Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

58
Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis of the Clientele Effect in the Corporate Bond Market * Jing-Zhi Huang, Zhenzhen Sun, Tong Yao, and Tong Yu September 2014 Abstract This paper examines how liquidity and investors’ heterogeneous liquidity preferences interact to affect asset pricing. We construct measures of liquidity preferences us- ing data on insurer corporate bond holdings, and find that investors’ preferences are highly persistent over time and related to investment horizons and funding con- straints. We provide evidence that investors vary widely in their preferences and, more importantly, evidence for liquidity clientele. Further, we find evidence that liq- uidity clienteles affect corporate bond prices—specifically, both the level and volatility of liquidity premia are substantially attenuated among corporate bonds heavily held by investors with a weak preference for liquidity. Keywords : Corporate Bond Holdings, Liquidity Clientele, Corporate Bond Liquidity and Spreads * We are very grateful to Yakov Amihud, Sandro Andrade (SFS Finance Cavalcade discussant), Jennie Bai, Jack Bao (EFA discussant), Dan Bergstresser (BAFC discussant), Pierre Collin-Dufresne (AFA discus- sant), Jens Dick-Nielsen (MFA discussant), Song Han (CICF discussant), Jean Helwege, Jennifer Huang, Igor Kozhanov (FMA discussant), Marco Rossi, and Adam Zawadowski (FIRS discussant) for helpful and detailed comments and suggestions. We also thank seminar participants at Baruch College, City University of Hong Kong, Nanjing University, SAIF, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, University of Iowa, and Washington State University; and conference participants at the 2013 SFS Finance Cavalcade, 2013 European Finance Association Meetings, 2013 Midwest Finance Association Meetings, 2013 China International Conference in Finance, 2013 Boston Area Finance Conference, 2013 Financial Management Association meetings, 2014 American Finance Association meetings, and 2014 Financial Intermediation Re- search Society meetings for valuable comments and suggestions. Huang is at the Smeal College of Business, Pennsylvania State University. Email: [email protected]. Sun is at School of Business, Siena College. Email: [email protected]. Yao is at Henry B. Tippie College of Business, University of Iowa. Email: [email protected]. Yu is at College of Business and Administration, University of Rhode Island. Email: [email protected].

Transcript of Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Page 1: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder:

An Analysis of the Clientele Effect in the Corporate Bond Market∗

Jing-Zhi Huang, Zhenzhen Sun, Tong Yao, and Tong Yu†

September 2014

Abstract

This paper examines how liquidity and investors’ heterogeneous liquidity preferences

interact to affect asset pricing. We construct measures of liquidity preferences us-

ing data on insurer corporate bond holdings, and find that investors’ preferences

are highly persistent over time and related to investment horizons and funding con-

straints. We provide evidence that investors vary widely in their preferences and,

more importantly, evidence for liquidity clientele. Further, we find evidence that liq-

uidity clienteles affect corporate bond prices—specifically, both the level and volatility

of liquidity premia are substantially attenuated among corporate bonds heavily held

by investors with a weak preference for liquidity.

Keywords: Corporate Bond Holdings, Liquidity Clientele, Corporate Bond Liquidity and Spreads

∗We are very grateful to Yakov Amihud, Sandro Andrade (SFS Finance Cavalcade discussant), JennieBai, Jack Bao (EFA discussant), Dan Bergstresser (BAFC discussant), Pierre Collin-Dufresne (AFA discus-sant), Jens Dick-Nielsen (MFA discussant), Song Han (CICF discussant), Jean Helwege, Jennifer Huang,Igor Kozhanov (FMA discussant), Marco Rossi, and Adam Zawadowski (FIRS discussant) for helpful anddetailed comments and suggestions. We also thank seminar participants at Baruch College, City Universityof Hong Kong, Nanjing University, SAIF, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, University ofIowa, and Washington State University; and conference participants at the 2013 SFS Finance Cavalcade,2013 European Finance Association Meetings, 2013 Midwest Finance Association Meetings, 2013 ChinaInternational Conference in Finance, 2013 Boston Area Finance Conference, 2013 Financial ManagementAssociation meetings, 2014 American Finance Association meetings, and 2014 Financial Intermediation Re-search Society meetings for valuable comments and suggestions.†Huang is at the Smeal College of Business, Pennsylvania State University. Email: [email protected]. Sun is

at School of Business, Siena College. Email: [email protected]. Yao is at Henry B. Tippie College of Business,University of Iowa. Email: [email protected]. Yu is at College of Business and Administration, Universityof Rhode Island. Email: [email protected].

Page 2: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

1 Introduction

Liquidity plays an important role in asset pricing. For example, liquidity premium—the

compensation demanded by investors for holding illiquid assets—has been documented in

various sectors of the financial market (e.g., Amihud, Mendelson, and Pedersen (2012) and

references therein). More recently, a growing literature on the credit market has argued

that liquidity may help explain the substantial unexplained component in corporate bond

yield spread changes (Collin-Dufresne, Goldstein, and Martin (2001)) and the “credit spread

puzzle” (Huang and Huang (2012)). Indeed, empirical studies such as Longstaff, Mithal, and

Neis (2005), Chen, Lesmond, and Wei (2007), Bao, Pan, and Wang (2011), Dick-Nielsen,

Feldhutter, and Lando (2012), and Friewald, Jankowitsch, and Subrahmanyam (2012), have

reported a significant liquidity component in corporate bond yield spreads.

In this study we examine the related phenomenon of “liquidity clientele”—that is, due

perhaps to heterogeneous investment horizons, some investors may require less compensation

for holding illiquid securities and prefer holding more illiquid securities given the same level

of compensation per extra unit of illiquidity, while other investors may prefer the opposite.

When illiquid securities predominantly attract investors with low liquidity preference, the

liquidity premium on these securities may be attenuated.

The idea of liquidity clientele can be traced to Amihud and Mendelson (1986), who

show that when investors with longer (exogenous) investment horizons tend to hold more

illiquid securities. In their model, the attenuating effect of liquidity clientele on liquidity

premium results in an unconditionally concave relation between trading cost and liquidity

premium. Subsequent theoretical studies (reviewed in Section II) have also concluded on the

importance of liquidity clientele when it comes to understanding the overall liquidity effect

on asset pricing. Despite such prominent predictions, however, so far there is little direct

empirical evidence on the liquidity clientele effect.

This study examines liquidity clientele and its asset pricing implications in the corporate

bond market—where liquidity presumably matters more than it does for equities or Treasury

securities. We analyze corporate bond holdings of insurance companies, which are by far

1

Page 3: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

the largest group of corporate bond investors (e.g., Campbell and Taksler (2003) and Ellul,

Jotikasthira, and Lundblad (2011)).1 Our data sample covers corporate bond holdings of

3,413 U.S. insurers during the period of 2003-2011.

To detect the presence of liquidity clientele, we quantify the illiquidity of an insurer’s

corporate bond portfolio (ILP) by the weighted average illiquidity of corporate bonds it

holds, where the bond-level illiquidity is based on five different measures from the existing

literature. We find that portfolio illiquidity is widely dispersed across insurers and highly

persistent over time. More importantly, insurers’ portfolio illiquidity can be linked to firm

characteristics indicative of their investment horizons. For example, insurers with higher

ILPs (i.e., holding more illiquid bonds) tend to have lower trading turnover and hold bonds

longer in their portfolios, and are more likely to be life insurers whose liability maturities are

typically longer than those of property and casualty insurers. These patterns are consistent

with the notion of the “liquidity clientele effect” introduced by Amihud and Mendelson

(1986). Going beyond the Amihud and Mendelson (1986) model, we find that investors’

funding constraints also affect their portfolio illiquidity. Insurers with higher ILPs tend to

be older, affiliated with an insurance group or a parent holding company, and more likely to

use re-insurance to outsource the risk in their insurance operations. Such evidence suggests

that access to external funding has a substitutive effect on insurers’ preference for portfolio

liquidity.

To detect the impact of liquidity clientele on bond pricing, we quantify the illiquidity

clientele (ILC ) for a corporate bond by the weighted average of its holders’ illiquidity pref-

erence (proxied by the portfolio illiquidity measure ILP). We find that ILC interacts with

bond illiquidity to affect the yield spreads, consistent with the hypothesis that liquidity

clientele attenuates the liquidity premium effect. For example, consider the case with the

1Based on insurer holdings and aggregate corporate bond outstanding provided by the National As-sociation of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) and Security Industry and Financial Market Association(SIFMA), insurers collectively hold about 25% corporate bonds in the U.S. market from 2004 to 2012.See www.naic.org/capital markets archive/140307.htm and www.sifma.org.

2

Page 4: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Amihud (2002) measure of bond-level illiquidity. Among investment-grade bonds2 in the

lowest ILC quintile (i.e., bonds held by insurers with strong preference for liquidity), the

average yield spread difference between bonds in the top illiquidity quintile and those in

the bottom quintile—a proxy for liquidity premium—is 0.94%. By contrast, among the

investment-grade bonds in the top ILC quintile (bonds held by insurers with weak prefer-

ence for liquidity), the average yield spread difference between the top and bottom illiquidity

quintiles is only 0.59%. Thus, going from the lowest to the highest ILC quintile, the liq-

uidity premium component in the yield spread is reduced by 0.35%. Similar results are

obtained when alternative bond-level liquidity measures are used, and after we control for

credit rating, maturity, and other bond characteristics in multivariate regressions.

Besides confirming the prediction on the level of liquidity premium, we find that clientele

also matters for the volatility of liquidity premium. Longer-horizon investors have lower

funding constraints since they demand less short-term funding. As a result, they are expected

to be more insulated from short-term market fluctuations. This conjecture is confirmed by

our data—liquidity premium is less volatile for bonds predominantly held by higher-ILP

insurers. The clientele effect on the liquidity premium volatility helps us understand the

recent data on liquidity premium. During and after the recent financial crisis, liquidity

premium in the corporate bond market has increased substantially; however, consistent with

the differential impact of market conditions on investor clienteles, the increase in liquidity

premium for high-ILC bonds is much modest relative to that for low-ILC bonds. As a result,

the clientele effect on bond pricing, measured by the difference in liquidity premium between

low-ILC bonds and high-ILC bonds, has become much larger in magnitude during recent

years.

We take advantage of rich information in the data to investigate several further impli-

cations of the liquidity clientele effect. First, if investment horizon matters for portfolio

liquidity and liquidity clientele, we expect the impact of liquidity clientele on liquidity pre-

mium to be stronger among longer-term bonds. This is because the effective holding horizon

2Insurers mainly hold investment-grade bonds (e.g., Ellul et al. (2011)). Therefore, our main analysisfocuses such bonds. In later analysis we separately look at high-yield bonds.

3

Page 5: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

on a short-term bond has to be short regardless of its holders’ investment horizon, and thus

long-term investors have no effective advantage amortizing the trading costs when holding

short-term bonds. Indeed, we find that the attenuating effect of liquidity clientele on liquidity

premium is strong among bonds with maturity beyond 5 years, but essentially non-existent

among bonds within 5 years of maturity.

Second, we investigate more directly the roles of both investment horizon and funding

constraint in the clientele effect on bond pricing. To examine the effect of funding constraint,

we construct an alternative illiquidity clientele measure by replacing portfolio illiquidity

(ILP) in the original definition of ILC with insurer’ funding constraint characteristics. In

order to directly examine the effect of investment horizon, we construct another clientele

measure by replacing ILP with the inverse of insurers’ portfolio turnover. This turnover-

based ILC is also motivated by the notion of latent liquidity proposed in Mahanti et al.

(2008). We find that bond liquidity premium becomes lower when a bond is heavily held

by insurers with lower funding constraints and lower portfolio turnovers. Interestingly, the

two types of ILC effects are both significant in joint regressions, suggesting that investment

horizon and funding constraints both play a role in explaining the clientele effect of bond

pricing.

Third, motivated by existing studies on the correlation between credit risk and liquidity

(e.g., Ericsson and Renault (2006) and He and Milbradt (2014)), we study the clientele

effect in a subsample of corporate bonds that permits a cleaner identification of the liquidity

premium effect. The subsample consists of bonds issued by the same firm that essentially

have the same credit risk. We find evidence of a significant clientele effect on yield spread in

this subsample, which confirms the impact of clientele effect through the liquidity channel.

Finally, observing that insurers account for varying fractions of ownership across bonds,

we separately investigate the clientele effect among bonds with high and low insurer own-

erships. We find that liquidity clientele has significant impact on the liquidity premium for

bonds with high insurer ownership, but insignificant impact among bonds with low insurer

ownership. In addition, the impact of the clientele measures on the liquidity premium of

4

Page 6: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

high-yield bonds is rather weak. A possible explanation for this observation is that insurers

only hold a small fraction of the high-yield bonds and thus their liquidity preference does

not matter much for the pricing of these bonds. Combined, these findings highlight the

importance of relying on marginal investors’ portfolio holdings in order to detect the effect

of liquidity clientele on bond pricing.

The main contribution of our study is to provide direct evidence on a long-standing

conjecture in the asset pricing literature on liquidity, i.e., the liquidity clientele effect. We

show that investors with longer investment horizons and weaker funding constraints tend to

hold more illiquid bonds. Further, the liquidity preference of bond holders has economically

and significantly large impact on bond pricing. Ownership by investors who do not have a

strong demand for liquidity substantially reduces the level and volatility of liquidity premium

of the bonds. Several of our findings, including the role of funding constraints and the

clientele effect on liquidity premium volatility, go beyond the direct predictions of existing

studies and thus further enrich our understanding of the liquidity clientele effect.

Our study is related to Mahanti et al. (2008) and Nashikkar, Subrahmanyam, and Ma-

hanti (2011). These studies introduce a measure of latent liquidity based on investors’

portfolio turnovers and holdings, in a way similar to how our liquidity clientele measure is

constructed. (See Section 3.2 for the differences and connections between the liquidity clien-

tele measure and the latent liquidity measure.) However, our study is distinct in terms of

research questions addressed. Mahanti et al. (2008) examine the relation between the latent

liquidity measure and other liquidity measures. Nashikkar et al. (2011) focus on liquidity

premium reflected in the relation between latent liquidity and CDS-bond basis. They do

not investigate the heterogeneity in the level or volatility of liquidity premium caused by

different liquidity preferences of investors holding the securities.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the related literature.

Section 3 outlines the empirical implications of liquidity clientele and discusses how we

measure illiquidity clientele. Section 4 discusses the data and sample. Section 5 presents the

empirical findings. Section 6 concludes.

5

Page 7: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

2 Related Literature

Amihud and Mendelson (1986) is the first to introduce the notion of liquidity clientele. In

their model, a security’s trading cost (or illiquidity) is the bid-ask spread, and an investor’s

liquidity preference is driven by her investment horizon. Both the bid-ask spread and the

investment horizon are exogenously specified. An investor’s net expected return per period

on a security is the gross expected return per period (before trading cost) minus the amortized

trading cost. In equilibrium, among securities with the same risk hence the same net expected

return, those with higher trading cost must have higher gross expected return. This is

generally known as the liquidity premium effect.

If investors’ horizons are heterogeneous, a separating equilibrium may exist where shorter-

horizon (longer-horizon) investors prefer more (less) liquid securities. Intuitively, this is

because investors with longer horizon have lower amortized trading costs and thus have

competitive advantage (i.e., requiring a lower gross return) for holding illiquid securities.

Liquidity clientele refers to the tendency for investors with less demand for liquidity (i.e.,

longer-horizon investors) to hold more illiquid securities.

The liquidity clientele effect has an asset pricing implication: liquidity premium is lower

for securities held by investors with longer horizons because they require less compensation in

the gross expected return for per unit of trading cost. Amihud and Mendelson (1986) take

this effect further to derive a concave relation between the trading cost and the liquidity

premium: since illiquid securities tend to be owned by investors with a long horizon, after

integrating out the security ownership (i.e., the liquidity clientele), the liquidity premium

associated with per unit of trading cost decreases with trading cost.

Other theoretical studies have developed different versions of the liquidity clientele effect.

Using a model with endogenous trading horizons, Constantinides (1986) shows that investors

reduce their trading frequency in response to high trading cost and thus hold illiquid securities

longer than they hold liquid ones. Various extensions of the basic models have also reinforced

the notion of liquidity clientele. For instance, Acharya and Pedersen (2005) develop an asset

pricing model with liquidity risk and risk aversion. By incorporating these two features into

6

Page 8: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

the Amihud and Mendelson (1986) model, Beber, Driessen, and Tuijp (2012) obtain a model

that can generate what they called liquidity risk clientele. Their calibration analysis shows

that liquidity risk clientele may substantially reduce the liquidity risk premium. Schuster,

Trapp, and Uhrig-Homburg (2013) propose an equilibrium model that can generate the

aging effect and a hump-shaped relation between trading volume and maturity, in addition

to liquidity clientele. In addition, Jang et al. (2007) extend Constantinides (1986) to allow

for time-varying investment opportunities. Trading in response to time-varying expected

returns essentially shortens investors’ holding horizon, resulting in a larger magnitude of

liquidity premium relative to the case of constant expected returns.

The aforementioned models generally take transaction costs as given. A recent devel-

opment in the literature on liquidity, especially for securities traded in over-the-counter

markets, is to endogenize trading frictions using search models, an approach originated from

Duffie, Garleanu, and Pedersen (2005). For example, Vayanos and Wang (2007) introduce a

model where investors with heterogeneous horizons can invest in two infinitely lived assets

with identical payoffs. They show that if investors can search for only one asset, then there

exists a clientele equilibrium. He and Milbradt (2014) develop a structural credit risk model

that explicitly incorporates endogenous illiquidity.

Relative to the active theoretic literature on liquidity clientele, the empirical literature is

rather sparse. In their seminal article, Amihud and Mendelson (1986) empirically document

a concave relation between quoted bid-ask spreads and stock returns, consistent with the

liquidity clientele effect without explicitly conditioning on the liquidity clientele. Using the

inverse of turnover as a proxy for the average holding period, Atkins and Dyl (1997) find

that among NYSE stocks, those with higher bid-ask spreads have longer holding periods.

However, efforts to find more direct evidence of liquidity clientele and its pricing impact

have been limited so far, in part due to data constraints to a large extent—typically we do

not know the identities of security holders and their liquidity preferences. As such, data on

insurance companies’ corporate bond holdings offer a unique opportunity to directly test the

liquidity clientele effect in the corporate bond market.

7

Page 9: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

3 Liquidity Clientele: Implications and Measures

3.1 Empirical Implications

We consider the following three implications of liquidity clientele.

Determinants of liquidity preference/clientele: The basic premise of “liquidity clien-

tele” is that in equilibrium, investors with stronger liquidity preference hold more liquid

stocks. In Amihud and Mendelson (1986), the driving factor for liquidity preference is in-

vestment horizon. In addition, we consider a feature important for the corporate bond

market – it is dominated by institutional investors. When an institution such as an insurer

needs cash, it can either sell securities or raise external financing. Therefore, access to exter-

nal funding may have a substitutive effect on the preference for keeping a liquid investment

portfolio. Combined, we have:

H1: Insurers with longer investment horizons and weaker funding constraints tend to

hold more illiquid corporate bond portfolios.

Effect on level of liquidity premium: As discussed earlier, we expect liquidity clientele

to have an attenuating effect on the level of liquidity premium. That is,

H2: Liquidity premium is lower for bonds held by insurers with weaker preference for

liquidity.

Note that after integrating out liquidity clientele, Amihud and Mendelson (1986) obtain

that unconditionally, liquidity premium is a concave function of trading cost. This concave

relation is the result of combining the two hypotheses H1 and H2 above. By separately

examining the two hypotheses (in addition to documenting the unconditional concave rela-

tion), we can offer sharper evidence on the liquidity clientele effect.

Effect on volatility of liquidity premium: Besides the prediction in existing theoretical

studies on the first moment of liquidity premium, we are interested in the liquidity clientele

8

Page 10: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

effect on its second moment as well. This is motivated by the following two observations.

First, longer-horizon investors may be less concerned with the short-term market conditions

when pricing the liquidity of securities. Second, for investors relying less on selling portfolios

to raise cash (i.e., those with easier access to financing), the liquidity premium they demand

may be more insulated from short-term market fluctuations.3 Both observations lead to the

following:

H3: Liquidity premium is more volatile for bonds primarily held by investors with

stronger liquidity preference.

3.2 Illiquidity Preference and Illiquidity Clientele Measures

To help understand what is to come, here we introduce the measure of insurers’ portfolio

illiquidity and the bond-level illiquidity clientele measure.

First, we quantify the illiquidity of an insurer’s corporate bond portfolio, ILP, by the

weighted-average illiquidity of all corporate bonds the insurer holds. That is,

ILPi,t =

Ni∑j=1

wi,j,tILQj,t =

∑Nij=1 Vi,j,tILQj,t∑Ni

j=1 Vi,j,t(1)

where ILQ j,t is the time-t illiquidity measure for bond j (detailed in Section 4.3), wi,j,t is the

weight of bond j in insurer i ’s corporate bond portfolio, Vi,j,t is the dollar value of holding

by the insurer on bond j, and Ni is the number of corporate bonds held by the insurer.

Based on the principle of revealed preference, portfolio illiquidity ILP is an indication

of an insurer’s illiquidity preference. That is, insurers with higher ILPs exhibit stronger

preferences for illiquidity. Hence ILP can be understood interchangeably as illiquidity of

portfolio or illiquidity preference.

Next, we quantify each bond’s illiquidity clientele ILC as the weighted-average of illiq-

uidity preferences (ILPs) across insurers holding the bond:

ILCj,t =

∑Mi=1 Vi,j,tILPi,t∑M

i=1 Vi,j,t(2)

3The notion that investors relying on selling portfolios to raise cash may find themselves sensitive tomarket funding conditions is related to the notion of funding liquidity by Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2008).

9

Page 11: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

where M is the total number of insurers. By construction, corporate bonds held more by

insurers with high ILPs (i.e., with strong preference for illiquid bonds) have greater ILC s.

Two observations regarding the liquidity clientele measure are worth noting here. First,

in the Amihud and Mendelson (1986) world, there is a deterministic relation between ILQ

and ILC, because in equilibrium long-horizon (short-horizon) investors always hold illiquid

(liquid) securities. Thus, ILC can be viewed as an alternative measure of bond illiquidity

given the liquidity clientele effect. However, in reality the empirical measures ILQ and ILC

would not be perfectly correlated. One reason is that corporate bonds trade in the over-

the-counter market with search frictions (e.g., Schultz (2001), Duffie et al. (2005), Vayanos

and Wang (2007), and Feldhutter (2012)). There is no guarantee that investors can always

locate bonds that perfectly fit their liquidity preferences. Another reason is that in reality

even a long-horizon investor may want to hold a certain amount of liquid securities. For

example, life insurers hold bonds to hedge the interest rate risk on the life insurance policies

they underwrite. While this may give life insurers a long investment horizon on average,

they still need to hold a certain amount of liquid investments to meet the claims that can

arrive at any given time.

Second, it is interesting to relate ILC to the latent liquidity measure introduced by

Mahanti et al. (2008). The latent liquidity of a bond (LLQit) in their study is the weighted

average of portfolio turnover of investors holding the bond:

LLQit =

∑j

πij,tTOj,t, (3)

where πij,t is the fraction of the total outstanding amount of bond i held by investor j at t,

and TOj,t is the turnover of investor j’s entire portfolio over the previous 12 months. Thus,

the main difference between ILC in (2) and LLQ in (3) is that the former uses portfolio

illiquidity (ILP) as input while the latter relies on portfolio turnover (TO). In Section 5.6.2

we also consider and implement a turnover-based ILC, where insurer j’s portfolio illiquidity

ILP j is replaced by its the inverse of portfolio turnover. However, this turnover is based

on an insurer’s corporate bond portfolio (not its entire portfolio), whereas TOj used in the

latent liquidity measure (LLQ) is the turnover at the fund level, i.e., based on an investor’s

10

Page 12: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

entire portfolio (that may include many securities other than corporate bonds). As such,

our turnover-based ILC is also different from the latent liquidity measure.

On the other hand, a link between ILC and LLQ can be justified when there is a liquidity

clientele effect–that is, when investors with short horizons (and thus high turnovers) prefer

holding liquid securities, portfolio turnover is negatively related to the illiquidity of portfolio.4

Despite the correlation between liquidity clientele and liquidity (including latent liq-

uidity), our study differs from Mahanti et al. (2008) in the research questions addressed.

Mahanti et al. (2008) (and Nashikkar et al. (2011)) use LLQ as an (advantageous) measure

of liquidity and establish an empirical relation between LLQ and expected return that is

consistent with the notion of liquidity premium. By contrast, we focus on the heterogeneity

of liquidity preferences and its impact on the magnitude and volatility of liquidity premium,

i.e., the attenuating role of ILC on liquidity premium.

4 Data

We use data from the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC), the Mergent

Fixed Investment Securities Database (FISD), and the Trade Reporting and Compliance

Engine (TRACE). While the NAIC and FISD data go back to the 1990s, a meaningful size

of corporate bond coverage by TRACE starts in 2003. Therefore, the sample period of this

study is from 2003Q1 to 2011Q4.

4.1 Insurers’ Corporate Bond Holdings

Insurers are required by state regulators to disclose their portfolio holdings and transactions

each year on stocks, bonds and other financial securities. Such information is collected in

4Mahanti et al. (2008) motivates the latent liquidity measure from both the liquidity clientele effectof Amihud and Mendelson (1986), and a reverse-causality effect of investors’ liquidity preference on bondliquidity: bonds held by investors with active trading are likely to be more accessible in the market, andthus more liquid. See also Vayanos and Wang (2007) for a theoretical model where liquidity of a securityis endogenous to investor horizon. In our empirical analysis, we treat the relation between bond liquidityand bond investors’ liquidity preference as an equilibrium association, without differentiating the directionof causality.

11

Page 13: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

the form of Schedule D filings available from the NAIC.5

We start with all corporate bonds held and traded by insurers in the NAIC Schedule D

data during the period from 2003 to 2011. In order to obtain bond characteristics and bond

liquidity measures, we merge this data with FISD and TRACE, and keep all the plain-vanilla

bonds issued by the U.S. firms that satisfy certain standard filters (detailed in Section 4.2).

In order to measure insurers’ portfolio illiquidity and bond-level liquidity clientele at

the quarterly frequency, we infer insurers’ quarterly corporate bond holdings based on the

reported year-end holdings and reported bond trades. To obtain the par value of an insurer’s

holding on a bond in a specific quarter, we start with the par value of the insurer’s holding

of this bond at the beginning of the year, and then add the par value of the insurer’s net

purchases (buy minus sell) on this bond from the beginning of the year to the end of the

quarter. The resulting sample includes 9,846,975 insurer-bond-quarter observations.6

We use additional data filters to ensure the quality of the above procedure. We infer

an insurer’s year-end holdings by adding the net purchases during the entire year to the

holdings at the beginning of the year. If for a given bond, an insurer’s inferred year-end

par value is below 90% or above 110% of the reported year-end par value, we exclude that

year’s observations on that bond by that insurer from the sample. If more than 10% of

observations are excluded for an insurer during a given year for this reason, we exclude all

observations in that year for the insurer. These filters reduce the sample size to 9,454,512

insurer-bond-quarter observations. In this final sample, there are 7,873 unique bonds and

3,413 unique insurers, including 963 life insurers and 2,450 property-and-casualty insurers.

4.2 Data on Bond Characteristics and Bond Trading

FISD has detailed information for corporate debt securities, such as the issuer, seniority,

coupon, face value, issuance date, maturity date, credit rating, and redemption features. As

5Studies that have used the NAIC corporate bond transaction data include Chakravarty and Sarkar(1999), Hong and Warga (2000), Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001), Schultz (2001), Campbell and Taksler (2003),among others. Chen et al. (2013) use the NAIC data on insurers’ Treasury bond holdings.

6Note that the Schedule D data have bond holdings by both insurers and their holding companies. Toavoid double-counting, we exclude corporate bond holding of insurance holding companies from our sample.

12

Page 14: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

mentioned earlier, we keep all the plain-vanilla corporate bonds issued by U.S. firms, and ex-

clude bonds with optionality (e.g., callable and putable bonds, and bonds with sinking-fund,

convertibility, and exchangeability features), asset-backed securities, bonds with credit en-

hancements, floating-rate bonds, foreign-currency denominated bonds, and bonds with odd

frequency of coupon payments. We also exclude bonds with missing data on key characteris-

tics such as issue date, maturity date, issue price, issuance size, coupon rate, and bonds with

missing credit ratings. Following the convention in the existing literature (e.g., Lin et al.

(2011)), we further exclude bonds that have less than six months to maturity by the end of

the year because such bonds are subject to high pricing errors and because our focus is on

relatively long-term bonds.

We measure bond-level liquidity using data from the TRACE, which provides information

on bond transactions, such as the date and time of execution, transaction price, and yield

to maturity at time of transaction. The TRACE reporting requirement is implemented in

three phases that progressively include more bonds: July 2002–February 2003, March 2003–

September 2004, and October 2004–present. Since only a limited number of corporate bonds

are included in phase I, we follow the existing literature (e.g., Edwards, Harris, and Piwowar

(2007) and Bao et al. (2011)) to start the analysis from Q1 2003. Note that changing the

sample starting date to either July 2002 (beginning of phase I) or October 2004 (beginning

of phase III) does not change any of our conclusions qualitatively.

Next, we apply two sets of data filters to alleviate potential reporting errors in TRACE.

The first set follows Dick-Nielsen (2009) and consists of the followings: (a) we delete dupli-

cates identified by the message sequence number; (b) if a trade is subsequently reversed we

exclude both the original trade and the reversal; and (c) we exclude the following two types

of same-day corrections: if the correction is cancellation, both reports are deleted; otherwise

only the original is deleted. The second set of filters includes a median filter and a reversal

filter that help control for price errors (Edwards et al. (2007)). The former filter eliminates

any trade where the price deviates from the daily median or from a nine-trading-day median

centered at the trading day by more than 10%; the latter filter eliminates any trade with an

13

Page 15: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

absolute price change deviating from the lead, lag, and average lead/lag price change by at

least 10%.

The resulting merged dataset from FISD and TRACE has 8,656 unique bonds during

the period from 2003 to 2011, including 6,839 investment-grade bonds and 1,717 speculative

bonds. Merging this sample with the Schedule D data then leads to our final sample that

covers 7,873 unique corporate bonds. Among them, 6,468 are investment-grade bonds and

1,405 are high-yield bonds.

Our sample size of unique corporate bonds is comparable to that of Dick-Nielsen et al.

(2012), which includes 5,376 bonds during the period from January 1, 2005 to June 30,

2009. When limited to their sample period, our sample has 6,749 bonds. Such difference

in sample size is likely because FISD, our data source, has more bond coverage relative to

Bloomberg, their data source. Our sample size is smaller than that of Friewald et al. (2012),

which consists of 23,703 bonds over the period from October 2004 to December 2008. This

is because in addition to plain-vanilla bonds, their sample also includes a large number of

bonds with embedded options and private bonds.

4.3 Yield Spreads and Bond Illiquidity

Following the existing literature, we look at the liquidity premium in corporate bond pricing

via the relation between bond illiquidity measures and bond yield spread.

At the end of a calendar quarter, we calculate the yield spread for a bond as the difference

between the bond’s yield to maturity and the fitted Treasury yield with matching maturity.

The Treasury yields for constant maturities of 1, 2, 3, 5, 7, 10, 20, and 30 years are obtained

from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.7 Following Duffee (1998) and Collin-Dufresne

et al. (2001), we use a linear interpolation scheme to fit the entire Treasury yield curve.

A well-known issue is that many corporate bonds are infrequently traded. We measure

quarter-end bond yields following the existing literature (e.g., Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012)). If

a bond is traded during the last month of a quarter, we take the average yield for all trades

7The data are available at http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/categories/115.

14

Page 16: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

on the last day it is traded. If a bond is not traded during the last month of the quarter but

traded during the first two months, we take the average yield over all trades on the bond

during the quarter.

We use the following five corporate bond illiquidity measures commonly in the literature.

The first is the Amihud (2002) measure of the price impact of per unit bond traded. The

second is the Roll’s (1984) effective bid-ask spread, based on the negative covariance between

returns of consecutive trades. Bao et al. (2011) consider a modified Roll’s measure. The third

is the LOT (Lesmond, Ogden, and Trzcinka (1999)) measure of round-trip transaction costs,

based on the frequency of zero-return days. The fourth is the imputed roundtrip cost (IRC )

proposed by Feldhutter (2012). Finally, we use the λ measure of Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012),

which takes the average of the normalized Amihud, IRC, the Amihud risk measure, and the

IRC risk measure. These measures are constructed for each bond in each quarter during

which the bond is traded. To alleviate the effect of outliers, we winsorize each illiquidity

measure at the top and bottom 1% across bonds in each quarter. More details on these

illiquidity measures are provided in the Appendix.

4.4 Summary Statistics

Table 1 provides summary statistics on corporate bond holdings by insurance companies in

our sample. As Panel A shows, the number of unique bonds in the combined FISD-TRACE

sample (reported in column 2) varies between 2,400 (in 2003) and 4,443 (in 2005), and the

number of unique bonds held by insurers (column 3) varies between 1,878 (in 2011) and 3,850

(in 2005). Overall, 91% (7,873 out of 8,656) of the bonds in the FISD-TRACE sample are

held by some insurers. Columns 4 through 8 report the numbers of bonds held by insurers

across five rating groups, respectively: AAA, AA (including AA+, AA, AA-), A (including

A+, A, A-), BBB (including BBB+, BBB, BBB-), and speculative bonds (Spec, including

all ratings below BBB-). Bond credit ratings are from S&P. If the S&P rating is missing,

we use the rating from Moody’s or Fitch, in this order; and bonds without credit ratings

are excluded. Most corporate bonds held by insurers are in the A and BBB groups, with a

15

Page 17: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

relatively small number of junk bonds. Columns 9 through 12 report respectively the number

of bonds held across four maturity groups: below 2 years, 2-5 years, 5-10 years, and above

10 years. Insurers hold significant numbers of bonds in all the four maturity categories.

Panel B reports the cross-sectional distribution of insurers’ portfolio weights on various

types of bonds. Here, we divide bonds into groups using the same five credit rating categories

or the four maturity bins as described above. We first compute the portfolio weight (i.e., the

value of a specific type of bonds as a percentage of an insurer’s aggregate corporate bond

holding) in a given quarter, and then compute the cross-sectional statistics on such portfolio

weights across insurers. The cross-sectional statistics include the 5th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and

95th percentiles, as well as the mean and standard deviations. The numbers reported in the

table are the time-series averages of these cross-sectional statistics. Across the five rating

categories, A-rated bonds have the highest mean portfolio weight (35%), followed by the AA

category (25.88%). Speculative bonds have the lowest mean weight (7.41%). Across the four

maturity groups, bonds with 2 to 5 years of time to maturity have the highest mean portfolio

weight (34.15%), followed by bonds with less than 2 years of time to maturity (28.80%).

In Panel C, we further present the cross-sectional distribution of bonds held by insurers

as fractions of the total bonds outstanding. Again, bonds are classified into five credit rating

groups and four maturity groups. In each quarter for each bond, we compute the fraction

of total bond outstanding in a given category held by insurers collectively. We average

the fractions within each bond category and then compute the cross-sectional distribution

statistics of the fractional insurer holdings across various bond categories. The cross-sectional

statistics are averaged over time and reported here. For reference purpose we also report the

average number of unique bonds held by insurers in each category. Note that the average

number of speculative bonds (516) is much lower than that of investment-grade bonds (2,400).

In terms of the fraction of holdings by insurers, the mean and median for speculative bonds

are 12.66% and 8.30%, much lower than the corresponding statistics for bonds in any of

the four investment-grade categories. For example, the mean and median fractions of BBB

bonds held by insurers are 39.29% and 37.62%, respectively. Further, the panel shows

16

Page 18: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

that insurance ownership on long-term bonds (bonds with maturity at or above 5 years) as

fractions of bonds outstanding are slightly higher than that on short-term bonds.8

These statistics show that insurers predominately hold investment-grade bonds. There-

fore, in the main analysis we focus on such bonds (with analysis on speculative bonds in a

later part). In Panel D of Table 1, we additionally report the cross-sectional distribution of

insurers’ holdings of investment-grade (IG) bonds. There are 6,468 unique IG bonds in the

full sample. The number of these bonds ranges from 1,492 (in 2011) to 3,099 (in 2005), with

a time-series average of 2,400. The mean fraction of IG bonds outstanding held by insurers

is in the ranges of 34% to 42% over the sample period. This provides further evidence on

the importance of insurers in the IG bond market.

Overall, the bond ownership statistics presented in Table 1 are in line with those reported

by other studies. Hong and Warga (2000) report that insurance companies account for

roughly 25% of the market for high-yield debt, while their share of trading in the IG debt

market is around 40%. Schultz (2001) estimates that life insurance companies by themselves

hold about 40% of all corporate bonds. Further, Ellul et al. (2011) find that on average,

insurance companies hold about 34 percent of IG bonds and only 8 percent of high-yield

bonds. See also Campbell and Taksler (2003) and Hotchkiss and Jostova (2007).

We illustrate the concave relation between the illiquidity of investment grade bonds and

their yield spreads in Figure 1. The plots are the results of piecewise linear regressions. For

each of the five illiquidity measures, we first breakdown the full range of the value of a given

illiquidity measure into five groups. For instance, as the 5th and 95th percentiles of the

Amihud measure are 0.04% and 4.77%, we choose 0.25%, 0.75%, 1.25%, 1.75%, and 2.25%

8It is interesting to observe that insurers hold a significant portion of short-term bonds, some of which canbe long bonds at the time of purchase and become short-term ones as time goes by. We have calculated somefurther statistics to get a clear idea on the maturity of bonds when they are purchased by insurers. For newlypurchased bonds by property casualty insurers, the three types of maturities most often purchased are 10years (27%), 5 years (21%) and 9 years (8%). In comparison, the most often purchased maturity categoriesfor life insurers are 10 years (35%), 30 years (11%), and 5 years (12%). The difference is consistent withthe differential liability structure across insurers: life insurers have more long-term liabilities than propertyinsurers, as a result life insurers may have longer investment horizons than property insurers.

17

Page 19: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

as the breakpoints to form the five groups.9 Then, we perform piecewise linear regressions

within each group in each quarter, with the dependent variable being the yield spread and the

explanatory variables being the five piecewise functions of the illiquidity measure. We then

take the average coefficients for each group over time to re-construct the average piecewise

linear relation between yield spread and illiquidity. The plots across the five illiquidity

measures consistently reveal that yield spreads are an increasing and concave function of

bond illiquidity. These patterns resemble the concave relation between stock returns and

stock trading cost (the relative bid-ask spread) shown in Amihud and Mendelson (1986).

Note that the yield spreads are based on promised yields, not the expected yields to

investors. To more strictly follow the prediction of Amihud and Mendelson (1986), we

further obtain expected yield spreads by subtracting the expected default losses from the

promised yield spreads. Specifically, we take Moody’s estimates of credit loss rates for each

rating category in each year, based on their proprietary data starting in 1982. For example,

to obtain expected yield spreads of all BBB-rated bonds in 2003, we use Moody’s estimate

for Baa-rated bonds published in early 2003 that is based on the period 1982–2002. The

pattern (e.g., a concave relation between bond illiquidity and expected yield spread) is quite

similar to that revealed in Figure 1. To save space we do not plot them in the paper.

5 Empirical Results

In this section we present the findings from the empirical analysis. Section 5.1 investigates

liquidity preference of insurers and the persistence of such preference. In Section 5.2, we

present evidence on the existence of liquidity clientele. Sections 5.3 and 5.4 examine the

liquidity clientele effect in corporate bond yield spreads. Section 5.5 examines time variations

of liquidity premiums across different liquidity clientele groups. Section 5.6 provides a set of

extended analyses and robustness checks.

For the reason discussed earlier, most of the results reported in this section are for the

9Additionally, the breakpoints we used are 1, 2, 3, 4, and 5 for Roll measure, 0.05, 0.20, 0.35, 0.50, and0.65 for LOT measure, 0.15%, 0.35%, 0.55%, 0.75%, and 0.95% for IRC, and -0.5, 0, 0.5, 1, and 1.5 for λ.

18

Page 20: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

investment-grade bonds. The results for high-yield bonds are presented in Section 5.6.4.

5.1 Bond Illiquidity, Portfolio Illiquidity, and Liquidity Clientele

Table 2 reports the cross-sectional statistics of the following four main variables used in our

empirical analysis: corporate bond yield spreads, ILQ, ILP, and ILC. The cross-sectional

statistics reported include the 5th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and 95th percentiles, as well as the mean,

and standard deviation of each variable. This provides an overall picture of the substantial

cross-sectional variation of each variable. These statistics are first computed cross-sectionally

in a given quarter (across bonds or across insurers) and then averaged over time.

Panel A illustrates the distribution of bond yield spreads, with a mean of 1.78%, a

median of 1.61%, and a standard deviation of 1.06%. These statistics are comparable to

those reported in other studies such as Friewald et al. (2012).

Panel B reports the distributions of the five bond illiquidity measures (ILQ). The Amihud

measure has a mean of 1.27%, a median of 0.61%, and a standard deviation of 2.01%. This

means that a trade of $1,000,000 in a bond, on average, has a price impact of 1.27%. The

variation in illiquidity (by the Amihud measure) across bonds is remarkably high and ranges

between 0.04% and 4.77% from the 5th to the 95th percentiles. This is consistent with the

findings in Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012) and Friewald et al. (2012). The Roll measure has a

mean of 1.69 and a standard deviation of 1.61, suggesting high liquidity variation across

bonds as well. The mean of LOT is 7.29%, and the median is 2.03%. The median imputed

roundtrip cost (IRC ) in percentage of the price is 0.43%. IRC is less than 0.10% for the

top 5% most liquid bonds. For the λ measure, we observe a mean of -0.03 and a median of

-0.15, consistent with Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012).

Panel C reports distributions of ILPAmihud, ILPRoll, ILPLOT , ILP IRC , and ILPλ—five

portfolio illiquidity measures with different underlying bond illiquidity measures. The mean

and median of ILPAmihud are 1.28% and 1.09%, respectively. The variation of this measure

is markedly large with the range between 0.73% at the 5th percentile and 3.03% at the

95th percentile. We observe similar patterns in the other four ILP measures. These results

19

Page 21: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

suggest that corporate bond portfolios have very different levels of illiquidity across insurers.

Lastly, Panel D reports the distributions of the bond-level illiquidity clientele measures,

ILC. Based on the Amihud measure of bond illiquidity, the mean and median of ILC are

1.24% and 1.21%, and its 5th- and 95th-percentile values are 0.99% and 1.54%, respec-

tively. Thus, compared with the mean or median, the dispersion of ILC is quite wide. The

distributions of other four ILC measures reveal a similar pattern.

Table 3 presents the correlation matrix of the five illiquidity proxies and the correspond-

ing ILC s. The correlations across the illiquidity measures are all positive. For example,

the correlations among Amihud, Roll, and LOT range from 0.11 to 0.43. The correlations

between Amihud, IRC, and λ are between 0.40 and 0.79. This is consistent with the findings

in Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012) and Friewald et al. (2012). Similarly, correlations among the

five liquidity clientele measures (ILC s) are all positive, ranging from 0.35 to 0.88. Interest-

ingly, correlations between each liquidity measure and the corresponding liquidity clientele

measure are all around 0.40, suggesting that the liquidity measures and the liquidity clientele

measures are positively correlated. This is consistent with our discussion in Section 3.2 on

the empirical relation between ILQ and ILC.

5.2 Evidence on Liquidity Preference/Clientele

An important issue is whether different levels of ILP across insurers indeed reflect their

differences in liquidity preferences, which is a key element of the clientele hypothesis. We

perform two sets of analysis on this issue.

First, we examine whether the constructed portfolio illiquidity measures persist. If port-

folio illiquidity ILP captures an insurer’s stable illiquidity preference, its value must be

persistent over time. Figure 2 illustrates such persistence. In each quarter, we sort insurers

into quintiles based on a measure of ILP. We then calculate the average ILP of insurers in

each initial quintile in the ranking year and the subsequent three years. As the figure shows,

based on all five bond-level illiquidity measures, insurers initially ranked in the highest ILP

quintile continue to have high ILPs during the subsequent three years.

20

Page 22: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Next, we link ILP to firm characteristics that potentially reflect insurers’ illiquidity pref-

erences. In Section 3, we hypothesize that investment horizon and funding constraint are

two key determinants of liquidity preference. Accordingly, here we look at six different firm

characteristics related to insurers’ investment horizon, and five other firm characteristics

related to their funding constraints.

The six characteristics related to investment horizon are the following. The first is the

annual portfolio turnover, TURN. Following the conventional portfolio turnover definition

(see, the CRSP Mutual Fund Database Guide), we compute TURN as the minimum of the

aggregate market value of bonds purchased by an insurer and the aggregate value of bonds

sold by the insurer in each quarter, scaled by the aggregate portfolio value at the end of the

quarter. Annual portfolio turnover is the quarterly measure multiplied by 4. A high portfolio

turnover rate indicates a short portfolio investment horizon. The next two characteristics,

STURN and LTURN, are variations of TURN. STURN is the annual turnover of an insurer’s

subportfolio that consists of bonds with maturity shorter than 5 years, and LTURN is the

annual turnover of the subportfolio of bonds with maturity at or above 5 years. We look at

turnover separately for the short-term and long-term bonds because the turnover on short-

term bonds is mechanically high, and the difference in investment horizon is more likely to

show up in the turnover for long-term bonds. The fourth characteristic is holding horizon

in years, HZ, which is the average time length a bond is held by an insurer since its initial

acquisition up to the current quarter. The NAIC’s Schedule D data report the acquisition

date of each bond by an insurer, which enables us to compute HZ.10 We also include MAT,

the average maturity of bonds purchased by insurers in years. If a long-horizon investor

engages in a buy-and-hold strategy, the bonds that the investor purchased should have long

maturities. The last characteristic, LIFE, equals to 1 for a life insurer and 0 otherwise. Life

insurance policies result in operating liabilities with much longer horizons relative to those

for property and casualty policies. Since insurers use bond portfolios to hedge the interest

10Note that since HZ is computed on a bond that is still in an insurer’s portfolio and not sold yet, it istherefore shorter than the true holding period of a bond.

21

Page 23: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

rate risk of their operating liabilities, life insurers tend to buy and hold long-term bonds.11

The five characteristics related to funding constraints include total assets (TA), firm age

(AGE ), a dummy for affiliated insurers (AFF ), insurers that issue stocks (STOCK ), and the

reinsurance ratio (REINS ). TA is the total assets in billion dollars. AGE is the number of

years since the year of firm incorporation. Affiliated insurers are those affiliated with parent

insurer groups or insurance holding companies. STOCK equals to 1 for insurers owned by

stockholders, known as stock insurers, and 0 for non-stock insurers, such as mutual insurers

owned by policyholders. We expect larger insurers, older insurers, affiliated insurers, and

stock insurers are more resourceful in meeting liquidity needs (via either external financing

or internal capital markets) and therefore are less constrained when investing in illiquid

assets. REINS is the ratio of the insurance premiums that an insurer cedes to other insurers

through the reinsurance arrangement relative to the sum of insurance premiums it collects

and the insurance premium the insurer accepts from other insurers through the reinsurance

arrangement. A high REINS indicates that the insurer outsources a large part of its insurance

operating risk, suggesting a low capacity to bear operating risk. We hypothesize that such an

insurer similarly has a low external funding capacity. To sum up, larger and older insurers,

affiliated and stock insurers, and insurers with lower reinsurance ratio tend to have less

funding constraints. These characteristics are constructed using the NAIC data on annual

financial statements.

Table 4 presents these insurer characteristics across ILP -sorted insurer deciles. We rank

insurers into ILP deciles each quarter and compute the average characteristics for each decile,

and then take the averages over time. We also compute the differences in characteristics

between the top (D10) and bottom (D1) deciles and the corresponding t-statistics using the

Newey-West procedure with a four-quarter lag. In the discussion of Table 4 that follows

we focus on the case where bond illiquidity is based on the Amihud measure (Panel A), as

results based on the other illiquidity measures (Panels B to E) are qualitatively similar.

11Portfolio turnover may be endogenous to the liquidity of securities in the portfolio. Thus, the relationbetween ILP and portfolio turnover should be interpreted as an equilibrium association instead of a one-waycausality by portfolio turnover onto ILP, or vice versa. However, other insurer characteristics, such as LIFEand those examined below (TA, AGE, AFF, STOCK, and REINS ), are likely exogenous to ILP.

22

Page 24: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Columns (1) through (6) are for investment-horizon characteristics. Note first that port-

folio turnovers are lower for insurers with higher ILP decile ranks. Specifically, in Panel A,

the average turnover drops from 16% per year for the bottom ILP decile to 9% per year for

the top decile. The average turnovers of short-term bonds exhibit some variations across

ILP deciles, while larger variations are observed for the turnover of long-term bonds. The

average STURN for the D1 (D10) portfolio is 0.18 (0.14) while the average LTURN for

the D1 (D10) portfolio is 0.12 (0.06). The differences in STURN between the D10 and D1

deciles are all insignificant while the differences in LTURN are all significant regardless of

the illiquidity measure used.

Note also from Panel A that the average holding horizon (HZ) increases in the decile rank

of ILP. Under the Amihud illiquidity measure, the average holding horizon for D1 insurers

is 1.83 years and it is 3.36 years for D10 insurers. The difference is statistically significant at

the 1 percent level. The average maturity (MAT ) of insurers’ newly acquired bonds increases

in insurers’ ILP ranks, consistent with the notion of liquidity clientele. Additionally, note

that the fraction of life insurers is roughly 17% in the bottom ILP decile portfolio and 53%

for the top ILP decile.

The last five columns of Table 4 report the average funding-constraint characteristics

across ILP -sorted insurer deciles. ILP is positively correlated with firm size and firm age.

For instance, in Panel A, the average TA (AGE ) for the bottom ILP decile is $0.58 billion

(37.89 years) and that of the top ILP decile is $2.86 billion (49.16 years). That is, insurers

with higher ILP tend to be larger and older. Further, affiliated insurers, stock insurers, and

insurers relying more in reinsurance, tend to have higher ILP.

The evidence presented above supports the notion of liquidity clientele: insurers with

longer horizons and easier access to financing hold more illiquid bond portfolios.

5.3 Clientele Effect on Yield Spread: Two-way Sorted Portfolios

We now investigate the effect of liquidity clientele on corporate bond pricing. We first use

an intuitive double-sorted portfolio approach that helps highlight the difference between

23

Page 25: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

the liquidity premium effect and the liquidity clientele effect. In each quarter, we sort all

the investment grade bonds on ILQ and ILC independently (i.e., sorting on ILC is not

conditional on ILQ). This results in 25 (5 by 5) groups with equal number of bonds in each

group. Across ILQs, ILQ1 and ILQ5 refer to the least illiquid (or most liquid) and the

most illiquid bonds, respectively. Across ILC s, ILC1 represents the group of bonds with

the lowest ILC (held by insurers with the lowest liquidity preference or equivalently, with

the highest liquidity demand), and ILC5 the group of bonds with the highest ILC (held by

insurers with the highest ILP, or the lowest liquidity demand).

Table 5 reports the average yield spreads for the 25 bond portfolios. In the lowest ILC

quintile (i.e., ILC1 ), yield spread monotonically increases in bond illiquidity, regardless of

the illiquidity measure used. For instance, under Amihud measure (Panel A), we find that,

for the lowest ILC group, the average yield spread for the most liquid bond group (ILQ1 )

is 1.28%, while that of the most illiquid bonds (ILQ5 is 2.22%. The liquidity premium,

proxied by the yield spread difference between the two groups, is 0.94% with a t-statistic

of 4.49. The liquidity premium remains significantly positive across all the ILC ranks. In

the highest ILC group (ILC5 ), the average yield spread of bonds in the top (bottom) ILQ

quintile is 2.39% (1.80%), resulting in a liquidity premium of 0.59%. The liquidity clientele

effect is measured by the difference in the liquidity premium between the top and bottom

ILC quintiles, which is -0.35% and significant at the 5% level in this case. Thus, going

from the bottom ILC quintile to the top ILC quintile, the liquidity clientele effect reduces

the liquidity premium by one third. The same pattern holds for all other bond illiquidity

measures—an increase in ILC reduces the liquidity premium component of corporate bond

yield spreads.

Also note that among bonds within the same ILQ quintile, there is a positive relation

between ILC and yield spreads. This is consistent with the notion of latent liquidity (Ma-

hanti et al. (2008)) discussed in Section 3.2; that is, when there exists liquidity clientele,

ILC could be viewed as an alternative bond-level illiquidity measure and thus commands a

liquidity premium.

24

Page 26: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

5.4 Panel Regressions on Yield Spreads

We now turn to a panel regression model to test the liquidity clientele effect while controlling

for various factors affecting yield spreads. We first classify all bonds into three groups

(terciles) based on a given bond liquidity clientele measure ILC (i.e., ILCAmihud, ILCRoll,

ILC LOT , ILC IRC , and ILC λ) in each quarter.12 Let T1 (T2, T3) be the indicator variable

that equals 1 if the bonds are in the first (second, third) tercile and zero otherwise. The

panel regression model has the following specification:

Spreadi,t = α0 + α1ILQi,t + α2T2i,t + α3T3i,t + α4ILQi,t ∗ T2i,t

+α5ILQi,t ∗ T3i,t + Controli,t + εi,t, (4)

where Spreadi,t is the yield spread of bond i in quarter t ; ILQ is a measure of bond illiquidity.

The error term εi,t includes both the time-fixed effects and the issuer-fixed effects.

Our main interest is on the interactions between ILQ and T2 as well as those between

ILQ and T3 in Eq. (4), as they represent the potential effect of liquidity clientele on liquidity

premium. We expect that α4 < 0 and α5 < 0. That is, liquidity clientele attenuates the

liquidity premium in yield spreads.

We include an extensive set of bond-specific and firm-specific control variables in Eq. (4).

The bond-specific control variables include bond age (the time since issuance, in years), a

bond’s time to maturity (in years), the logarithm of bond issue size (in million dollars),

annual coupon rates (in percentage), and credit rating dummies.13 Existing studies show

that bond age and issue size are positively related to bond yield spreads (e.g., Schultz (2001),

Campbell and Taksler (2003), and Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012)). In addition, Campbell and

Taksler (2003) argue that bonds with higher coupons are taxed more throughout the life of

the bond, making them less desirable than bonds with lower coupons, and thus implying a

12We report the results based on ILC terciles to save space. Results based on ILC quintiles are similar.13Bond ratings are obtained from Standard & Poor’s. In cases where the S&P’s rating is missing, we use

Moody’s, and then Fitch’s, in that order. A dummy for a specific rating (e.g., AAA) equals 1 when a bondhas this rating and 0 otherwise. Altogether, there are 25 rating categories from AAA to D. We includethe top 24 rating dummies in the regressions and exclude that the D rating to void multi-colinearity in theregression specification.

25

Page 27: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

higher yield spread.

Firm-specific control variables include the ratio of operating income to sales, ratio of long

term debt to assets (LTD), total debt to capitalization (Leverage), equity volatility (EqVol),

and four pretax interest coverage variables (Pretax1, Pretax2, Pretax3, and Pretax4 ).14 High

values of the ratio of operating income to sales and pretax interest coverage indicate financial

healthiness and are likely associated with low yield spreads (e.g., Blume et al. (1998), Collin-

Dufresne et al. (2001), and Campbell and Taksler (2003)). In addition, we expect the equity

volatility to have a positive effect on yield spreads (e.g., Campbell and Taksler (2003)). The

accounting data are as of the end of the previous calendar year. The market value of equity

is at the end of the quarter. These control variables are similar to those used in Blume et al.

(1998), Collin-Dufresne et al. (2001), Campbell and Taksler (2003), Chen et al. (2007), and

Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012). For robust statistical inference in a panel regression setting (e.g.,

Petersen (2009)), we compute two-way clustered standard errors along the time and issuer

dimensions, in addition to the control for the issuer- and time-fixed effects.

Columns (1) through (5) in Table 6 present the baseline results from Eq. (4) in absence of

any control variables, for each of five bond illiquidity measures considered. First, consistent

with the literature, we find that the coefficients on ILQ are positive and highly significant

with a t-statistic ranging from 2 to 14 across the five bond illiquidity measures, indicating

that high illiquidity demands high premium. For instance, note from column (1) that the

yield spread would increase by 0.69% for a one-percentage increase in the Amihud illiquidity

measure. Next, the coefficients on the dummy variables T2 and T3 are both significantly

positive, consistent with the idea that the latent liquidity commands substantial liquidity

premium. Most importantly, the coefficients on the interactions between ILQ and T2 as

well as between ILQ and T3 are significantly negative. Further, the coefficients on the inter-

14Following Blume et al. (1998), to control for the skewness of the distribution of pretax interest ratecoverage (PIRC, measured as EBIT divided by interest expenses), we construct four Pretax variables.Pretax1 takes the value of PIRC if PIRC is less than 5, and 5 if it is above. Pretax2 is zero if PIRC isbelow 5, takes the value of PIRC minus 5 if PIRC lies between 5 and 10, and 5 if PIRC lies above. Pretax3is zero if PIRC is below 10, takes the value of PIRC minus 10 if it lies between 10 and 20, and 10 if it isabove. Pretax4 is zero if PIRC is below 20 and takes value of PIRC minus 20 if it is above 20 (we set themaximum at 80 for observations with PIRC greater than 100).

26

Page 28: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

actions involving T3 are more negative than those involving T2. This finding is consistent

with the hypothesis that liquidity clientele attenuates the liquidity premium.

Columns (6) through (10) report the results from regressions specified in Eq. (4) with

the full set of control variables. We find that illiquidity continues to be positively related to

yield spread after controlling for various bond-specific and firm-specific variables, regardless

of bond illiquidity measures used. Again, highly significant coefficients on the bond illiquidity

measures are consistent with the theoretical prior that liquidity is priced in the yield spread.

Next, note that the coefficient estimates on the interactions between ILQ and T2 as well

as those between ILQ and T3 are significantly negative across all five different illiquidity

measures used. For example, as shown in column (6) for the case of the Amihud liquidity

measure, the coefficient on ILQ*T2 is -0.10 (t-stat = -3.68) and that of ILQ and T3 is -0.20

(t-stat = -8.22), indicating that liquidity clientele reduces the liquidity premium of bonds.

Moreover, we note that the coefficients on control variables are largely consistent with

those reported in the literature. For instance, the coefficients of bond maturity are sig-

nificantly positive, consistent with the evidence that longer term bonds have higher yield

spreads. Coefficient estimates on coupon rates are also significantly positive, suggesting that

high coupon bonds (normally high-yield bonds) have high yield spreads. The firm-specific

variables generally have expected signs when they are significant. As might be expected, the

coefficient on the ratio of income to sales is significantly negative while the coefficients on

LTD, Leverage, and equity volatility are significantly positive.

Overall, the results from panel regressions indicate that corporate bond yield spreads

are strongly correlated with the interaction between bond illiquidity and liquidity clientele.

This finding supports the hypothesis that the liquidity premium is attenuated when illiquid

securities predominantly attract investors with low liquidity preference.

5.5 Time Variation of Liquidity Premium

As discussed in Section 3 (i.e., hypothesis H3), we expect the liquidity premium for bonds

held by insurers with stronger liquidity preference to be be more sensitive to market condi-

27

Page 29: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

tions and thus are more volatile. We investigate this hypothesis here. In each quarter we

sort sample bonds into terciles based on ILC. We then estimate the liquidity clientele effect

on yield spread using the following cross-sectional regression in each quarter for each ILC

tercile:

Spreadi,t = α0 + α1ILQi,t + Controli,t + εi,t, (5)

where Spreadi,t is the yield spread of bond i in quarter t and ILQ is a measure of bond

illiquidity. We include the same set of control variables as those specified in Eq. (4).

To illustrate the time variation of liquidity premium, in Figure 3 we plot the time series

of the estimated coefficients for ILQ, i.e., the quarterly liquidity premium estimates. The

liquidity premium estimates for bonds in the lowest (T1 ) and highest (T3 ) ILC terciles are

plotted separately. The plot shows that the liquidity premium is much more volatile for the

T1 bonds than for the T3 bonds. According to our estimates (not tabulated in the paper),

based on the Amihud measure, the time-series standard deviation of the liquidity premium

estimates for the T1 bonds is 5.68%. By comparison, that for the T3 bonds is 2.69%. The

same pattern obtains under other bond illiquidity measures. This is consistent with the

implication of liquidity clientele on liquidity premium volatility.

The clientele effect on liquidity premium volatility can also help understand the behavior

of liquidity premium during the recent financial crisis. An eye-catching pattern in the plots

is that the liquidity premiums peaked in 2008Q3 or 2008Q4, when the financial crisis hit its

climax – when Lehman collapsed and several other financial institutions, including Merrill

Lynch, Citigroup, and AIG, were either acquired under duress or subject to government

takeover. The spike of liquidity premium is much more visible for the T1 bonds than for the

T3 bonds in the plots. As a result, when we measure the clientele effect by the difference in

liquidity premium between the two bond groups, the clientele effect is the strongest during

the crisis period.

The liquidity premium for the T1 bonds comes down after the crisis, however it remains

higher than the pre-crisis period until the end of our sample period. This is consistent with

the fact that during this subperiod, many investors including insurers struggle to obtain

28

Page 30: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

financing or roll-over short-term financing, and liquidity remains scarce and the premium on

liquidity remains high (e.g., Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012) and Friewald et al. (2012)). However,

note that for the T3 bonds, i.e., those held by investors who are less subject to the funding

constraints, the liquidity premium remains relatively modest during the same period.

Overall, the findings here highlight the importance of liquidity clientele on the time

variation of liquidity premium.

5.6 Further Analysis

We conduct further analysis to test additional implications of liquidity clientele. We look at

the clientele effect among short-term vs. long-term bonds, two alternative liquidity clientele

measures that separately quantify the effect of investment horizon and funding constraints,

a subsample of bonds with relative clean control of credit risk, and the clientele effect among

speculative bonds as well as among bonds with varying degrees of insurer ownership. And

finally, we use expected yield spreads instead of promised yield spreads in analysis.

5.6.1 Short-term vs. Long-term Bonds

In contrast to the indefinite life of stocks typically considered in the theoretical models of

liquidity clientele, corporate bonds have finite maturities. This distinction offers an inter-

esting opportunity to study the investment horizon effect. The effective holding horizon for

short-maturity bonds has to be short, regardless of how long an investor’s horizon is when

holding other securities. Consequently, for short-term bonds, long-horizon investors do not

have an advantage in amortizing trading costs. Thus, we expect the liquidity clientele effect

to be weaker among short-term bonds relative to long-term bonds.

To test this conjecture, we perform regressions specified by Eq. (4) for the short- and long-

term bonds separately. The short-term bonds are those with less than five years to maturity,

and the long-term bonds with five or more years to maturity. Table 7 reports the regression

results. For short-term bonds, most of the coefficients on the interaction terms between

ILQ and the ILC tercile dummies are either insignificant or have wrong signs relative to

29

Page 31: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

what the clientele effect suggests. For instance, under the Amihud illiquidity measure, across

short-term bonds, the coefficient on ILQ*T2 is -0.03 (t-stat = -0.75) and the coefficient on

ILQ*T3 is -0.11 (t-stat = -2.29). By contrast, across long-term bonds, the coefficients on

ILQ*T2 and ILQ*T3 are -0.14 (t-stat = -3.58) and -0.22 (t-stat = -6.28), respectively. This

confirms the notion that the effect of liquidity clientele on liquidity premium is stronger

among long-term bonds than among short-term bonds.

5.6.2 Alternative Liquidity Clientele Measures

In Table 4 we show that insurers’ liquidity preference is related to both investment horizon

and access to financing. Here, we more directly examine impact of these two types of insurer

characteristics on liquidity premium.

To investigate the investment horizon effect, we construct an alternative ILC measure

based on insurers’ portfolio turnover. Specifically, in the clientele measure definition of Eq.

(2), we replace ILP by the inverse of the 4-quarter rolling average of an insurer’s corporate

bond portfolio turnover (i.e., 1/TURN ). As noted earlier, this measure is also related to the

latent liquidity measure of Mahanti et al. (2008).

To investigate the effect of funding constraints, we construct a second alternative ILC

measure, which involves two steps. First, in each year, we combine five insurer characteristics

related to ease of financing into one combined measure. Specifically, we sort firms into

percentiles (with value from 0 to 1) based on each of the following three characteristics:

total assets (TA), firm age (AGE ), and the inverse of the reinsurance ratio (1/REINS ). For

the dummy variables AFF and STOCK, we keep their values of either 0 or 1. We then

take the average over the three percentile variables and the two dummy variables to obtain

the combined measure. Second, in the clientele measure definition of Eq.(2), we replace the

portfolio illiquidity ILP by the above combined measure for ease of financing.

We perform panel regressions following the specification in Eq. 4 but using the turnover-

based and funding constraint-based ILC as the main explanatory variables (separately and

jointly) instead of the original ILC. The regression results for the turnover-based ILC are

30

Page 32: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

reported in the first five columns of Table 8, with each column involving one of the five bond-

level illiquidity measures ILQ. The pattern is consistent with those reported in Table 6 under

the original ILC measures. First, the coefficients on ILQ and the two ILC tercile dummies

(denoted as T2A and T3A) are all significantly positive regardless of bond illiquidity measures

used. For example, under the Amihud measure (column (1)), one percentage increase in ILQ

raises the yield spread by 0.16%. The coefficients on T2A and T3A are respectively 0.05

(t-stat = 2.29) and 0.14 (t-stat = 5.53), consistent with the notion of latent liquidity. The

coefficients on the interactions of ILQ with T2A and T3A are all significantly negative. This

is consistent with the finding in Table 6 although the magnitude of coefficients is slightly

smaller here. This suggests that liquidity clientele driven by differential investment horizons

across insurers attenuates liquidity premium. Again, the patterns of coefficients on control

variables are similar to those in Table 6.

The regression results for funding constraint-based ILC are reported in columns (6) to

(10) of Table 8. Across five different bond-level illiquidity measures ILQ, the coefficients

on ILQ and on the two ILC tercile dummies (denoted as T2B and T3B) are significantly

positive. The coefficients on the interactions of ILQ with T2B and T3B are significantly

negative. The magnitudes of the coefficients for the interactions in columns (6) through (10)

are slightly lower than those reported in the first five columns and those reported in Table

6. But the clientele effects under these ILC measures are largely consistent with each other.

Finally, we include the two alternative ILC measures jointly in the regressions. The

results, reported in the last five columns of Table 8, show that both investment horizon and

funding constraints drive the liquidity clientele effect on liquidity premium. For instance,

using the Amihud bond illiquidity measure, we find that the coefficient on the interaction

of ILQ with T2A (based on turnover) is -0.04 (t-stat = -2.69) and the coefficient on the

interaction of ILQ with T2B (based on funding constraint) is -0.03 (t-stat = -1.82). Further,

the interaction coefficient involving the turnover-based T3A is -0.06 (t-stat = -4.69) and that

involving funding constraint-based T3B is -0.03 (t-stat = -1.98).

Taken together, the results suggest that both investment horizon and funding constraints

31

Page 33: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

are important drivers of the liquidity clientele effect on liquidity premium.15

5.6.3 Analysis on Bond Pairs

The literature suggests that liquidity and credit risk are endogenous to each other and

interwined in affecting bond pricing (e.g., Ericsson and Renault (2006), He and Xiong (2012),

and He and Milbradt (2014)). This gives rise to an interesting possibility: ILC may affect

bond yield spreads via both the liquidity channel and the credit risk channel. In the regression

analysis reported in Table 6, we control for the effect of credit risk by including explanatory

variables such as the LTD, leverage, equity volatility, credit rating dummies as well as the

“catch-all” issuer-fixed effects. Here, we pursue an additional approach that has even stronger

control for credit risk and thus further highlights the liquidity channel of the clientele effect.

Specifically, we perform analysis on a sample of bond pairs by the same issuers. We

follow Helwege, Huang, and Wang (2014) to identify bond pairs which must have the same

issuer, same seniority, coupon type, interest frequency, and credit ratings. In addition, we

require the bond pairs to have sufficiently close maturity (no more than 1 year difference)

so that there is only minimal difference in the credit risk of the two bonds. When multiple

bond pairs are identified from the same issuer at the same time, we keep the pair with the

largest yield difference. In this way, we identify 963 unique bond pairs. Among each bond

pair, we define the base bond as the one with higher yield spread and the other as the paired

bond. By construction, the differences in yield spreads between the bond pairs are more

likely due to difference in liquidity rather difference in credit risk. Of course, because of the

correlation between credit risk and liquidity, by removing the credit risk effect, we may have

also removed part of the liquidity effect.

We perform panel regressions with the dependent variable being the difference in the

yield spreads of bond pairs (the yield spread of the base bond minus the yield spread of the

15We have also examined the liquidity premium volatility effect using the two alternative IlC measures.We separately estimate the liquidity premium in each quarter based on Eq. (5) for the top and bottom ILCterciles using turnover-based ILC and funding constraint-based ILC. The patterns in the time variations ofliquidity premium using the alternative ILC s are consistent with those in Figure 3. That is, the liquiditypremium is more volatile for T1 bonds than for T3 bonds.

32

Page 34: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

paired bond). The main independent variables are i) the difference in ILQ between the bond

pair, ii) the differences in T2 and T3, and iii) the difference in the interaction between ILQ

and T2, and the difference in the interaction between ILQ and T3. As the control variables,

we include the differences in bond characteristics including bond age, maturity, issue size

and coupon rate.

The results are reported in Table 9. We find a significant liquidity clientele effect on bond

pricing in the bond pair analysis. For example, using the Amihud illiquidity measure, we

find that the coefficient on the difference in the interaction between ILQ and T2 is -4.69%

(t-stat = -2.86), and the coefficient on the difference in the interaction between ILQ and

T3 is -9.76% (t-stat = -2.73), respectively. In addition, the coefficient on the difference in

ILQ is 6.34 with the 5% significant level. The coefficients on the differences in T2 and T3

are significantly positive, too. Moreover, the differences in bond age and the coupon rates

are significantly and positively correlated with the differences in yields. We find consistent

results under other bond-level illiquidity measures.

The results suggest a clientele effect on liquidity premium among bond pairs. This is

unlikely attributable to the credit risk channel, but rather to the liquidity channel.

5.6.4 Speculative Bonds and Bonds with Varying Degrees of Insurer Ownership

We now look into the importance of insurance ownership in detecting the clientele effect. As

observed in Panel C of Table 1, insurer ownership as a fraction of bonds outstanding varies

across bonds. For bonds with low insurer ownership, insurers may not be the marginal

investors and the clientele measures based on insurer holdings may not significantly affect

bond pricing.

To examine the effect of insurer ownership, we divide the investment-grade bond sample in

each quarter into two groups—those with insure ownership below 20% of bonds outstanding

and those on or above the 20% threshold. We perform panel regressions following Eq. (4)

within each subsample. As shown in Panels A and B of Table 10, the clientele effect on

liquidity premium, as measured by the coefficients on ILQ*T2 and ILQ*T3, are rarely

33

Page 35: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

significant in the sample of bonds with low insurance ownership. However, the coefficients

on the interactions are pervasively significant in the sample of bonds with high insurance

ownership (i.e., insurers’ holding exceeds 20%). The coefficients and t-statistics also suggest a

weaker relation of T2 and T3 with yield spreads among bonds with lower insurer ownership.

However, not that the coefficients on ILQ (the construction of which does not depend on

insurer ownership) are comparable between the two subsamples. These results suggest that

it is important to rely on the holdings of marginal investors in detecting the clientele effect

on bond pricing.

Well known in existing literature (e.g., Campbell and Taksler (2003), Ellul et al. (2011),

Ambrose et al. (2012), and Becker and Ivashina (2013)) and confirmed by Panel C of Table

1, insurers have limited participation in the speculative bond market. If being marginal

investors is important for constructing effective liquidity clientele measures, then the ILC

based on insurer holdings is expected to have weak impact on the liquidity premium of

speculative bonds. This is indeed the case. We perform panel regressions following Eq. (4)

on the speculative bonds, and report the results in Panel C of Table 10. Most of the

coefficients on ILQ*T2 and ILQ*T3 are insignificant.16

5.6.5 Analysis based on Expected Yield Spreads

Lastly, we repeat the panel regressions following Eq. (4) with expected yield spreads as

the dependent variable. Recall from Section 4.4 that expected yield spreads are computed

by adjusting the (promised) yield spreads with expected default losses. Results from the

regressions on expected yield spreads are largely similar to those based on promised yield

spreads reported in Table 6. Thus, our main findings are robust to the use of expected yield

spreads. For brevity, these results are not tabulated.

16Another possible reason for the insignificant clientele effect among speculative bonds is that for suchbonds, credit risk matters more than liquidity in bond pricing. This also helps explain the observation thatsome of the ILQ measures (albeit not all) have weak or insignificant coefficients in Panel C.

34

Page 36: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

6 Conclusions

Although the notion of “liquidity clientele,” first introduced by Amihud and Mendelson

(1986), is well known in the theoretical literature, to our knowledge it has not been formally

tested in the corporate bond market. In this study, we conduct such a test using a compre-

hensive dataset on corporate bond holdings of insurance firms, which are by far the largest

group of corporate bond investors. The dataset provides detailed information on these hold-

ers and thus allows us to quantify their liquidity preferences and link the preferences to

corporate bond yield spreads.

Our results provide evidence for the existence of liquidity clientele. We find substantial

heterogeneity in the liquidity preference across insurers. We also find that such liquidity

preference is persistent over time and correlated with characteristics indicative of insurers’

investment horizons and their funding constraints. Furthermore, we document that insur-

ers’ liquidity preference interacts with bond liquidity to affect corporate bond yield spreads.

Bonds with higher illiquidity have higher yield spreads, consistent with the liquidity premium

effect. Moreover, liquidity clientele attenuates the liquidity premium. Additional implica-

tions of the clientele effect also find support in the data, such as the behavior of liquidity

premium volatility, the differential impact on short-term and long-term bonds, and the effect

of funding constraints on bond pricing.

35

Page 37: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Appendix: Corporate Bond Illiquidity Measures

This appendix describes the details of the five bond illiquidity measures.

1. Amihud

The daily Amihud measure is the average ratio of absolute return to the trade size (in $

million) of consecutive transactions during a day:

Amihudi,t =1

Ni,t

Ni,t∑j=1

∣∣∣Pi,j−Pi,j−1

Pi,j−1

∣∣∣Qi,j

, (6)

where Ni,t is the number of trades of bond i on day t ; Pi,j and Pi,j−1 are the prices for two

consecutive trades (j − 1th and jth), for bond i on day t; Qi,j is the size of the jth trade

for bond i. As such, at least two transactions are required on a given day to calculate the

measure. Following Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012), the quarterly Amihud measure is the median

of daily measures within the quarter.

2. Roll

The Roll (1984) measure infers the effective bid-ask spread from negative serial dependence

of successive transaction price changes. Bao et al. (2011) show that this measure is posi-

tively related to corporate bond yields. Our procedure follows Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012).

Specifically, the daily Roll measure is:

Rolli,t = 2√−cov(Ri,t, Ri,t−1), (7)

where Ri,t and Ri,t−1 are returns to two consecutive trades, computed as price changes

scaled by the price of the first trade. The covariance is computed using a rolling window

of 21 trading days. The quarterly Roll measure is the median of daily measures within the

quarter.

36

Page 38: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

3. LOT

The LOT measure of Lesmond et al. (1999) is based on the idea that given the same amount

of new information, more illiquid securities should have fewer trades, thus more zero-return

days. Specifically,

LOTi,t = α2,j − α1,j (8)

where α1,j and α2,j are buy-side and sell-side costs of bond j that can be estimated using the

maximum likelihood method. We follow Chen et al. (2007) to specify the likelihood function:

LnL =∑

1

Ln1

(2πσ2j )

1/2−∑

1

1

2σ2j

(Rj,t + α1,j − βj1Durj,t ∗∆Rft

−βj2Durj,t ∗∆S&Pt)2 +

∑2

Ln1

(2πσ2j )

1/2

−∑

2

1

2σ2j

(Rj,t + α2,j − βj1Durj,t ∗∆Rft

−βj2Durj,t ∗∆S&Pt)2

+∑

0

Ln(Φ2,j − Φ1,j)

where∑

1 (region 1) and∑

2 (region 2) refer to nonzero measured returns in negative and

positive market return regions, respectively.∑

0 (region 0) refers to the region of zero returns.

The return generating process is given as R∗j,t = βj1Durj,t ∗∆Rft + βj2Durjt ∗∆S&Pt + εj,t.

R∗j,t is the unobserved “true” bond return for bond j that investors would bid given zero

liquidity costs; Durj,t is the bond’s duration; ∆Rft is the daily change in the 10-year risk-free

interest rate; and ∆S&Pt is the daily return on the S&P 500 index. The liquidity effects on

bond returns can be stated as Rj,t = R∗j,t − αi,j. The term Rj,t is the measured return; α1,j

is the effective sell-side cost for bond j and α2,j is the effective buy-side cost. Φ1,j and Φ2,j

are the distribution function of the standard normal distribution.

37

Page 39: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

4. IRC

The imputed round-trip cost (IRC) follows Feldhutter (2012) and is based on the dispersion

of traded prices around the market-wide consensus valuation:

IRCi,t =Pmaxi,t − Pmin

i,t

Pmini,t

(9)

where Pmax is the largest price in an imputed roundtrip transaction (IRT ) and Pmin is

the smallest price in the IRT. If two or three trades on a given bond with the same trade

size take place on the same day, they are likely the result of a dealer taking one side of a

trade and then taking an offsetting trade subsequently. They are considered as imputed

roundtrip transactions. The price differences among such trades likely reflect the bid-ask

spread charged by the bond dealers. The daily IRC measure is the average of roundtrip

costs on that day. A quarterly IRC measure is the average of the daily estimates.

5. λ

This measure, based on Dick-Nielsen et al. (2012), is an equally weighted sum of four variables

normalized to a common scale: Amihud measure, IRC, and the variability of each of these

two measures. To be specific, for each bond and quarter, we first calculate the four liquidity

measures: Amihud, IRC, and the standard deviations of the daily Amihud measure and IRC

measure over a quarter. Then we normalize each measure and compute λ as follows:

λi,t =4∑j=1

ILQji,t − µj

σj, (10)

where ILQji,t, j = 1, . . . , 4, denote the four illiquidity measures mentioned above, and µj and

σj are the mean and standard deviation of each measure across bonds and quarters. See also

Han and Zhou (2008).

38

Page 40: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

References

Acharya, Viral V. and Lasse Heje Pedersen (2005), “Asset Pricing with Liquidity Risk,”Journal of Financial Economics , vol. 77, 375–410.

Ambrose, Brent W., Kelly Nianyun Cai, and Jean Helwege (2012), “Fallen angels and pricepressure,” Journal of Fixed Income, vol. 21, 74–86.

Amihud, Yakov (2002), “Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Cross-Section and Time-Series Ef-fects,” Journal of Financial Markets , vol. 5, 31–56.

Amihud, Yakov and Haim Mendelson (1986), “Asset Pricing and the Bid-Ask Spread,”Journal of Financial Economics , vol. 17, 223–249.

Amihud, Yakov, Haim Mendelson, and Lasse Heje Pedersen (2012), Market Liquidity: AssetPricing, Risk, and Crises , Cambridge University Press.

Atkins, Allen B. and Edward A. Dyl (1997), “Transactions Costs and Holding Periods forCommon Stocks,” Journal of Finance, vol. 52, 309–325.

Bao, Jack, Jun Pan, and Jiang Wang (2011), “Liquidity of Corporate Bonds,” Journal ofFinance, vol. 66, 911–946.

Beber, Alessandro, Joost Driessen, and Patrick Tuijp (2012), “Pricing Liquidity Risk withHeterogeneous Investment Horizons,” Working paper, Cass Business School.

Becker, Bo and Victoria Ivashina (2013), “Reaching for Yield in the Bond Market,” Journalof Finance, forthcoming.

Blume, Marshall E., Felix Lim, and Craig A. Mackinlay (1998), “The Declining CreditQuality of U.S. Corporate Debt: Myth or Reality?” Journal of Finance, vol. 53, 1389–1413.

Brunnermeier, Markus K. and Lasse H. Pedersen (2008), “Market Liquidity and FundingLiqudity,” Review of Financial Studies , vol. 22, 2201–2238.

Campbell, John Y. and Glen B. Taksler (2003), “Equity Volatility and Corporate BondYields,” Journal of Finance, vol. 58, 2321–2350.

Chakravarty, Sugato and Asani Sarkar (1999), “Liquidity in U.S. fixed income markets: acomparison of the bid-ask spread in corporate, government and municipal bond markets,”Staff Report 73, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Chen, Long, David A. Lesmond, and Jason Wei (2007), “Corporate Yield Spreads and BondLiquidity,” Journal of Finance, vol. 62, 119–149.

Chen, Xuanjuan, Zhenzhen Sun, Tong Yao, and Tong Yu (2013), “In Search of Habitat,”Working paper, University of Iowa.

39

Page 41: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Collin-Dufresne, Pierre, Robert S. Goldstein, and Spencer J. Martin (2001), “The Determi-nants of Credit Spread Changes,” Journal of Finance, vol. 56, 2177–2207.

Constantinides, George M. (1986), “Capital Market Equilibrium with Transaction Costs,”Journal of Political Economy , vol. 94, 842–862.

Dick-Nielsen, Jens (2009), “Liquidity Biases in TRACE,” Journal of Fixed Income, vol. 19,43–55.

Dick-Nielsen, Jens, Peter Feldhutter, and David Lando (2012), “Corporate Bond LiquidityBefore and After the Onset of the Subprime Crisis,” Journal of Financial Economics ,vol. 103, 471–492.

Duffee, Gregory R. (1998), “The Relationship between Treasury Yields and Corporate BondYield Spreads,” Journal of Finance, vol. 53, 2225–2241.

Duffie, Darrell, Nicolae Garleanu, and Lasse Heje Pedersen (2005), “Over-the-Counter Mar-kets,” Econometrica, vol. 73, 1815–1847.

Edwards, Amy K., Lawrence E. Harris, and Michael S. Piwowar (2007), “Corporate BondMarket Transaction Cost and Transparency,” Journal of Finance, vol. 62, 1421–1451.

Ellul, Andrew, Chotibhak Jotikasthira, and Christian T. Lundblad (2011), “Regulatory Pres-sure and Fire Sales in the Corporate Bond Market,” Journal of Financial Economics ,vol. 101, 596–620.

Ericsson, Jan and Olivier Renault (2006), “Liquidity and Credit Risk,” Journal of Finance,vol. 61, 2219–2250.

Feldhutter, Peter (2012), “The Same Bond at Different Prices: Identifying Search Frictionsand Selling Pressures,” Review of Financial Studies , vol. 25, 1155–1206.

Friewald, Nils, Rainer Jankowitsch, and Marti G. Subrahmanyam (2012), “Illiquidity orCredit Deterioration: A Study of Liquidity in the US Corporate Bond Market DuringFinancial Crises,” Journal of Financial Economics , vol. 105, 18–36.

Han, Song and Hao Zhou (2008), “Effects of Liquidity on the Nondefault Componentof Corporate Yield Spreads: Evidence from Intraday Transactions Data,” Available athttp://ssrn.com/paper=946802.

He, Zhiguo and Konstantin Milbradt (2014), “Endogenous Liquidity and Defaultable Bonds,”Econometrica, forthcoming.

He, Zhiguo and Wei Xiong (2012), “Rollover Risk and Credit Risk,” Journal of Finance,vol. 67, 391–430.

Helwege, Jean, Jing-Zhi Huang, and Yuan Wang (2014), “Liquidity Effects in CorporateBond Spreads,” Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 45, 105–116.

40

Page 42: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Hong, Gwangheon and Arthur Warga (2000), “An Empirical Study of Bond Market Trans-actions,” Financial Analysts Journal , vol. 56, 32–46.

Hotchkiss, Edith and Gergana Jostova (2007), “Determinants of Corporate Bond Trading:A Comprehensive Analysis,” Working paper, Boston College.

Huang, Jing-Zhi and Ming Huang (2012), “How Much of the Corporate-Treasury YieldSpread is due to Credit Risk,” Review of Asset Pricing Studies , vol. 2, 153–202.

Jang, Bong-Gyu, Hyeng Keun Koo, Hong Liu, and Mark Loewenstein (2007), “Liquiditypremia and transaction costs,” Journal of Finance, vol. 62, 2329–2366.

Lesmond, David A., Joseph P. Ogden, and Charles A. Trzcinka (1999), “A New Estimate ofTransaction Costs,” Review of Financial Studies , vol. 12, 1113–1141.

Lin, Hai, Junbo Wang, and Chunchi Wu (2011), “Liquidity Risk and Expected CorporateBond Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics , vol. 99, 628–650.

Longstaff, Francis A., Sanjay Mithal, and Eric Neis (2005), “Corporate Yield Spreads: De-fault Risk or Liquidity? New Evidence from the Credit-Default-Swap Market,” Journalof Finance, vol. 60, 2213–2253.

Mahanti, Sriketan, Amrut Nashikkar, Marti G. Subramanyam, George Chacko, and GauravMallik (2008), “Latent Liquidity: A New Measure of Liquidity with An Application toCorporate Bonds,” Journal of Financial Economics , vol. 88, 272–298.

Nashikkar, Amrut, Marti G. Subrahmanyam, and Sriketan Mahanti (2011), “Liquidity andArbitrage in the Market for Credit Risk,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis ,vol. 46, 627–656.

Petersen, Mitchell A. (2009), “Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets:Comparing Approaches,” Review of Financial Studies , vol. 22, 435–480.

Roll, Richard (1984), “A Simple Implicit Measure of the Effective Bid-Ask Spread in AnEfficient Market,” Journal of Finance, vol. 39, 1127–1139.

Schultz, Paul (2001), “Corporate Bond Trading Costs: A Peek Behind the Curtain,” Journalof Finance, vol. 56, 677–698.

Schuster, Philipp, Monika Trapp, and Marliese Uhrig-Homburg (2013), “A HeterogeneousAgents Equilibrium Model for the Term Structure of Bond Market Liquidity,” Workingpaper, available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2237879.

Vayanos, Dimitri and Tan Wang (2007), “Search and Endogenous Concentration of Liquidityin Asset Markets,” Journal of Economic Theory , vol. 136, 66–104.

41

Page 43: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 1: Statistics for Corporate Bonds Held by Insurers

This table reports summary statistics on sample bonds and insurers’ holdings of these bonds. Panel Areports the statistics on the numbers of unique bonds in the entire sample and in various subsamples, atthe end of each year from 2003 to 2011. The “FISD-TRACE Sample” (Column 2) refers to plain-vanillabonds in the merged FISD and TRACE datasets. We require bonds to have non-missing yields, non-missingcredit rating, and maturity no less than six months. The “Bonds held by insurers” (Column 3) refers tobonds in the FISD-TRACE sample that are held by insurers. Columns (4) to (8) report the numbers ofinsurer-held bonds in five different credit rating categories, and Columns (9) to (12) for the numbers in fourmaturity categories. The five rating groups are labeled AAA, AA (including AA+, AA, AA-), A (includingA+, A, A-), BBB (including BBB+, BBB, BBB-) and speculative bonds (with ratings below BBB-). Thefour maturity categories include below 2 years, 2-5 years, 5-10 years, and above 10 years. The second to lastrow captioned “All” reports the numbers of unique bonds throughout the entire period of 2003-2011. Thelast row captioned “Average” reports the average number of unique bonds over the sample years. Panel Breports the distributions of insurers’ portfolio weights on corporate bonds in five credit rating categories andin four maturity categories. We first compute the portfolio weight of an insurer in a given bond categoryin each quarter. We then compute the cross-sectional statistics on these weights across insurers in thatquarter. The distribution statistics include the 5th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and 95th percentiles, as well as themean and standard deviation. We then average these statistics over time and report the averages in thispanel. Panel C reports the distributions of insurer holdings as fractions of bonds outstanding in the fivecredit rating categories and in the four maturity categories. The panel also reports (column captioned “N”)the average number of bonds insurers hold in each category. Panel D reports statistics for the investment-grade bonds held by insurers, for each year between 2003 and 2011. The statistics include the number ofunique bonds and the cross-sectional distributions of insurer holdings as fractions of bonds outstanding. Thelast row captioned “All/Average” reports the time-series averages of the number of unique bonds and thedistributions of fractional insurer holdings, and the total number of unique bonds during the entire sampleperiod.

Panel A: Number of unique corporate bonds

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

FISD- Bonds held by insurers

TRACE Total by credit rating by maturity

Year Sample AAA AA A BBB Spec <2y 2-5y 5-10y >10y

2003 2,400 2,252 72 310 1,284 422 164 446 724 627 455

2004 3,607 3,192 81 355 1,276 1,103 377 724 1,059 966 443

2005 4,443 3,850 84 386 1,328 1,301 751 895 1,218 1,145 592

2006 4,439 3,724 89 405 1,309 1,213 708 929 1,129 1,046 620

2007 4,310 3,469 97 426 1,199 1,144 603 842 1,095 918 614

2008 4,047 3,054 69 182 1,062 1,154 587 663 1,121 747 523

2009 4,167 2,599 14 208 860 940 577 655 919 620 405

2010 4,122 2,250 25 183 763 784 495 642 660 574 374

2011 4,054 1,878 13 103 727 649 386 557 469 532 320

All 8,656 7,873 166 757 2,954 2,591 1,405 2,058 2,018 2,066 1,731

Average 3,954 2,916 60 284 1,089 967 516 705 932 797 482

42

Page 44: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Panel B: Insurers’ portfolio weights on corporate bonds (%)

Year P5 P25 Mean Median P75 P95 Std Dev

i. by credit rating

AAA 0.00 0.00 10.75 0.78 18.37 39.35 15.95

AA 0.00 5.61 25.88 24.67 38.94 65.17 22.31

A 0.27 18.46 35.00 30.32 45.19 96.40 25.31

BBB 0.00 0.21 20.97 18.13 31.94 60.71 21.69

Speculative 0.00 0.00 7.41 0.00 8.23 36.93 15.89

ii. by maturity

< 2 years 0.19 8.33 28.80 26.47 41.68 80.75 24.65

2-5 years 0.04 16.94 34.15 31.83 47.58 94.59 24.99

5-10 years 0.00 4.16 25.54 25.01 39.05 73.05 23.64

> 10 years 0.00 0.00 11.51 2.38 20.11 49.78 19.47

Panel C: Insurers’ bond holdings as fractions of bonds outstanding (%)

Type N P5 P25 Mean Median P75 P95 Std Dev

i. by credit rating

AAA 60 3.81 8.53 20.45 17.66 30.27 45.46 14.96

AA 284 3.51 9.79 23.15 18.42 33.48 56.08 17.25

A 1,089 6.95 19.26 36.52 34.21 52.01 72.88 20.86

BBB 967 8.25 22.46 39.29 37.62 54.68 76.04 21.01

Speculative 516 0.44 3.41 12.66 8.30 17.32 40.35 13.18

ii. by maturity

<2 years 705 2.19 10.12 26.00 21.35 38.46 63.96 19.64

2-5 years 932 2.92 12.11 28.44 24.55 41.61 66.02 20.00

5-10 years 797 3.43 15.27 33.89 31.83 50.29 72.18 21.68

> 10 years 482 3.59 20.84 40.80 40.95 59.25 81.07 24.22

Panel D: Numbers and fractions of insurer holdings of investment-grade bonds (%)

Year N P5 P25 Mean Median P75 P95 Std Dev

2003 2,088 5.00 16.76 34.13 31.19 49.67 72.41 21.14

2004 2,815 6.11 21.98 40.69 39.18 57.98 79.88 23.09

2005 3,099 5.39 20.92 40.89 39.79 58.99 81.44 23.81

2006 3,016 7.10 22.64 41.77 39.78 58.95 83.59 23.56

2007 2,866 5.81 20.40 38.56 36.24 55.36 78.80 22.64

2008 2,467 5.35 19.93 38.00 35.19 54.56 79.07 22.90

2009 2,022 4.85 17.40 35.55 32.47 51.75 77.12 22.46

2010 1,755 5.10 17.70 37.05 34.22 54.49 78.38 22.91

2011 1,492 4.75 16.57 35.54 31.97 51.89 76.10 22.45

All/Average 6,468/2,400 5.50 19.37 38.02 35.56 54.85 78.53 22.77

43

Page 45: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 2: Cross-sectional Distributions of Yield Spreads, Liquidity, Liquidity

Preference, and Liquidity Clientele Measures

This table reports the cross-sectional distribution of yield spreads, bond illiquidity measures, insurer liquiditypreference, and bond clientele measures. Panel A reports the distribution of investment-grade corporate bondyield spreads (in %), computed as the difference between the yield of a bond and the U.S. Treasury yield withthe same maturity. Panel B reports the distribution of bond illiquidity measures (ILQ) including the Amihudmeasure (in %), Roll measure, LOT (in %), imputed roundtrip cost (IRC, in %), and the comprehensivemeasure λ. Panel C reports the distributions of insurers’ liquidity preference measures (ILP) and Panel Dreports the distributions of bond liquidity clientele measures (ILC ). The distributional attributes include the5th, 25th, 50th, 75th and 95th percentiles, as well as the mean and standard deviation (“Std Dev”) of eachvariable. We obtain each statistic in the fourth quarter of each year and then take the average over time.The column captioned “N” shows the average numbers of investment-grade bonds or insurers (in Panel C)included in the sample. The sample period is from 2003:Q1 to 2011:Q4.

Panel A: Yield spreads

N P5 P25 Mean Median P75 P95 Std Dev

spread (%) 2,400 0.49 1.04 1.78 1.61 2.24 3.74 1.06

Panel B: Bond illiquidity measures (ILQ)

Amihud (%) 2,034 0.04 0.23 1.27 0.61 1.44 4.77 2.01

Roll 2,166 0.46 0.85 1.69 1.29 1.95 4.14 1.61

LOT (%) 2,201 0.05 0.55 7.29 2.03 5.70 26.11 25.22

IRC (%) 2,115 0.10 0.26 0.51 0.43 0.66 1.23 0.37

λ 1,847 -0.74 -0.44 -0.03 -0.15 0.24 1.09 0.59

Panel C: Insurers’ illiquidity preference measures (ILP)

ILPAmihud (%) 3,410 0.73 0.82 1.28 1.09 1.44 3.03 0.65

ILPRoll 3,411 0.97 1.12 1.40 1.25 1.54 2.47 0.44

ILPLOT (%) 3,413 1.55 2.42 3.43 2.95 4.03 8.22 1.79

ILPIRC (%) 3,410 0.38 0.42 0.49 0.45 0.53 0.75 0.10

ILPλ 3,392 -0.25 -0.19 -0.03 -0.09 0.05 0.62 0.24

Panel D: Bond illiquidity clientele measures (ILC )

ILCAmihud (%) 2,400 0.99 1.12 1.24 1.21 1.32 1.54 0.27

ILCRoll 2,400 1.33 1.56 1.72 1.70 1.86 2.16 0.25

ILCLOT (%) 2,400 3.26 5.05 6.32 6.22 7.46 9.49 2.04

ILCIRC (%) 2,400 0.44 0.49 0.53 0.53 0.56 0.64 0.07

ILCλ 2,400 -0.12 -0.05 0.01 -0.01 0.05 0.16 0.11

44

Page 46: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 3: Correlation of Liquidity and Liquidity Clientele Measures

This table reports the correlation matrix of five liquidity measures (Amihud, Roll, LOT, IRC, and λ) andthe corresponding liquidity clientele measures (ILCAmihud, ILCRoll, ILCLOT , ILC IRC , and ILC λ). Wecompute the correlations over investment grade bonds in each quarter and then take the averages over time.The sample period is from 2003:Q1 to 2011:Q4.

Bond Illiquidity Measures Illiquidity Clientele Measures

Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ ILCAmihud ILCRoll ILCLOT ILCIRC ILCλ

Amihud 1.00

Roll 0.18 1.00

LOT 0.11 0.43 1.00

IRC 0.40 0.38 0.14 1.00

λ 0.69 0.38 0.12 0.79 1.00

ILCAmihud 0.40 0.22 0.13 0.37 0.43 1.00

ILCRoll 0.17 0.47 0.19 0.37 0.32 0.48 1.00

ILCLOT 0.11 0.36 0.34 0.26 0.20 0.35 0.79 1.00

ILCIRC 0.28 0.34 0.20 0.48 0.45 0.81 0.64 0.62 1.00

ILCλ 0.32 0.30 0.17 0.45 0.49 0.88 0.53 0.48 0.83 1.00

45

Page 47: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 4: Liquidity Preference and Insurer Characteristics

This table reports firm characteristics across insurer deciles sorted on liquidity preference (ILP). The five panels are for ILP based on fivedifferent bond illiquidity measures, i.e., Amihud, Roll, LOT, IRC, and λ. The six characteristics related to insurers’ investment horizons areportfolio turnover (TURN ), turnover of short-term bonds (STURN ), turnover of long-term bonds (LTURN ), the average holding horizon(HZ, in years) since initial acquisition of bonds, the maturity of bonds when purchased by insurers (MAT, in years), and the fraction of lifeinsurers within an ILP decile (LIFE, in %). The five characteristics related to insurers’ ease of financing are total assets (TA, in $billion),firm age (AGE, in years), the percentage of affiliated firms (AFF ) in an ILP decile, the percentage of stock insurers (STOCK, in %), andthe fraction of reinsurance premiums in an insurer’s aggregate collected premiums (REINS, in %). Insurers are classified into ILP deciles ineach quarter. We first compute the average characteristics within each decile in each quarter and then take their time-series averages for eachdecile. We also compute the difference between the top (D10) and bottom (D1) deciles and the associated t-statistics using the Newey-Westprocedure with a four-quarter lag. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sampleperiod is from 2003:Q1 to 2011:Q4.

Investment Horizon Funding Constraints

TURN STURN LTURN HZ MAT LIFE TA AGE AFF STOCK REINS(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)

Panel A: Insurer deciles sorted by ILPAmihud

D1 (L) 0.16 0.18 0.12 1.83 7.44 16.55 0.58 37.89 0.62 79.54 39.08D2 0.14 0.18 0.10 2.07 7.77 25.00 1.09 40.89 0.69 76.74 32.67D3 0.14 0.18 0.08 2.17 8.09 30.21 1.79 44.79 0.68 76.91 31.89D4 0.14 0.18 0.09 2.26 9.43 37.53 2.38 49.81 0.71 80.19 29.69D5 0.14 0.18 0.09 2.42 8.50 42.30 3.28 52.92 0.72 78.47 29.13D6 0.13 0.17 0.08 2.54 8.43 42.71 3.12 57.72 0.69 79.70 29.18D7 0.13 0.16 0.09 2.65 9.46 49.84 4.34 63.52 0.70 75.52 28.67D8 0.12 0.15 0.08 2.80 9.71 51.71 2.76 61.07 0.70 80.66 31.08D9 0.11 0.15 0.07 3.09 10.17 53.77 2.92 56.04 0.71 80.24 27.81D10 (H) 0.09 0.14 0.06 3.36 10.34 52.93 2.86 49.16 0.72 85.18 25.04H-L -0.07*** -0.04 -0.06*** 1.53*** 2.90*** 36.38*** 2.28*** 11.27*** 0.10*** 5.64*** -14.04***(t-stat) (-4.78) (-1.63) (-4.28) (8.12) (5.29) (11.35) (4.07) (7.29) (3.27) (3.15) (-11.62)

Panel B: Insurer deciles sorted by ILPRoll

D1 (L) 0.13 0.17 0.09 1.79 6.12 13.20 0.36 35.06 0.57 75.55 35.47D2 0.13 0.17 0.08 2.01 7.10 15.64 0.45 38.05 0.60 75.92 34.16D3 0.14 0.17 0.09 2.15 7.61 21.78 0.71 40.02 0.65 75.94 33.68D4 0.14 0.18 0.09 2.24 8.87 23.19 0.95 41.71 0.66 74.67 33.73D5 0.13 0.18 0.09 2.39 7.96 32.28 1.46 42.84 0.68 74.25 31.10D6 0.14 0.18 0.08 2.53 9.26 43.39 2.62 47.04 0.70 78.41 27.94D7 0.13 0.17 0.09 2.64 9.52 49.14 3.94 55.11 0.72 81.56 28.90D8 0.12 0.17 0.09 2.84 10.24 58.99 4.64 65.73 0.72 82.69 27.38D9 0.11 0.16 0.07 3.11 11.03 69.56 4.48 65.35 0.71 83.48 26.71D10 (H) 0.10 0.16 0.06 3.48 11.61 71.33 2.90 53.00 0.70 88.59 25.35H-L -0.03*** -0.01 -0.03*** 1.69*** 5.49*** 58.13*** 2.54*** 17.94*** 0.13*** 13.04*** -10.12***(t-stat) (-2.96) (-1.36) (-3.25) (5.47) (5.55) (15.42) (4.36) (11.56) (4.55) (4.42) (-7.19)

46

Page 48: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Investment Horizon Funding Constraints

TURN STURN LTURN HZ MAT LIFE TA AGE AFF STOCK REINS(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11)

Panel C: Insurer deciles sorted by ILPLOT

D1 (L) 0.14 0.18 0.08 1.81 7.54 15.15 0.30 35.42 0.53 70.08 35.44D2 0.13 0.18 0.07 2.03 7.13 15.73 0.45 37.50 0.64 74.03 34.20D3 0.13 0.18 0.07 2.17 7.73 21.27 0.55 41.69 0.69 74.90 32.39D4 0.13 0.17 0.07 2.22 8.40 24.80 0.69 37.91 0.70 72.46 30.09D5 0.13 0.18 0.06 2.40 8.58 29.29 0.93 46.87 0.72 74.74 32.33D6 0.13 0.18 0.06 2.54 8.60 40.38 1.67 47.43 0.75 79.58 31.89D7 0.13 0.17 0.06 2.70 9.57 46.44 2.75 53.71 0.77 81.22 28.27D8 0.13 0.17 0.06 2.81 9.71 59.71 4.37 61.06 0.77 85.93 29.14D9 0.11 0.16 0.05 3.02 11.15 72.00 6.25 60.76 0.82 87.38 25.34D10 (H) 0.10 0.16 0.05 3.35 10.97 69.81 4.11 61.48 0.77 88.85 25.37H-L -0.04*** -0.02 -0.03*** 1.54*** 3.43** 54.66*** 3.81*** 26.06*** 0.24*** 18.77*** -10.07***(t-stat) (-2.96) (-1.57) (-3.60) (5.85) (2.43) (10.63) (4.25) (7.28) (4.84) (9.02) (-5.62)

Panel D: Insurer deciles sorted by ILPIRC

D1 (L) 0.13 0.17 0.10 1.79 6.72 15.54 0.38 35.14 0.64 78.49 37.26D2 0.12 0.17 0.08 2.05 7.09 19.18 0.60 37.88 0.66 75.72 33.62D3 0.12 0.18 0.09 2.14 7.81 25.21 1.03 42.84 0.67 75.21 34.13D4 0.12 0.17 0.09 2.24 8.43 31.12 1.83 47.01 0.69 75.91 31.05D5 0.12 0.18 0.09 2.41 8.32 38.46 3.22 51.04 0.70 80.49 29.73D6 0.12 0.17 0.07 2.54 9.69 44.14 3.09 53.92 0.70 79.23 29.28D7 0.11 0.17 0.07 2.59 10.05 48.56 3.79 61.54 0.73 78.99 27.88D8 0.11 0.16 0.06 2.84 9.10 54.97 3.93 60.37 0.71 81.47 29.76D9 0.11 0.16 0.05 3.05 10.94 63.18 2.99 59.09 0.67 80.68 28.63D10 (H) 0.09 0.16 0.04 3.36 11.17 60.20 2.25 50.70 0.74 85.56 23.04H-L -0.04*** -0.01 -0.06*** 1.57*** 4.45*** 44.66*** 1.87*** 15.56*** 0.10*** 7.07*** -14.22***(t-stat) (-5.12) (-1.31) (-4.36) (6.97) (4.36) (9.72) (5.41) (6.47) (3.54) (3.26) (-9.50)

Panel E: Insurer deciles sorted by ILPλ

D1 (L) 0.12 0.16 0.09 1.80 6.74 14.28 0.47 35.85 0.60 74.59 38.38D2 0.14 0.17 0.08 2.07 8.19 20.64 0.73 40.24 0.64 75.41 33.74D3 0.14 0.16 0.09 2.20 7.80 30.26 1.37 45.49 0.67 78.92 32.69D4 0.14 0.16 0.09 2.28 8.85 37.31 3.40 52.32 0.70 77.14 31.36D5 0.14 0.16 0.08 2.44 8.53 38.44 2.63 49.27 0.71 79.39 28.68D6 0.13 0.17 0.07 2.52 8.49 42.55 3.36 58.01 0.71 80.07 27.87D7 0.12 0.17 0.06 2.63 9.46 49.20 3.33 60.79 0.72 78.37 29.38D8 0.12 0.17 0.05 2.75 10.21 54.31 3.76 59.10 0.73 80.68 30.26D9 0.10 0.16 0.05 2.95 10.34 58.14 2.07 57.42 0.72 79.57 27.56D10 (H) 0.09 0.15 0.04 3.39 10.70 56.30 1.94 49.99 0.73 81.15 24.36H-L -0.03*** -0.01 -0.05*** 1.59*** 3.96*** 42.02*** 1.47*** 14.14*** 0.13*** 6.56*** -14.02***(t-stat) (-5.21) (-1.44) (-4.79) (6.79) (4.00) (10.80) (4.61) (7.73) (4.49) (3.50) (-7.55)

47

Page 49: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 5: Yield Spreads for Bond Portfolios Sorted on ILQ and ILC

This table reports yield spreads of investment-grade bond portfolios sorted on ILQ and ILC. The five panelsare for five different bond illiquidity measures. Yield spread is expressed in percentage points. In each quarterwe sort bonds into 5x5 groups on a measure of ILQ and the corresponding measure of ILC independently.We first calculate the average yield spreads in each group, and then average over time. Within each ILCquintile, we also calculate the difference in yield spread between the top (ILQ5) and bottom (ILQ1) illiquidityquintiles. The associated t-statistics are computed using the Newey-West procedure with a four-quarter lag.*, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The sample periodis from 2003:Q1 to 2011:Q4.

ILC1 ILC2 ILC3 ILC4 ILC5 ILC5-ILC1

Panel A. Illiquidity Measure: AmihudILQ1 1.28 1.55 1.73 1.81 1.80 0.52ILQ2 1.35 1.56 1.72 1.77 1.82 0.47ILQ3 1.40 1.57 1.74 1.78 1.86 0.46ILQ4 1.55 1.73 1.82 1.93 1.92 0.38ILQ5 2.22 2.17 2.26 2.19 2.39 0.17ILQ5-ILQ1 0.94*** 0.62*** 0.53*** 0.38*** 0.59*** -0.35**(t-stat) (4.49) (4.22) (3.15) (3.52) (5.95) (-2.50)

Panel B. Illiquidity Measure: RollILQ1 0.88 1.12 1.37 1.59 1.73 0.86ILQ2 1.27 1.43 1.62 1.92 1.76 0.49ILQ3 1.76 1.78 2.04 2.18 1.79 0.04ILQ4 2.13 2.19 2.34 2.34 1.82 -0.30ILQ5 2.24 2.38 2.37 2.09 1.96 -0.28ILQ5-ILQ1 1.36*** 1.26*** 1.00*** 0.50*** 0.23*** -1.14***(t-stat) (4.62) (5.16) (6.17) (6.70) (2.56) (-3.63)

Panel C. Illiquidity Measure: LOTILQ1 1.29 1.56 1.82 1.86 1.99 0.70ILQ2 1.40 1.59 1.73 1.79 1.85 0.45ILQ3 1.57 1.68 1.83 1.75 1.84 0.27ILQ4 1.83 1.84 1.93 1.95 1.97 0.14ILQ5 2.34 2.17 2.17 2.15 2.17 -0.17ILQ5-ILQ1 1.05*** 0.61*** 0.35** 0.29** 0.18* -0.87***(t-stat) (3.16) (3.14) (2.48) (2.20) (1.79) (-3.51)

Panel D. Illiquidity Measure: IRCILQ1 0.83 1.10 1.39 1.68 1.71 0.88ILQ2 1.08 1.30 1.59 1.78 1.75 0.67ILQ3 1.45 1.68 1.85 2.07 1.74 0.29ILQ4 1.99 2.10 2.20 2.20 1.83 -0.16ILQ5 2.50 2.47 2.36 2.07 2.17 -0.33ILQ5-ILQ1 1.67*** 1.37*** 0.97*** 0.39*** 0.46*** -1.21***(t-stat) (4.26) (5.02) (5.91) (4.21) (6.03) (-3.40)

Panel E. Illiquidity Measure: λILQ1 0.90 1.15 1.36 1.65 1.71 0.80ILQ2 1.04 1.31 1.55 1.86 1.70 0.65ILQ3 1.32 1.58 1.80 1.94 1.72 0.40ILQ4 1.83 1.93 2.11 2.07 1.81 -0.02ILQ5 2.53 2.65 2.44 2.18 2.20 -0.33ILQ5-ILQ1 1.63*** 1.50*** 1.08*** 0.53*** 0.49*** -1.13***(t-stat) (4.38) (4.11) (4.58) (4.26) (6.32) (-3.53)

48

Page 50: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 6: Panel Regressions of Yield Spreads

This table reports the results of panel regressions on yield spreads of investment grade bonds. The dependent variable, yieldspread, is expressed in percentage points. The main explanatory variables include bond illiquidity ILQ, two dummies T2 and T3for the second and third terciles of the illiquidity clientele measure ILC (ranked each quarter), the interaction terms of ILQ withT2 and T3. The control variables include the year since the bond was issued (Bond age), time to maturity (Maturity), issuesize (Issue size), annual coupon rates (Coupon), an issuer’s ratio of operating income to sales (Income to sales), an issuer’s ratioof long term debt to assets (LTD), an issuer’s leverage ratio (Leverage), an issuer’s equity volatility (EqVol), and four pretaxinterest coverage variables of an issuer (Pretax1, Pretax2, Pretax3, and Pretax4 ). The regressions additionally include creditrating dummies, the issuer-fixed effects, and the time-fixed effects (not tabulated). The t-statistics reported in the parenthesesare based on two-way clustered (by time and by issuer) standard errors. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. Columns (1) to (5) report results for regressions without control variables. Columns (6)to (10) are results with control variables. The row under the column numbers indicates the bond illiquidity measure used. Thelast two rows report the adjusted R-square and the number of observations used in the regression.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ

Intercept 1.08*** 0.44*** 1.61*** 0.35*** 2.22*** -4.67*** -5.99*** -5.56*** -5.49*** -3.25***

(14.64) (3.76) (25.17) (2.80) (12.11) (-7.93) (-10.18) (-8.55) (-9.74) (-6.04)

ILQ 0.69*** 1.13*** 0.04** 3.59*** 2.29*** 0.29*** 0.59*** 0.06*** 1.60*** 0.98***

(13.92) (10.69) (2.27) (11.38) (14.22) (11.28) (10.77) (4.11) (14.38) (16.17)

T2 0.29*** 0.63*** 0.07** 0.40*** 0.13*** 0.20*** 0.45*** 0.17*** 0.34*** 0.15***

(7.51) (6.18) (2.48) (4.90) (4.02) (7.16) (7.20) (6.11) (7.42) (5.18)

T3 0.58*** 1.00*** 0.15*** 0.78*** 0.51*** 0.30*** 0.84*** 0.28*** 0.62*** 0.24***

(9.28) (8.48) (3.19) (7.56) (11.94) (7.72) (11.08) (7.33) (9.59) (2.80)

ILQ*T2 -0.23*** -0.52*** -0.01*** -1.04*** -0.31*** -0.10*** -0.25*** -0.03*** -0.43*** -0.10**

(-6.25) (-5.69) (-3.03) (-3.90) (-4.72) (-3.68) (-4.25) (-2.99) (-3.95) (-2.11)

ILQ*T3 -0.48*** -0.93*** -0.03*** -2.44*** -1.16*** -0.20*** -0.49*** -0.05*** -1.12*** -0.55***

(-11.18) (-8.93) (-3.77) (-9.01) (-9.50) (-8.22) (-8.34) (-3.70) (-9.78) (-8.93)

Bond age 0.02** 0.06** 0.03** 0.04** 0.02*

(2.18) (2.34) (2.35) (2.07) (1.90)

Maturity 0.68*** 1.55*** 0.72*** 1.37*** 1.60***

(3.31) (6.37) (3.73) (5.34) (5.79)

Issue size 0.17*** 0.25*** 0.24*** 0.19*** 0.15***

(5.61) (8.47) (7.30) (6.29) (5.18)

Coupon 0.08*** 0.02 0.05*** 0.06*** 0.08***

(5.27) (1.11) (3.30) (4.27) (5.35)

Income to sales (%) -0.22*** -0.26*** -0.25*** -0.24*** -0.28***

(-2.69) (-3.14) (-2.86) (-2.97) (-3.43)

LTD (%) 2.79*** 2.75*** 2.99*** 2.79*** 2.55***

(4.41) (4.40) (4.60) (4.43) (4.17)

Leverage (%) 7.07*** 7.08*** 7.82*** 7.15*** 6.22***

(6.70) (6.93) (7.23) (6.83) (6.52)

EqVol 0.98*** 0.97*** 1.03*** 0.98*** 0.91***

(9.26) (9.61) (9.99) (9.49) (8.70)

Pretax1 (%) -1.24 -1.21 -1.26 -1.21 -1.20

(-1.50) (-0.88) (-0.65) (-0.48) (-0.57)

Pretax2 (%) -1.19 -2.05 -2.15 -2.10 -0.99

(-0.11) (-0.39) (-0.35) (-0.64) (-0.59)

Pretax3 (%) -3.24 -4.40 -4.13 -2.15 -2.17

(-1.01) (-1.22) (-1.11) (-1.38) (-1.65)

Pretax4 (%) 0.21 0.23 0.21 0.23 0.24

(1.32) (1.59) (1.42) (1.68) (1.60)

Rating dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Fixed effect - issuer Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Fixed effect - quarter Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adj.R2 0.16 0.21 0.15 0.18 0.23 0.55 0.57 0.54 0.57 0.58

N 69,656 74,394 75,639 72,566 62,913 30,574 32,073 32,422 31,550 28,342

49

Page 51: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 7: Effects of Clientele on Liquidity Premium in Short-term and

Long-term Bonds

This table reports the results of panel regressions with the same specification as Table 6, but for short-term bonds and long-term investment-grade bonds separately. Short-term bonds are those with maturitybelow 5 years (Panel A) and long-term bonds are those with maturity on or above five years (Panel B).The dependent variable is the yield spread expressed in percentage points. The main explanatory variablesinclude bond illiquidity ILQ, two dummies T2 and T3 for the second and third terciles of the illiquidityclientele measure ILC (ranked each quarter), the interaction terms of ILQ with T2 and T3. The controlvariables are the same as Table 6. The t-statistics reported in the parentheses are based on two-way clustered(by time and by issuer) standard errors. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and1% level, respectively. The first row indicates the bond illiquidity measure used. The last two rows reportthe adjusted R-square and the number of observations used in the regression.

Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ

A. Short-term bonds B. Long-term bonds

ILQ 0.21*** 0.36*** 0.06*** 1.00*** 0.69*** 0.29*** 0.41*** 0.03*** 1.09*** 0.80***

(6.50) (6.00) (3.01) (6.27) (6.91) (7.93) (5.04) (3.41) (7.70) (10.43)

T2 -0.03 0.01 0.03 -0.10 -0.08 0.09** 0.20* 0.02** 0.10** 0.11***

(-0.86) (-0.08) (0.75) (-1.34) (-1.45) (2.21) (1.83) (2.52) (2.39) (2.82)

T3 -0.05 0.12 0.12** -0.34* 0.10 0.19*** 0.53*** 0.14*** 0.32*** 0.13**

(-0.76) (1.11) (2.17) (-1.72) (0.46) (3.61) (4.43) (2.98) (3.89) (2.16)

ILQ*T2 -0.03 0.01 -0.01 0.01 0.11 -0.14*** -0.15*** -0.02** -0.14*** -0.13**

(-0.75) (0.08) (-0.64) (0.05) (0.89) (-3.58) (-2.81) (-2.37) (-2.97) (-2.46)

ILQ*T3 -0.11** -0.20*** -0.05** 0.17 0.28 -0.22*** -0.33*** -0.03*** -0.69*** -0.45***

(-2.29) (-2.63) (-2.45) (0.36) (1.05) (-6.28) (-3.91) (-2.97) (-5.04) (-6.40)

Bond age 0.03*** 0.03*** 0.03*** 0.02*** 0.02** 0.02*** 0.03*** 0.03*** 0.04*** 0.02**

(3.38) (3.91) (4.35) (3.08) (2.21) (3.16) (4.81) (5.48) (4.14) (2.22)

Maturity 0.18*** 0.14*** 0.18*** 0.15*** 0.13*** 0.80*** 1.76*** 0.91*** 1.40*** 1.83***

(10.44) (7.66) (11.13) (7.00) (5.74) (10.29) (8.02) (9.90) (8.38) (9.25)

Issue size 0.06 0.08*** 0.09** 0.02 0.06 0.22*** 0.29*** 0.28*** 0.24*** 0.20***

(0.17) (2.62) (2.06) (0.52) (0.19) (6.00) (7.51) (7.04) (6.36) (5.25)

Coupon 0.02 0.03** 0.02 0.05 0.06 0.07*** 0.03 0.04 0.08*** 0.10***

(0.09) (2.32) (1.47) (0.04) (0.52) (3.09) (1.29) (1.61) (3.32) (4.35)

Income to sales (%) -0.05 -0.05 -0.04 -0.04 -0.05 -0.28*** -0.27*** -0.22*** -0.26*** -0.25**

(-1.18) (-1.07) (-0.91) (-0.85) (-0.98) (-2.98) (-3.34) (-2.94) (-3.10) (-2.29)

LTD (%) 1.07** 1.13** 1.23*** 1.32* 1.07** 2.35*** 2.32*** 2.44*** 2.36*** 2.18***

(2.29) (2.53) (2.59) (1.81) (2.16) (3.67) (3.57) (3.66) (3.65) (3.46)

Leverage (%) 6.10*** 6.22*** 6.80*** 6.48*** 5.91*** 7.76*** 7.87*** 8.42*** 7.81*** 6.77***

(4.58) (5.12) (5.19) (5.07) (4.81) (7.14) (7.26) (7.55) (7.18) (7.03)

EqVol 0.14 0.13 0.18 0.15 0.07 0.88*** 0.89*** 0.92*** 0.88*** 0.82***

(1.28) (1.61) (1.12) (1.37) (1.21) (9.92) (10.13) (10.32) (9.94) (9.51)

Pretax1 (%) -0.15 -0.18 -0.16 -0.10 -0.08 -1.40 -1.45 -1.46 -1.31 -1.25

(-0.11) (-0.24) (-0.26) (-0.34) (-0.18) (-1.55) (-0.97) (-0.95) (-1.10) (-1.66)

Pretax2 (%) -0.22 0.14 -0.51 -0.27 -0.25 -1.21 -2.43 -2.07 -2.02 -0.96

(-0.01) (0.18) (-0.40) (-0.21) (-0.25) (-1.10) (-0.37) (-0.99) (-1.14) (-0.69)

Pretax3 (%) -0.15 -0.36 -0.50 -0.40 -0.22 -3.55 -4.20 -4.41 -3.15 -2.73

(-0.28) (-0.51) (-0.54) (-0.45) (-0.63) (-1.25) (-1.21) (-1.08) (-1.25) (-1.22)

Pretax4 (%) 0.10 0.12 0.14 0.13 0.10 0.25 0.23 0.24 0.25 0.22

(0.56) (0.64) (0.58) (0.55) (0.47) (1.41) (1.62) (1.49) (1.65) (1.54)

Control variables Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Fixed effect - issuer Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Fixed effect - quarter Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adj.R2 0.57 0.58 0.58 0.58 0.59 0.60 0.60 0.59 0.61 0.62

N 12,054 12,583 12,682 12,433 11,289 18,520 19,490 19,740 19,117 17,053

50

Page 52: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 8: Panel Regressions of Yield Spreads using Alternative Illiquidity Clientele Measures

This table reports the results of panel regressions of yield spreads. The regression specification is the same as Table 6, but with two alternativeilliquidity clientele measures, one based on portfolio turnover and the other based on funding constraints. T2A and T3A are dummies for thesecond and third turnover-based ILC, and T2B and T3B are dummies for the second and third funding constraint-based ILC. The dependentvariable is the yield spread expressed in percentage points. The main explanatory variables include bond illiquidity ILQ, the ILC terciledummies T2A and T3A (and/or T2B and T3B), and the interactions of ILQ with the tercile dummies. The control variables are the sameas Table 6. The regressions additionally include dummies for each credit rating category, the issuer-fixed effects, and the time-fixed effects(not tabulated). The t-statistics reported in the parentheses are based on two-way clustered (by time and by issuer) standard errors. *, **,and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The first row indicates the bond illiquidity measure used.The last two rows report the adjusted R-square and the number of observations used in the regression.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15)

Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ

Intercept -4.76*** -5.80*** -8.13*** -5.55*** -3.58*** -4.55*** -5.55*** -4.89*** -5.38*** -3.42*** -4.73*** -5.79*** -5.11*** -5.52*** -3.52***

(-7.88) (-9.72) (-8.14) (-9.61) (-6.41) (-7.50) (-9.29) (-7.74) (-9.25) (-6.11) (-7.79) (-9.66) (-8.09) (-9.48) (-6.24)

ILQ 0.16*** 0.20*** 0.02*** 0.92*** 0.72*** 0.13*** 0.17*** 0.01*** 0.84*** 0.66*** 0.17*** 0.21*** 0.02*** 0.96*** 0.74***

(10.93) (9.44) (3.95) (14.28) (16.15) (11.59) (10.05) (4.58) (14.08) (16.42) (10.85) (9.87) (3.59) (14.12) (16.11)

T2A 0.05** 0.08** 0.06** 0.09*** 0.10** 0.05** 0.08** 0.04** 0.09*** 0.02**

(2.29) (2.42) (2.06) (3.15) (2.36) (2.27) (2.40) (2.29) (3.24) (2.18)

T3A 0.14*** 0.18*** 0.12*** 0.14*** 0.08** 0.14*** 0.18*** 0.12*** 0.14*** 0.03**

(5.53) (4.59) (4.53) (3.97) (2.43) (5.44) (4.73) (4.50) (3.98) (2.33)

ILQ*T2A -0.04*** -0.04*** -0.01** -0.16*** -0.08* -0.04*** -0.04* -0.01** -0.18*** -0.10**

(-2.66) (-2.83) (-2.22) (-2.88) (-1.96) (-2.69) (-1.92) (-2.15) (-3.16) (-2.39)

ILQ*T3A -0.06*** -0.06*** -0.02** -0.32** -0.12*** -0.06*** -0.07*** -0.02** -0.16** -0.12***

(-4.62) (-2.69) (-2.05) (-2.25) (-2.77) (-4.69) (-2.83) (-2.08) (-2.30) (-2.80)

T2B 0.08** 0.13*** 0.06* 0.13*** 0.05* 0.08** 0.14*** 0.06* 0.14*** 0.04**

(2.51) (2.92) (1.99) (3.05) (1.85) (2.54) (3.06) (1.98) (3.07) (2.27)

T3B 0.08** 0.15*** 0.06* 0.14*** 0.05*** 0.09** 0.17*** 0.08** 0.16*** 0.06**

(2.30) (3.15) (1.87) (3.59) (2.74) (2.52) (3.24) (2.17) (3.67) (2.26)

ILQ*T2B -0.01* -0.04** -0.01* -0.13** -0.04* -0.03* -0.05** -0.01 -0.18** -0.06

(-1.75) (-2.35) (-1.90) (-2.40) (-1.91) (-1.82) (-2.51) (-0.87) (-2.41) (-1.39)

ILQ*T3B -0.02* -0.04*** -0.02*** -0.18*** -0.09* -0.03* -0.09*** -0.01*** -0.23*** -0.10*

(-1.94) (-3.76) (-3.28) (-3.34) (-1.99) (-1.98) (-3.85) (-3.29) (-3.42) (-2.10)

Bond age 0.02** 0.03** 0.03** 0.05** 0.02*** 0.03 0.04 0.04 0.04 0.03*** 0.01* 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.02***

(2.08) (2.19) (2.26) (2.00) (2.88) (1.49) (0.67) (0.75) (0.67) (2.65) (1.75) (0.39) (0.31) (0.84) (2.71)

Maturity 0.45** 0.90*** 0.28*** 1.33*** 1.64*** 0.50*** 0.93*** 0.28** 1.38*** 1.68*** 0.49*** 0.94*** 0.30* 1.38*** 1.67***

(2.51) (5.00) (2.57) (6.72) (7.34) (2.67) (4.91) (2.26) (6.70) (7.32) (2.63) (4.97) (1.68) (6.68) (7.28)

Issue size 0.18*** 0.25*** 0.22*** 0.20*** 0.16*** 0.18*** 0.25*** 0.21*** 0.20*** 0.16*** 0.18*** 0.25*** 0.22*** 0.20*** 0.16***

(5.70) (8.30) (6.78) (6.52) (5.50) (5.45) (7.93) (6.44) (6.37) (5.25) (5.63) (8.19) (6.74) (6.49) (5.39)

Coupon 0.09*** 0.05*** 0.07*** 0.08*** 0.09*** 0.09*** 0.05*** 0.07*** 0.07*** 0.08*** 0.09*** 0.05*** 0.07*** 0.08*** 0.09***

(5.87) (3.27) (4.38) (5.53) (6.45) (5.61) (3.05) (4.20) (5.32) (6.19) (5.73) (3.06) (4.28) (5.31) (6.20)

Continued on next page

51

Page 53: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 8 – continued from previous page

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15)

Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ

Income to sales (%) -0.21** -0.25*** -0.23*** -0.23*** -0.26*** -0.21** -0.26*** -0.25*** -0.24*** -0.27*** -0.22*** -0.26*** -0.25*** -0.24*** -0.27***

(-2.52) (-3.02) (-2.73) (-2.96) (-3.34) (-2.49) (-3.19) (-2.90) (-3.04) (-3.38) (-2.62) (-3.20) (-2.92) (-3.07) (-3.43)

LTD (%) 2.87*** 2.84*** 3.02*** 2.85*** 2.65*** 2.92*** 2.88*** 3.05*** 2.88*** 2.69*** 2.92*** 2.88*** 3.04*** 2.89*** 2.70***

(4.47) (4.41) (4.61) (4.50) (4.32) (4.50) (4.45) (4.62) (4.50) (4.32) (4.51) (4.46) (4.63) (4.53) (4.35)

Leverage (%) 7.21*** 7.22*** 7.84*** 7.18*** 6.32*** 7.35*** 7.29*** 7.95*** 7.28*** 6.44*** 7.31*** 7.28*** 7.92*** 7.28*** 6.43***

(6.75) (6.97) (7.20) (6.78) (6.50) (6.87) (6.99) (7.28) (6.84) (6.59) (6.84) (7.00) (7.28) (6.84) (6.60)

EqVol 0.99*** 1.02*** 1.04*** 0.98*** 0.91*** 0.98*** 0.99*** 1.03*** 0.97*** 0.90*** 0.97*** 0.99*** 1.02*** 0.97*** 0.90***

(9.31) (9.87) (10.04) (9.63) (8.76) (9.35) (9.88) (10.06) (9.63) (8.75) (9.32) (9.91) (10.06) (9.64) (8.78)

Pretax1 (%) -1.22 -1.30 -1.44 -1.39 -1.21 -0.92 -1.15 -1.42 -1.36 -1.17 -1.26 -1.14 -1.39 -1.42 -1.10

(-1.55) (-0.78) (-1.25) (-1.33) (-0.50) (-1.58) (-0.71) (-1.23) (-1.31) (-0.55) (-1.58) (-0.82) (-1.21) (-1.30) (-0.58)

Pretax2 (%) -1.43 -1.21 -1.22 -1.23 -1.21 -1.45 -1.24 -1.16 -1.25 -1.22 -1.06 -1.20 -1.21 -1.22 -1.18

(-0.46) (-0.69) (-0.43) (-0.73) (-0.70) (-0.32) (-0.62) (-0.38) (-0.70) (-0.67) (-0.35) (-0.32) (-0.38) (-0.71) (-0.67)

Pretax3 (%) -3.59 -4.13 -4.17 -4.15 -3.79 -3.30 -4.16 -4.12 -4.10 -3.82 -3.31 -4.12 -3.83 -3.59 -3.78

(-0.80) (-1.18) (-1.15) (-1.42) (-1.67) (-0.85) (-1.16) (-1.13) (-1.41) (-1.66) (-0.85) (-1.14) (-1.12) (-1.41) (-1.62)

Pretax4 (%) 0.80 0.92 0.90 0.95 0.83 0.79 0.92 0.91 0.96 0.82 0.82 0.97 0.82 0.86 0.95

(1.35) (1.44) (1.40) (1.60) (1.64) (1.34) (1.44) (1.41) (1.61) (1.68) (1.32) (1.43) (1.35) (1.61) (1.65)

Rating dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Fixed effect - issuer Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Fixed effect - quarter Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adj.R2 0.49 0.48 0.49 0.49 0.50 0.40 0.41 0.38 0.41 0.44 0.52 0.53 0.52 0.53 0.53

N 30,574 32,073 32,422 31,550 28,342 30,574 32,073 32,422 31,550 28,342 30,574 32,073 32,422 31,550 28,342

52

Page 54: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 9: Panel Regressions on Bond Pairs

This table reports the results of panel regressions of yield spreads on a sample of bond pairs that arefrom the same issuers and thus have similar credit risks. The dependent variable is the difference in yieldspread (expressed in percentage points) between the bond pairs. The main explanatory variables include thedifference in ILQ between the bond pairs, the differences in the values of the ILC tercile dummies T2 andT3 between the bond pairs, as well as the bond pairs’ differences in the interactions of ILQ with T2 and T3.The control variables include the bond pair’s differences in the year since the bond was issued (∆Bondage),the difference in time to maturity (∆Maturity), the difference in issue size (∆Issuesize), and the differencein coupon rates (∆Coupon). The t-statistics reported in the parentheses are based on two-way clustered (bytime and by issuer) standard errors. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1%level, respectively. The row under column numbers indicates the bond illiquidity measure used. The lasttwo rows report the adjusted R-square and the number of observations used in the regression.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ

Intercept 0.62*** 0.62*** 0.63*** 0.73*** 0.51***(24.91) (21.18) (18.35) (22.55) (21.87)

∆ILQ (x100) 6.34** 7.89*** 2.26** 27.50*** 9.17**(2.47) (4.21) (2.21) (4.65) (2.32)

∆T2(x100) 4.20* 7.16** 1.20* 6.33** 6.76***(1.98) (2.03) (1.74) (2.25) (3.00)

∆T3 (x100) 7.15** 13.31*** 2.15* 12.97*** 6.17**(2.21) (3.07) (1.93) (3.86) (2.01)

∆(ILQ ∗ T2) (x100) -4.69*** -5.92** -0.65** -8.71** -0.82**(-2.86) (-2.24) (-2.10) (-2.11) (-2.39)

∆(ILQ ∗ T3) (x100) -9.76*** -10.54*** -1.32** -16.70*** -1.97***(-2.73) (-3.45) (-2.22) (-3.33) (-2.61)

∆BondAge (x100) 0.61*** 0.41** 0.48** 0.52** 0.49**(2.77) (2.07) (2.43) (2.52) (2.14)

∆Maturity (x100) 2.14 2.16 2.16* 2.23** 2.16**(1.38) (1.51) (1.73) (2.05) (2.14)

∆IssueSize (x100) -0.23 -0.35 -0.52 -0.84 -0.45(-0.28) (-0.46) (-0.65) (-1.09) (-0.51)

∆Coupon (x100) 1.34* 1.17* 1.42** 1.38** 1.36*(1.88) (1.70) (2.06) (2.04) (1.85)

Adj.R2 0.32 0.35 0.32 0.30 0.30N 4,354 4,736 4,751 4,406 4,269

53

Page 55: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Table 10: Panel Regressions on Bond Subsamples

This table reports the results of panel regressions on yield spreads among three subsamples of corporate bonds: investment-grade bondswith insurer ownership below 20% of bonds outstanding (Panel A), investment-grade bonds with insurer ownership above 20% of bondsoutstanding (Panel B), and speculative bonds (Panel C). The regression specification is the same as Table 6. The dependent variable isthe yield spread expressed in percentage points. The main explanatory variables include bond illiquidity ILQ, two dummies T2 and T3 forthe second and third terciles of the illiquidity clientele measure ILC (ranked each quarter), the interaction terms of ILQ with T2 and T3.The control variables are the same as Table 6. The regressions additionally include credit rating dummies, the issuer-fixed effects, and thetime-fixed effects (not indicated or tabulated). The t-statistics reported in the parentheses are based on two-way clustered (by time and byissuer) standard errors. *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively. The first row indicates thebond illiquidity measure used. The last two rows report the adjusted R-square and the number of observations used in the regression.

Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ Amihud Roll LOT IRC λ

A. IG bonds < 20% held by insurers B. IG bonds ≥ 20% held by insurers C. Speculative-grade bonds

ILQ 0.38*** 0.57*** 0.06*** 1.77*** 1.06*** 0.27*** 0.58*** 0.04*** 1.52*** 0.95*** 0.18*** 0.30* 0.01 2.55*** 1.92***

(6.04) (6.83) (3.76) (6.60) (7.23) (10.42) (9.67) (3.59) (14.10) (15.53) (4.57) (1.96) (1.59) (5.09) (4.98)

T2 0.08 0.33** 0.16* 0.13 0.13 0.20*** 0.43*** 0.13*** 0.32*** 0.13*** 0.04 0.12 -0.10 0.37 0.12

(0.91) (2.13) (1.98) (0.84) (1.69) (6.87) (7.05) (4.36) (7.03) (4.51) (0.32) (0.49) (-0.61) (1.51) (0.76)

T3 0.33*** 0.90*** 0.33*** 0.60*** 0.08 0.29*** 0.82*** 0.26*** 0.59*** 0.21** 0.14 0.19 0.01 0.02 -0.10

(3.12) (5.01) (4.17) (3.62) (0.60) (7.27) (10.56) (6.38) (9.69) (2.47) (0.75) (0.63) (0.02) (0.05) (-0.53)

ILQ*T2 -0.06 -0.11 -0.02 -0.13 -0.21 -0.10*** -0.26*** -0.03** -0.42*** -0.13*** -0.07 -0.10 -0.01* -0.76 0.13

(-0.63) (-0.88) (-0.85) (-0.41) (-1.27) (-4.10) (-4.48) (-2.33) (-3.83) (-2.69) (-0.81) (-0.85) (-1.99) (-1.56) (0.32)

ILQ*T3 -0.28 -0.48 -0.06 -1.02 -0.33 -0.19*** -0.47*** -0.04*** -1.09*** -0.58*** -0.18 -0.16 -0.01 -0.09 0.03

(-1.13) (-1.22) (-1.59) (-0.39) (-1.52) (-7.87) (-7.73) (-3.14) (-9.84) (-10.61) (-1.24) (-0.91) (-1.09) (-0.15) (0.08)

Adj.R2 0.20 0.25 0.26 0.21 0.20 0.54 0.56 0.53 0.56 0.57 0.60 0.59 0.58 0.61 0.63

N 4,235 4,330 4,354 4,289 4,110 26,339 27,743 28,068 27,261 24,232 6,670 6,833 6,888 6,756 6,405

54

Page 56: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Figure 1. Yield Spreads and Bond Illiquidity Measures

The figure shows the piecewise-linear relation between yield spreads and bond illiquidity measuresbased on piecewise-linear regressions. In each quarter we regress investment-grade bond yieldspreads onto the piecewise functions of a bond illiquidity measure. We average the time seriesaverages of the estimated coefficients and reconstruct the piecewise-linear relation based on theaverage coefficients. The five panels are for the relation under five different bond illiquidity measuresAmihud, Roll, LOT, IRC, and λ.

0.25% 1.25% 2.25%

1.5%

2%

Amihud

1 3 5

1.5%

2%

Roll

0.05 0.35 0.65

1.5%

2%

LOT

0.15% 0.55% 0.95%

1.5%

2%

IRC

-0.5 0.5 1.5

1.5%

2%

Yield Spread

55

Page 57: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Figure 2. Persistence in Portfolio Illiquidity

This figure plots the average portfolio illiquidity measures ILP during the ranking year (Y) andthe subsequent three years (Y+1 to Y+3), across five insurer quintiles sorted by ILP. In the fivepanels, ILP is constructed following Eq. (1) and based on the five different bond-level illiquiditymeasures Amihud, Roll, LOT, IRC, and λ.

Y Y+1 Y+2 Y+3-1%

0

1%

ILPAmihud

Q1Q2Q3Q4Q5

Y Y+1 Y+2 Y+3-0.5

00.5

1

ILPRoll

Y Y+1 Y+2 Y+3-5%

0 5%

ILPLOT

Y Y+1 Y+2 Y+3-0.2%

0

0.2%

ILPIRC

Y Y+1 Y+2 Y+3-0.4

0

0.4

ILP

56

Page 58: Liquidity Premium in the Eye of the Beholder: An Analysis ...

Figure 3. Liquidity Premium over Time in the Lowest and Highest ILC Terciles

The figure plots the time series of liquidity premium estimates among bonds in the lowest (T1 )and highest (T3 ) terciles of illiquidity clientele (ILC ). The liquidity premium estimates are thecoefficients on bond illiquidity measures (ILQ) in the yield spread regressions specified by Eq. (5).The five panels present the estimates under the five illiquidity measures Amihud, Roll, LOT, IRC,and λ. The solid line is for the liquidity premium estimates of the lowest ILC tercile and the dashline is for the highest ILC tercile.

2003Q4 2007Q4 2011Q40

0.2

Amihud

2003Q4 2007Q4 2011Q40

0.5

Roll

2003Q4 2007Q4 2011Q40

0.04

LOT

2003Q4 2007Q4 2011Q40

1

2

IRC

2003Q4 2007Q4 2011Q40

0.5

1

57