22 Guidance Paper, supra n. 12, paras 5, 8, 19 fn 2 (‘consumers’ stands for ‘final consumers’); James

Kavanagh, Neil Marshall & Gunnar Niels, Article 82 EC – Reflections on its Recent Evolution 17 (ArielEzrachi ed., Hart Publishing 2009); Martin Andreas Gravengaard & Niels Kjaersgaard, The EUCommission Guidance on Exclusionary Abuse of Dominance – And Its Consequences in Practice, 31 Eur.Compet. L. Rev. 285, 285f (2010).

23 European Commission, ‘Antitrust: Consumer Welfare at Heart of Commission Fight against Abuses byDominant Undertakings’ (Commission Press Release, Dec. 2008) IP/08/1877, 1; Lovdahl Gormsen,supra n. 8, at 169.

24 Regarding the insufficiency of the Commission’s discussion of margin squeeze in the GuidancePaper, see CEPS, supra n. 20, 75f; John Temple Lang, ‘Article 82 EC – The Problems and theSolution’ (Conference ‘Ten Years of Mercato Concorrenza Regole’, Milan, June 2009)http://www.papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1467747 accessed Sept. 1, 2011 (hereinafterTemple Lang 2009b): 1, 18.

25 Guidance Paper, supra n. 12, para. 20.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 209

without a detailed assessment, which is contrary to an economics-basedapproach.26

Next, the Commission will turn to the specific factors of margin squeezecases: objective necessity of the input (indispensability), elimination of effectivecompetition, consumer harm and efficiencies.27 Surprisingly, despite the existenceof these criteria, paragraph 82 expresses that ‘[in] certain specific cases’ antitrustintervention can be more easily justified if regulation has already proceeded to abalancing of the interests in question or where the dominant position is the resultof special or exclusive rights.28 These (form-based) prerequisites are present inmost liberalized telecommunications markets and it appears impossible forcompanies to draw any concrete conclusions from the vague formulation of thispassage.

Given the apparent difficulty of an incumbent successfully arguing against anallegation of margin squeeze, the field where battles are lost and won will mostoften be the economic analysis of the price margins.29 As a general rule, theCommission will evaluate if a hypothetical rival as efficient as the incumbent’sdownstream operations (equally efficient competitor) could trade profitably, assuming itincurs the latter’s long-run average incremental costs (LRAIC).30 But here again,the Commission states that ‘in certain circumstances’ the LRAIC of a less efficientcompetitor could be taken into account, which would make a finding of abusemore likely.31

Overall, while the Guidance Paper offers certain structures of analysis, it alsocreates considerable legal uncertainty through many imprecise exceptions andinconsistencies with case law.32 On the positive side, it does make two centralpoints: (1) the Commission intends to apply modern economic models to marginsqueeze cases; (2) effects on consumers form an integral part of the analysis.

Following the discussion of the theoretical underpinnings of theCommission’s methodological framework, the next chapter will focus on howcourts and competition authorities have approached margin squeeze in practice. In

26 Id. paras. 21f; Orit Dayagi-Epstein, Article 82 EC – Reflections on Its Recent Evolution 79f (Ariel Ezrachied., Hart Publishing 2009); Penelope Papandropoulos, Implementing an Effects-Based Approach underArticle 82 4 Concurrences 1, 3(2008).

27 Guidance Paper, n. 12, paras 21, 81.The Commission seems to apply the same analytical framework torefusals to supply and margin squeeze (para. 81: ‘these practices’);Temple Lang (2009b), supra n. 24, at18.

28 See Telefónica, supra n. 6, para. 303; Rousseva, supra n. 14, 423;Temple Lang (2009b), supra n. 24, at 20f.29 Chapter IV.30 Guidance Paper, supra n. 12, paras 23, 25f, 80. See also TeliaSonera, supra n. 1, para. 45.31 Guidance Paper, supra n. 12, paras 24, 80 fn. 9.32 Ariel Ezrachi, Form and Effects Based Approaches: A Challenging Duality in the Application of Art 102

TFEU, 6 Concurrences 1, 2 (2010) (hereinafter Ezrachi 2010); Forwood, supra n. 16, at 3; John TempleLang, Article 82: Progress to Date, 5 Competition Law Insight 3 (2006) (hereinafter Temple Lang 2006);John Temple Lang, A Question of Priorities, 8 Competition Law Insight 3 (2009) (hereinafter TempleLang 2009a).

WORLD COMPETITION210

Europe, there has been a clear trend towards a more economics- and effects-basedapproach. In the four other jurisdictions examined, three basic approaches can bediscerned: (1) rejection of the margin squeeze doctrine (United States), (2) aneconomics- yet not effects-based approach (France, Switzerland) and (3) awell-developed economics- and effects-based approach (United Kingdom).

3 DECISIONAL PRACTICE

3.1 EUROPEAN UNION

3.1[a] The Early Decisions

Before the term ‘margin squeeze’ even came into use, the Commission and theGeneral Court had availed themselves of the concept of margin squeeze. Althoughnone of the early decisions contained analyses as detailed as in recent cases, theyalready focused on efficient competitors as a benchmark for abusive pricing.

In the National Carbonizing decision (1976), the National Coal Board (NCB)was dominant in the production of coal (upstream market) as well as, through itssubsidiary, in the production of coke (downstream market).33 The NationalCarbonizing Company (NCC), which bought all its coal from the NCB, was onlyactive in the downstream market, and after an upstream price rise without acorresponding rise in the retail price, the NCC could no longer trade profitably.34

The Commission considered this conduct abusive and ordered the NCB to reducethe price of coal supplied to the NCC to allow a sufficient margin for a‘reasonably efficient manufacturer’.35

In the Napier Brown decision (1988), British Sugar (BS) was dominant in boththe production of industrial sugar (upstream market) and the repackaging andselling of retail sugar (downstream market).36 Napier Brown, which had only beenactive downstream, found it was a victim of abusive pricing.37 The Commissionexplicitly focused on the ‘repackaging margin’ and concluded that a company‘equally efficient as BS’ would have been excluded from the retail market.38 Inthis case, however, margin squeezing was only one abuse among several.39

The Industrie des Poudres Sphériques case, the first margin squeeze case to bedecided by the General Court (2000), concerned a margin squeeze claim by a

33 National Carbonizing Company Limited, Commission decision 76/185/ECSC [1976] OJ L35/6, 6f.34 Id. 6f.35 Id. 7, 9.36 Napier Brown – British Sugar (Case IV/30.178) Commission decision 88/518/EEC [1988] OJ

L284/41, 60.37 Id. paras 4, 24.38 Id. paras 25, 66.39 Id. para. 66 (‘in the context’). See also paras 16–18, 31 (internal documents).

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 211

downstream firm less efficient than its upstream rival.40 PéchineyÉlectrométallurgie (PEM) was the sole Community producer of primary calciummetal (upstream market) as well as a seller of broken calcium metal (downstreammarket).41 Industrie des Poudres Sphériques (IPS) was only active downstreamand, despite the fact that it required a specially manufactured version of the inputproduct, considered the price charged by PEM abusively high when comparedwith PEM’s downstream price.42 Three findings were important in the Court’srejection of the claim:

(1) there were other suppliers of the input product available;(2) neither was the upstream price excessive nor the downstream price

predatory;(3) IPS’s production method was inefficient, and it had failed to prove that

an efficient competitor would have been eliminated from the retailmarket.43

While an inefficient company could therefore have made a claim of predatory orexcessive pricing, it could not – based on its own costs and revenues – allege thatits margin was insufficient.44

The early decisions revealed the European institutions’ willingness torecognize margin squeeze as form of abuse under Article 102 TFEU. However, itwas only in the subsequent decisions in the telecommunications sector that theconcept began to take shape.

3.1[b] The Decisions in theTelecommunications Sector

A direct analogy can be drawn from markets where non-integrated firms dependon supplies from raw material producers to markets where such firms rely onaccess to essential facilities controlled by ex-State firms. In the telecommunicationssector, the majority of new entrants would have no prospect of flourishing withoutequitable access to the incumbents’ upstream inputs such as their networkinfrastructure (interconnection) or customer base (call termination).45

40 Industrie des Poudres Sphériques v. Commission, supra n. 1.41 Id. para 11.42 Id. paras 10, 20, 133, 177.43 Id. paras 57f, 179f, 185.44 Bernard Amory & Alexandre Verheyden, Comments on the CFI’s Recent Ruling in Deutsche Telekom v

European Commission, 5 Global Competition Policy 1, 4 (2008); Pierre-André Buigues & RobertKlotz, Margin Squeeze in Regulated Industries:The CFI Judgment in the Deutsche Telekom Case, 7 GlobalCompet. Policy 1, 4 (2008); Gianluca Faella & Roberto Pardolesi, Squeezing Price Squeeze under ECAntitrust Law, 6 Eur. Compet. J. 255, 281f (2010).

45 ICN Report, supra n. 3, 5–7.

WORLD COMPETITION212

3.2[a][i] Deutsche Telekom

Having led to the first explicit recognition of margin squeeze as a stand-alonecategory of abuse, the Deutsche Telekom case can be regarded as the leading case ofEuropean margin squeeze jurisprudence.46

The allegations of margin squeeze were aimed at Deutsche Telekom (DT),which was dominant in both the provision of wholesales network access (upstreammarket) and the provision of retail internet access (downstream market).47 Theregulatory context was as follows: at the wholesale level, charges had to becost-oriented and were subject to authorization by the national regulatoryauthority; at the retail level, a price cap was applied to baskets of similar serviceswith the exception of retail ADSL,48 which was not regulated.49 Despite theserestraints, both the General Court and the Court of Justice (2008 and 2010respectively) agreed with the Commission (2003) that DT would have hadsufficient scope to adjust its retail prices to avoid a margin squeeze and consideredit irrelevant that prices had been authorized and the existence of a margin squeezedenied by the national regulatory authority.50

The Commission had based its margin squeeze calculations on an aggregatedretail price (the weighted average price of a basket of services).51 By reference tothe Community policy of ‘tariff rebalancing’, the Commission had further rejectedDT’s argument that call services should have been taken into account whenevaluating the downstream cash-flow despite the fact that, through the wholesaleinput, downstream rivals had also been enabled to offer such services.52

The Union courts accepted both the aggregated approach to calculation andthe exclusion of call services on regulatory grounds.53 They further found that theequally efficient competitor (EEC) test was compatible with their earlier Akzo54

and FranceTélécom55 judgments, holding that it would be contrary to legal certainty

46 Deutsche Telekom (Case COMP/C-1/37.451, 37.578, 37.579) Commission decision 2003/707/EC[2003] OJ L263/9 (Deutsche Telekom [Commission]), para. 57; Case T-271/03 Deutsche Telekom v.Commission [2008] ECR II-477 (Deutsche Telekom [GC]), para. 102; Deutsche Telekom (CJEU) (n 1),paras. 3f, 178.

47 DeutscheTelekom (Commission), supra n. 46, paras. 58, 96.48 ADSL (asymmetric digital subscriber line): a technology for providing high-speed internet

connections over standard telephone lines Concise Oxford English Dictionary (11th ed., OUP 2009).Cambridge Advanced Learner’s Dictionary (3d ed., CUP 2008).

49 Id. paras. 17, 20–51.50 Deutsche Telekom (CJEU), supra n. 1, para 85; Deutsche Telekom (GC), supra n. 46, paras. 24, 105, 151;

DeutscheTelekom (Commission), supra n. 46, paras. 163–175, 199.51 DeutscheTelekom (Commission), supra n. 46, paras. 116, 144–162.52 Id. paras 117–120.53 DeutscheTelekom (CJEU), supra n. 1, para. 226; DeutscheTelekom (GC), supra n. 46, paras 200, 206.54 Case C-62/86 Akzo v. Commission [1991] ECR I-03359, para. 74.55 Case C-202/07 P FranceTélécom v. Commission [2009] ECR I-2369, para. 108.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 213

to expect dominant firms to know the cost structures of their competitors.56

Indeed, while the EEC test is based on the dominant company’s own financialsituation, other tests, such as the reasonably efficient competitor (REC) test,would, at least implicitly, require access to sensitive data of competitors.

Regarding the need to prove effects on competition, the Commission’sapproach was corrected by the Court of Justice. The Commission had thoughtthat it was not under an obligation to demonstrate any exclusionary effects of theconduct in question (but nevertheless assessed the evolution of market shares andthe state of competition).57 The Court of Justice began by stating that Article 102TFEU aimed at protecting consumers through undistorted competition and thatconsumers may suffer because of reduced choice and higher prices in marginsqueeze situations.58 When assessing whether there was an obligation todemonstrate effects, the court stated in an unclear way that:

a pricing practice […] constitutes an abuse within the meaning of Article [102 TFEU] if it(1) has an exclusionary effect on competitors who are at least as efficient as the dominantundertaking itself by squeezing their margins and (2) is capable of making market entrymore difficult or impossible for those competitors, (3) and thus of strengthening itsdominant position on that market (4) to the detriment of consumers’ interests.59

It can be deduced that a margin squeeze must (1) have an effect on competitorsand (4) be detrimental to consumers.The Court went on to state that ‘the fact thatthe desired result [had not been] ultimately achieved [did] not alter itscategorisation as abuse’ but that the ‘absence of any effect’ would not suffice.60 Thiscan be interpreted to mean that some effect indicating exclusion must be shown butthat a demonstration of the fact of exclusion (the ‘desired result’) is not necessary.

Significant as this judgment may be, only an interpretation considering thelater TeliaSonera decision provides the full picture of the Union courts’ currentapproach to margin squeezing.

3.2[a][ii] TeliaSonera

The 2011 TeliaSonera case61 was triggered by a reference for a preliminary rulingby a Swedish court. The national competition authority had accused verticallyintegrated TeliaSonera of having squeezed the margin of its downstreamcompetitors, to which TeliaSonera had been voluntarily providing wholesale ADSL

56 DeutscheTelekom (CJEU), supra n. 1, paras 198, 200; DeutscheTelekom (GC), supra n. 46, paras 187–193.57 DeutscheTelekom (Commission), supra n. 46, paras. 178–181.58 DeutscheTelekom (CJEU), supra n. 1, paras. 180, 182.59 Id. para. 253 (numbers added).60 Id. para. 254.61 TeliaSonera, supra n. 1.

WORLD COMPETITION214

access.62 In its decision, the Court of Justice relied heavily on Deutsche Telekom,citing it nearly twenty times. Four of the main findings in TeliaSonera areparticularly relevant:

First, on the basis of case law, the court favoured the equally efficientcompetitor test.63 However, it added that it might be appropriate to refer to thecosts of competitors not only where the dominant company’s cost structure wasnot identifiable, but also where the latter was in a ‘competitively advantageoussituation’.64 Since dominant companies usually are in such a position, this passagemight in future cases be relied upon in order to apply the reasonably efficientcompetitor test.

Secondly, the court stated that a margin squeeze could be committed even bydominant undertakings under no regulatory obligation to deal and that – sincemargin squeeze was a standalone case of abuse – the Bronner65 criteria for refusalto supply cases could not be decisive.66

Thirdly, the court made a restrictive reading of the Deutsche Telekom decisionregarding effects. It held that the assessment of effects only referred to the degreeof competition (consumer harm was not mentioned at this stage) and that they didnot have to be concrete.67 In the same context, the court stated – in anunnecessarily complicated formulation – that it could not be ruled out thatindispensability was a necessary condition for an upstream input to be capable ofproducing exclusionary effects.68

Fourthly, and most importantly, the judges in Luxembourg made clear thatexclusionary effects ‘[could] be counterbalanced […] by advantages in terms ofefficiency which also benefit the consumer’, thereby paving the way not only forobjective justifications, but also for an effects analysis including consumer welfareconsiderations.69 However – contrary to Deutsche Telekom, where consumerconsiderations were part of the abuse analysis – TeliaSonera placed the burden ofproof regarding consumer benefits on the undertaking by treating such benefits asobjective justifications.70

Finally, in response to further questions, the court stated that according toTetra Pak II,71 dominance in only one market was sufficient as it could be

62 Id. paras. 4–9.63 Id. paras. 39–44, 112.64 Id. para. 45.65 Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co KG v. Mediaprint Zeitungs- und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co

KG [1998] ECR I-7791, paras. 41–47.66 TeliaSonera, supra n. 1, paras. 51–59.67 Id. paras. 62–67.68 Id. para. 72.69 Id. paras 75–77, 76, 112.70 See DeutscheTelekom, supra n. 1, para. 253.71 Case C-333/94 Tetra Pak International v. Commission [1996] ECR I-5951, para. 31.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 215

leveraged into other markets, and that given sacrifice was no element of a marginsqueeze, recoupment could not be either.72

*The court’s Deutsche Telekom and TeliaSonera decisions clearly constitute

important endorsements of the more economics-based approach. TheCommission, however, decided to go even further by demonstrating actualexclusionary effects, a practice exemplified in the Telefónica decision.

3.2[a][iii] Telefónica

Telefónica was the dominant provider of both national and regional broadbandinternet access in Spain (upstream market) and, through its subsidiaries, of retailbroadband internet access (downstream market).73 Regulation required one of itssubsidiaries to provide wholesale access to Telefónica’s network.74 When asked toanalyse whether a margin squeeze had occurred, the Commission (2007) laid outan elaborate five-step framework, which in 2012 was upheld by the GeneralCourt.75

First, the Commission chose to apply the equally efficient competitor test,aware that, due to Telefónica’s economies of scale and scope, the reasonablyefficient competitor test would have been more beneficial to potential newentrants.76 Next, the Commission stated that the LRAIC test was the mostappropriate for assessing margin squeezing.77 As to the relevant time frame, theCommission chose to rely on both a period-by-period and a forward-lookingdiscounted cash flow (DCF) approach to reduce the chance of false positives.78

Finally, in steps four and five, the Commission applied an aggregated approach toTelefónica’s portfolio of retail products, while deciding, with regard to thewholesale market, to run the tests separately for the national and regionalmarkets.79 The former choice would force entrants to adopt an equally profitableproduct range, while the latter choice recognized that operators entering themarket would likely start at a small critical mass and that they had to be protectedfrom abusive pricing at all levels of the market.80

72 TeliaSonera, supra n. 1, paras. 84–89, 99f.73 Telefónica, supra n. 6, paras. 12, 36, 125–127.74 Id. paras. 11, 119, 288.75 Id. para. 310; Case T–336/07 Telefónica v. Commission [2012] unreported, see particularly paras 19,

135–143, 188–194, 212–232, 234–244.76 Id. paras. 311–315.77 Id. paras. 316–323.78 Id. paras. 325–349, particularly 332, 349.79 Id. paras. 388f.80 Id. paras. 388, 392.

WORLD COMPETITION216

The Commission found that Telefónica had squeezed its competitors’ marginson both the national and regional markets.81 The analysis of effects was equallyclear: Telefónica’s conduct had kept competitors from entering the Spanishbroadband market and developing their own infrastructure, which resulted inSpain’s having some of the highest prices and lowest broadband penetration ratesin Europe.82 Telefónica’s claims regarding efficiencies and objective justificationwere rejected.83

*To conclude the section on decisional practice in Europe, it can be observed

that case law has undergone a process of significant sophistication towards aneconomics-based approach. While validation from the highest court is still recentand incomplete, the telecommunications sector can be expected to continue to actas a motor of evolution in margin squeeze cases. The Telefónica case may haveopened the road to an increasingly economics-savvy practice, similar to thatanalysed in the following section.

3.2 UNITED KINGDOM

In the UK, margin squeeze claims are explicitly recognized and have producedmany decisions.84 Effects were already assessed at a time when the EuropeanCommission considered such an analysis unnecessary.

While two noteworthy cases, Genzyme85 and Albion Water,86 have led tosuccessful allegations of margin squeezing, the following discussion focuses on fourunsuccessful, but no less instructive, margin squeeze claims in thetelecommunications sector. The Office of Fair Trading (OFT) and the Office ofCommunications (OFCOM) have concurrent jurisdiction in antitrust matters inthis sector.87

In the BSkyB case (2002), the company BSkyB was dominant in the marketsfor both the wholesale provision of premium television channels to distributors(upstream market) and the distribution of such channels to consumers

81 Id. paras. 397–542, particularly 464, 482, 533, 541.82 Id. paras. 554, 557f, 592, 603.83 Id. para. 664.84 Office of Fair Trading, Competition Act 1998,The Application in the Telecommunications Sector, para. 7.26

(Feb. 2000) (hereinafter OFT 417).85 Genzyme Ltd v. Office of FairTrading [2004] CAT 4, [2004] CompAR 358, paras. 560f, 711.86 Dwr Cymru Cyfyngedig v.Albion Water Limited [2008] EWCA Civ 536, [2009] 2 All ER 279, paras. 90,

105, 111.87 OFT 417, supra n. 84, paras. 2.6f; OECD Competition Committee, ‘Margin Squeeze’, 228, 299

(Competition Policy Roundtables, Sept. 2010) (hereinafter OECD 2010).

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 217

(downstream market) in competition with other distributors.88 When a marginsqueeze was alleged, the OFT’s Director General embarked on an analysis of theconduct in question and, referring to section 60 of the Competition Act 1998,decided to apply an EEC test in conformity with European case law.89 Havingfurther chosen an historical approach, he analysed in detail BSkyB’s downstreamcosts and revenues by assessing the return on turnover during comparable periodsof several months.90 He found that BSkyB had indeed been unprofitable in someof the early periods, but that since these losses had been limited and the appliedmodels were ‘subject to uncertainties’, no margin squeeze had been exercised.91

The analysis of effects was even more clearly highlighted in the 2003 BTOpenworld (Freeserve) decision, which concerned a margin squeeze allegation inrelation to broadband services offered by British Telecommunications plc (BT).92

OFTEL chose a clearly structured, two-tier approach.93 First, it analysed whetherthere was a margin squeeze by using two tests to assess profitability: (1) adiscounted cash flow test applied to the entire broadband business (in BSkyB, nofuture revenues were taken into account), and (2) a ‘cohort analysis’ of newcustomers over their expected subscriber lifetimes.94 After having found that anequally efficient competitor could have traded profitably on the downstreammarket concerned, OFTEL nevertheless engaged in an effects analysis, concludingthat there had indeed been no margin squeeze.95 The fact that OFTEL analysedthe effects despite having found no margin squeeze in the first place could beinterpreted as an effort to weaken objections to the EEC test, which oftenconstitutes too high a bar for new entrants.

In another 2003 decision, the effects analysis was to play an equally prominentrole. The BT/UK-SPN case concerned access to a BT network named‘UK-SPN’.96 Even though OFTEL had found that there was a margin squeeze, itdenied the existence of abuse on the grounds that there was ‘no evidence todemonstrate that the UK-SPN service [had] had a material adverse effect on

88 BSkyB investigation: alleged infringement of the Chapter II prohibition (Case CP 01916-00), Decision of theDirector General of Fair Trading CA98/20/2002 of Dec. 17, 2002, paras. 321, 341.

89 Id. paras. 354–356.90 Id. paras. 388–390, 413, 539.91 Id. paras. 541, 546f.92 Investigation by the Director General of Telecommunications (the ‘Director’) into alleged anticompetitive practices

by British Telecommunications plc (‘BT’) in relation to BTOpenworld’s (‘BTOW’) consumer broadbandproducts, OFTEL decision of Nov. 20, 2003, paras. 2.1–2.13.

93 Now OFCOM.94 Id. paras. 5.6, 6.147–6.161.95 Id. 5.6, 6.162, 7.1–7.21.96 Investigation by the Director General of Telecommunciations (The Director) into alleged anti-competitive pricing by

British Telecommunicaitons plc (BT) in relation to its UK-SPN calls service, OFTEL decision of May 23,2003, para. 7f.

WORLD COMPETITION218

competition’.97 It should be underlined that a form-based approach would havereached a diametrically opposed result.

Finally, the 2004 BT Together decision concerned the market for calls toresidential retail customers.98 This decision is notable because of the sheer numberof test variations OFCOM applied.They can be summarized as follows:

– All tests were based first on the data of an EEC and then on the data of anREC in order to take into account the customer acquisition costs faced byBT’s downstream rivals.99

– Two cost tests were applied: a fully allocated costs (FAC) test and a LRAICtest.100

– Additionally, all tests were based on different combinations of local, nationaland international calls, including a combinatorial test.101

BT’s prices passed all these tests, no margin squeeze was found.102

While it can be observed that even the most elaborate analyses do not removeall uncertainties, they obviously improve the traceability and quality of decisions.The European Commission could clearly learn a lesson from the flexibility withwhich tests are applied by the UK authorities.

3.3 FURTHER EUROPEAN DECISIONS

As in the United Kingdom, margin squeeze is a recognized stand-alone case ofabuse in France and Switzerland. In both these jurisdictions (the latter of which isoutside the European Union), competition authorities regularly refer to EUdecisions in their economic analyses. However, so far they do not seem to haveembraced a systematic analysis of effects.

The French case Tenor (2004)103 concerned a margin squeeze between theprice of fixed-to-mobile calls which France Télécom (FT) charged its retailbusiness customers (downstream market) and the wholesale price of calls to FT’smobile division (call termination in the upstream market). While the upstreamprices for call termination had been fixed by regulation, FT had over severalmonths charged its customers downstream prices that would not have allowed an

97 Id. paras. 41, 49.98 Investigation against BT about potential anti-competitive exclusionary behaviour (Case CW/00760/03/04),

OFCOM decision of July 12, 2004, para. 41.99 Id. paras. 55, 108, 119, 121f.100 Id. para. 109.101 Id. paras. 65, 112f.102 Id. paras. 111, 124f.103 Pratiques mises en œuvre par FranceTélécom, SFR, Cegetel et BouyguesTélécom (Case No. 04-D-48) Conseil

de la concurrence decision of Oct. 14, 2004 (hereinafter Tenor).

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 219

equally efficient competitor to recover its long-run incremental costs.104 In twoinstances, the Conseil de la concurrence105 quoted the Commission’s Deutsche Telekomdecision: first, to state that competition law was applicable despite pre-existingregulatory rules and second, to make a point that proving the existence of amargin squeeze did not require demonstration of any effects on competition.106

This pattern of analysis, relying on a presumption of effects, was upheld by theCour de Cassation in 2009.107 Nevertheless, two years later, the Cour d’Appel deParis ordered all fines to be repaid because it found that the Conseil had failed toprove that the conduct ‘had [had] or could have [had] any restrictive or distortiveeffect on competition’.108

Finally, in the 2010 Preispolitik Swisscom ADSL decision, the SwissCompetition Commission (COMCO) fined the incumbent Swisscom for havingengaged in a margin squeeze between its prices for wholesale broadband internetaccess (upstream market) and its retail broadband prices (downstream market).109

COMCO calculated the admissible margin by applying a retail minus approach onthe basis of a historical profitability test and found that neither an equally nor areasonably efficient competitor could have traded profitably on the retail ADSLmarket.110 Notably, Swisscom had been under no regulatory duty to deal;however, COMCO observed that given Swisscom’s market power, this wasirrelevant as an antitrust duty to deal would have existed.111

*Overall, in Europe there is a clear tendency towards an economics-based

approach. While the UK authorities seem most at ease with handling economicmodels, the European Commission can be said to have made up much of theleeway in the Telefónica decision.The next section will contrast this approach withthat of the United States.

104 Tenor, supra n. 103, paras. 18, 51, 54, 66–69. In addition, the regulated (upstream) price was above FT’sactual costs (para. 184).

105 Now Autorité de la concurrence.106 Id. paras. 201, 242–245 (nevertheless, the Conseil did demonstrate the relevant effects). See also

Autorité de la concurrence, ‘Rapport annuel 2008’ (Mar. 2009) http://www.autoritedelaconcurrence.fr/doc/etudes_ra08.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011, 156.

107 Case SFR [2009] Cour de Cassation decision 198 FS-P+B of Mar. 3, 2009, 5f.108 Case SFR/France Télécom [2011] Cour d’Appel de Paris decision 2010/08945 of Jan. 27, 2011, 17

(‘avaient ou pouvaient avoir pour effets de restreindre ou de fausser le jeu de la concurrence’).109 Preispolitik Swisscom ADSL (Case 32-0198) Wettbewerbskommission decision of Oct. 19, 2009, paras.

329, 425.110 Id. paras. 223, 231, 264, 281;Alessandro Celli, Boris Wenger & Nicolas Diebold, The Public Competition

Enforcement Review 410f (Shaun Goodman ed., Law Business Research 2010).111 Preispolitik Swisscom ADSL, supra n. 109, paras. 192–197.

WORLD COMPETITION220

3.4 UNITED STATES

The approach to margin squeeze cases chosen by the United States differsconsiderably from Europe’s. This divide can partly be explained by institutionaldifferences.112 However, the discrepancy is also philosophical: the willingness ofEuropean antitrust authorities to intervene in already regulated markets has metwith little acceptance in the US Supreme Court.

What the DeutscheTelekom and TeliaSonera decisions are to Europe, the linkLinedecision (2009) is to the United States.113 AT&T, a vertically integrated companyactive and dominant in the markets of both wholesale and retail broadbandinternet access, had a regulatory duty to provide wholesale access to its network atprices no higher than its retail prices.114 The question before the Supreme Courtwas whether, absent an antitrust duty to deal, a price squeeze claim under section2 of the Sherman Act was admissible.115

Before turning to the court’s assessment, the relevant findings of fourprecedents will briefly be outlined:

– In the 1945 Alcoa judgment, a Circuit Court held it unlawful for a vertically integrated company to fix an upstream price higher than a ‘fair price’ if this resulted in a ‘squeeze’ of competitors’ profits.116

– In Town of Concord (1990), it was held that a court being no ‘rate-settingregulatory agency’, it was in no position to determine what a ‘fair price’was.117

– In the Brooke Group decision (1993), the Supreme Court held that acompany’s prices were predatory if they were (1) below its rivals’ costs, and(2) there was a dangerous probability of recoupment.118

– Finally, in Trinko (2004), this court decided that regulatory duties did notcreate any new obligations under competition law and that in the absenceof a (rare) special duty to deal, ‘insufficient assistance’ to competitors didnot amount to an abuse.119

The Supreme Court’s reasoning in the linkLine case consisted of three main steps:(1) given the District Court’s binding decision that AT&T had no antitrust dutyto deal, it followed from Trinko that AT&T had even less of a duty to deal under

112 Chapter IV.5.113 Pacific BellTelephone Co v linkLine Communications Inc 172 L Ed 2d 836 (2009).114 linkLine, supra n. 113, 842.115 Id. 844.116 United States v.Aluminium Co of America 148 F2d 416 (2d Cir 1945), 438.117 Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Company 915 F2d 17 (1st Cir 1990), 25.118 Brooke Group Ltd v. Brown &WilliamsonTobacco Corp 509 US 209 (1993), 222–224.119 Verizon Communications Inc v Law Offices of CurtisVTrinko LLP 540 US 398 (2004), 410–412.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 221

terms favourable to downstream competitors;120 (2) retail prices could not betested under Brooke Group as the plaintiff had made no such claim;121 (3) the pricesqueeze doctrine in this context was ‘nothing more than an amalgamation of ameritless claim at the retail and a meritless claim at the wholesale level’.122 TheSupreme Court stated that admitting such a doctrine could chill price competitionand would ask courts to set prices which, as had been held in Town of Concord, theywere ill-suited to do.123 Considering therefore that margin squeeze belonged tothe regulatory sphere, the court also rejected the Alcoa decision by a vaguereference to changes in economic theory and competition jurisprudence.124

In a hardly noticeable statement, the court further rebuffed the EEC test as ameans to determine a fair price as it lacked grounding in the court’sjurisprudence.125 Interestingly, in a 2008 report, the Department of Justice (DOJ)had declared this test to be preferred when assessing single-firm price conduct.126

However, this same report also endorsed the Trinko approach on refusals to dealand omitted to recognize margin squeeze as a form of abuse.127 When the DOJadopted this position in an amicus curiae brief for the linkLine decision, theFederal Trade Commission chose to publicly disagree as it considered marginsqueeze to have been part of the section 2 doctrine since Alcoa.128

While by no means uncontested in the United States,129 the SupremeCourt’s decision spares antitrust authorities the hassle of engaging in uncertainprice assessments, leaving this task to the regulators. However, it is notable that inEurope, and most markedly in the United Kingdom, the co-existence ofregulatory and antirust issues has led to no comparable institutional schism.

120 linkLine, supra n. 113, 842f, 846f.121 Id. 847.122 Id. 848.123 Id. 847, 849.124 Id. 848, fn. 3.125 Id. 849.126 Department of Justice, Competition and Monopoly: Single-firm Conduct under Section 2 of the Sherman Act

(Sept. 2008) (hereinafter DOJ Report) http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/reports/236681.pdfaccessed Sept. 1, 2011, 43–45.This report has been withdrawn by the Obama administration.

127 Id. 119–129.128 Department of Justice, ‘Pacific Bell Telephone Company, dba AT&T California, Petitioners v linkLine

Communications, Inc, Brief for the United States as Amicus Curiae’ (May 2008) http://www.justice.gov/atr/cases/f233500/233594.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011 7; Federal Trade Commission,‘Statement of the Federal Trade Commission Declining to Join the US Department of JusticeRecommendation That the United States Supreme Court Review the Decision of the Court ofAppeals for the Ninth Circuit In linkLine Comms v Pacific Bell Telephone Company’ (May 2008)http://www.ftc.gov/os/2008/05/P072104stmt.pdf, accessed Sept. 1, 2011, 3–4.

129 Aryeh Friedman & Joyce Choi, linkLine: Supreme Court Weighs Survival of Price-Squeeze Claims, TheAntitrust Source 1, 6 (2008).

WORLD COMPETITION222

4 A MORE ECONOMICS-BASED APPROACH TO MARGINSQUEEZE ANALYSIS

The European model of margin squeeze analysis implies the use of economicmodels. Economic models help determine which competitors should be deemedefficient and therefore be able to trade profitably.Authorities applying such modelsshould address four main dimensions: (1) which company is to be consideredefficient, (2) which of its costs must be taken into account, (3) which time frame isrelevant for the analysis and (4) which level of product aggregation is adequate.After the discussion of these issues, the analysis will turn to the fundamentalquestion of how regulation and competition law can coexist (5).

4.1 WHOSE COSTS?: THE IMPUTATION TEST

The predominant view is that the vertically integrated firm should be the modelof reference for an efficient company. The relevant margin is calculated bydeducing this firm’s upstream access price from the downstream price charged toits consumers (equally efficient competitor/EEC test).130 The advantage of thisstandard is that the dominant firm is able to evaluate whether it is ‘squeezing themargin’ on the basis of its very own data.131

However, the EEC test is criticized on two main fronts. On the one hand, anew entrant without the incumbent’s economies of scale and scope might beunable to reach this level of efficiency;132 on the other hand, a competitor couldbe selling slightly differentiated products.133 Additionally, an assessment based onthe dominant firm’s situation may even lead to false positives if the rival’s productsare in fact more profitable or subject to less demand elasticity.134

Several authors have therefore advocated an approach which would ‘allow areasonably efficient service provider in the downstream market to obtain a normal

130 European Commission,‘Notice on the Application of the Competition Rules to Access Agreements inthe Telecommunications Sector’ COM (1998) C265/2 (Access Notice), para. 117; O’Donoghue &Padilla, supra n. 1, 313; Margarita Fernández Álvarez-Labrador, Margin Squeeze in the TelecommunicationsSector: an Economic Overview, 29 W. Comp. 247, 258 (2006).

131 Kavanagh, supra n. 1, at 192; Fernández, supra n. 130, at 257, 260;Amory &Verheyden, supra n. 44, at 6;Dennis W. Carlton, Should “Price Squeeze” Be a Recognized Form of Anticompetitive Conduct?, 4 J. Compet.L. & Econ. 271, 274 (2008); Simon Genevaz, Margin Squeeze after Deutsche Telekom, Global Compet.Policy 1, 20 (2008); Oxera, No Margin for Error: the Challenges of Assessing Margin Squeeze in Practice(Oxera Agenda 2009) http://www.oxera.com/cmsDocuments/Agenda_November%2009/Margin%20squeeze.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011 (Oxera 2009), 4.

132 TeliaSonera, supra n. 1, para. 45.133 Damien Geradin & Robert O’Donoghue, The Concurrent Application of Competition Law and Regulation:

the Case of Margin Squeeze Abuses in the Telecommunications Sector, 1 J. Compet. L. & Econ. 355, 393f(2005); Fernández, supra n. 130, at 260;Amory &Verheyden, supra n. 44, at 13; CEPS, supra n. 20, 82.

134 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 393f; Fernández, supra n. 130, at 260.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 223

profit’ (reasonably efficient competitor/REC test).135 Having already been applied inregulatory contexts, the REC test is most often cited in relation to recentlyliberalized industries such as telecommunications.136 While the downside of thisapproach would be the risk of protecting less efficient competitors, supportersargue that possible short-term losses would be offset by the long-term gains ofmore vigorous competition.137 However, the dominant firm’s inability to exactlycalculate the relevant margin might lead to a situation of legal uncertainty hostileto vigorous price competition.138

In Europe, the 1998 Access Notice prepared the ground for the two tests.139

The Discussion Paper, the Guidance Paper and most recently the TeliaSonera caseendorsed the EEC test but reserved the right to base the analysis on data of lessefficient operators.140 The Deutsche Telekom case, however, can be seen as anunequivocal statement in favour of the EEC test.141 Similarly, the majority ofcountries taking part in a 2010 OECD survey expressed preference for this test.142

Nonetheless, the REC test has often been applied as a second test and led tothe same outcome.143 The question is what would happen if a firm passed theEEC test but failed the REC test.While an automatic preference for the EEC testwould make the second test look farcical, the REC test should only prevail wherea competition authority can transparently show that the entry of a less efficientcompetitor will lead to positive effects on competition within a reasonable timehorizon, according to antitrust standards of efficiency and consumer welfare.

4.2 WHICH COSTS?: THE COST TEST

Two main methods strive to answer the question of exactly which costs should betaken into account when applying an imputation test.

135 Access Notice, supra n. 130, para. 118. See also Kavanagh, supra n. 1, at 193; Serge Clerckx & LaurentDe Muyter, Price Squeeze Abuse in the EUTelecommunications Sector:A Reasonably or Equally EfficientTest?,GCP 1, 6 (2009); Faella & Pardolesi, supra n. 44, at 276f.

136 See supra n. 135; Oxera (2009), supra n. 131, 4.137 Kavanagh, supra n. 1, at 193; Oxera (2009), supra n. 131, 4.138 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 392; Oxera (2009), supra n. 131, 4.139 Access Notice, supra n. 130, para. 117f.140 TeliaSonera, supra n. 1, para. 45; Discussion Paper, supra n. 19, paras. 63, 67; Guidance Paper, supra n. 12,

paras. 23f;Temple Lang (2009a), supra n. 32, 3.141 See supra n. 56.142 Autorité de la concurrence, supra n. 106, 148f; DOJ Report, supra n. 126, 43–45; OECD (2010), supra

n. 87, 97 (France), 127f (Germany), 143 (Italy), 153 (Korea), 162 (Mexico), 182 (Norway), 185(Poland), 193 (Portugal), 202 (Slovak Republic), 218 (Turkey).

143 See the Genzyme, supra n. 85, BT Together, supra n. 98, and Preispolitik Swisscom ADSL, supra n. 109,cases.

WORLD COMPETITION224

Access pricing:144 The first method focuses on the access price charged by theincumbent. An incumbent who provides a bottleneck input incurs three sorts ofcosts: those for the input itself, those for providing the input and those regardingforegone profits because the incumbent does not sell the end product itself(opportunity costs).145 A common method to assess these costs is the efficientcomponent pricing rule (ECPR) according to which upstream costs includeincremental costs plus foregone profits; as this figure corresponds to the subtractionof the downstream costs from the downstream revenues (minus a profit margin),this approach is also called retail minus.146 While the merit of this approach is thatit reflects conditions in a market environment, a clear disadvantage is that theincumbent’s price level is accepted as given.147 Furthermore, as a consequence ofthe inclusion of opportunity costs, only competitors that are more efficient than theincumbent will manage to trade profitably, which contradicts the EEC test.148

LRAIC: The test most commonly applied in order to directly measure thedownstream costs which an efficient rival is expected to cover is the long-runaverage incremental costs (LRAIC) test.149 It takes account of all product-specificvariable and fixed costs incurred in relation to the relevant products, but as it iscost-based, it does not factor in foregone profits.150 LRAIC are similar to fullyallocated costs (FAC) except when there are costs common to many products:common costs are included in FAC calculations, while this is only the case inLRAIC calculations when common costs are product-specific and would not havebeen incurred anyway.151 Several authorities and authors propose to consider amark-up (LRAIC+) whenever the LRAIC test would lead to the exclusion of

144 In practice, the access price is often regulated. See Crocioni & Veljanovski, supra n. 1, at 58; JohnVickers, Competition Policy and Property Rights, 120 The Econ. J. 375, 379 (2010).

145 Liam Colley & Sebastian Burnside, Margin Squeeze Abuse, 2 Eur.Compet. J. 185, 194 (2006);Fernández, supra n. 130, at 253; Laura Ferrari Bravo & Paolo Siciliani, Exclusionary Pricing andConsumers Harm:The European Commission’s Practice in the DSL Market, 3 J. Compet. L. & Econ. 243,252 (2007); Michele Polo, Price Squeeze: Lessons from the Telecom Italia Case, 3 J. Compet. L. & Econ.453, 455–458 (2007).

146 Crocioni &Veljanovski, supra n. 1, at 59; Robert W. Crandall & Hal J. Singer, Life Support for UnaffiliatedISPs?, 28 Regulation 46, 51 (2005); Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 374f; Ricardo Gonçalves,‘Cost Orientation and xDSL Services: Retail-Minus vs LRAIC’ 31 Telecommunications Policy 524,525 (2007).

147 Crocioni & Veljanovski, supra n. 1, at 59 fn. 77; Milena Stoyanova, Regulation and Competition LawApproaches to Price Squeeze: Access Pricing in the Telecommunications Sector 1 Eur. Compet. J. 347 (2005);Vickers 2010, supra n. 144, at 378.

148 Polo, supra n. 145, at 456; Crandall & Singer, supra n. 146, at 51.149 Average variable costs would not cover the whole range of costs which a new entrant incurs, see

OFTEL, ‘Analytical Framework for New Freeserve Case’ (Draft, Aug. 2003) http://www.ofcom.org.uk/static/archive/oftel/publications/comp_bull/cases/cw_613a.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011, para.72.

150 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 374; Rousseva, supra n. 14, at 375.151 Derek Ridyard, The Commission’s Article 82 Guidelines: Some Reflections on the Economic Issues, 30 ECLR

230, 231 (2009); Pietro Crocioni, Price Squeeze and Imputation Test: Recent Developments, 26 ECLR 558,564 (2005); Rousseva, supra n. 14, at 375.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 225

significant common costs in markets where variable costs are minimal.152 The factthat fixed costs are taken into consideration makes it more favourable to newentrants and forces the incumbent to remain competitive.153

The European Commission has endorsed the LRAIC test in the Telefónicadecision and in the Guidance Paper.154 Furthermore, this methodology isfrequently used at the international level.155 The US Federal CommunicationsCommission even considered the ECPR test incompatible with the requirementsof the 1996 Telecommunications Act.156

Nevertheless, the fact that the LRAIC test is more favourable to competitorshas led to concerns that it would discourage investment and innovation.157 In acase concerning the British broadband market, OFCOM applied the ECPR testafter considering that it was more important not to discourage investment by theincumbent, given the uncertain evolution of competition.158

To conclude, it should be noted that while the focus here has been on onlytwo tests, agencies with sufficient resources and expertise are capable of applyingan almost infinite variety of cost tests.159

4.3 WHICH TEMPORAL DIMENSION?: THE PROFITABILITY TEST

Two main tests answer the question of what time frame the economic modelsshould focus on.

The static period-by-period test (or historical test) measures costs and revenuesduring sequences of fixed periods, for instance accounting years.160 In stable and

152 Direction to resolve a dispute between BT, Energis and Thus concerning xDSL interconnection at the ATMswitch, OFTEL direction of June 21, 2002, para. 4.2; OFT 417, supra n. 84, para. 7.6; Guidance Paper,supra n. 12, para. 26 fn. 2; CEPS, supra n. 20, 35f; Ferrari Bravo & Siciliani, supra n. 145, 259; Oxera(2009), supra n. 131, 5.

153 Rousseva, supra n. 14, at 375.154 Telefónica, supra n. 6, para. 318; Guidance Paper, supra n. 12, para. 80.155 BT Together, supra n. 98, para. 109; Tenor, supra n. 103, para. 54; OFT 417, supra n. 87, paras. 7.7–7.10;

OECD (2010), supra n. 87, 11; Gonçalves, supra n. 146, 524.156 Federal Communications Commission, First Report and Order in the Matter of Implementation of the Local

Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Interconnection between Local Exchange Carriersand Commercial Mobile Radio Service Providers (FCC 96–325, Aug. 1996) http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common_Carrier/Orders/1996/fcc96325.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011, paras. 625, 632f.

157 Direction BT, Energis and Thus, supra n. 152, para. 4.9f; Rousseva, supra n. 14, 375; Gonçalves, supra n146, 527.

158 OFCOM, Review of the Wholesale Broadband Access Markets (May 2004) http://stakeholders.ofcom.org.uk/binaries/consultations/wbamp/summary/broadbandaccessreview.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011, paras.4.46–4.48.

159 See Complaint from Energis Communications Ltd about BT’s charges for NTS call termination (CaseCW/00823/03/05), OFCOM decision of Aug. 1, 2008, paras. 6.511, 6.74–6.86.

160 European Regulators Group, Report on the Discussion on the Application of Margin Squeeze Tests to Bundles(Mar. 2009) http://www.erg.eu.int/doc/publications/2009/erg_09_07_report_on_the_discussion_of_

WORLD COMPETITION226

mature markets, this backward-looking method allows for an adequate assessmentof profitability.161

In dynamic or immature markets, a static evaluation would risk ignoring thepotential for future profits, particularly when applied to a period during whichheavy investments were necessary.162 The forward-looking discounted cash flow(DCF) method seems more appropriate: the expected cash flow (revenues, costs)caused by an investment is forecast over a period of several years, then discountedback while taking into account the cost of capital, and finally added up to create ameasure called net present value (NPV).163

There are two problems with this latter method: first, initial losses can alreadybe sufficient to cause efficient competitors to leave; second, profits are taken intoaccount irrespective of whether they are earned as a consequence of exclusionarybehaviour.164 In spite of these flaws, a dynamic view will often be the moreappropriate approach in the telecommunications sector.165 However, in order toovercome the danger of inequitable outcomes, competition agencies should alwaysengage in a proper effects analysis.166

4.4 WHICH PRODUCTS?: THE AGGREGATION TEST

In many cases, there will not be a ‘linear vertical chain of production’ between theupstream and downstream services; similarly, the dominant company and its rivalsmay sell different ranges of services, which may be offered in various bundles.167

The choice of the level of aggregation (downstream market definition) willnecessarily influence the outcome of a margin squeeze case.

If only part of a bundle of services offered by the incumbent is assessedbecause its rivals only sell smaller bundles, an exact allocation of costs (within theincumbent’s bundle) might be impossible.168 Under such circumstances, it iscertainly advisable to also run the tests on the basis of rivals’ data in order tostrengthen the result’s credibility.169

the_application_of_margin_squeeze_tests_to_bundles.pdf accessed Sept. 1, 2011 (hereinafter ERG),para. 70; Oxera (2009), supra n. 131, 3.

161 Kavanagh, supra n. 1, at 195; OECD (2010), supra n. 87, 259f.162 O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 318; OECD (2010), supra n. 87, 260.163 O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 318f; ERG, supra n. 160, paras. 72–77.164 OFT, Assessing Profitability in Competition Policy Analysis, (Economic Discussion Paper 6, July. 2003)

(hereinafter OFT 656), 49; O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 319; ERG, supra n 160, para. 78;CEPS, supra n. 20, 85.

165 Guidance Paper, supra n. 12, paras. 13, 24, 83 fn. 3.166 OFT 656, supra n. 164, 50.167 O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 330f; J. Gregory Sidak, Abolishing the Price Squeeze as a Theory of

Antitrust Liability, 4 J. Compet. L. & Econ. 279, 301 (2008).168 Autorité de la concurrence, supra n. 106, 152f; Crocioni, supra n. 151, 559.169 TeliaSonera, supra n. 1, para. 45; O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 331.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 227

In case the incumbent and its rivals offer comparable product ranges, anaggregated approach would allow the tests to be based on a presumably efficientstructure.170 If there were a risk that a margin squeeze is overlooked, acombinatorial test would be appropriate, which would require that the ‘revenue ofevery product by itself, and the combined revenue of every combination of thefirm’s products, […] be equal the corresponding average-incremental costs’.171

*With regard to economic models, one main lesson – highlighted in the

BSkyB and BT/UK-SPN decisions – stands out: given the relative arbitrarinessinherent in the choice and application of these models, a thorough effects analysisis required to make sure the outcome of an assessment harmonizes with theultimate objectives of competition law.172

The next section will deal with the delicate question of whether and howcompetition law should be applied in a regulatory environment.

4.5 THE REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT

Regulation can be seen as a ‘substitute for competitive market forces where thoseforces are weak or absent’.173 Despite incisive liberalization programmes, theEuropean telecommunications market has so far failed to become trulycompetitive.174 The question is whether competition law can add some missingpieces to fragmentary regulatory frameworks.

It has often been argued that pre-existing regulation leaves no room forcompetition law because:

– competition law would be pursuing regulatory goals;– there would be a risk of contradictory or inconsistent decisions;– competition authorities would be unable to handle the complexity of

technical questions;

170 NERA, Imputation Tests for Bundled Services (Report for the Australian Competition and ConsumerCommission, Jan. 2003) http://www.accc.gov.au/content/index.phtml/itemId/756876 accessed Sept.1, 2011, 26; Polo, supra n. 145, at 461;Autorité de la concurrence, supra n. 106, 153.

171 Baumol & Sidak, supra n. 4, at 70f (emphasis omitted); OFT 417, supra n. 84, para. 7.11.172 UK-SPN, supra n. 96, paras. 41–49; Genzyme, supra n. 85, para. 87; Forwood, supra n. 16, 3.173 Baumol & Sidak, supra n. 4, at 5.174 Directive 2002/19/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of Mar. 7, 2002 on access to,

and interconnection of, electronic communications networks and associated facilities (AccessDirective) [2002] OJ L108/7,Art. 12f; Baumol & Sidak, supra n. 4, at 5f, 46; Geradin & O’Donoghue,supra n. 133, at 345; Gonçalves, supra n. 146, at 528; ICN Report, supra n. 3, 9, 15, 25f; OECD (2010),supra n. 87, 229.

WORLD COMPETITION228

competition authorities could not appropriately monitor compliance with theirdecisions.175

Ex ante regulation differs from the ex post application of competition law inseveral respects. Based on a detailed assessment of a particular sector, regulationnormally has a much broader mandate than competition law, including policygoals such as environmental and social equality or the encouragement ofinvestment.176 Regulation therefore promotes competition in more interventionistways than would be allowed under antitrust provisions. This need not, however,exclude parallel application of regulation and competition law. What follows is ashort examination of how two major jurisdictions have resolved this issue.

The US Supreme Court has taken a clear stance, holding in Trinko that wherea regulatory structure exists, ‘the additional benefit to competition provided byantitrust enforcement will tend to be small’, an interpretation upheld in the CreditSuisse and linkLine decisions.177 The fact that the 1996 Telecommunications Act178

explicitly provides for the applicability of competition law was interpreted inTrinko to mean that while established antitrust standards would apply, no newcompetition law claims could be derived from that act.179 As a general rule, thecourt stated in Credit Suisse that ‘[w]here regulatory statutes are silent in respect toantitrust, […] courts must determine whether, and in what respects, they implicitlypreclude application of the antitrust laws’.180

In contrast, Europe’s highest court favoured parallel application, provided thatthe firm’s infringement of competition law was not caused by its duty to complywith regulatory requirements.181

Organizational differences may partly explain this divide: while in Europecompetition law is enforced by specialist agencies, in the United Statesenforcement is primarily private, and it is feared that courts could interfere withregulators’ expert assessments.182

175 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 361, 410, 412; John Temple Lang, Neueste Entwicklungen imeuropäischen und internationalen Kartellrecht 163 (Carl Baudenbacher ed., Helbing Lichtenhahn 2007)(hereinafter Temple Lang 2007); Caroline Cavaleri Rudaz, Did Trinko Really Kill Antitrust Price SqueezeClaims? A Critical Approach to the Linkline Decision through a Comparison of EU and US Case Law, 43VJTL 1077, 1110f (2010); Rousseva, supra n. 14, at 424.

176 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 362f; O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 245 fn. 138;Temple Lang (2006), supra n. 32, 4; Temple Lang (2007), supra n. 175, 163; Cavaleri, supra n. 175, at1111.

177 Trinko, supra n. 119, 412; Credit Suisse Securities (USA) LLC fka Credit Suisse First Boston LLC v. Billing168 L Ed 2d 145 (2007), 160f; linkLine, supra n. 113, 846; Genevaz, supra n. 131, 34;Vickers (2010),supra n. 144, 391.

178 Section 601(b) Telecommunications Act 1996.179 Trinko, supra n. 119, 407.180 Credit Suisse, supra n. 177, 153.181 Deutsche Telekom (CJEU), supra n. 1, para. 85; see also Case T–398/07 Spain v. Commission [2012]

unreported, para. 71f.182 Genevaz, supra n. 131, at 37; Sidak, supra n. 167, at 307.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 229

Another point is that in the European Union competition law is primary lawwhich prevails over the secondary law instruments containing the regulatoryprogrammes, whereas in the United States antitrust and regulation are on equalfooting.183 Commenting on the situation in Europe, Geradin and O’Donoghueargue that the Commission may simply choose not to intervene wheresector-specific regulation exists.184 If regulation has adequately taken account ofcompetition concerns and is effectively enforced by the responsible authority, thisis certainly reasonable; but it should not be an option otherwise, since a lacunalregulatory regime cannot be an excuse for suspending the application ofcompetition law.185

Overall, and given that regulation and competition law have comparableobjectives with regard to margin squeeze, it appears sensible to stress theircomplementary character.186 Indeed, both use similar microeconomic techniquesto design measures intended to guide markets back to the avenue of efficiency.187

While Trinko correctly stated that regulation does not create any new antitrustclaims, it seems right to apply competition law whenever a regulatory regime failsto adequately address antitrust concerns.

5 CONCLUSION

The treatment of margin squeeze by the Commission and the courts of theEuropean Union has undergone a significant transformation from a barelyconceptualized assessment in the early decisions to a progressively systematicanalysis.

As its experience in assessing margin squeeze cases increased, the Commission– like other European competition authorities – began to rely on a moreeconomics-based approach. Quite conversely, the US Supreme Court categoricallyrejected both the recognition of margin squeeze as a stand-alone case of abuse andthe application of antitrust law in regulatory contexts.

While the European agencies’ approach is justified by their growingcompetence and expertise, the use of economic models implies considerableuncertainties.This calls for a transparent effects analysis ensuring that the application

183 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 418.184 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 418. While the Commission is unlikely to be able to

categorically rule out intervention in such cases, this would seem to be possible on a case-by-casebasis, see Ezrachi (2009b), supra n. 14, 10.

185 Geradin & O’Donoghue, supra n. 133, at 418; Sidak, supra n. 167, at 282.186 Friedman & Choi, supra n. 129, at 6; Genevaz, supra n. 131, at 37;Tu Thanh Nguyen, Price Squeezing:

Linkline in the United States – No Link to the European Union, Intl. Rev. Intell. Prop. Competition L.316, 335 (2010).

187 Baumol & Sidak, supra n. 4, at 26f; O’Donoghue & Padilla, supra n. 1, at 345.

WORLD COMPETITION230

of these models ultimately leads to the promotion of competition, efficiency andconsumer welfare.

Regrettably, the courts, while supporting the idea of an effects-basedapproach, seem to be satisfied with a demonstration of potential effects, which,furthermore, only have to relate to competition in the market, not to consumerwelfare.While consumer detriment was clearly part of the abuse analysis after theDeutsche Telekom case, the TeliaSonera decision degraded it to the status of anobjective justification, which has to be proven not by the Commission, but by theundertaking concerned.

It is crucial that the Commission continue to take consumer considerationsinto account when assessing a potential abuse and it is hoped that it does so notjust by way of a simple reference to the apparently self-evident causality betweendistorted competition and consumer harm,188 but by specifically demonstratingeffects on consumers with the help of economic evidence. Such an approach willallow the Commission to focus on truly harmful forms of conduct, therebyavoiding chilling competition.

While the latest margin squeeze cases are clearly among the European courts’most progressive decisions on effects in the context of Article 102 TFEU,189 thereis room for improvement. Generally, a look over the Channel and across theAtlantic will often prove instructive. First, with regard to the Commission, there issomething to be said for the robustness of the economic analysis as it is practised inthe United Kingdom. Second, with regard to the courts, the US Supreme Court’ssystematic focus on consumer welfare would not only be in perfect harmony withEuropean competition policy, it could also become a beacon in the windy watersof margin squeeze analysis.

If the European institutions consistently cling to the economics-basedstandards set in policy papers and recent court decisions, and if they require effectsanalyses to convincingly prove a ‘net negative economic effect’190 on competitionand consumers, then the normative force of quality could come to constitute thehallmark of decisions based on the more economics- and effects-based approach.

188 See Case C-95/04 P British Airways v. Commission [2007] ECR I-2331, Opinion of AG Kokott, para.68.

189 See Ezrachi (2009a), supra n. 17, 57f; Dayagi-Epstein, supra n. 26, at 83; Manuel Kellerbauer, TheCommission’s New Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 EC to Dominant Companies’ ExclusionaryConduct:A ShiftTowards a More Economic Approach?, 31 Econ. Competition L. Rev. 175, 181 (2010).

190 Paraphrase of an expression in C-468/06 to C-478/06 Sot Lelos kai Sia EE v. GlaxoSmithKline [2008]ECR I-7139, Opinion of AG Ruiz-Jarabo Colomer, para. 79.

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE TELECOMMUNICATIONS SECTOR 231