International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are...

31
Introduction Model Data Results References International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework Mario Larch 1 Steffen Sirries 2 1 University of Bayreuth, ifo Institute, CESifo, and GEP 2 University of Bayreuth ETSG 2013 1 / 31

Transcript of International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are...

Page 1: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

International Trade and Migration:A Quantitative Framework

Mario Larch1 Steffen Sirries2

1University of Bayreuth, ifo Institute, CESifo, and GEP 2University of Bayreuth

ETSG 2013

1 / 31

Page 2: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why international trade?

Because we are trade economists?

Academic: Welfare (gains from trade).

Media and politics: Globalization.

Interdependence: Multilateral resistance (what others do mightaffect us (GE)).

2 / 31

Page 3: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why international migration?

Because, as an Austrian living in Germany, Mario is a migrant?

Because international migration is big!

Even within the OECD-OECD matrix 4% of the population aremigrants → much more from the dominant south-north migration.

Today over 22% of the Swedish population are migrants, about 18%in Germany, about 15% in Switzerland and 10% in the US(depending on the definition: country of birth, citizenship, 2ndgeneration).

Migration is always a topic in media and politics!

3 / 31

Page 4: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why trade and migration? I

Because Mario is a migrant and we are trade economists?

Traditional view: H-O-type trade models with migration:

Trade substitutes for migration.Signing free trade agreements lowers the pressure of migration.Expected (bilateral) correlation between trade and migration:negative.

BUT... New trade models with intra-industry trade and north-northmigration → complementarity of trade and migration (e.g OECD).

4 / 31

Page 5: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why trade and migration? II

−5

05

1015

TR

AD

EF

LOW

S in

logs

(no

rmal

ized

)

−5 0 5 10 15 20MIGRATION STOCKS in logs (normalized)

5 / 31

Page 6: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why trade and migration? III

−4

−2

02

Res

idua

ls o

f tra

de g

ravi

ty

−5 0 5Residuals of migration gravity

corr(etrade , emigr ) = 0.2304 6 / 31

Page 7: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why trade and migration? III

There might be more than just a spurious correlation between tradeand migration.

This is not new (Head and Ries (1998)): Migrants also bring alongpreferential access to the markets of the country of origin.

Migrants are not just a factor but consumers and though they bringtheir demand! BUT...

7 / 31

Page 8: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why “A Quantitative Framework”? I

Quantitative means structural!

General equilibrium effects are natural to trade shocks!

The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)welfare analysis of migration- and trade-policy evaluations:“Gravity has long been applied to empirically model factormovements. As with trade flows, the model always fits well. But, incontrast to the recent development of an economic structural gravitymodel of trade, there has been little progress in building atheoretical foundation.” (?)

To the best of our knowledge, there is no structural model withtrade AND migration. (Redding (2012), di Giovanni, Levchenko,and Ortega (2012), Behrens, Mion, Murata, and Sudekum (2011)).

8 / 31

Page 9: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

Why “A Quantitative Framework”? II

One of the core issues in empirical international trade is thequantification of the welfare gains from trade liberalization.

Workhorse model: gravity equation for trade flows (Eaton undKortum 2002, Anderson und van Wincoop 2003, Santos Silva undTenreyro 2006, Anderson und Yotov 2010, Waugh 2010, Fieler 2011,Arkolakis, Costinot und Rodrıguez-Clare 2012).

All frameworks in the literature so far assume labor to be immobile.

BUT: economic migration or the integration of labor markets mightbe an issue!“The exact relationship between trade and migration is potentiallyimportant. For example, if the relationship were a complementaryone, and if policy makers were to view further reductions in tradebarriers as improbable, then in order to facilitate trade, liberalizingmigration might make economic sense.” (Gaston and Nelson (2013))

9 / 31

Page 10: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

What we do! I

We develop a structural trade model which explicitly accounts formigration.

Therefore we use one of the most simple new trade frameworks forintra-industry trade.

We add a very recent and simple modelling of the migration decision.

So, we propose a framework which enables us to disentangle tradeand migration cost reductions in counterfactual analysis (examples:TAFTA, EU single market, ...).

10 / 31

Page 11: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

What we do! II

One big question in the migration literature is through whichchannel migration contributes to the welfare of the destinationcountry. We offer a new one!

Questions we ask:

Does accounting for economic migration matter for an evaluation ofwelfare gains from trade?Should we also negotiate for free movement of labor within apreferential trade agreement?

Keep in mind: We focus on economic migration, north-northmigration! (OECD sample)

11 / 31

Page 12: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

What we don’t do!

... for the moment ...

unemployment, return migration (dynamics), remittances,heterogeneous migrants, heterogeneous firms, firm-level data, 2ndgeneration effects, refugee migration ...

Actually this is the second of many steps of a bigger research agenda:Heid and Larch (2012).

12 / 31

Page 13: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

What we find! I

From theoryA clear cut link between trade and migration:real wage differences influence migration decision → increasedimmigration increases size (respectively nominal GDP) of a country →changes nominal wages and price indices → equilibrium changes

13 / 31

Page 14: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Motivation

What we find! II

From empiricsAnalysis of a hypothetical Transatlantic Free Trade Agreement; once withmigration and once without.Take home messages:

Signing TAFTA would have positive welfare effects for signers.

Accounting for migration for such an evaluation matters a lot!

14 / 31

Page 15: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Trade I

We start with a standard trade model:

Multi-country perfect competition model (Armington (1969)) with

differentiated goods at the country-level and

iceberg type-trade costs.

15 / 31

Page 16: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Trade II

Representative consumer in country j . The quantity of purchased goodsfrom country i is given by cij , leading to the following utility function:

Uj =

[N∑i=1

β1−σσ

i cσ−1σ

ij

] σσ−1

. (1)

With iceberg trade costs tij > 1, profit maximization implies thatpij = pi tij , where pi is the factory gate price of the good in country i .

16 / 31

Page 17: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Trade III

The representative consumer maximizes Equation (1) subject to the

budget constraint Yj =∑N

i=1 pi tijcij . The value of aggregate sales ofgoods from country i to country j can then be expressed as

Xij = pi tijcij =

(βipi tijPj

)1−σ

Yj , (2)

and Pj is the standard CES price index.In general equilibrium, total sales correspond to nominal income, i.e.,Yi =

∑Nj=1 Xij .

Assuming labor to be the only factor of production and full employment,GDP is given by total factor income, i.e., Yi = wiLi .⇒ nothing new here!

17 / 31

Page 18: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Migration I

Migration is a choice from a

menu of locations with

individual/idiosyncratic costs of migration.

Bilateral migration costs are equal to all migrants from i to j and weend up with

McFadden (1974) like discrete choice equation.

⇒ comparable to ?

18 / 31

Page 19: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Migration II

So we start with the log utility from migration from i to j for a worker h

Vij = ln(U∗i )− ln(U∗

j ) + ln(εijh)− ln(δij), (3)

where U∗j and U∗

i are the indirect utility functions taken from the tradesystem, εjih captures idiosyncratic, individual specific utility frommigration and δji are migration costs. The migration flow from i to j isgiven by

Mij = G (Vij)Ni , (4)

where Ni is the number of natives in i and G (Vij) gives the proportion ofmigrants from i to j . When εijh is assumed to be i.i.d. this proportion isgiven by the probability as in McFadden (1974)

G (Vij) =exp(Vij)∑k expVik

, (5)

19 / 31

Page 20: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Migration III

since U∗j =

wj

Pjand U∗

i = wi

Pifor one worker, we get

Vij = ln(wi

Pi)− ln(

wj

Pj) + ln(εijh)− ln(δij). (6)

Inserting (6) in (4) gives

Mij =

wj

wj

Pi

Pj

1δij∑

k(wk

wi

Pi

Pk

1δij

)Ni (7)

=

wj

Pj

1δij∑

k(wk

Pk

1δik

)Ni . (8)

20 / 31

Page 21: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Linking Trade and Migration

The new and very simple channel is:migration is driven by real wage differences → migration changesdemand/size of a country → changes wages (nominal) and price indices→ again changes real wage differences

21 / 31

Page 22: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Data

We started with two very clean data sets in a cross section for the year2000.

CEPII bilateral trade data from Head, Mayer, and Ries (2010) withmany geographical information.

“Where on Earth is everybody”-data from Ozden, Parsons, Schiff,and Walmsley (2011).

International bilateral migration stock data (censuses and officialregisters).

We just keep the OECD sample to avoid zero migration cells (remember:no volume decision! → north-north migration).

22 / 31

Page 23: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Estimation stage and fit of the model I

We estimate

a standard trade gravity with importer and exporter fixed effects(Head, Mayer, and Ries (2010) JIE)

and a standard migration gravity with importer and exporter fixedeffects (Grogger and Hanson (2011) JDE).

23 / 31

Page 24: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Estimation stage and fit of the model II

05

1015

trad

eflo

w in

logs

mod

el

−5 0 5 10 15tradeflow in logs observed

24 / 31

Page 25: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Estimation stage and fit of the model III

05

1015

20m

igra

tion

in lo

gs m

odel

0 5 10 15migration in logs observed

25 / 31

Page 26: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Counterfactual Analysis I

What would happen if TAFTA would be signed?That means, we will have a PTA equal to one between the USA and theEU in addition to existing PTAs.

First step: We look at the inception of TAFTA at all, i.e. we changethe PTA vector.

Second step: We do the same in a framework without migration, i.e.Anderson and van Wincoop (2003).

Other, more differentiated counterfactuals possible and of highestinterest: EU single market, other reduction of migration cost, ...

26 / 31

Page 27: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Counterfactual Analysis II

Changes from inception of TAFTA with migration:

world migration: +0.46%

world trade: +0.96%

average welfare change at country level: +1%

Top and bottom three country-level results (welfare):

EST +5.9%, PRT +2%, SVK +2%

TUR -0.1%, CHL -0.1%, MEX -0.2%

Sweden is top 10: +1.5%

27 / 31

Page 28: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Counterfactual Analysis III

Changes from inception of TAFTA without migration:

average welfare change at country level: +0.6%

Top and bottom three country-level results (welfare):

EST +4.5%, IRL +1.6%, PRT +1.3%

CHE -0.37%, NOR -0.39%, ISL -0.4%

Sweden is still top 10: +0.9%

Comparison:

accounting for migration almost doubles the welfare effects (up to120% difference for single countries!)

28 / 31

Page 29: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Conclusion

Quantitative framework for international trade and migration.

Demand effect of migrants contributes to welfare.

Signing TAFTA would have positive effects for signers.

Migration matters for a welfare analysis of trade cost reductions.

29 / 31

Page 30: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Thank’s a lot for your attention and your comments!

30 / 31

Page 31: International Trade and Migration: A Quantitative Framework · General equilibrium e ects are natural to trade shocks! The interdependence might be interesting especially for (ex-ante)

IntroductionModelData

ResultsReferences

Anderson, J. E., and E. van Wincoop (2003): “Gravity withGravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle,” American EconomicReview, 93(1), 170–192.

Armington, P. S. (1969): “A Theory of Demand for ProductsDistinguished by Place of Production,” Staff Papers - InternationalMonetary Fund, 16(1), 159–178.

Behrens, K., G. Mion, Y. Murata, and J. Sudekum (2011):“Spatial frictions,” CEPR Discussion Papers.

di Giovanni, J., A. Levchenko, and F. Ortega (2012): “A GlobalView of Cross-Border Migration,” .

Gaston, N., and D. R. Nelson (2013): “Bridging Trade Theory andLabour Econometrics: the Effects of International Migration,” Journalof Economic Surveys, 27(1), 98–139.

Grogger, J., and G. H. Hanson (2011): “Income maximization andthe selection and sorting of international migrants,” Journal ofDevelopment Economics, 95(1), 42–57.

Head, K., T. Mayer, and J. Ries (2010): “The erosion of colonialtrade linkages after independence,” Journal of InternationalEconomics, 81(1), 1 – 14.

Head, K., and J. Ries (1998): “Immigration and Trade Creation:Econometric Evidence from Canada,” Canadian Journal of Economics,31(1), 47 – 62.

Heid, B., and M. Larch (2012): “International Trade andUnemployment: A Quantitative Framework,” .

McFadden, D. L. (1974): “Conditional Logit Analysis of QualitativeChoice Behavior,” Frontiers in Econometrics, pp. 105–143.ΩOzden, Parsons, Schiff, and Walmsley

Ozden, C., C. R. Parsons, M. Schiff, and T. L. Walmsley(2011): “Where on Earth is Everybody? The Evolution of GlobalBilateral Migration 1960-2000,” World Bank Economic Review, 25(1),12 – 56.

Redding, S. J. (2012): “Goods Trade, Factor Mobility and Welfare,” .

31 / 31