Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law

14
Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law Benito ARRUÑADA (UPF) Veneta ANDONOVA (ITAM)

description

Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law. Benito ARRUÑADA (UPF) Veneta ANDONOVA (ITAM). Motivation. Previous work on property rights ( JLEO ’03): Courts end up conditioning market transition Pro-market intent & nature of civil law reform in 1800s—(e.g., mortgage market) - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Transcript of Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law

Page 1: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Judicial Rulemaking in Western Law

Benito ARRUÑADA (UPF)

Veneta ANDONOVA (ITAM)

Page 2: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Motivation

▪ Previous work on property rights (JLEO’03): ♦ Courts end up conditioning market transition♦ Pro-market intent & nature of civil law reform

in 1800s—(e.g., mortgage market) ♦ Common / civil law divide nonexistent

▪ Reinvigorated efficiency claims of common law (La Porta, Shleifer et al.)

▪ GOAL: Explore an adaptation hypothesis for explaining modern Western law

Page 3: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Analytical framework

▪ A key design difference b/w common & civil law: allocation of rule making power to judges:♦ Rule making power of the whole judiciary♦ ‘Centralization’ of this power—binding precedent

▪ Four areas of trade-offs:♦ Self-interest (1)♦ Information (2)♦ Cognitive: Rationality (allegedly decisive)

• Bias and heuristics (3)

• Unnaturalness of markets (4)

Page 4: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (1): Self-interest

▪ Parties♦ Legislators retain rulemaking supremacy♦ Judges do not need rules to be corrupt♦ Rent-seeking by parties to contracts require

biased rule-maker

▪ Depends on fields of law (?)♦ In private law, less legislative rent seeking♦ Choice of field temporary and endogenous

Page 5: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (2): Lack of information

▪ Geographic scope of markets advantage for centralized standards (?)♦ But, in any case, binding precedent enough

(especially if centralized)

▪ Speed of technical change need faster adjustment♦ But unclear which system adapts faster

Page 6: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (3): Rationality—Biases & heuristics

▪ Guthrie, Rachlinski & Wistrich (2001), judges fail♦ The same in Hindsight, Anchoring & Egocentrism advises

constraining judicial ruling—e.g., liability standards♦ Less in Framing & Representativeness

▪ Doubt how judges process key experimental info♦ Is a defendants’ move for dismissal irrelevant when testing for

anchoring effects?

▪ Hindsight: applicable, more than to negligence, to:♦ Emphasis on balanced compensation ex post ♦ Prejudice against asymmetric contracting

▪ But affects equally judges from all jurisdictions

Page 7: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Drivers of rulemaking inefficiency (4): Rationality—Unnaturalness of markets

▪ Sharing redistributive rulemaking

▪ Identifiable persons tendency to ignore rule-setting effects of individual sentences (justice vs. efficiency)

▪ Greater bias against abstract transactions (capital, intangibles, perhaps trade)

Page 8: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

‘Cognitive gap’ between continental legislators and judges in 19th century

▪ Legislators♦ Aristocratic democracy made ‘political leadership’

possible instead of ‘political agency’ (20th) more ‘rational’ (pro-market) elites

♦ Also had market experience & profit opportunities?

▪ Judiciary♦ Continent: judicial nobility, more Canon law♦ England: former barristers

Page 9: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Hypothesis: Western law as pro-market adaptation

▪ Common law evolved within a slow transition to the market economy

▪ Civil law changed from above, as part of a pro-market liberal revolution, by constraining judges rulemaking powers

▪ Historical ‘test:’ ♦ 19th and ♦ 20th centuries

Page 10: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Test: Western law in the 19th century

▪ Few changes in common law♦ Needed Roman law introduced w/o codification♦ Binding precedent—national markets

▪ Pro-market revolution of the civil law♦ Freedom of contract achieved by combining:

• Codification Default rules

• Minimal judicial discretion: Sentence according to law & bound by centralized precedents

• Also: Codification doctrinal changes diluting Canon law influence: credit, penal clauses, ‘lesion’, ‘cause’

♦ Mandatory law to reduce transaction costs—e.g., land titling

Page 11: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Test: Anti-market trends in Western law

▪ Changes: statue law in ‘new’ fields and:♦ Common law: courts interfere with contractual

freedom—e.g., unconscionability (= Canon Law)♦ Civil law: greater judicial discretion

▪ Cognitive hypotheses♦ Increased uncertainty in 1910-30s ‘sharing’

• Why not before?

♦ Political change: Elites as political ‘agents’ instead of leaders• Exogenous?

Page 12: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Alternative perspectives

▪ The efficiency debate is not a comparative exercise analyses internal consistency, not efficiency

▪ Comparative performance—La Porta et al.♦ Self-selection♦ Measurement nightmare♦ Correlation ≠ Causation

▪ Need to ♦ Consider self-selection♦ Use institutional dimensions as independent variables (e.g.,

judicial discretion) instead of labels (civil & common law)

Page 13: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Concluding remarks (1)

▪ How to create market friendly institutions—the rule of law—in transition & developing economies♦ Adaptation♦ Constrain judges—but does a cognitive gap exist?

• Lack of market-wise judges

• But political elites more often agents (South America) than leaders (Asian tigers)

♦ Self-enforcing institutions• Example: community mortgage systems

Page 14: Judicial Rulemaking  in Western Law

Concluding remarks (& 2)

▪ How to preserve market friendly institutions in developed economies♦ A doses of redistribution required b/c of the

cognitive anti-market bias?