Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

download Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

of 24

Transcript of Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    1/24

    Liquidity and Transparency

    in Bank Risk Management

    Lev Ratnovski

    Bank of England and

    University of Amsterdam

    June 2007

    Abstract

    Liquidity risk is associated with uncertainty over solvency at the renancingstage. To insure, banks can accumulate liquid assets, or enhance transparency to

    facilitate renancing. Both are important components of risk management. A liq-

    uidity buer provides complete insurance against small liquidity needs, while trans-

    parency oers partial insurance against large ones as well. Due to leverage, banks

    can under-invest in both liquidity and transparency. While liquidity can be imposed,

    transparency is not veriable. This multi-tasking problem complicates liquidity

    regulation: liquidity requirements can compromise banks endogenous transparencychoices.

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    2/24

    1 Introduction

    Banks perform maturity transformation and insure publics liquidity needs, but in

    process become exposed to liquidity risk (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). When re-

    nancing frictions prevent a solvent bank from covering a liquidity shortage, it may go

    bankrupt despite having valuable long-term assets.

    There are two principal stylized facts about recent liquidity events in developed

    countries. Firstly, most of them were associated with increased solvency concerns:

    1991, Citibank and Standard Chartered (HK): rumors of technical insolvency;

    1998, Lehman Brothers (US): rumors of severe losses on emerging markets;

    2002, Commerzbank (Germany): rumors of insolvency due to trading losses.

    Secondly, in contrast to traditional retail runs, the impact of liquidity events was

    most acute in wholesale nance markets. There, a bank with uncertain solvency typically

    has to cover all maturing (and demandable) outows without any access to new funds.

    In contrast, retail outows were relatively modest, e.g. only 5% of depositor base during

    the BAWAG episode in 2006.

    Even when rumors turn out to be unsubstantiated, withdrawals and restricted access

    to new funds impose signicant strain. To survive a liquidity shock, a bank must be able

    to support itself with own funds for the duration of liquidity stress, and/or alleviate the

    markets concerns over its solvency to regain access to funds as soon as possible.

    This paper studies the options for bank liquidity risk management, when liquidity

    risk is driven by asymmetric information, and in presence of active wholesale nance

    markets. We suggest that there are two distinct ways in which a solvent bank can

    insure against inability to renance. One is to accumulate liquidity form a precau-

    tionary buer of short-term assets to cover possible outows internally. Another is to

    adopt transparency establish a set of mechanisms that facilitate solvency information

    transmission to the market and improve access to external funds Both investments

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    3/24

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    4/24

    tasking problem, which complicates optimal policy design. We show that liquidity re-

    quirements can compromise banks endogenous transparency choices. This can damage

    nancial stability and social welfare, particularly when transparency is an eective risk

    management mechanism, and market access is important in managing liquidity shocks.

    This paper builds on the notion of banks strategic endogenous transparency. We

    believe that this is an important and topical dimension, particularly in the context of

    recent debates on the role of market discipline pillar of Basel II, "principles-based" regu-

    lation (which relies on sound processes rather than "rules-based" formal requirements),

    and the importance of sound corporate governance.

    Banking business is inherently opaque, because in the course of lending relationships

    they obtain private and commonly not veriable information on borrowers. Banks can

    alter the degree of asymmetric information by choosing more of less information-sensitive

    loans (Boot and Thakor, 2000). Our interpretation of transparency is that, in addition

    to asset choice, a bank can also make a specic investment, in transparency, which for

    any given asset mix, will reduce ex-post information asymmetry over banks assets value.

    It is instructive to compare transparency to disclosure (Perotti and Von Thadden,

    2003). Disclosure is an ex-post action information release of uncertain reliability.

    Disclosure can be not credible (when outsiders do not believe that information is truth-

    ful) and not eective (when outsiders have no incentives to interpret information, Boot

    and Thakor, 2001). In this context contrast, transparency can be regarded as an ex-ante

    investment that enables credible and eective disclosure ex-post.

    There are a number of examples of possible transparency investments. Banks can

    issue subordinated debt (Calomiris, 1999) even when cheaper funds are available in

    order to have market participants who specialize in assessing the bank available should

    a genuine need for funds arise. Banks can create more robust risk management systems

    that produce more veriable information on eects of possible shocks. Banks can invest

    in establishing better external oversight. Transparency can also be improved by stream-

    lining "large and complex nancial institutions" (LCFIs) so as to make their individual

    businesses more comparable with specialized counterparts

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    5/24

    While transparency improves future communication, it cannot be perfect. In some

    circumstances, ex-post communication channels fail, and even a transparent bank can

    be unable to conrm its solvency. The eectiveness of transparency probability of

    successful communication is at least partially determined by factors outside a single

    banks control. The factors can be country-specic (more developed and liquid nancial

    markets) or industry-specic (more transparent other banks, or location in the nan-

    cial centre, when transparency is associated with positive externalities, Admati and

    Peiderer, 2000).

    Transparency has many benetical eects2. For example, transparency can help

    increase fundamental value by improving monitoring capabilities (Boot and Schmeits,

    2000), or reduce overall funding costs by allowing better ex-ante screening. But in this

    paper we focus on eects of transparency within response to shocks. The reason is that

    since unforeseen shocks likely associated with an increase in asymmetric information,

    the eects of thransaprency can be particularly pronounced during such such times.

    This paper contributes to the literature on liquidity crises. The closest model of

    liquidity events based on asymmetric information is Chari and Jagannathan (1987).

    Chari and Jagannathan describe consumer-based panics. In their model, uninfored

    depositors observe others withdrawals and make inferences over a banks solvency, but

    are unable to distinguish whether withdrawals have information-based or liquidity-drivenreasons. This information friction amplies liquidity shocks, so that uninformed runs

    can be a consequence of abnormal liquidity-based withdrawals in fundamentally solvent

    bank.

    In contrast, our paper has a wholesale nance perspective. We therefore focus on

    dierent triggers and eects of liquidity events. The model purposefully downplays

    the determinants of bank withdrawals. With ecient funding markets those should beunimportant, as a bank known to be solvent should be able to obtain renancing to

    cover any of them3 (Goodfriend and King, 1988). We therefore focus on the renancing

    problem itself. This problem, we suggest, is driven by imprecise solvency information if

    informed investors. The bank may need to prove its solvency. This allows an immediate

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    6/24

    sheet, and funding problems are driven by moral hazard. In our model, liquidity needs

    originate on the liabilities side of the balance sheet (consistent with the mainstream

    view on bank fragility), and funding problems are driven by asymmetric information

    (consistent with the well-documented "ight to quality" episodes, Bernanke et al., 1996).

    There is so far scarce literature on the choice between cash in hand and borrowing

    capacity. In a recent paper, Acharya et al. (2006) note that future risky borrowing

    capacity depends on cash-ows. Therefore, when the correlation of future cash ows with

    investment opportunities is positive, rms prefer reducing risky debt ("saving borrowing

    capacity"), while if negative rms prefer accumulating cash. We oer an additional

    perspective, emphasizing that the funding capacity of cash holdings is limited to small

    liquidity needs but certain, while that of transparency (borrowing capacity) is unlimited

    (can serve large needs as well) but uncertain when ex-post communication channels can

    fail.

    Empirical literature has demonstrated that both liquidity (Paravisini, 2006) and

    transparency (access to nancial markets, Kashyap and Stein, 1990, Holod and Peek,

    2004) determine bank nancial constraints. There is also evidence that banks can be

    insuciently liquid (Gatev et al., 2004, Gonzalez-Eiras, 2003) and transparent (Mor-

    gan, 2002). While empirical literature has mostly considered liquidity and transparency

    separately, this paper brings them into the joint framework. This generates novel em-

    pirical predictions for bank liquidity risk and its management. Our model suggests

    that more liquid banks will be resilient to small shocks, while more transparent banks

    (with higher borrowing capacity) will be able to withstand large shocks as well. In re-

    sponse, banks will rely on liquidity to manage routine liquidity needs, but put emphasis

    on transparency in anticipation of large shocks. The degree to which banks can rely

    on transparency and market access (larger or listed banks, or those in more developed

    nancial systems) should be negatively correlated to their liquidity choices.

    Lastly, the paper contributes to topical regulatory debates. Is solvency enough?

    when do you need liquidity? under asymmetric information

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    7/24

    2 Setup

    2.1 Economy and Agents

    Consider a risk-neutral economy with three dates: 0; 1; 2. The economy is populated by

    multiple small investors and a single bank. Small investors are endowed with money.

    They have access to a safe storage technology (cash), or can lend to the bank, charging

    the gross interest rate of 1.

    The bank has no initial capital, but has exclusive access to a protable investment

    project. For each unit of nancing at date 0, the project returns at date 2 a high return

    X with probability 1 s, but 0 with a small probability s (s for the probability of a

    solvency problem). A bank operates under a leverage constraint (representing capital

    requirements) and cannot borrow more than 1 at date 0. It is nanced by debt and

    maximizes date 2 prot.

    2.2 Solvency Uncertainty and Liquidity Risk

    Two events happen at date 1. One is a random withdrawal of initial nancing. Another is

    a signal on the banks solvency. The two events are independent withdrawals are made

    by uninformed depositors or represent maturing term funding, and are not inuencedby the solvency signal.

    Withdrawals and liquidity need. While the project is long-term, some debt matures

    earlier and must be renanced. In reality there may be multiple renancing events

    through the course of the project, but for the analysis we collapse them into a single

    "intermediate" date 1. The amount of funds maturing at date 1 liquidity need is

    random. With probability 1=2, the liquidity need is low the bank has to repay someL < 1. With additional probability 1=2, the liquidity need is high the bank has to

    repay 1. If the bank cannot repay, it fails and goes bankrupt with no liquidation value.

    Information and liquidity risk. Because investors always oer an elastic supply of

    funds, a bank known to be solvent is able to renance itself by new borrowing and

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    8/24

    With the residual probability s + q, the signal indicates that the bank is likely to be

    insolvent. This represents a probability q that a solvent bank is pooled with insolvent

    banks. The posterior probability of insolvency in such a case, s=(s + q), is higher then

    the ex-ante probability of insolvency, s. This higher uncertainty over banks value may

    prevent external renancing. We therefore call such event a "liquidity shock". The

    informational structure of the game is illustrated on Figure 1.

    >

    We impose the following restrictions on parameter values:

    1. A bank has a positive NPV, even if it always failed in a liquidity shock.

    X >1

    1

    (s + q)

    (A1)

    This assures that a bank is always nanced at date 0.

    2. A bank in a liquidity shock has a negative posterior expected NPV at date 1.

    X 2 (A3)

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    9/24

    2.3 Liquidity Risk Management

    We consider two distinct ways in which a bank can hedge its liquidity risk.

    1. Accumulate liquidity. A bank can invest L units in the short-term asset (cash).

    This allows to fully cover small withdrawals at date 1, and therefore insure against

    small liquidity shocks that happen with probability 1=2.

    2. Adopt transparency. A bank can invest T to establish transparency. We think

    of transparency as a strategic ex-ante investment, such as credible disclosure, that

    allows a bank to better communicate solvency information to the market. In par-

    ticular, this may enable the bank to publicly conrm its solvency in the event of

    liquidity shock. We assume that, since transparency relies on ex-post informa-

    tion communication, it is eective (enables a bank to prove its solvency) with a

    probability t < 1. The eectiveness of transparency may be determined by factorsoutside a single banks control, such as the level of nancial market development

    in a country. Notice that transparency allows to insure against both small and

    large liquidity shocks.

    Both liquidity and transparency have costs. We consider two sources of liquidity

    costs. Firstly, given maximum date 0 leverage, liquidity crowds out investment in aprotable project. This reduces the return to a successful liquid bank from X to X(1

    L) + L, a loss of(X 1)L.

    Secondly, we assume that when a liquid bank fails (e.g., due to inability to renance

    a large liquidity shock or insolvency), the value of its liquidity buer is lost. It may be

    spent in costly bankruptcy proceedings, or appropriated by the bankers and transformed

    into marginal private benets (as in Myers and Rajan; we model such moral hazard inmore detail in Section 6). This makes the return to a failing liquid bank 0.

    The cost of transparency is the value of associated investment, T, which is, rstly,

    a direct expense and, secondly, crowds out investment in a protable project. Trans-

    parency reduces return to a successful bank from X to X(1 T), a loss ofT X.

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    10/24

    Liquidity and transparency are therefore costly hedges against liquidity risk. The

    decisions on whether and how to hedge are made by the bankers, and, we assume here,

    are not contractible. In the presence of leverage, this gives rise to a risk-shifting problem

    (Jensen and Meckling, 1976) that may lead to insucient hedging. This basic conict

    of interest is the principal distortion of our model.

    The timeline of the game is as follows.

    Date 0. Banks attract deposits. They divide assets between the protable project,the precautionary liquidity buer, and the investment in transparency;

    Date 1 . A bank may be hit by a liquidity shock and require renancing. A bank

    that is unable to cover withdrawals from the precautionary buer or by borrowing from

    the market, is liquidated;

    Date 2. Project returns realize; successful banks repay debts and consume prots.

    The game tree with payos depending on banks strategic choicesis shown on

    Figure 2.

    >

    3 First Best

    In this section, we derive socially optimal levels of bank liquidity and transparency.

    We show that, for low enough costs of hedging, banks can optimally combine them in

    liquidity risk management. A precautionary liquidity buer completely insures a solvent

    bank against small withdrawals in a liquidity shock. Transparency partically insures

    against against large withdrawals as well, by possibly enabling external renancing.

    3.1 Risk Management Options

    We rst derive the social payos depending on the banks liquidity management choices.

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    11/24

    For a strategy "L" when a bank is liquid but not transparent:

    SL = (1 s q=2) (X C) 1

    A solvent bank is able to survive a small liquidity shock by covering it from the pre-

    cautionary buer (probability q=2), but fails in a large liquidity shock that is above the

    buer size. The probability of a solvency shock is s; and of a large liquidity shock q=2.

    Therefore the probability of survival is 1

    s

    q=2; the return in that case is X

    C (Cis the hedging cost), and the initial investment is 1.

    For a strategy "T" when a bank is transparent but not liquid:

    ST = (1 s q(1 t)) (X C) 1

    A solvent bank is able to survive a liquidity shock (either small or large) when it is

    successful in communicating solvency information to the market, with probability t. The

    probability of a solvency shock is s, and that of a solvent bank being unable to prove its

    solvency to the market q(1 t). Therefore the probability of survival is 1 s q(1 t);

    the return in that case is X C, and the initial investment is 1.

    Lastly, for a strategy "LT", when a bank is both liquid and transparent:

    SLT = (1 s q(1 t)=2) (X 2C) 1

    A solvent bank is able to survive a small liquidity shock always by covering it from a

    precautionary buer, and a large liquidity shock with probability t when it is successful

    in communicating solvency information. The probability of a solvency shock is s, and

    of a large liquidity shock when a bank is unable to prove its solvency to the market

    q=2 (1 t). Therefore the probability of survival is 1sq(1 t)=2, the return in that

    case is X 2C (note double hedging cost), and the initial investment 1.

    3.2 Optimal Risk Management

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    12/24

    hedge (liquidity or transparency whichever more eective), or have both hedges. Note

    that the marginal benet of the second hedge is lower than that of the rst hedge. This

    is because the rst hedge is a more eective one (liquidity for t < 1=2 and transparency

    for t > 1=2), and moreover already protects a bank from a range of liquidity shocks.

    We analyze the optimal depth of hedging, as a function of the cost of hedging C, in two

    cases:

    Case 1: Liquidity more eective, t < 1=2. It is optimal that a bank:

    Has no hedge, "N", for SN

    > SL

    , corresponding to high costs of hedging:

    C >q=2

    1 s q=2 X

    Is only liquid, "L", for SL

    > SN

    and SL

    > SLT

    , corresponding to intermediate

    costs of hedging:

    qt=2

    1 s q(1=2 t) X < C SL

    , corresponding to low costs

    of hedging:

    C 1=2. Analogously, it is optimal that

    a bank:

    Has no hedge, "N", for SN

    > ST

    , corresponding to:

    C >qt

    1 s q(1 t) X

    Is only transparent, "T", for ST

    > SN

    and ST

    > SLT

    , corresponding to:

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    13/24

    having both hedges is socially optimal:

    We can formulate the rst main result.

    Proposition 1 Banks can combine liquidity and transparency in their risk manage-

    ment. There exist parameter values (1) or (2), such that it is optimal that a bank is both

    liquid and transparent.

    Proposition 1 establishes that when costs of hedging are suciently low, it is optimal

    that banks use both liquidity (to fully hedge small withdrawals) and transparency (to

    partially hedge large withdrawals) as mechanisms to mitigate liquidity risk. It implies

    that that both are important dimensions of liquidity risk management, which may need

    to be combined in a socially optimal outcome.

    In the following analysis we will focus on the case when conditions (1) or (2) are

    satised.

    4 Suboptimal Liquidity Risk Management

    We now turn to banks private liquidity and transparency choices. They may deviate

    from the social optimum due to leverage. The presence of debt creates risk-shiftingincentives, revealed as lower private incentives to hedge. The reason is that the bankers

    incur the costs of hedging as a reduced payo in the good state, but do not carry the

    burden of failure in the bad state thanks to limited liability. The losses in case of default

    are born by debtholders. We study how leverage can distort hedging incentives and bias

    banks liquidity risk management choices away from the socially optimal ones.

    In this section, we treat liquidity and transparency choices as not contractible (e.g.because depositors are small). We introduce the possibility of contracting on liquidity

    choices in the next section, which deals with scope for regulation.

    4 1 Private Payos

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    14/24

    We can now derive the private payos. They are similar to the social payos, with

    the dierence that the bankers repay initial investment only if the project succeeds. The

    payos are:

    For a strategy "N" when a bank is not liquid and not transparent:

    N = (1 s q) (X 1)

    For a strategy "L" when a bank is liquid but not transparent:

    L = (1 s q=2) (X C 1)

    For a strategy "T" when a bank is transparent but not liquid:

    T = (1

    s

    q(1

    t))

    (X

    C

    1)

    Lastly, for a strategy "LT", when a bank is both liquid and transparent:

    LT = (1 s q(1 t)=2) (X 2C 1)

    4.2 Risk Management Choices

    Since liquidity and transparency have the same costs, and the bankers benet from the

    eectiveness of hedge they adopt, the private choice between liquidity and transparency

    is not distorted by leverage. As in the social optimum, liquidity is preferred L > T

    for t < 1=2, and transparency is preferred T > L for t > 1=2.

    However, leverage aects the choice of the depth of hedging. Since the incentives to

    hedge are lower, the same depth is chosen only for lower costs of hedging. As before, we

    distinguish two cases:

    Case 1: Liquidity more eective, t < 1=2. The bank:

    Chooses not to hedge "N" for > corresponding to high costs of hedging:

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    15/24

    Chooses to be both liquid and transparent, "LT", for LT > L, corresponding

    to low costs of hedging:

    C 1=2. The bank:

    Chooses not to hedge, "N", for N > T, corresponding to:

    C >qt

    1 s q(1 t) (X 1)

    Chooses to be transparent, "T", for T > N and T > LT, corresponding to:

    q(1

    t)=21 s (X 1) < C < qt1 s q(1 t)

    (X 1) (4)

    Chooses to be both liquid and transparent, "LT", for LT > T, corresponding

    to:

    C ST

    but LT < T, is:

    q(1 t)=2

    1 s (X 1) < C L (3) as determined by low C and high t:

    C qt=2

    1 s q(1=2 t) (X 1) (9)

    Observe that there exist parameters such that this interval is nonempty:

    qt=2

    1 s q(1=2 t) (X 1) 1=2) in countries with de-

    veloped nancial markets, where banks can better rely on external renancing. There,

    ill-designed liquidity requirements may have adverse eects. Developing countries are

    likely to gain less from transparency (t < 1=2), and may have to rely on liquidity in-

    stead. (This corresponds to the evidence that banks in developed countries are typically

    highly liquid, and face more binding reserve requirements.) Therefore, there may be

    heterogeneity in optimal liquidity-transparency outcomes across countries of dierent

    nancial development, and this has to be borne in mind during possible internationalconvergence of liquidity regulation.

    6 Discussion

    6.1 Liquidity Risk and Solvency Regulation

    Solvency regulation alone cannot prevent liquidity risk. Liquidity risk and welfare losses

    in liquidity events can be signicant for any given solvency (1 s)X. This implies that,

    in the presence of asymmetric information, a second regulatory mechanism liquidity

    regulation cum transparency incentives is desirable.

    6.2 Implications for Liquidity Regulation

    Incorrect liquidity requirements can compromise banks transparency choices. There-

    fore, it is important that liquidity regulation is thoroughly designed. Sole reliance on

    stock liquidity is likely suboptimal, particularly when market access plays a large role

    in managing liquidity risks. Then, an additional emphasis on transparency would be

    benecial.

    Our results are consistent with the evidence of dierent stock liquidity and liquidity

    regulation across countries with varying nancial development. Bennet and Peristiani

    (2002) for the US and Chaplin et al. (2000) for the UK, show that liquidity regulation is

    not binding in advanced market economies (where banks have superior market access).

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    19/24

    6.4 Liquidity shocks

    Can be positive (e.g. Barclays cash for ABN-AMRO take-over)

    Buer: all tradeable (or collateralizeable) assets

    6.5 Other eects of liquidity

    Liquidity bias

    Liquidity as signalling

    Liquidity to hide losses

    6.6 Empirical Implications

    To add

    7 Conclusion

    This paper studied the roles of liquidity and transparency in bank risk management. Liq-

    uidity risk was modelled as solvency uncertainty at the renancing stage. We showed

    that both liquidity and transparency are important hedges, and moreover can be com-

    bined in risk management. However, banks private choices can be distorted by leverage,

    and policy response is complicated by multi-tasking. Reserve requirements may com-

    promise banks transparency incentives, and target the lesser distortion altogether. The

    paper has identied a number of empirical implications.

    A Proofs

    Lemma 1 Proof. For t < 1=2 we have to show that

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    20/24

    Indeed, in the nominator, X 1 < (1 t)X since X > 2 and (1 t) > 1=2; and in the

    denominator, 1 s q(1 t) < 1 s.

    References

    [1] Acharya, Viral V., Heitor Almeida and Murillo Campello (2006) "Is Cash Negative

    Debt? A Hedging Perspective on Corporate Financial Policies", London Business

    School IFA Working Paper Series

    [2] Admati, Anat, and Paul Peiderer (2000) "Forcing Firms to Talk: Financial Dis-

    closure Regulation and Externalities", Review of Financial Studies 13(3): 479-519

    [3] Bennet, Paul and Stavros Peristiani (2002) "Are US Reserve Requirements still

    Binding?", FRBNY Economic Policy Review 8(1)

    [4] Bernanke, Ben, Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist (1996) "The Financial Acceler-

    ator and the Flight to Quality", Review of Economics & Statistics 78(1): 1-15

    [5] Boot, Arnoud, and Anjan Thakor (2001) ""The Many Faces of Information Disclo-

    sure", Review of Financial Studies, 14(4): 1021-1057

    [6] Calomiris, Charles W. (1999) "Building an Incentive Compatible Safety Net", Jour-nal of Banking and Finance, 23: 1499-1519

    [7] Chaplin, Graeme, Alison Emblow and Ian Michael, 2000, "Banking System Liquid-

    ity: Developments and Issues", Financial Stability Review, Dec: 93-112

    [8] Chari, V.V. and R. Jagannathan (1988), Banking Panics, Information, and Ratio-

    nal Expectations Equilibrium, Journal of Finance 43: 749-61.

    [9] Diamond, Douglas W., Philip H. Dybvig, 1983, "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance,

    and Liquidity", Journal of Political Economy 91(3): 401-419

    [10] Flannery, Mark J., Simon H Kwam, M. Nimalendran (2004) Market Evidence on

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    21/24

    [13] Glaeser, Edward L. and Andrei Shleifer (2001) "A Reason for Quantity Regulation",

    American Economic Review 91(2), : 431-435.

    [14] Grin, Paul K. and Samoa Wallach (1991) "Latin American Lending by Major

    U.S. Banks: The Eects of Disclosures about Nonaccrual Loans and Loan Loss

    Provisions", Accounting Review, 86(4): 830-846

    [15] Gonzalez-Eiras, Martin (2004) "Banks Liquidity Demand in the Presence of a

    Lender of Last Resort". working paper Universidad de San Andres, Buenos Aires

    [16] Goodfriend, Marvin and Robert G. King, 1998, "Financial Deregulation, Mone-

    tary Policy, and Central Banking", Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic

    Review, May/June: 3-22

    [17] Holmstrom, Bengt and Jean Tirole (1998) "Private and Public Supply of Liquidity",

    Journal of Political Economy 106(1): 1-40

    [18] Holod, Dmytro and Joe Peek (2005) "Asymmetric Information and Liquidity Con-

    straints: A New Test", FDIC Center for Financial Research Working Paper No.

    2005-02

    [19] Jensen, Michael C. and William Meckling (1976) "Theory of the Firm: Manager-

    ial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure", Journal of Financial Eco-

    nomics

    [20] Kashyap, Anyl K. and Jeremy C. Stein (2000), "What do a Million Observations

    on Banks Say about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?" American Economic

    Review, 90(3): 407-28.

    [21] Morgan, Donald P. (2002), Rating Banks: Risks and Uncertainty in an Opaque

    Industry", American Economic Review 92: 874-88.

    [22] Myers, Stewart C. and Raghuram G. Rajan (1998) "The Paradox of Liquidity",

    Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3): 733-771

    [23] P i i i D i l (2006) "L l B k Fi i l C t i t d Fi A t

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    22/24

    [26] Perotti, Enrico C. and Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden (2003) "Strategic Transparency

    and Informed Trading: Will Globalization Force Convergence of Corporate Gover-

    nance? ", Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38, (1): 61-85.

    [27] Rajan, Raghuram G. and Douglas W. Diamond (2001) "Liquidity Risk, Liquid-

    ity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking" Journal of Political

    Economy 109 (2): 287-327

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    23/24

    Figure 1: Information structure

    1sq sq

    InsolventSolvent 1s

    Positive signal, known solvent

    Solvent,

    but unable

    to refinance

    Negative signal,pooled together

    s

  • 8/6/2019 Liquidity and Transparency in Bank Risk Managment

    24/24

    EX-ANTE

    HEDGING

    DECISIONS

    BANK

    probability q

    UNKNOWN SOLVENT=>LIQUIDITY SHOCK

    probability sINSOLVENT

    probability 1-s-qKNOWN SOLVENT

    HIGH LIQUIDITY NEED

    (withdrawals 1)

    LOW LIQUIDITY NEED

    (withdrawalsL