Jurnal Human Capital Theory

download Jurnal Human Capital Theory

of 35

Transcript of Jurnal Human Capital Theory

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    1/35

    Determinants of salary growth in Shenzhen, China: An analysis of formaleducation, on-the-job training, and adult education with a three-level model

    Jin Xiao

    Faculty of Education

    the Chinese University of Hong Kong, Hong KongSha Tin, N.T. Hong Kong Special Administration Region, China

    Email: [email protected]

    Received 19 March 1999; Accepted 6 June 2001

    Abstract

    Using 1996 surveyed data of 1,023 employees in Shenzhen, China, this study estimated the effects of threeforms of human capital on employee salary, namely formal education, on-the-job training provided byemployers, and adult education pursued by employees. Using a hierarchical linear model, the analysis

    estimated employee monthly salary growth over a maximum of six years due to (a) such temporal factors aswork experience and improved performance, (b) individual-level characteristics, and (c) firm-levelcharacteristics. This study found that (a) pre-work formal education was positively associated with salaryonly at hiring, (b) employees experience in changing production technology as well as on-the-job trainingwere positively associated with salary increases through improved technical proficiency, formal educationwas not; (c) manufacturing firms introduced more new production technology than the service sector andprovided more on-the-job training, thus improving workers performance and increasing their salary.

    JEL classification: [C00, I20, J31]

    Keywords: Salary growth, Educational economics, Human capital, Economic development, Productivity

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    2/35

    1

    Determinants of salary growth in Shenzhen, China: An analysis of formaleducation, on-the-job training, and adult education with a three-level model

    1. Introduction

    Human capital theory suggests that education or training raises the productivity of workers by

    imparting useful knowledge and skills, hence raising workers future income by increasing their lifetime

    earnings (Becker, 1964). Becker (1964) and Mincer (1974) provide an explanation that links investment in

    training with workers wages. In particular, their theory draws a crucial distinction between general

    education and firm-specific training. Over the past thirty years or so, hundreds of studies have been

    conducted to estimate rates of return to education (RORE); most such studies show that formal schooling is

    a crucial factor in explaining variations of salary and wages in well developed countries (Cohn & Addison,

    1998). Comparative studies have been conducted in some less developed countries, focusing on investment

    in formal education (Psacharopoulos, 1985, 1994).

    While formal education has expanded rapidly in many countries, a large portion of human capital

    accumulation in the forms of on-the-job training and other modes for working adults actually take place

    both inside and outside the workplace. Adult education development in developed countries in recent years

    has focused on a strengthening of vocational training to meet the needs of skill development across all

    occupational strata in the global economy (Belanger & Tuijnman, 1997). Studies in some developing

    countries find that a mix of education and training is available for skill acquisition and there are multiple

    paths to skill development for a given occupation (Middleton, Ziderman, & Adams, 1993; Ziderman and

    Horn, 1995. A study of education provision in Shenzhen, China shows that both firm-provided on-the-job

    training and adult education financed by employees offer substantial means to develop vocational/technical

    skills (Xiao & Tsang, 1994), and provided about 2.07 million head counts of education and training to theworkforce of 2.5 million during the period of 1980-1996 (Xiao, 1998a:13). Given that education and

    training programs for working adults have experienced significant expansion, it is important that they be

    included in estimations of returns to education and training. This paper attempts to estimate the effects of

    formal education, on-the-job training, and adult education both on employees performance and salary

    growth with data from a survey conducted in Shenzhen in 1996 (Xiao & Tsang, 1999).

    This study was conducted in the municipality of Shenzhen, China, which is situated on the border

    with Hong Kong. Prior to 1980, Shenzhen was a small, poor county. The countys population of 0.3

    million was mainly engaged in farming and fishing. In 1980, the State Council, China, inaugurated the

    Shenzhen Special Economic Zone, which was designed as a prototype for economic development. The

    policies of reform and opening to the outside world were implemented to experiment market economy and

    help boost the Chinese economy. Over the last two decades, Shenzhen has developed into a large

    industrialized area with an emerging tertiary sector. Its economic growth is rapid. For example, in 1980,

    Shenzhens per-capita real GDP (in 1978 prices) was RMB 719.8, less than one-third that of Shanghai

    (RMB 2,360.3). In 1994, Shenzhens per-capita real GDP reached RMB 4,032, which exceeded that of

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    3/35

    2

    Shanghai by RMB 1,410, ranking first in China ever since (Xiao, 1998a).

    Economic reforms brought substantial change to the economic system. In addition to the two

    major forms of ownership in a planned economy, namely state-owned and collective firms, there have

    emerged other forms of ownership. They include cooperatives and firms with sole-investment from and

    joint ventures with firms in Hong Kong, Macau, and Taiwan, other countries, a large number of localprivate firms and corporate firms. These firms have created a competitive market and they make businesses

    in both domestic and international markets. In the period of 1980 and 1996, these firms had provided about

    2.3 million new jobs. These new occupations required that employees have new knowledge, skills, and

    attitudes/values. Employees had to learn to treat their clients as kings in order to win market share; time

    became as valuable as gold and efficiency was vital for a firms survival. Advanced production technology

    was imported to replace outdated hand-operated equipment.

    The local workforce was unable to meet the human-capital demands of the Shenzhen economy in

    the early 1980s. In addition to expanding its formal education system, Shenzhen has cultivated and

    nurtured the development of workplace training and adult education over time. Two types of institutions

    provide education and training to working adults (Xiao & Tsang, 1994). First, employee-oriented adult

    education/training centers, set up and financed by large firms, provide training to their own employees.

    Training is job-related, corresponding to the productivity requirements of the firm. The second type of

    training is run by community organizations that provide education and training to adults in the local

    community. This community-oriented education/training provide job-related practical skills programs,

    vocational/technical certificate programs and credential programs. Participants usually voluntarily attend

    the adult course and pay for the courses themselves, though some may receive subsidies from their firms.

    Xiao and Tsang (1999) found that among the 4,002 sampled employees, 59 percent received on-the-job

    training, and 31.1 percent attended adult education/training programs. This study distinguished three types

    of education and training programs: pre-job formal education, firm-based on-the-job training (OJT)

    provided by employers, and self-financed adult education/training (AET) outside the firm.

    By using a three-level hierarchical linear growth model, this study incorporates both individual and

    firm-level factors to estimate their impact on salary growth over time. The remainder of this paper is

    divided into five sections. The next section provides a framework to interpret the rising demand for job-

    related training and adult education in the fast growing economy of Shenzhen. Followed is a discussion on

    conceptualized issues with a three-level analytic method. The fourth presents the survey and data sets. The

    fifth section examines empirical results. Finally, the concluding section presents a discussion on findingsand their implication in development policy.

    2. A framework for human capital development in the workplace

    While Becker (1964) suggests that education or training raise the productivity of workers by imparting

    useful knowledge and skills, others provide different explanations for how education is related to worker

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    4/35

    3

    productivity. One is based on the argument that the higher earnings of educated workers simply reflect their

    superior ability acquired during the process of education, rather than through skills and knowledge. Spence

    (1973) argues that education is used as a market signal to indicate the potential productivity of workers.

    Thurow (1975) maintains that productivity is largely characteristic of jobs rather than of workers;

    employers use education credentials to select workers because better-educated workers can be trained forspecific jobs more quickly and at a lower cost than their less-educated peers. Schultz (1975) suggests that

    education enhance an individuals ability to successfully deal with disequilibria in changing economic

    conditions. Such ability includes that of perceiving a given disequilibrium, analyzing information, and

    reallocating resources to act. Another argument is based on the conditions of production. For instance,

    Levin (1987) argues that the organization of production, such as the extent of discretion, participation in

    decision-making, responsibility sharing, and information available to employees, all affect employees

    utilization of their ability to act. Levin and Kelley (1994) suggest that education can improve productivity

    only if complementary inputs exit, which include training, contract terms, and management practices; they

    point out that economists and other social scientists have overestimated the payoffs resulted from increased

    formal education while they have ignored the complementary inputs and conditions. Recently, Hall and

    Jones (1999) maintain that differences in capital accumulation, productivity, and therefore output per

    worker are fundamentally related to differences in social infrastructure across countries. Such social

    infrastructure includes the institutions and government policies that determine the economic environment,

    within which individuals accumulate skills and firms accumulate capital and produce output. Lack of these

    conditions would cause loss in production. Tsang (1987) found that mismatch of workers characteristics

    such as over-education caused dissatisfaction among workers and this was associated with a loss of over 8%

    in an output for the $57 billion dominant U.S. telecommunication industry AT & T in 1981.

    In this article, I offer an interpretation for the large demand of learning in a workplace in a modern,

    fast changing economic state of Shenzhen, China. I argue that job-related training provided to working

    adults is a strategy to re-equilibrate in the changing economy. The economic reform, and new technologies

    have resulted in qualitative economic changes, which aim to boost economic development in Shenzhen.

    Employees, nested in a given production organization, face such changes together with their firms; both

    firms and employees are involved in an equilibrating process to increase productivity.

    As technological innovations and economic reforms have been continuously adopted in the

    workplace in order to speed up growth, the organization of production, and management practices of the

    firm that formerly worked well in a planned economy are now obsolete. Such qualitative changes createdisequilibrium, causing a technical discrepancy between the firms new investments and their employees

    competence; employees are unable to perform to meet the new demand. They may have accumulated

    significant knowledge, skills, and attitudes/values (KSA) through both formal schooling and work

    experience, but as change accelerated, KSA gained in previous learning gradually became also largely

    obsolete.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    5/35

    4

    In a market-oriented economy, the competitiveness of a firm depends on its stock of both physical

    and human capitals as well as the uniqueness of management practices that can bring the firms capacity

    into full play. In response, OJT provided by employers has thus become a firm strategy to develop human

    capital in order to adapt to changes in the workplace. OJT, while upgrading job skills of employees, also

    develops shared values and ways of working together to strengthen a firms unique competitiveness in atransforming economy. Therefore, in-firm training, as opposed to formal education, as a strategy to develop

    human capital can over time compensate for competence gaps of the internal market and the increasingly

    complex technological demands of the workplace. By receiving OJT, the competence of employees is to be

    re-established.

    In Shenzhen, individual employees are free to change jobs whenever they find better opportunities

    to realized their personal potentials. If their job performance is not up to an expected level over time,

    employees may also be dismissed. Employees are cognizant of both changes in the firm and the increased

    discrepancy in their KSA and of opportunities outside the firm. They seek learning to close the gap, either

    to remain competent in their current jobs, or to change to new jobs. When employer-provided training does

    not fulfill the employees personal expectations, external open-market AET becomes an option. By taking

    AET, employees can close up the gap between competence and expectations.

    Employees look to OJT or AET to enable them to disengage from obsolete sets of KSA and to

    regain job competence. Given that firms constitute an economic setting where human capital is utilized,

    training and education related to the job setting for employees develop unique sets of KSA that can engage

    them in organized production. Therefore it is argued that in a fast-changing economic context, education

    and training programs related to jobs are a means to readjust to the changing workplace and improve

    productivity.

    3. Measuring salary growth with a three-level model

    An estimation of human capital effects is complicated by the existence of different types of human

    capital (Chapman, 1993:69-72). Training can be taken in the pre-work form of formal education.

    Individuals can also train themselves through learning-by-doing in their jobs. The Mincerian method has

    been commonly used to estimate RORE to formal education in the earning function equation. It might

    measure the second type of human capital by using job experience, as proxied by years of working.

    However, various vocational adult education and training have been widely used in both OECD countriesand other less developed countries to develop human capital. Recently Cohn and Addison (1998)

    conducted a comprehensive review of the literature on returns to both formal schooling and various

    vocational training programs for youth and adults. Regarding the former, they concluded that RORE is

    substantial across levels of schooling. Regarding the latter, they found that returns to training investment

    are mixed. Of course, education and training take place in more heterogeneous forms, namely, provided by

    different agencies to different age and occupations groups or delivered in various modes and settings. In

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    6/35

    5

    addition, the sample selection problems present greater ambiguity for an empirical investigation of training

    for adults than for formal education. It is unclear to what extent ability factors endogenous, determined by

    training and experience, and to what extent they are exogenous to other influences such as the market

    (Chapman, 1993:71-72). To date, most studies have used the three conventional methods to estimate

    returns of investment in education and training, namely short-cut methods, internal RORE or the Mincerianapproach (see Cohn & Addison, 1998; Psacharopoulos and Woodhall, 1985). By focusing on the end result

    of earnings, few methods make allowances for the endogeneity of training decisions in a workplace setting.1

    In order to understand the occurrence and benefits of training, it is interesting to combine an

    analysis of the decisions of employers and employees regarding various education and training programs

    with the presence of influences of workplace characteristics within a single study. Such a study draws on

    recent advances in multilevel statistical theory by Bryk & Raudenbush (1992) and attempts to measure

    changes in earnings due to the effects of different types of education and training.

    Since employees are not randomly assigned to firms, the task of measuring changes in earnings

    becomes challenging. For instance, hirings and earnings increase over time are firm decisions affected by

    the firms characteristics, as well as by individual characteristics pre-embodied and carried to the firm (e.g.,

    formal schooling, sex, age, previous work experience, etc.) or developed while working (e.g., improved job

    skills and then performance through OJT). An aggregation bias can occur when a variable takes on

    different meanings, and therefore it may have a different effect at a different level of analysis. For example,

    receiving OJT may have an impact on ones job skills at the individual level, which can be measured by

    performance assessment and increased earning increase. At the firm level, providing OJT is a proxy

    measure of a firms capacity and normative management practices. The recent statistics advancement in

    hierarchical linear models (HLM) resolves this problem by facilitating a decomposition of any observed

    relationship between variables into different level components (Bryk & Raudenbush, 1992). Again, within

    the firm, employees may develop dependence among themselves while working in the same normative

    environment. HLM incorporates a unique random effect for each organization unit and the variability in

    these random effects is taken into account to estimate standard errors. HLM also resolves the problem of

    heterogeneity of regression by estimating a separate set of regression coefficients for each organizational

    unit and by then modeling variations among firms in their sets of coefficients. The other advantage of HLM

    is that it accommodates multiple-time-point observations of an individual over time.

    The analysis employs a three-level growth model (Bryk & Raudenbush, 1992:130-154, 185-196),

    which offers an integrated approach for studying determinants of salary growth in an organized structureand presents both individual and firm predictors of salary growth from a multiple-time-point design. The

    analysis consists models at three levels: (a) salary observations at three time points, (b) employee factors,

    and (c) firm factors. At Level-1 (L1), the within-individual level, such variables as employee salary growth

    within a span of a maximum of six years at three observations and gains in ones technical proficiency level

    at corresponding observation time points are examined. At Level-2 (L2), the individual level, such

    variables as sex, age, formal schooling, OJT and AET, and experience of changes in the firm are

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    7/35

    6

    considered. At Level-3 (L3), such firm characteristics as firm size, location, ownership, industrial sector

    and firms capacity to provide OJT are included in the analysis.

    It is then assumed that Ytij, the observed log salary at time tfor employee i, is a function of a

    systematic growth curve plus random error. The systematic growth over time is represented as a polynomial

    of degree P. Then, the L1 Model is:

    Ytij = 0ij + 1ij (OBSERVATION) tij + 2ij (OBSERVATION2) tij + 3ij (OBSERVATION

    3) tij + 4ij(PERF

    GAIN)tij + etij (1)

    For i = 1,., 1,023 employees in firmj (j =1, 71), where

    Ytij is the outcome variable of log monthly salary at time tfor employee i in

    firmj; the total tconsists of three observations, the first in the initial working year, the second in the

    third year, and the third in 1996 (see Table 1);

    0ijis the mean log salary of employeeij at the second observation, which is coded as 0 (see discussion on

    data coding in the next section);

    1ij is the parameter of mean annual salary growth rate for employee ij;

    2ij is the parameter of the accelerated rate of salary growth based on a squared term;

    3ij is the parameter of the accelerated rate of salary growth based on a cubic term;

    4ij is the parameter of a gain in employees technical proficiency level;

    etii is the error which is independent, with a mean of zero and normally distributed with

    a common variance 2. It is assumed that each etij is independently and normally distributed with a mean of

    zero and constant variance,

    2

    .Equation 1 is the assumption that the growth parameters vary across employees. At L2, the

    parameters of L1 (Equation 1) become outcomes variables and the L2 model represents the growth

    variation due to individual factors as:

    Q p

    pij = p 0j + pqj Xqij + rpij (2)q=1

    p0j is the intercept term for firmj in modeling the employee effect pij;

    Xqij is a measured characteristic of the individual background for employee i in

    firmj (e.g., sex, formal education, OJT, or AET, etc.).

    pqjrepresents the effect ofXqij on thepth growth parameter; and

    pij is a random effect with a mean of zero. The set ofP + 1 random effects for employee

    i are assumed multivariate normally distributed with full covariance matrix, T, dimensioned (P +

    1) x (P + 1).

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    8/35

    7

    At L3, a similar modeling process is repeated for firm factors. Each L2 outcome (i.e., each pqj

    coefficient) may be predicted by some firm-level characteristics as,

    Spqpqj = pq0 + pqs Wsj + upqj (3)

    s = 1

    wherepq0 is the intercept term in the firm-level model for pqj;

    Wsj is a firm characteristic used as a predictor for the firm effect on pqj (note that each pq may have a

    unique set of the L3 predictor, Wsj s = 1, , Spq);

    pqs is the corresponding L3 coefficient that represents the direction and strength of association between

    firm characteristic Wsj and pqj ; and

    upqj is a L3 random effect that represents the deviation of firmjs coefficient, pej, from its predicted value

    based on a firm-level model.

    Note that for each form there are Pp = 0 (Q + 1) equations in the L3 model. The residuals from

    these equations are assumed multivariate normally distributed. Each is assumed to have a mean of zero,

    some variance, and covariance among all pairs of elements.

    4. The survey and data set

    In order to investigate the extent of OJT and AET provided to working adults and their effects,

    Xiao and Tsang (1999) conducted a reverse tracer study survey in 1996. The reverse tracer technique

    focuses on the analysis of employees who are currently employed in certain occupations and traces back the

    education and training histories pursued by employees (Ziderman & Horn, 1995). The reverse tracer studyin Shenzhen began with the current job destinations and sought to identify each major alternative education

    and training route pursued by employees to reach the current destination in the previous five years.

    The 1996 survey questionnaire consisted of five groups of questions on: (a) an employees pre-job

    formal education, (b) technological changes experienced in the workplace, (c) OJT provided by firms to

    employees; (d) AET courses that an employee attended outside the firm; and (e) an employees position

    technical proficiency level and salary at three time points over six years. This questionnaire was

    administrated to a stratified random sample of 6,200 employees, slightly less than one percent of the

    registered workforce in Shenzhen.2 The sample included (a) firms in both manufacturing and service

    sector; (b) firms of eight types of ownership;3 (c) firms of different sizes, and (d) one or two major

    production lines in the firms, which included all the personnel from managers, clerk, technicians to front

    workers.

    In both manufacturing and service sectors, three large-size firms (see Table 1 for definition), two

    medium-size firms and one to two small-size firms in each of the 8 types of ownership were to be sampled

    (96 firms). The Yearbook of Registered Firms (Shenzhen AE, 1996) in these classifications was obtained

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    9/35

    8

    from the Association for Shenzhen Enterprises. Representatives of industrial and service firms were

    randomly selected. Managing directors and personnel offices were contacted about ownership, size, and

    acceptance of the study in their firms. Replacement was made with another randomly selected firm when

    either of the condition was not agreed. After deleting some types, which did not exist (large private service

    and manufacturing, for instance), finally 76 firms were selected and agreed to participate in the study. Thesurvey was conducted during later 1996. Information was collected from 4,002 workers in these 76 firms,

    corresponding to a 65% response rate. Among the returned questionnaires, it is found that the state-owned

    firms were under-represented while corporation firms were over-sampled due to that their production lines

    were big. Weights were then applied to analysis in order to arrived at estimation for a representative sample

    of the overall workforce.

    As the first work year in the current firm for each employees varied from 1980 to 1996, this study

    selected a sub-sample of 1,023 employees who were hired by their current firm in 1990, 1991, 1992, or

    1993.4 One advantage of HLM is that it allows observation time points and interval lengths to vary,

    especially those associated with growth and change. With employees hired within a short span of four years

    in the beginning of the third economic development stage in Shenzhen5 and observations over a time span

    of a minimum of four years and maximum of six years, biases in growth rates should be reduced to a

    minimum. A sub-sample with all newly employed workers allows us to examine the effects of formal

    education, OJT, and AET on performance improvement and salary growth in the first few years of work.

    Table 1 presents descriptions of temporal variables that reflect individual change over time for the

    L1 model. The sub-sample of 66 firms, with an average of 15.5 employees in each, had three observations

    of salary and gain in technical proficiency level: for the first work year, the end of the third year, and the

    end of 1996 for each employee.6

    OBSERVATIONS. OBSERVATIONS are the number of years that elapsed from the initial

    recruiting year to the time when salary and performance data were reported (see Table 1). To avoid

    collinearity in the analysis that occurred with other temporal variables in the estimation, the secondary

    observation is coded as 0, and the first occasion is coded in negative number of years that elapsed from the

    initial to the second occasion. The third occasion is coded in the number of years that elapsed from the

    second to the third occasion.

    SALARY. SALARY refers to actual monthly salary in 1996 price. Shenzhen was the first city in

    China to restructure salaries to suit the market-oriented economy in 1985 (Shenzhen ESRC, 1989). Salary

    consists of three components: basic salary, seniority, and position-based salary. Basic salary is mostly fixedat RMB 75 (1985 price) for all managerial /professionals, supporting staff, as well as workers (Shenzhen

    Government, 1989: 341-366). Seniority is rewarded at about RMB 10.5 for every additional year of work.

    Position-based salary can correspond to at least 60 percent of the total monthly payment. It consists of two

    categories, performance-based and profitability-based. Performance-based salary relates to the annual

    assessment of performance of task accomplishment, including technical skills, quality, quota, attendance,

    and security. Salary can be reduced if ones job tasks are not accomplished. The profitability-based salary

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    10/35

    9

    can be zero if the firm fails to generate profits, there is no ceiling because it is based on firm profitability.

    Fast economic growth in Shenzhen led to rapid profitability-based salary increases. The Shenzhen

    Statistical Bureau has created salary index to indicate the rate of salary increase not due to personnel factors

    (e.g., performance improvement, promotion, etc.), but due to increases in bonuses and overall firm profits.

    Therefore, SALARY in this study is transformed into actual salaries in 1996 price, with both a price indexand salary index control (Shenzhen Statistical and Information Yearbook Committee, 1997:335) and log

    SALARY is used in the analysis.

    (Insert Table 1 about here)

    PERF GAIN. PERF GAIN refers to a gain in job positions technical proficiency level from the

    previous observation time point, which is a reference for performance-based salary. In China, there are

    three payroll categories: cadre/managerial/professional staff, supporting staff, and workers. Among the

    three categories, managerial/professional ranks were the most prestigious followed by supporting staff and

    the workers. Firms in Shenzhen, use three levels to define ones technical proficiency: entry, intermediate,

    and senior for each category. Shenzhen has adopted performance assessments to determine ones

    performance, which are carried out annually. The assessment includes the technical skills that the employee

    could perform, quality of work accomplished (e.g., scrap rates), quota accomplished, ability to deal with

    diverse tasks, attendance, security records, technical and innovative suggestions made during a year, attitude

    and co-operativeness.7 The level of ones technical proficiency is an official record of the assessment

    results and is reflected in performance-based salary.

    In this study, PERF GAIN for the initial observation at the hiring trial point is coded as zero. A

    gain during the first two observation points is coded as 1, two gains codes as 2, etc., for the second

    observation point. For the third observation point, any gains during the second interval of observations are

    added to values at the second observation point. An outstanding performance may give one a promotion

    from worker category to staff, or from staff to managerial/professional category. In such case, 4 is coded as

    the former across-category promotion occurs, and 5 is coded as the latter across-category promotion occurs.

    Table 2 contains individual-level variables. Shenzhen is a newly industrialized. Generally, female

    employees outnumber male employees, and the workforce is very young.8 EXPERIENCE refers to whether

    an employee had any work experience prior to work in the current firm. POSITION refers to the current

    job position. Front-line workers are those employees who work on the floor. They can be either unskilledor skilled workers. Supporting staff includes clerical personnel and salespersons. Managerial/professionals

    staff refers to managers, senior supervisors, engineers, and senior technicians.

    (Insert Table 2 about here)

    CHANGE. CHAGNE refers to the amount of change employees experienced on the job. In the

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    11/35

    10

    survey, employees were asked if they had experienced changes of three kinds: the introduction of new

    production technology, production of a new product, and new requirements for increased job skills. If they

    experienced a single kind, they were coded 1; two kinds were coded 2; and three kinds of changes on the

    job were coded 3.

    EDUCATION. EDUCATION refers to formal schooling before the first job. PRE-JOBTRAINING refers to short-term vocational/technical training before applying for the first job. ADULT

    EDUCATIN refers to AET attended by employees at a local community-oriented center. TRAINING is a

    dummy variable with 1 referring to having received OJT and 0 to no. Many employees had OJT more than

    once. TRAINING AMOUNT ranks the amount of OJT received in the firm, with 0 for having received no

    OJT, 1 for one session, and 6 for six sessions.

    (Insert Table 3 about here)

    Table 3 presents firm-level variables. SECTOR, and LOCATION are dummy variables. Firm

    SIZE is coded in an ordered manner, with small firms coded as 0, medium as 1, and large as 2.

    OWNERSHIP refers to types of investment owners. Local private and collective firms, coded as 0, state-

    owned and newly created corporate firms, mostly coming from the state-owned sector, are coded as 1.

    Those firms with sole-investment from Hong Kong, Macau, and Taiwan, and other countries, or joint-

    ventures with firms from outside the PRC, are coded as 2. The first two types are the least formal in terms

    of personnel and production management. The second two types have formal management, and the last two

    types are most formal in management, in terms of recruitment, selection for training, performance

    assessment, cost-analysis, and production control. This ranking accords with per employee productivity

    (see Xiao, 1996b).9 TRAINING EXTENT is an aggregated proxy variable made from the overall OJT that

    employees received in the firm. It is coded as 0 if less than one-third of the employees in a firm received

    OJT, 1 if between one- and two-thirds had received OJT, and 2 if over two-thirds received OJT in the job.

    5. Empirical results

    The results are presented in three groups. An analysis of salary growth over time as a baseline

    model is conducted first, in which variance is left randomly in the L2 model and L3 model. Thereafter,

    follows an explanatory model that allows for an estimation of the separate effects of employee characteristicvariables on employee initial salary, the annual salary increase rate, and PERF GAIN. Finally, the L3

    model estimates the explanatory effects of the firms characteristics variables to define employee

    performance in the firm context.

    5.1 Unconditional model

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    12/35

    11

    Employees mature in performance and their salaries tend to increase over time. The L1 model (see

    Equation 1) estimates salary growth of an employee over time. There are no predictions in the L2 and L3

    models on salary growth. This provides useful empirical evidence to determine a proper specification of the

    individual growth equation and baseline statistics for evaluating the effects of subsequent the L2 and L3

    models later (Bryk & Raudenbush, 1992:135). The unconditional models can partition variability in theindividual growth parameters into L2 and L3 components:

    Level-2 Model,

    0ij= 00j + r0ij (2.0a)

    1ij= 10j + r1ij (2.1a)

    2ij= 20j (2.2a)

    3ij= 30j (2.3a)

    4ij= 40j (2.4a)

    and the Level-3 Model,

    00j = 000 + u00j (3.00a)

    10j = 100 + u10j (3.10a)

    20j = 200 (3.20a)

    30j = 300 (3.30a)

    40j = 400 + u40j (3.40a)

    Where pij become the outcome variables in the L2 Model, and pqj become the outcome variables in L3

    Model. 00j is the mean salary within firmj at the initial occasion while 000is the grand mean salary of

    1,023 employees in 66 firms at the initial observation occasion. 10j is the mean annual growth rate of

    salary within firmj, while 100is the grand mean growth rate for all employees; and 40j is the mean rate of

    performance increase within firmj, while 400is the grand mean rate of performance gain among 1,023

    employees. 20 and 40 are the mean accelerated rates of salary increase within firm j in squared and cubic

    terms respectively; and 200 and 400 are the grand mean accelerating rates in squared and cubic terms

    respectively.

    Because there are only three occasions in the observations, variance at the individual level can

    only allow t-1 random variance for freedom in calculation, in this case, two Level-2 random effects, r0ij and

    r1ij with variances 00j and 11j, respectively, and with a covariance of01j. Level-2 random effects represent

    the deviation of employee ijs coefficients (pij

    ) from its predicted value based on the individual level

    model. There are three random effects, 00j , 10j,and 20j in the L3 model, which represent the deviation of

    firm,js coefficients (pqj) from its predicted value based on the firm-level model.

    (Insert table 4 about here)

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    13/35

    12

    Table 4 presents the results of salary growth with unconditional modes at Level-2 and Level-3.

    The fixed effects, as presented in the top panel, indicate a strong positive salary growth trajectory. The

    estimated grand mean SALARY for 0 parameter in the linear growth model represents the true average

    salary of the employee at the second time point, (e.g., the third year in the current firm, which is coded as 0)

    ^000is ln 6.89 (about RMB 979.54; t= 246.998 and p =0.000), significantly different from that at the initial

    and third observation time points and therefore, the true initial salaries are 000 minus three times of100 .10

    Over time, SALARY appears as an positive growing trend. The average annual SALARY increase was

    estimated a 14.3 percent (i.e., 100 ), with another increase of 7.7 percent if an employee had a gain in ones

    technical proficiency level (i.e., 400). The estimate of the growth rate in a cubic acceleration

    (300 < 0) indicates that salary growth is in a nonlinear function over times. The growth of SALARY over

    time is a parabola in a concave downward direction.

    Estimates for the random effects testing appear in the lower panel of the table, which separate the

    variance in employee initial salary and mean growth rate into within-firm and between-firm components.

    Residual variance at the growth level (2) is .0700. The residual variance among employees, , is .12072

    (R 0ij) for average initial salary and .00533 (R1ij) for annual growth slope. The residual variance between

    firms, is .03095 (U00j) for average initial salary, 0.00163 (U10j) for annual growth, and .00321 (U40j) for

    FERF GAIN. The 2statistics accompanying these variances indicate that there is significant variation

    among employees within firms in initial salary and annual growth (0ij, and 1ij). There is also significant

    variation between firms in terms of mean initial salary, annual salary increase, and gain in proficiency level

    (i.e., 00j, 10j and 40j). Analysis at L2 should explain these variances.

    Table 4 shows that the reliability for the initial salary intercept is .760, based on an average of 15.5

    employees in each firm, and .451 for the annual salary increase slope, based on the three temporal

    observations. Due to the small number of observations, the annual salary increase appears to be less

    reliable, but it is still fairly acceptable. The reliability of the initial salary intercept (i.e., .580) and the

    annual increase rate intercept (i.e.,0.466) at the firm level are acceptable; but the reliability of the

    performance improvement intercept (i.e., .351) seems a bit low with only three observations, but still can be

    considered to be fair.11

    5.2 Conditional L2 model with individual characteristics as predictors

    Now, the L1 model being the same as in Equation 1, the parameters in L1 model become outcome

    variables in the L2 Model, and their variability will be predicted by the employee characteristic variables.

    The specific L2 model is:

    0ij= 00j + 01j(SEX)ij + 02j (EDUCATION)ij + 03j(POSITION)ij

    + 04j (EXPERIENCE)ij + 05j(PRE-JOB TRAINING)ij + r0ij (2.0b)

    1ij= 10j + 11j(AGE)ij + 12j(EDUCATION)ij + 13j(POSTION)ij

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    14/35

    13

    + 14j (ADUTL EDUCATION)ij + 15j (TRAINING)ij + r1ij (2.1b)

    2ij= 20j (2.2b)

    3ij= 30j (2.3b)

    4ij= 40j + 41j(EDUCATION)ij + 42j(CHANGE)ij + 43j (TRAINING6)ij

    + 44j(ADULT EDUCAITON)ij (2.4b).

    It is hypothesized (1) that sex, years of formal education, job position assigned, work experience, and pre-

    job vocational/technical training are related to initial salary; (2) that age, formal education, job position,

    adult education, and training are all related to annual salary increases over time; and (3) that sex, formal

    education, amount of change experienced in the job, amount of on-the-job training received within the firm,

    and adult education pursued outside the firm are all related to the performance gain. We leave the L3

    model still unpredicted at this stage.

    Table 5 shows the results with the individual explanatory variables in the L2 model. The

    SALARY parameter remains positive and significant. SEX, FORMAL EDUCATION, and POSITION

    show a significantly positive effect on the grand mean SALARY, the initial hiring salary, but

    EXPERIENCE and PRE-JOB TRAINING do not.

    ^

    On average, an employee earned ln RMB 6.514 (000, t = 77.319 and p =.000) at the third year of

    working in the firm (about RMB 674.56). However, male employees on average start with 5.9 percent

    (010) more than their female counterparts, indicating a difference in the initial salary between male and

    female employees, all other things being equal. Formal education has a significant positive effect on being

    hired. For every additional year of education, one can receive about 2.37 percent (020) more initial salary

    when hired by a firm. This means that formal education is an important factor that affects employers hiring

    decisions. The assigned job position (030) has a significantly positive effect on initial salary. Support staff

    are likely to received 10 percent more salary at time of hire than front-line workers, and

    professional/managerial staff receive another 10 percent more.

    (Insert Table 5 about here)

    Work experience (040) before coming to the current firm does not have an effect on initial salary.

    As discussed earlier, most jobs in Shenzhen resulted from the economic changes, thus they were new jobs.

    Previous work experience may have been less relevant for the current jobs. Prospective employees and

    employers often did not find the right match for the specific jobs in the market. We will see below that on-

    the-job training has an effect on current job skill improvements. Vocational training before hiring became

    a national labor policy from 1993 (China CC & SC, 1993). Some employees received pre-job vocational

    training before coming to the firm. However, the coefficient indicates that, PRE-JOB TRAINING (050) did

    not have a job preparation effect on the firms hiring decision.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    15/35

    14

    The salary increase parameter (100) had an average of 18.7 percent slope, which is substantially

    high. Age group (110) had no effect on the annual salary increase. Shenzhen has a very young workforce

    and the salary reform favors those with job competence instead of seniority or age. Though formal

    education (120) had a strong positive effect on ones initial salary, it showed a negative effect of 0.45

    percent less salary increase for employees with every additional year of formal education. In Shenzhen,

    salary scheme is set up in such a way (see discussion on data set) that formal education only counts in

    computing the fixed basic salary and employers can decide on the salary increase based on performance.

    This statistic reflects the effect of the implementation of such salary scheme. It indicates that employees

    with less formal education tend to have a higher annual salary increase slope than those with more years of

    education do though they have a higher salary at the time of hiring. The position assigned (130 = .0129, t

    =2.624,p = .009) had a significantly positive effect on the annual salary increase. Support staff received a

    1.3 percent more annual salary increase and managerial/professional staff received another 1.3 percent more

    than front-line workers. Therefore, the positions, as determined by the firm, have an effect on salary. Adult

    education (140) selected by employees outside the firm shows no relation to the annual salary increase, nor

    does on-the-job training (150) have an effect on the annual salary increase . Although the actual salary is

    used to control for salary inflation, the annual salary increase is still substantial. Nevertheless, the annual

    increase is not due to formal education, on-the-job training, or adult education per se.

    EDUCATION (410), CHANGE (420), TRAINING AMOUNT (423), and ADULT EDUCATION

    (440) were used to predict PERF GAIN (1ij). First, formal education prior to the job (410) offered marginal

    or no effect on gains in firm recognized proficiency level (410 = .00655, p = .056). The amount of change

    experienced in the job (420 = .0122, p = .007) showed a positive and significant association with a gain in

    proficiency level, about a 1.2 percent increase in salary for every one more change experience in the job.

    This indicates that change promotes performance improvement through learning by doing. The amount of

    OJT (430= .013, p = .005) also showed a positive and significant association with a gain in proficiency

    level, thus associated with increased salary. With each OJT received in the workplace, employees are likely

    to obtain some gain in jobs technical proficiency level, in association with 1.3 percent salary increase.

    AET received outside the firm showed no association with job performance. AET chosen by employees

    outside the firm may largely suit employees individual needs, or needs perceived by employees themselves.

    Such needs may not be relevant to specific job requirements, though AET can be a means to change jobs.

    Thus, those who received AET showed no gain in firm recognized technical proficiency level, thus no

    salary increase.

    With CHANGE and TRAINING AMOUNT as predicting variables, the PERF GAIN slope now

    becomes non-significant (400= -.0471, t = -1.129, p = .260), which means that statistically, CHANGE and

    TRAINING AMOUNT have explained all the variations of PERF GAIN among individuals within firms.

    CHANGE and TRAINING AMOUNT are powerful predictors and have contributed to explain a gain in

    firm recognized technical proficiency in association with salary increase in the positive direction. OJT and

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    16/35

    15

    experience of change in the workplace are associated with increased salary through improved performance,

    as recognized by firms with a gain in proficiency level.

    In short, formal education and job position largely determine the initial salary. Sex discrimination

    exists; females receive 5.9 percent less initial salary than their male counterparts. Annual salary growth is

    substantial and also due to the effect of position; formal education had no effect on annual salary increases.A gain in proficiency is strongly associated with increased salary, but such gains are associated with an

    employees experience of change in their firms, a type of learning-by-doing in technical changes in the job,

    and with receiving OJT.

    It is interesting to note that formal pre-job education has a positive effect on initial salary, but no

    positive effect on annual salary increase, nor on improved job performance. This supports the Spences

    (1973) argument that in hiring, formal education provides a signal in the labor market that employees with

    more education might have higher productivity. With respect to productivity, more educated employees can

    be trained at a lower cost (Thurow, 1975). Therefore, only the initial salary is in accord with formal

    education.

    (Insert Table 6 about here)

    For random effects testing, Table 6 shows that the residual variance among employees (R0ij)is

    now reduced from 0.12072 in the baseline model to 0.10754 for the average initial salary, and from .00533

    to .00508 for annual growth (R1ij). About 11 percent of the variance in initial salary and 4.7 percent of the

    variance in annual salary growth among employees within firms were explained by predictors in the L2

    model. The residual variance is .03095 (U00j) for the average initial salary between firms, 0.00163 (U10j) for

    annual growth, and .00321 (U40j) for PERF GAIN in the baseline model. With the individual predictors

    included in the L2 model, about 31 percent, -11.7 percent, and 44.2 percent of variance at the firm was

    explained in association with the personal characteristics of employees. For the variance in mean growth

    (U10j) across firms, that the variance among individuals within firms (R1ij)was reduced made the variance

    between firms appear to be larger. The variance due to firm impact, which was confused, is decomposed by

    the individual variables.

    It is interesting to note that the individual characteristics of employees explain more for the firm-

    level difference than for the individual-level difference. This indicates that individual variables affect salary

    due to the employees being nested in a firm and due to firm decisions about individuals. Thus, productivity

    is largely a workplace characteristic; and individual characteristics promote productivity in a collective

    manner according to how production is organized in the firm context rather than in an individual manner.

    Nevertheless, the corresponding 2 statistics accompanying these variance components remain

    significant, except variance for PERF GAIN (U40j). This indicates that there is still significant variation

    (R0ij and R1ij) among employees within firms in terms of mean initial salary and mean annual growth as well

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    17/35

    16

    as significant variance (U00j, U10j ) between firms for mean initial salary, and mean annual salary increase.

    Individual predictors in the L2 model explain all the variance of PERF GAIN (U40j).

    5.3 Conditional L3 model with firm characteristics as predictors

    The L1 model and L2 model being the same, the L3 model will use firm characteristic variables topredict six Level-2 parameters and to present their variability between firms. In the following equations,

    the firms characteristic variables serve as explanatory variables to define the association of employees

    performance in the firm context:

    00j = 000 +001 (SIZE)j + u00j (3.00c)

    01j= 010 +011 (OWNERSHIP)j (3.01c)

    02j = 020 + 021 (SECTOR)j (3.02c)

    03j = 030 (3.03c)

    04j = 040 (3.04c)

    05j = 050 (3.05c)

    10j = 100 + 101(TRAINING EXTENT)j+ 102(OWNERSHIP)j+ u10j (3.10c)

    11j = 110 (3.11c)

    12j = 120 (3.12c)

    13j = 130 (3.13c)

    14j = 140 (3.14c)

    15j = 150 (3.15c)

    20j = 200 (3.20c)

    30j = 300 (3.30c)

    40j = 400 + u40j (3.40c)

    41j = 410 (3.41c)

    42j = 420 +421(SIZE)j + 422 (LOCATION)j +423 (SECTOR)j

    +424 (OWNERSHIP)j (3.42c)

    43j = 430 + 431 (SIZE)j+ 432 (LOCATION)j+433(SECTION)j

    +434 (OWNERSHIP)j (3.43c)

    44j = 440 (3.44c).

    It is hypothesized these firm level predictors (Wsj) have effect on their corresponding level 2

    parameters (pqj).

    (Insert Table 7 about here)

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    18/35

    17

    Table 7 presents estimations of the L3 model. Look at the fixed effects first. When hiring

    employees, firms of a smaller size (001) pay about 9 percent more than larger size firms.12 Small firms are

    usually at the periphery in the market and their working conditions are far less attractive. Consequently,

    they offer higher salaries to attract prospective employees but their annual salary increase rate does not

    differ from other firms. Changes occurred with respect to the effect of sex on the initial salary. With firmownership as a predictor, it was found that male employees in the more formally managed state-

    owned/corporate firms received on average about 10 percent more than female employees. Male employees

    in firms with outside investment on average received another 10 percent more.13 Generally speaking, males

    received higher salaries than females. Across firms of different ownership, firms with investment from

    outside China ranked females at bottom and males at the top in terms of salary. This indicates that

    discrimination in salary exists and is most prevalent in those firms with investment from outside China.

    Regarding the firms ability to pay, the local private/collective firms ranked the lowest and this is believed

    to be associated with productivity (see Endnote 9). Though hypothesized, sectors had no difference in

    hiring preference with respect to formal education.

    Regarding the salary growth slope (100), the capacity to provide OJT (101) to employees did not

    have a direct effect on the annual salary increase. This is consistent with estimation for OJT received by

    employees at an individual level (15j). However, when OWNERSHIP (102) is considered, employees in

    state-owned/corporate firms tend to have a 2.5 percent higher annual salary increase than those in local

    private/collective firms. Employees in firms with investment from outside China tend to have another 2.5

    percent higher annual increase. These estimations reflect findings in previous studies (Xiao, 1996a; see

    Endnote 13). Well-managed firms tend to generate much higher productivity and thus are able to provide

    higher salary increase.

    Now consider PERF GAIN and its effect on salary with firm-level variables.14 SIZE (421),

    LOCATION (422), and SECTOR (423) did not show any effect on the amount of technical change (42) that

    employees experienced in the job. However, the firms ownership (424) did have an effect, indicating that

    state-owned/corporate firms presented individual employees with fewer changes in the job. In the same

    manner, firms with investment from outside presented fewer changes compared to state-owned/corporate

    firms.

    Regarding the amount of OJT that an employee received (43), SIZE (431) and LOCATION (432)

    had no effect. SECTOR (433 = -0.0189, t = -2.140, and p = 0.032) showed a negative but significant effect

    on the amount of OJT that employers provided to employees. It suggested that service industries provided

    less training while manufacturing provided more training, something associated with a gain in proficiency,

    thus salary increases. Firms in manufacturing were at the forefront of economic development in Shenzhen

    through the introduction of new production technology [see (Li, 1995); (Liu, 1985, 1992)]. Provision of

    OJT enables employees to continue to learn new skills. Though firms with investment from outside and

    state-owned/corporate firms presented fewer technological changes to individual employees, they provided

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    19/35

    18

    more OJT (434 = 0.015, t = 1.981, and p = 0.047), suggesting a positive association with skill improvement,

    thus about a 1.5 percent increase in salary.

    All these findings about improved performance due to technological changes and OJT suggest an

    interesting relationship. For instance, OJT on its own did not contribute to a salary increase, either at the

    individual (15 = 0.01 and p =.173) or at the firm level (101 = 0.032 and p = .251). OJT contributed to asalary increase through firm-recognized gain in proficiency level (43), indicating that firms did associate

    performance with salary decisions. Ownership has an effect on changes in experienced by employees and

    on the provision of OJT. This indicates that firms are rational in organizing their production, considering

    both individual and firm factors, which in turn have effects on skill improvements. Firms in the

    manufacturing sector, the spearhead of Shenzhen development strategy--to accumulate capital and

    technology through manufacturing--provided more OJT to their employees. It is suggested that employers

    have used workplace training as a complementary strategy to upgrade human capital in abreast of replacing

    of physical capital, thus improving productivity. The findings of this analysis indicate that receiving OJT

    and learning-by-doing have a strong and positive association with firm recognized skill improvement, and

    thus subsequent salary increases.

    The lower panel of Table 7 shows the tests of the random effects 2. With the firm-level variables

    added in the L3 model, the corresponding 2 statistics accompanying the variance components among

    employees (R0ij and R1ij) and between firms (U00j and U10j) still remain significant (Ps < 0.000). This

    indicates that there is still significant variation among employees within firms in terms of mean initial salary

    and mean annual salary growth as well as between firms in terms of mean initial salary and mean annual

    salary increase.

    Table 6 presents a comparison of the explanatory power of the three-level models. For variance

    between firms, L3 Model predicts another 20 percent of the variance in the mean initial salary difference

    (U00j), another 25 percent in the salary increase slope (U10j), and 27 percent in gain in proficiency (U20j). In

    total, the three-level models explain 46 percent of the variance between firms for initial salary, 16 percent of

    the variance for annual salary increase, and 60 percent of the variance in gain in technical proficiency. By

    contrast, for the within-firm variance, 12 percent and 5.4 percent were explained for the initial salary and

    the annual salary increase slope, respectively. Rowan, Raudenbush, and Kang (1991:261) point out that

    between-unit variation in HLM models is accounted for by unit-level as well as by within-unit individual

    characteristics. Given that individuals are nested in their firms, firm production is an interactive process:

    employees contribute to productivity with their characteristics and the firms organize production in a way

    that makes use of employees potentials. Therefore, studying individuals in their social context helps to

    explain how employees behaves due to both their own individual factors as well as the firm factors.

    HLM also allows us to detect proportions of variation existing among employees within firms and

    among firms. The low panel of Table 6 shows that in the baseline model, 80 percent of the variance in

    initial salary lies among employees within firms while 20 percent of the variance lies among firms. For the

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    20/35

    19

    growth slope, 77 percent of the variance in salary lies among employees within firms and 23 percent across

    firms. As the individual variables and firms variables were put into L2 and L3 models, variation among

    firms tends to decrease while that among employees tends to increase.

    6. CONCLUDING DISCUSSION

    This study analyses how three different human capital development strategies contribute to salary

    growth over time. In the workplace, employees are nested in their firms; individual characteristics are

    promoted or constrained as the firm makes production decisions. If this process is neglected in estimates of

    rates of return, for instance including only individual variables and pre-job characteristics, the human

    capital concept will be flawed theoretically.15 This is because other alternatives that impart skills and

    knowledge to individuals are omitted and other complements in the workplace are neglected. The most

    important of these neglected conditions involves the process of how knowledge and learnt skills is

    transferred into productivity, through many complementary and necessary conditions, in the context of firm.

    The analysis in this study has attempted to discover what is going on in this black box by revealing

    several important findings in the context of the emerging economy of Shenzhen. I argue that qualitative

    changes in a transitional economy create disequilibria in the workplace. As changes accelerate and become

    a constant, OJT and AET serve as complementary strategies to regain equilibrium. OJT provided in the

    workplace strengthens a firms capacities in a market economy, while AET suits individual expectations of

    the external market. Therefore, both OJT and AET engage employees in the changing economic process

    and upgrade their human capital. The major findings of this study support this argument and can be

    summarized by the following points.

    First, formal education has a significant impact on employers hiring decisions, and the initial

    salary. However, additional years of formal education are not associated with annual salary increases or

    with technical proficiency improvements recognized by the firm. Second, OJT provided by employers in

    the workplace does not automatically contribute to annual salary growth at either the individual or the firm

    level. OJT contributes to salary increases only through firm-recognized improved job performance, which

    is positively associated with an increase in salary. Firms in Shenzhen associate job performance salary.

    This finding shows that OJT has a positive impact on productivity. Third, firms with more formalized

    management, such as firms with investment from outside China and state-owned/corporate firms, provide

    more OJT to their employees. These firms are able to pay higher salaries, both at the initial hiring point andduring annual increases; but they are associated with gender discrimination to female employees at hiring.

    Fourth, manufacturing firms, which are at the forefront of economic development, provide significantly

    more OJT to match their human capital with physical capital. This indicates that firms are rational in

    utilizing OJT to keep abreast of changes in the workplace. Fifth, technological changes in the workplace

    provide as learning-by-doing and contribute to job performance improvements, thus they are associated

    with salary increases. Nevertheless, compared with more formally managed firms such as those with

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    21/35

    20

    investment from outside China and state-owned/corporate firms, local private/collective firms tend to let

    their employees experience more job changes and they are less likely to provide their employees formal

    OJT. Their ability to pay is also the lowest both at the hiring point and during the annual salary increases.

    Finally, voluntary AET outside of the firms by individual employees does not have an impact on job

    performance or on salary increases. While AET may suit individual expectations of the external market,firms do not yet associate it with salary decisions.

    The findings on formal education and OJT are in accord with Spences (1973) assumption that

    formal education is a signal of potential productivity, which Thurow (1975) refers to as trainability at lower

    cost. The findings also indicate that employers are rational in matching individual characteristics to the

    changing characteristics of the firms: they provided OJT to close the skill gap when changes resulted in

    disequilibria. They also associate OJT with salary through firm-recognized job proficiency. Learning

    through OJT in the workplace is located in the social context of the firm, a collective and intentional

    process. Learning in such a mode makes content relevant, thus giving performance application and

    meaning (Xiao, 1999). The association of OJT with firm-recognized job proficiency further creates

    incentives for the transfer of training. The findings on ownership, which is a proxy for the formality of

    management, show that a firm with formal management can provide higher pay and more OJT. All these

    findings confirm that complementary inputs in the workplace promote the transfer of training. Organized

    learning, OJT in this study, in the changing context of appropriate technology is found to improve skills and

    increase salary.

    With respect to formal vocational/technical education, Xiao and Tsang (1999, Table 3), found that

    secondary vocational/technical graduates and tertiary graduates did not receive less on-the-job training than

    general education graduates. Formal VTE is expensive and costs more than general education (Tsang,

    1997). Furthermore, research findings from China have thus far not favored VTE graduates (Lo and Lee,

    1996; Yang, 1997; Min & Tsang, 1990). These studies suggest that the Chinese government would be well

    advised to re-examine its national education policy, which favors a western pattern of formal vocational

    education, whereby VTE enrolment constitutes 50 per cent or more of the upper-secondary level (China

    SEC, 1996).

    Because of the contextual nature of the workplace, it is doubtful that formal education will be able

    to accommodate the specific, ever-changing demands for workplace competence. It is thus not surprising

    that this study found no effect of formal education on specific job skills improvement. Moreover, the

    human resource strategy of continuing learning that has been observed in the early industrialization processin the developed world (Gospel, 1991) has also been observed at different stages of development during the

    twentieth century in China: from the early revolution movement in the 1920s through the socialist

    modernization program in the 1950s and early 1960s (Zang, 1985), as well as in other nations at the present

    time (see discussion in the introduction section). Continuing learning is a strategy incorporated in the

    process in development, even though it has been marginalized in educational investment policies. The

    literature findings suggest that learning in the workplace, as in Shenzhen, does not supplement gaps in

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    22/35

    21

    education credentials due to the absence of formal education, as was also the case in the early history of

    adult education in China (Xiao, 1998b). The continual upgrading of human capital in order to reduce

    discrepancies due to constant changes in the workplace has been an effective strategy in Shenzhen to regain

    an equilibrium. The experience of Shenzhen is relevant to other fast changing regions in China.

    There are two important policy implications in the Chinese context. As part of the socialisttradition, adult education and workplace learning have played a dual role in the education system in China.

    It has attempted to close gaps in education among the population since 1949. Due to the recent focus on

    economic development adult learning now plays an important, complementary role to upgrade job skills in

    the workplace (Xiao, 1999; this study). Considering relevance and efficiency, education and training for

    working adults should be integrated into social policies, along with an expansion of formal education. In

    the last two decades, economic reforms in China have focused on macro policies. Improvements in firm

    management have received little attention. Because firm polices are complementary to the utilization of

    human capital and thus productivity, efforts should be made to improve firm-level management, thus

    promoting the transfer of training.

    Given that the purpose of this study is to survey the educational and training histories of employees

    in firms, it does not examine the personal characteristics developed through formal education and/or

    associated with family background as well as the impact of AET on other aspects of ones life (e.g.,

    changing ones job). Much variance at the individual level is still unexplained. Since an ability to deal with

    disequilibria is critical to increasing productivity, as argued by Shultz (1975), future studies should explore

    how employees with different personal characteristics deal with disequilibria in the workplace. Levin

    (1987) suggests that individual discretion in the workplace is important to allow educated employees to

    allocate resources and improve productivity. Therefore, it is important to examine if the involvement of

    employees in decision making will improve productivity in Chinas new market economy. These factors

    might reflect how individuals behave in the workplace, thus explaining more variance at the individual

    level.

    Acknowledgements

    This study is part of a research project entitled Evaluation of the External Efficiency ofVocational/technical Education in Shenzhen funded by the Chinese University of Hong Kongs DirectGrant (SSEP AC No. 2020287). The author is indebted to Professor Brian Rowan, School of Education,University of Michigan, for providing the analytical method as well as suggestions for revision. The authoralso acknowledges the collaborative efforts of the Shenzhen Institute of Educational Research, especially

    the assistance of Ms. Zhao Peifeng in data collection; Dr. Chan Wing Shing, of the Education & ManpowerBureau, Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, for technical advice; Dr. Michael Agelasto forcommenting on the manuscript; and Ms. Nancy Hearst, Fairbank Center for East Asian Research, HarvardUniversity for copyediting. Finally, thanks go to the reviewers and editor of this journal for suggestions andcomments.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    23/35

    22

    Notes

    1 Some studies have allowed for endogeneity of training decisions (Heckman, 1979), occupational changes(Greenhalgh and Stewart, 1987), and experiments in participation and non-participation in training(Lalonde, 1986).

    2

    The total workforce in Shenzhen is 2.45 million. Among it, there are 0.46 million town individuals, 1.1million village labor force, 0.89 million registered employees, and .05 million others. Firms andorganizations that registered their employees with the government labor department or personneldepartment hire the third group. They are considered as registered workforce.

    3 These eight types of ownership refer to state-owned, collectively owned, joint-venture with firms fromHong Kong and Macau, and Taiwan, joint-ventures with firms from other countries, sole-investment firmsfrom Hong Kong, Macau, and Taiwan, sole-investment firms from other countries, local private firms, andcorporate firms. There first two types are considered typical in the planned economy and the six latter onesare new forms of ownership in the transferred economy after 1980.

    4 The minimum individual cases within a unit for analysis with HLM are 12. On the average, for the total

    sample, each production line/group contained 52 employees. Each year, a firm would hire a few new

    employees, about five to six in this sample in the early 1990s. If only one year is used as a sub-sample,there are not enough individual cases for a reliable estimation of a firm unit. Therefore, a sub-sample withemployees recruited in four years meets the statistical requirement of at least 12 individual observations in aunit. Eleven firms with less than 12 observations were automatically excluded from the analysis.

    5 Development in Shenzhen Special Economic Zone took place in three stages. The first stage (1980 tomid-1980s) was the take-off stage, characterized by a priority on infrastructure construction to attractinvestment. The second stage (mid-1980s to late-1980s) was devoted to expanding labor-intensivemanufacturing for the international market to build up an industrial base and accumulate capital. Since1990, the development strategy has shifted from manufacturing toward a diversified economy, with anincreased emphasis on services (Li, 1995; Liu, 1985, 1992).

    6 For data sets arranging, please see Appendix A for Determinants of salary growth in Shenzhen, China at

    www.fed.cuhk.edu.hk/eap/people/xiaoj.html.7 Performance assessments were conducted systematically in those firms with investment from outsideChina, the state-owned and newly created corporate firms. And decisions on skill proficiency were largelymade on technical grounds. In some firms, particularly the local collectives and private firms, performanceassessment were not well conducted. In such case, non-technical factors as subjectivity, personal relation oreven political consideration (mostly in the state-owned firms) might make an influence. Nevertheless,PERF GAIN is the best available indicator an employees job performance in China.

    8 The average age was 28.7 years for the 1 million permanent residents and 26 years for the 2.5 milliontemporary residents in 1996 (Shenzhen SIYC, 1997: 111-112).

    9 Xiao (1996b) finds that in 1992 firms with investment from the outside ranked highest in per employee

    industrial product (RMB 74,357.00 in 1978 price); while state-owned firms ranked second (RMB29,581.00); corporations ranked third (RMB 11,949.00), and collective and local private firms tanked last(RMB 3,262). Productivity is due to management practices, and training, all else being the same (Xiao,1996a).

    10 The intercept parameter, 0, is the true salary of each employee at some fixed time point. The specifictime point depends on the scaling of the observations. In this model, the second observation time point iscoded as 0 to avoid collinearity with other temporal variables.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    24/35

    23

    11 It is important to examine the reliability of the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimate at individual andfirm levels and the correlation among the growth parameters. The reliability of L2 and L3 outcomevariables will help ensure that the data can detect systematic relations between growth parameters andpersonal-level variables, and between personal and firm variables (Bryk & Raudenbush, 1992: 69, 137,177-178). For each employee ij at L2,

    ^reliability ( 0ij ) = / [ + 2/tjk] (5)

    is the reliability of individual mean for use in discrimination among employees within the firm. For anyfirmj at L3,

    ^ reliability ( 00j ) = (6)

    + { [ + 2/tjk]

    1 }1

    is the reliability of the firms sample mean as an estimate of its true mean. The averages of thesereliabilities across employees and firms (Equation 6) provide summary measures of the reliability of theemployee and firm means, respectively.

    With multi-wave data, the correlation of the true initial status and true change can be obtained with moreconsistence than a simple pre-test and post-test design or two points comparison (Bryk & Raudenbush,1992:137-138). Under a linear individual growth model, this correlation is just the correlation between

    0ij, and 1ij,

    ^ ^ ^ ^

    (0ij, 1ij) = 01 / [ 00+ 11]1/2 (4)

    For the salary data, the estimated correlation between initial salary status and true annual growth rate was 0.122. This means that employees whose initial salary was low when entering the firm tended to have asalary increase at a mildly steeper slope over time. This can be inferred as a true negative relationship andnot a spurious result of the measurement process.

    12 Size is not included in the model because it is not significant for predicting salary growth slope, 100because it reduced the power to explain the variability. Appendix B portrays salary trends predicted by firmsize, which is available at www.fed.cuhk.edu.hk.eap/people/xiaoj.html.

    13 Appendix C delineates the estimation trends and is available atwww.fed.cuhk.edu.hk.eap/people/xiaoj.html.

    14 To test if association of PERF GAIN with salary increase is true, a three-level model was run, excludingPERF GAIN, thus all its L2 and L3 predictors. Estimations of variables remaining the essentially the same,

    2 increased by 2 per cent, R0ij increased by 8 per cent, R1ij increased by .8 per cent, U00j by 62 per cent andU10j by 9 per cent. Excluding PERF GAIN only increased variance across firms for grand mean initial

    salary (000). This shows the PERF GAIN does not have collinearity with OBSERVATIONS, and its L2and L3 predictors shared little the same effects with other L2 and L3 predictors for other L1 parameters.

    15 A comparison of the Mincerian method is provided with the third salary data in 1996 (see Appendix D atwww.fed.cuhk.edu.hk.eap/people/xiaoj.html). The ANOVA only provide variance in a single sum. It isalso observed that with only one year of salary data, sex as a predictor appeared not to be significant,contrary to the estimations of the three-level salary growth model. The three-level model finds significanteffect of gender on salary decisions (see Tables 6 and Table 8) and it tends to increase the disparity asportrayed in Appendix C for the salary growth trajectory. With only one year of salary data, the estimationof the Mincerian method failed to detect such a gender effect on salary.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    25/35

    24

    REFERENCES

    Becker, G. S. (1964).Human capital. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Belanger, P. & Tuijnman, A. (1997). The silent explosion of adult learning. In: P. Belanger, & A.Tuijinman (Ed.), New patterns of adult learning: A six-country comparative study (pp. 1-16).Oxford: Pergamon.

    Bryk, A. S. & Raudenbush, S. W. (1992). Hierarchical linear model: Applications anddata analysis methods. Newburg Park, CA: Sage Publications.

    Chapman, P. G. (1993). The economics of training. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    China Central Committee and State Council [CC & SC] (1993). Guideline on Chinas education reformand development decisions on strengthening employee Training. Beijing.

    China State Education Commission [SEC] (1996). The ninth five-year plan of the nationaleducation and development plan for 2010. In: Policy report of State EducationCommission No 6(pp. 219-227). Beijing: China State Education Commission

    Cohn, E. & Addison, J. (1998). The economic returns to lifelong learning in OECD countries.EducationEconomics6(3), 253-307.

    Gospel, H. F. (1991).Industrial training and technological innovation: A comparative andhistorical Study. London and New York: Routledge.

    Greenhalgh, C. & Stewart, M. (1987). The effects and determinants of training. OxfordBulletin of Economics and Statistics 49(2), 171-190.

    Hall. R. E. & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce much more output per worker thanothers? The Quarterly Journal of Economics114 (1), 83-116.

    Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error.Econometirca 47, 153-162.

    Lalonde, R. J. (1986). Evaluating the econometric evaluations of training programs. TheAmercian Economic Review76(4), 604-620.

    Levin, H. M. & Kelley, C. (1994). Can education do it along?Economics of Education Review13 (2), 97-108.

    Levin, H. M. (1987). Improving production through education and technology. In G. Brude, andR. W. Rumberger (Ed.), The future impact of technology on work and education (pp. 194-214).London: The Falmer Press.

    Li, Q. S., (1995). Foreign investment on a large scale. In Shenzhen special economic zone yearbook 1995

    (pp. 88-91). Shenzhen: Shenzhen Special Economic Zone Publishing House, Shenzhen.

    Liu, G. G. (1985).Research on development strategies of Shenzhen special economic zone.Hong Kong: Hong Kong Economic Guide Press and Shenzhen Research Centre forEconomics.

    Liu, G. G. (1992). Strategies of Economic Development for Shenzhen Special Economic Zone in1990s: Building up a prototype of socialist market economy and an internationally

    integrated city. Beijing: Economic Management Press.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    26/35

    25

    Lo, L. N. K., and Lee, C. H. (1996). In rural China: which road to relevant education?EducationalLeadership 35 (8), 60-63.

    Middleton, J., Ziderman, A., & Adams, A. V. (1993). Skills for productivity: Vocational education andtraining in developing countries. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Min. W. F. & Tsang, M. C. (1990). Vocational education and productivity: A case study of the BeijingGeneral Auto Industry Company. Economics of Education Review9 (4): 351-364.

    Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience, and earnings. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Psacharopoulos, G. (1985). Returns to Education: A further international update and implications.Journalof Human Resources 20, 583-604.

    Psacharopoulos, G. (1994). Return to investment in education: A global update. World Development 22(9), 1325-1343.

    Psacharopoulos, G. & Woodhall, M. (1985).Education for development: Analysis of investmentchoices. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Rowan, B, Raudenbush, S. and Kang . J. (1991). Organizational design in high schools: A multilevelanalysis.American Journal of Education99 (fall), 238-266.

    Schultz, T. (1975). The value of the ability to deal with disequilibira.Journal of EconomicLiterature 13 (3), 827-846.

    Shenzhen Association for Enterprises [AE] (1996). Yearbook of Shenzhen registered firms. Shenzhen.

    Shenzhen Economic System Reform Commission [ESRC](1989). Section Five: Labor, salary,and security system. Shenzhen special economic zone selected documents on reform,(pp.333-363).

    Shenzhen Government (1989). Salary reform scheme for Shenzhen state-owned and non-profit

    Units (1984); Salary reform scheme for manufacturing firms and factories (1984); Decisions onfirm salary reform (1985); Temporary ordinance for salary tax in Shenzhen Special EconomicZone (1985). In: Shenzhen Economic Reform Commission, Selected documents of Shenzhenspecial economic zone (pp. 341-366).

    Shenzhen Statistical and Information Yearbook Committee[SIYC] (1997). Statistical andInformation Yearbook of Shenzhen. Beijing: China Statistics Press.

    Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics 87(3),355-375.

    Thurow. L. (1975). Generating inequality. New York: Basic Books, Inc.

    Tsang, M. C. (1987). The Impact of underutilization of education on productivity: A case study of the U.S.Bell Companies.Economics of Education Review 6(3): 239-254.

    Tsang, M. C. (1997). The costs of vocational training. International Journal of Manpower18 (1/2): 63-89.

    Xiao, J. (1996a). A study of the relationship between organizational factors and the transfer oftraining in the electronics industry in Shenzhen, China.Human Resource DevelopmentQuarterly 7(1), 55-73.

    Xiao, J. (1996b). Multi-ownership, management and productivity: A case of Shenzhen. Paper

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    27/35

    26

    presented at the International Conference on Co-ordinated Development Among Regions, inChinas Economic Reform and Social Development, Dec. 11-12, 1996, Hong Kong. Available inthe conference proceedings (pp. 421-431).

    Xiao, J. (1998a). Education expansion in Shenzhen, China: Its interface with economicdevelopment. International Journal of Educational Development 18 (1), 3-19.

    Xiao, J. (1998b). Higher adult education in China: Redefining its roles. In: M. Agelasto & B.Adamson (Ed.), Higher education in the post-Mao era (pp. 189-210). Hong Kong: Hong KongUniversity Press.

    Xiao, J. (1999). Alternative learning approaches in an Emerging Economy:An Experience of Shenzhen, China.Educational Practice and Theory21 (1), 27-49.

    Xiao, J. & Tsang, M. C. (1994). Costs and financing of adult education in Shenzhen, ChinaInternational Journal of Educational Development14 (1), 55-73.

    Xiao, J. & Tsang, M. C. (1999). Human capital development in an emerging economy:The experience of Shenzhen, China. China Quarterly 157(March), 72-114.

    Yang, J. (1997). The interaction between the socialist market economy and technical and vocationaleducation and training in the Peoples Republic of China. Ph.D Dissertation, University of Manchesterand Bolton Institute, U. K.

    Zang, Y. C. (1985). Chinas history of employee education [Zhongguo zhigong jioayu shigao].Lianning Peoples Press.

    Ziderman A. & Horn, R. (1995). Many paths to skilled employment: A reverse tracer studyof seven occupations in Colombia.Education Economics3 (1), 61-79.

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    28/35

    Table 1

    Descriptions of level-1 variables

    Variable Definition Mean Std Dev Min. Max. N

    OBSERVATIONS: Years elapsed between observation time points

    entry year 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1023

    the second point 2.99 0.08 2.00 3.00 1023the third point 5.25 1.01 4.00 6.00 1023

    SALARY: Actual salary observations in 1996 price (RMB)

    entry salary 793.76 562.63 150.63 4752.60 1023

    salary at the second point 1191.64 875.45 187.44 7764.15 1023

    salary at the third point 1625.75 1182.90 199.19 8872.78 1023

    PERF GAIN: Gain in job performance between observation time points (level)

    entry year 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1023

    the second point 0.94 0.96 0.00 4.00 1023

    the third point 2.26 1.02 1.00 5.00 1023

  • 8/2/2019 Jurnal Human Capital Theory

    29/35

    Table 2

    Descriptions of level-2 variables (1,023 employees)

    Variables Definition Coding %

    SEX Sex

    female 0 51.1

    male 1 46.6missing missing 2.1

    AGE Age in group

    16-25 0 52.8

    26-35 1 34.6

    36 and above 2 12.7

    EXPERIENCE Had work experience before the current job

    no 0 58.0

    yes 1 42.0

    POSITION Types of current positions

    front-line workers 0 56.7

    support staff 1 19.1

    managerial/professional staff 2 24.2

    CHANGE Extent of technical changes experienced in job

    none 0 29.6

    once 1 14.6

    two times 2 22.6

    three times 3 33.2

    EDUCATION Education attainment in years

    missing missing 1.1

    9 years 9 25.1

    12 years 12 58.7

    13 years 13 3.6

    14 years 14 3.7

    16 years 16 6.4

    18 years or more 18 1.4PRE-JOB TRAINING Vocational/technical training before current job

    no 0 91.3

    yes 1 8.7

    TRAININ