Information-Based Asset Pricing

download Information-Based Asset Pricing

of 64

Transcript of Information-Based Asset Pricing

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    1/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing

    Dorje C. Brody

    Reader in MathematicsDepartment of Mathematics,

    Imperial College London, London SW7 2BZwww.imperial.ac.uk/people/d.brody

    (Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop)Advanced Mathematical Methods for Finance September, 17th-22nd, 2007: Technische Universitat Wien

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    2/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 2 - 17 September 2007

    1. Information-based pricing framework

    Information-driven asset-price dynamics

    In derivative pricing, the starting point is usually the specification of a model forthe price process of the underlying asset.

    For example, in the Black-Scholes-Merton theory, the underlying asset has ageometric Brownian motion as its price process.

    More generally, the economy is often modelled by a probability space equipped

    with the filtration generated by a multi-dimensional Brownian motion, and it isassumed that asset prices are adapted to this filtration.

    The basic problem with this approach is that the market filtration is fixed, andno comment is offered on the issue of where it comes from.

    In other words, the filtration, which represents the revelation of information tomarket participants, is modelled first, in an ad hoc manner, and then it isassumed that the asset price processes are adapted to it.

    But no indication is given about the nature of this information, and it is not

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    3/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 3 - 17 September 2007

    obvious why the Brownian filtration is providing information rather than noise.

    In a complete market there is a sense in which the Brownian filtration providesno irrelevant information.

    Nevertheless, the notion that the market filtration should be prespecified is anunsatisfactory one in financial modelling.

    What is unsatisfactory about the prespecified-filtration is that little structureis given to the filtration: price movements behave as though they werespontaneous.

    In reality, we expect the price-formation process to exhibit more structure.

    It would be out of place to attempt an account of the process of priceformationnevertheless, we can improve on the prespecified approach.

    In that spirit we proceed as follows.

    We note that price changes arise from two sources.

    The first is that resulting from changes in agent preferencesthat is to say,

    changes in the pricing kernel.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    4/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 4 - 17 September 2007

    Movements in the pricing kernel are associated with (a) changes in investorattitudes towards risk, and (b) changes in investor impatience, the subjective

    discounting of future cash flows.

    Equally important are changes in price resulting from the revelation ofinformation about the future cash flows derivable from a given asset.

    When a market agent decides to buy or sell an asset, the decision is made inaccordance with the information available to the agent concerning the likelyfuture cash flows associated with the asset.

    A change in the information available to the agent about a future cash flow willtypically have an effect on the price at which they are willing to buy or sell, evenif the agents preferences remain unchanged.

    The movement of the price of an asset should, therefore, be regarded as an

    emergent phenomenon.

    To put the matter another way, the price process of an asset should be viewed asthe output of (rather than an input into) the decisions made relating to possibletransactions in the asset, and these decisions should be understood as being

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    5/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 5 - 17 September 2007

    induced primarily by the flow of information to market participants.

    Taking into account this observation we propose a new framework for assetpricing based on modelling of the flow of market information.

    Mathematical framework

    The framework discussed here will be based on modelling the flow of partialinformation to market participants about impending debt obligation and equitydividend payments.

    As usual, we model the financial markets with the specification of a probabilityspace (,F,Q) with filtration {Ft}0t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    6/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 6 - 17 September 2007

    With these conditions the existence of a unique risk-neutral measure is ensured.

    We assume that the default-free discount-bond system, denoted by{PtT}0tT

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    7/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 7 - 17 September 2007

    we have

    St =

    nk=1

    1{t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    8/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 8 - 17 September 2007

    More precisely, we shall assume that the following {Ft}-adapted marketinformation process is accessible to market participants:

    t = tDT + tT. (5)

    Here the process {tT}0tT is a standard Brownian bridge on the interval [0, T].We assume that

    {tT

    }is independent of DT, and thus represents pure noise.

    The Brownian bridge process satisfies 0T = 0, and T T = 0 (see Figure 1).

    We also have E[tT] = 0 and

    E [sTtT] = s(T t)T (6)for all s, t satisfying 0 s t T.The market participants do not have direct access to the bridge process

    {tT

    }.

    That is to say, {tT} is not assumed to be adapted to {Ft}.We can thus think of{tT} as representing the rumour, speculation,misrepresentation, overreaction, and general disinformation often occurring, in

    one form or another, in connection with financial activity.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    9/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 9 - 17 September 2007

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    t

    -1.5

    -1

    -0.5

    0.5

    1

    1.5

    t

    Figure 1: Sample paths for the Brownian bridge over the time period [0, 2].

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    10/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 10 - 17 September 2007

    The parameter represents the rate at which the true value of DT is revealedas time progresses.

    If is low, then the true value of DT is effectively hidden until very near thepayment date of the asset.

    On the other hand, if is high, then DT is revealed quickly.

    On Markovian nature of the information process

    More generally, the rate at which the true value of DT is revealed is not

    constant.

    In that case we will have

    t = DTt

    0

    sds + tT, (7)

    where s 0.When {t} is constant, the resulting information process (5) is Markovian.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    11/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 11 - 17 September 2007

    Along with the fact that DT is FT-measurable we thus find thatE [D

    T|Ft] = E [D

    T|

    t] , (8)

    which simplifies the calculation.

    For the moment we shall assume that t = is constant.

    Determining the conditional expectation

    If the random variable DT that represents the payoff has a continuousdistribution, then the conditional expectation in (8) can be expressed as

    E [DT|t] =

    0

    xt(x) dx. (9)

    Here t(x) is the conditional probability density for the random variable DT:

    t(x) =d

    dx Q(DT x|t). (10)

    We assume appropriate technical conditions on the distribution of the dividendthat will suffice to ensure the existence of the expressions under consideration.

    Also, for convenience we use a notation appropriate for continuous distributions,Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    12/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 12 - 17 September 2007

    though corresponding results can be inferred for discrete distributions, or moregeneral distributions, by a slight modification.

    Bearing these in mind, the conditional probability density process for thedividend can be worked out by use of a form of the Bayes formula:

    t(x) =p(x)(t|DT = x)0 p(x)(t|DT = x)dx. (11)

    Here p(x) denotes the a priori probability density for DT, which we assume isknown as an initial condition, and (t|DT = x) denotes the conditional densityfor the random variable t given that DT = x.

    Since tT is a Gaussian random variable with mean zero and variancet(T t)/T, we deduce that the conditional probability density for t is

    (t|

    DT

    = x) = T2t(T t)

    exp(t tx)2T

    2t(T t) . (12)Inserting this expression into the Bayes formula we get

    t(x) =p(x)exp

    T

    Tt(xt 122x2t)0 p(x)exp TTt(xt 122x2t) dx. (13)Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    13/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 13 - 17 September 2007

    We thus obtain the following result for the asset price:

    The information-based price process{St}0tT of a limited-liability asset thatpays a single dividend DT at time T with a priori distributionQ(DT y) =

    y0

    p(x) dx (14)

    is given by

    St = 1{t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    14/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 14 - 17 September 2007

    Thus in obtaining the dynamics we need to find the stochastic differentialequation of which

    {St

    }is the solution.

    Let us write

    DtT = E[DT|t]. (16)Evidently, DtT can be expressed in the form DtT = D(t, t), where D(, t) is

    defined by

    D(, t) =

    0 xp(x)exp

    T

    Tt(x 122x2t)

    dx

    0 p(x)exp T

    Tt(x 122x2t) dx. (17)

    A straightforward calculation making use of the Ito rules shows that thedynamical equation for {DtT} is given by

    dDtT =T

    T

    t

    Vt 1

    T

    tt T DtTdt + dt . (18)

    Here Vt is the conditional variance of the dividend:

    Vt = Et

    (DT Et[DT])2

    =

    0

    x2t(x) dx

    0

    xt(x) dx

    2. (19)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    15/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 15 - 17 September 2007

    Therefore, if we define a new process {Wt}0t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    16/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 16 - 17 September 2007

    in financial modelling in which {Wt} is regarded on the one hand as noise,and yet on the other hand also generates the market information flow.

    Therefore, instead of hypothesising the existence of a driving process for thedynamics of the markets, we are able to deduce the existence of such a process.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    I fo atio Based Asset P ici 17 17 Se te be 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    17/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 17 - 17 September 2007

    2. Black-Scholes theory from the information perspective

    From cash flow to market factors

    In general the cash flow DT is determined by a number of independent marketfactors (called the X factors):

    DT = D(X1T, X2T, . . . , X nT). (24)

    For each market factor we have the vector-valued information process

    tT = XTt +

    tT, (25)

    which generates the market filtration.

    Log-normal cash flow

    The simplest application of the X-factor technique arises in the case ofgeometric Brownian motion models.

    We consider a limited-liability company that makes a single cash distribution DT

    at time T.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information Based Asset Pricing 18 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    18/64

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 18 - 17 September 2007

    We assume that DT has a log-normal distribution under Q, and thus can bewritten in the form

    DT = S0 exp

    rT + T XT 122T

    , (26)

    where the market factor XT is normally distributed with mean zero and varianceone, and r > 0 and > 0 are constants.

    The information process {t} is taken to be of the formt = tXT + tT, (27)

    where the Brownian bridge

    {tT

    }is independent of XT, and where the

    information flow rate is of the special form

    =1T

    . (28)

    Geometric Brownian motion model

    By use of the Bayes formula we find that the conditional probability density is of

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 19 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    19/64

    Information Based Asset Pricing - 19 - 17 September 2007

    the Gaussian form:

    t(x) = T

    2(T t) exp 12(T t) T x t2

    , (29)

    and has the following dynamics

    dt(x) =1

    T t

    T x

    t t(x)dt. (30)

    A short calculation then shows that the value of the asset at time t < T is

    St = er(Tt)Et[DT]

    = er(Tt)

    S0e

    rT+

    T x12 2Tt(x)dx

    = S0 exp

    rt + t 122t

    . (31)

    The surprising fact in this example is that {t} itself turns out to be theinnovation process.

    Indeed, it is not too difficult to verify that {t} is an {Ft}-Brownian motion.Hence, setting Wt = t for 0 t < T we obtain the standard geometricBrownian motion model:

    St = S0 exp

    rt + Wt 1

    22

    t

    . (32)Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 20 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    20/64

    Information Based Asset Pricing 20 17 September 2007

    We see therefore that starting with an information process of the form (27) weare able to recover the familiar asset price dynamics given by (32).

    Orthogonal decomposition of Brownian motion

    An important point to note here is that the Brownian bridge process {tT}appears quite naturally in this context.

    In fact, if we start with (32) then we can make use of the following orthogonaldecomposition of the Brownian motion:

    Wt =t

    T WT +

    Wt t

    T WT

    . (33)

    The second term in the right, independent of the first term on the right, is astandard representation for a Brownian bridge process:

    tT = Wt t

    T WT. (34)

    Thus by writing

    XT = WT/

    T and = 1/

    T (35)

    we find that the right side of (33) is indeed the market information.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 21 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    21/64

    g p

    In other words, formulated in the information-based framework, the standardBlack-Scholes-Merton theory can be expressed in terms of a normally distributed

    X-factor and an independent Brownian bridge noise process.

    The special feature of the Black-Scholes theory therefore is the fact that theinformation flow rate takes the specific form = 1/

    T.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 22 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    22/64

    3. Application to credit risk management

    Credit derivatives: an information-based approach

    It turns out that the information-based approach has a nice application inmodelling credit risk.

    Models for credit risk management and for the pricing of credit derivatives areusually classified into two types: structural and reduced-form.

    The latter are more commonly used in practice on account of their tractability,

    and the fact that fewer assumptions are required about the nature of the debtobligations involved and the circumstances that might lead to default.

    Most reduced-form models are based on the introduction of a random time ofdefault, where the default time is modelled as the time at which the integral of a

    random intensity process first hits a certain random critical level.

    An unsatisfactory feature of intensity models is that they do not adequately takeinto account the fact that defaults are typically associated with a failure in thedelivery of a promised cash-flowfor example, a missed coupon payment.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 23 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    23/64

    Another drawback of the intensity approach is that it is not well adapted to thesituation where one wants to model the rise and fall of credit spreads.

    The present framework provides a way forward in dealing with these issues.

    The credit model in more detail

    Let us consider the case of a simple credit-risky discount bond that matures attime T to pay a principal of h1 dollars, providing there is no default.

    In the event of default, the bond pays h0 dollars.

    For example we might consider the case h1 = 1 and h0 = 0.

    When just two such payoffs are possible we shall call the resulting structure abinary discount bond.

    Let us write p1 for the probability that the bond will pay h1, and p0 for theprobability that the bond will pay h0.

    The probabilities here are the risk-neutral probabilities, and hence build in any

    risk adjustments required in expectations needed in order to deduce prices.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 24 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    24/64

    If we write B0T for the price at time 0 of the risky discount bond then

    B0T = P0T(p1h1 +p0h0). (36)

    It follows that, providing we know the market data B0T and P0T, we can inferthe a priori probabilities p1 and p0:

    p0 =1

    h1 h0 h1 B0T

    P0T , p1 = 1

    h1 h0 B0T

    P0T h0 . (37)

    Let HT denotes the random payout of the bond.

    The true value of HT, therefore, is not fully accessible until time T.

    That is to say, we assume that HT is FT-measurable, but is not necessarilyFt-measurable for t < T.

    Modelling the flow of informationWe make the reasonable assumption that some partial information regarding thevalue of the principal repayment HT is available at earlier times.

    More precisely, we shall assume that the following {Ft}-adapted marketMathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 25 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    25/64

    information process is accessible to market participants:

    t = HTt + tT. (38)

    Here the process {tT}0tT is a standard Brownian bridge over [0, T],independent of HT, and thus represents pure noise.

    Expression for the price process of a credit-risky bond

    For simplicity, we assume that the only information available about HT at timesearlier than T comes from observations of{t}.

    More specifically, if we denote by Ft Ft the subalgebra ofFt generated by{t}0st, then our assumption is that

    E [HT|Ft] = E

    HT

    Ft

    . (39)

    Now we are in a position to determine the price-process {BtT}0tT for acredit-risky discount bond with payout HT.In particular, we wish to calculate

    BtT = PtTE HTF

    t . (40)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 26 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    26/64

    From the result obtained earlier we see that the conditional expectation

    HtT =E

    HTFt (41)

    can be worked out explicitly.

    The result is given by the following expression:

    HtT =p0h0 exp T

    Tt h0t 122h20t+p1h1 exp TTt h1t 122h21tp0 exp

    T

    Tt

    h0t 122h20t

    +p1 exp

    TTt

    h1t 122h21t

    .(42)The value of the bond at any time t before maturity can be expressed as afunction of the value of t.

    Since {t} is given by a combination of the random bond payoff and anindependent Brownian bridge, this means that it is straightforward to simulatesample trajectories for the bond price process.

    The bond price trajectories will then rise and fall randomly in line with thefluctuating information about the likely final payoff.

    Determining the conditional expectationMathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 27 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    27/64

    Now consider the more general situation where the discount bond pays out thevalue HT = hi (i = 0, 1, . . . , n) with a priori probability Q[HT = hi] = pi.

    For convenience we assume hn > hn1 > > h1 > h0.The case n = 1 then corresponds to the binary bond we have just considered.

    We think of HT

    = hn

    as the case of no default, and all of the other cases asvarious possible degrees of partial recovery.

    Writing t = tHT + tT as before, we want to find the conditional expectationE[HT|Ft ] of the bond payoff.It follows from the Markovian property of{t} that the conditioning withrespect to the -algebra Ft can be replaced by conditioning with respect to t.Therefore, writing

    HtT = E[HT|t] (43)for the conditional expectation of HT given t, we have

    HtT = i

    hiit. (44)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 28 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    28/64

    The process {it} is defined byit = Q(HT = hi

    |t). (45)

    Thus {it} is the conditional probability that the credit-risky bond pays out hi.The a priori probability pi and the a posteriori probability it at time t arerelated by the Bayes formula:

    Q(HT = hi|t) = pi(t|HT = hi)ipi(t|HT = hi)

    . (46)

    Here (|HT = hi) is the conditional density function for the random variable t,given by

    (|HT = hi) =

    T

    2t(T t) expT( thi)

    2

    2t(T t)

    . (47)

    Expression (47) can be deduced from the fact that conditional on HT = hi therandom variable t is normally distributed with mean thi and variancet(T t)/T.As a consequence of (46) and (47), we deduce that the conditional probabilities

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 29 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    29/64

    are

    it =pi exp

    TTt(hit 122h2i t)

    i pi exp

    TTt(hit 122h2i t). (48)It follows that

    HtT = ipihi exp

    T

    Tt

    hit 122h2i t

    i

    pi exp TTt hit

    1

    2

    2h2i t . (49)This is the desired expression for the conditional expectation of the bond payoff.

    The discount-bond price process {BtT} is therefore given byBtT = PtTHtT. (50)

    Defaultable discount bond dynamics

    Let us now proceed to analyse the dynamics of the discount bond price process.

    The key relation we need for determining the dynamics of the bond price processis that the conditional probability {it} satisfies a diffusion equation of the form

    dit =T

    T t(hi

    HtT)itdWt. (51)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 30 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    30/64

    The process {Wt}0t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    31/64

    The absolute bond volatility tT is given by

    tT =

    T

    T tPtTVtT. (54)The process {VtT} appearing here is defined by the relation

    VtT =

    i(hi HtT)2it. (55)

    We see that VtT has the interpretation of being the conditional variance of theterminal payoff HT.

    It should be apparent that as the maturity date is approached the absolute

    discount bond volatility will be high unless the conditional probability has mostof its mass concentrated around the true outcome.

    Simulation of credit-risky bond price processes

    The present framework allows for a very simple and natural simulationmethodology for the dynamics of defaultable bonds and related structure.

    In the case of a defaultable discount bond all we need to do is to simulate the

    dynamics of the process {t}.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 32 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    32/64

    Thus for each run of the simulation we choose at random a value for HT (inaccordance with the correct a priori probabilities), and a sample path for the

    Brownian bridge.

    That is to say, each simulation corresponds to a choice of , and for eachsuch choice we simulate the path

    t() = tHT() + tT() (56)for t [0, T].One way to simulate a Brownian bridge is to write

    tT = Bt tTBT. (57)Here {Bt} is a standard Brownian motion.It is straightforward to verify that if

    {tT

    }is defined in this way then it has the

    correct auto-covariance properties.

    Since the bond price at time t is expressed directly as a function of t, thismeans that a pathwise simulation of the trajectory of the bond price is feasible

    for an arbitrary number of recovery levels.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 33 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    33/64

    1 2 3 4 5

    T

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    BtT

    Figure 2: Examples of sample paths for = 0.04.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 34 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    34/64

    1 2 3 4 5

    T

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    BtT

    Figure 3: Examples of sample paths for = 0.2.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 35 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    35/64

    1 2 3 4 5

    T

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    BtT

    Figure 4: Examples of sample paths for = 1.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 36 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    36/64

    1 2 3 4 5

    T

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    BtT

    Figure 5: Examples of sample paths for = 5.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 37 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    37/64

    Dynamic consistency and model calibration

    The information-based framework exhibits a property that might appropriately

    be called dynamic consistency.

    Loosely speaking, the question is: if the information process is given asdescribed, but then we re-initialise the model at some specified intermediate

    time, is it still the case that the dynamics of the model moving forward from thatintermediate time can be consistently represented by an information process?

    To answer this question we proceed as follows.

    First we define a standard Brownian bridge over the interval [t, T] to be aGaussian process {uT}tuT satisfying tT = 0, T T = 0, E[uT] = 0 for allu [t, T], and

    E[uTvT] = (u t)(T v)/(T t) (58)for all u, v such that t u v T.Let{tT}0tT be a standard Brownian bridge over the interval [0, T], and

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 38 - 17 September 2007

    { }

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    38/64

    define the process{uT}tuT by

    uT = uT T

    u

    T t tT. (59)Then {uT}tuT is a standard Brownian bridge over the interval [t, T], and isindependent of{sT}0st.

    Now let the information process {s}0sT be given, and fix an intermediatetime t (0, T).Then for all u [t, T] let us define a process {u} by

    u = u T

    u

    T t t. (60)We claim that {u} is an information process over the time interval [t, T].In fact, a short calculation establishes that

    u = HT(u t) + uT, (61)where {uT}tuT is a standard Brownian bridge over the interval [t, T],independent of HT, and = T /(T t).

    Thus the original information process proceeds from time 0 up to time t.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 39 - 17 September 2007

    A h i lib h d l b ki f h l f h

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    39/64

    At that time we can re-calibrate the model by taking note of the value of therandom variable t, and introducing the re-initialised information process {u}.The new information process depends on HT; but since the value of t issupplied, the a priori probability distribution for HT now changes to theappropriate a posteriori distribution consistent with the knowledge of t.

    These interpretive remarks can be put into a more precise form as follows.For 0 t u < T we want a formula for the conditional probability iuexpressed in terms of the information u and the new a priori probability it.

    Such a formula exists, and is given as follows:

    iu =it exp

    TtTu

    hiu 122h2i (u t)

    i it exp

    TtTu

    hiu 122h2i (u t)

    . (62)

    This remarkable relation can be verified by substituting the given expressions forit, u, and into the right-hand side of (62).

    But (62) has the same structure as the original formula for it, and thus we seethat the model exhibits manifest dynamic consistency.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 40 - 17 September 2007

    4 P i i d h d i dit d i ti

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    40/64

    4. Pricing and hedging credit derivatives

    Options on credit-risky bonds

    We now turn to consider the pricing of options on credit-risky bonds.

    In the case of a binary bond there is an exact solution for the valuation of

    European-style vanilla options.

    The resulting expression for the option price exhibits a structure that is strikinglyanalogous to that of the Black-Scholes option pricing formula.

    We consider the value at time 0 of an option that is exercisable at a fixed timet > 0 on a credit-risky discount bond that matures at time T > t.

    The value C0 of a call option is

    C0 = P0tE

    (BtT K)+

    , (63)where K is the strike price.

    Inserting formulae (49) and (50) for BtT into the valuation formula (63) for the

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 41 - 17 September 2007

    optio e obtai

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    41/64

    option, we obtain

    C0 = P0tE (PtTHtT K)+

    = P0tE

    n

    i=0

    PtTithi K+

    = P0tE 1

    t

    ni=0

    PtTpithi K+

    = P0tE 1t

    n

    i=0

    PtThi Kpit+

    . (64)Here the random variables pit, i = 0, 1, . . . , n, are the unnormalisedconditional probabilities, defined by

    pit = pi exp

    TT t

    hit 122h2i t

    . (65)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 42 - 17 September 2007

    Then p / where

    p or more explicitly

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    42/64

    Then it = pit/t, where t =

    ipit, or, more explicitly,

    t =

    ni=0

    pi exp T

    T t

    hit 122

    h2i t

    . (66)

    Change of measure techniqueOur plan now is to use the factor 1/t appearing in (64) to make a change ofprobability measure on (,Ft).To this end, we fix a time horizon u at or beyond the option expiration butbefore the bond maturity, so t u < T.We define a process {t}0tu by use of the expression (66), where now we let tvary in the range [0, u].

    It is a straightforward exercise in Ito calculus, making use of (52), to verify that

    dt = 2

    T

    T t2

    H2tTt dt + T

    T t HtTt dWt. (67)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 43 - 17 September 2007

    It follows then that

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    43/64

    It follows then that

    d1t =

    T

    T tHtT

    1t dWt, (68)

    and hence that

    1t = exp

    t0

    T

    T s HsT dWs 12

    2

    t0

    T2

    (T s)2 H2sT ds

    . (69)

    Since {HsT} is bounded, and s u < T, we see that the process {1

    s }0suis a martingale.

    In particular, since 0 = 1, we deduce that EQ[1t ] = 1, where t is the option

    maturity date, and hence that the factor 1/t in (64) can be used to effect a

    change of measure on (,Ft).Writing BT for the new probability measure thus defined, we have

    C0 = P0tEBT n

    i=0

    PtThi Kpit

    +

    . (70)

    We call BT the bridge measure because it has the special property that itmakes {s}0st a BT-Gaussian process with mean zero and covarianceE

    BT

    [rs] = r(T s)/T for 0 r s t.Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 44 - 17 September 2007

    In other words with respect to the measure BT and over the interval [0 t] the

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    44/64

    In other words, with respect to the measure BT, and over the interval [0, t], theinformation process has the law of a standard Brownian bridge over the interval

    [0, T].

    The bridge measure

    The proof that{

    s}0st

    has the claimed properties under the measure BT

    is asfollows.

    For convenience we introduce a process {Wt }0tu which we define as thefollowing Brownian motion with drift in the Q-measure:

    Wt = Wt +

    t

    0

    TT s HsT ds. (71)

    It is straightforward to check that on (,Ft) the process {Wt }0tu is aBrownian motion with respect to the measure defined by use of the density

    martingale {1t }0tu given by (69).It then follows from the definition of{Wt}, given in (52), that

    Wt = t + t

    0

    1

    T ss ds. (72)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 45 - 17 September 2007

    Taking the stochastic differential of each side of this relation we deduce that

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    45/64

    Taking the stochastic differential of each side of this relation, we deduce that

    dt

    =

    1

    T t

    tdt + dW

    t. (73)

    We note, however, that (73) is the stochastic differential equation satisfied by aBrownian bridge over the interval [0, T].

    Thus we see that in the measureB

    T defined on (,Ft) the process {s}0sthas the properties of a standard Brownian bridge over [0, T], albeit restricted tothe interval [0, t].

    For the transformation back from BT to Q on (,

    Ft), the appropriate density

    martingale {t}0tu with respect to BT is given by:t = exp

    t0

    T

    T s HsT dWs 122

    t0

    T2

    (T s)2 H2sT ds

    . (74)

    The crucial point that follows is that the random variable t is BT-Gaussian.

    Options on binary bonds

    In the case of a binary discount bond, therefore, the relevant expectation for

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 46 - 17 September 2007

    determining the option price can be carried out by standard techniques, and we

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    46/64

    determining the option price can be carried out by standard techniques, and weare led to a formula of the Black-Scholes type.

    In particular, for a binary bond, Equation (70) reads

    C0 = P0tEBT

    (PtTh1 K)p1t + (PtTh0 K)p0t

    +, (75)

    where p0t and p1t are given byp0t = p0 exp

    T

    Tt

    h0t 122h20t

    ,

    p1t = p1 exp TTt h1t 12

    2h21t .(76)

    To compute the value of (75) there are essentially three different cases that haveto be considered: (i) PtTh1 > PtTh0 > K, (ii) K > PtTh1 > PtTh0, and (iii)PtTh1 > K > PtTh0.

    In case (i) the option is certain to expire in the money.Thus, making use of the fact that t is BT-Gaussian with mean zero andvariance t(T t)/T, we see that EBT[pit] = pi; hence in case (i) we haveC0 = B0T

    P0tK.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 47 - 17 September 2007

    In case (ii) the option expires out of the money, and thus C0 = 0.

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    47/64

    In case (ii) the option expires out of the money, and thus C0 0.

    In case (iii) the option can expire in or out of the money, and there is acritical value of t above which the argument of (75) is positive.

    This is obtained by setting the argument of (75) to zero and solving for t.

    Writing t for the critical value, we find that t is determined by the relation

    T

    T t(h1 h0)t = lnp0(PtTh0 K)p1(K PtTh1)

    + 12

    2(h21 h20), (77)where = tT /(T t).Next we note that since t is BT-Gaussian with mean zero and variancet(T t)/T, for the purpose of computing the expectation in (75) we can sett = Z

    t(T t)/T, where Z is BT-Gaussian with zero mean and unit variance.

    Then writing

    Z for the corresponding critical value of Z, we obtain

    Z =ln

    p0(PtTh0K)p1(KPtTh1)

    + 1

    22(h21 h20)

    (h1 h0) . (78)

    With this expression at hand, we can work out the expectation in (75).Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 48 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    48/64

    Figure 6: Call price as a function of initial bond price. The parameters are: r = 5%, = 25%, T = 2 year, t = 1 year,and K = 0.6.

    We are thus led to the following option pricing formula:

    C0 = P0t

    p1(PtTh1 K)N(d+) p0(K PtTh0)N(d)

    . (79)

    Here d+

    and d are defined by

    d =ln

    p1(PtTh1K)p0(KPtTh0)

    122(h1 h0)2

    (h1 h0) . (80)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 49 - 17 September 2007

    Greeks

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    49/64

    A short calculation shows that the corresponding option delta, defined by

    = C0/B0T, is given by

    =(PtTh1 K)N(d+) + (K PtTh0)N(d)

    PtT(h1 h0) . (81)This can be verified by using (79) to determine the dependency of the option

    price C0 on the initial bond price B0T.

    It is interesting to note that the parameter plays a role like that of thevolatility parameter in the Black-Scholes model.

    The more rapidly information is leaked out about the true value of the bondrepayment, the higher the volatility.

    It is straightforward to verify that the option price has a positive vega, i.e. that

    C0 is an increasing function of .This means that we can use bond option prices (or, equivalently, caps andfloors) to back out an implied value for , and hence to calibrate the model.

    Writing V= C0/ for the corresponding option vega, we obtain the followingMathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 50 - 17 September 2007

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    50/64

    Figure 7: Delta hedge for a defaultable digital bond option with r = 5%, = 25%, T = 2 year, and K = 0.6.

    positive expression:

    V= 12

    ert12A(h1 h0)

    p0p1(PtTh1 K)(K PtTh0), (82)

    where

    A =1

    2(h1 h0)2

    ln

    p1(PtTh1 K)p0(K PtTh0)

    2+ 14

    2(h1 h0)2. (83)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 51 - 17 September 2007

    Options on general bonds

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    51/64

    In the more general case of a stochastic recovery, a semi-analytic option pricing

    formula can be obtained that, for practical purposes, can be regarded as fullytractable.

    In particular, starting from (70) we consider the case where the strike price Klies in the range P

    tTh

    k+1> K > P

    tTh

    kfor some value of k

    {0, 1, . . . , n

    }.

    It is an exercise to verify that there exists a unique critical value oft such thatthe summation appearing in the argument of the max(x, 0) function in (70)vanishes.

    Writing t for the critical value, which can be obtained by numerical methods,we define the scaled critical value Z as before, by setting t = Z

    t(T t)/T.

    A calculation then shows that the option price is given by the following

    expression:

    C0 = P0t

    ni=0

    pi (PtThi K) N(hi

    Z). (84)

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 52 - 17 September 2007

    5. Volatility and correlation: modelling dependent assets

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    52/64

    y g p

    Market factors and multiple cash flows

    We proceed to consider the more general situation where the asset pays multipledividends.

    This will allow us to consider a wider range of financial instruments.

    Let us write DTk (k = 1, . . . , n) for a set of random dividends paid at thepre-designated dates Tk (k = 1, . . . , n).

    Possession of the asset at time t entitles the bearer to the cash flows occurringat times Tk > t.

    For each value of k we introduce a set of independent random variables XTk( = 1, . . . , mk), which we call market factors or X-factors.

    For each value of we assume that the market factor XTk is FTk-measurable,where {Ft} is the market filtration.For each value of k, the market factors

    {XTj

    }j

    k represent the independent

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 53 - 17 September 2007

    elements that determine the cash flow occurring at time Tk.

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    53/64

    Thus for each value of k the cash flow DTk is assumed to have the following

    structure:

    DTk = Tk(XT1

    , XT2,...,XTk

    ), (85)

    where Tk(XT1

    , XT2,...,XTk

    ) is a function ofkj=1 mj variables.For each cash flow it is, so to speak, the job of the financial analyst (or actuary)to determine the relevant independent market factors, and the form of thecash-flow function Tk for each cash flow.

    With each market factor XTk we associate an information process {tTk}0tTkof the form

    tTk = Tk

    XTkt + tTk

    . (86)

    The X-factors and the Brownian bridge processes are all independent.The parameter Tk determines the rate at which the market factor X

    Tk

    isrevealed.

    The market filtration{Ft}

    is generated by the totality of the independent

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 54 - 17 September 2007

    information processes {tTk}0tTk for k = 1, . . . , n and = 1, . . . , mk.

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    54/64

    Hence, the price of the asset is given by

    St =n

    k=1

    1{t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    55/64

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.60.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.60.8

    1

    0.5 1 1.5 2

    0.2

    0.4

    0.60.8

    1

    Figure 8: Sample paths for a two-factor bond price process, with r = 0%.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 56 - 17 September 2007

    With asset number (i) we associate the cash flows {D(i)Tk} paid at the dates

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    56/64

    k

    {Tk

    }k=1,2,...,n.

    The dates {Tk}k=1,2,...,n are not tied to any specific asset, but rather representthe totality of possible cash-flow dates of any of the given assets.

    If a particular asset has no cash flow on one of the dates, then it is assigned a

    zero cash-flow for that date.

    From this point, the theory proceeds exactly as in the single asset case.

    That is to say, with each value of k we associate a set of X-factors XTk

    ( = 1, 2, . . . , mk), and a system of market information processes {tTk}.

    The X-factors and the information processes are not tied to any particular asset.

    The cash flow D(i)Tk

    occurring at time Tk for asset number (i) is given by a cash

    flow function of the formD

    (i)Tk

    = (i)Tk

    (XT1, XT2

    ,...,XTk). (89)

    In other words, for each asset, each cash flow can depend on all of the X-factorsthat have been activated at that point.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 57 - 17 September 2007

    Thus for the general multi-asset model we have the following price process:n

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    57/64

    S(i)

    t=

    n

    k=1

    1

    {t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    58/64

    1 2 3 4 5t

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    B

    Figure 9: Sample paths for a T-maturity bond price with parameters = 25%, r = 5%, T = 2.5, and T = 5. The cashflows are given by HT = X and HT = XY.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 59 - 17 September 2007

    Origin of unhedgeable stochastic volatility

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    59/64

    Based on the general model introduced here, we are in a position to make an

    observation concerning the nature of stochastic volatility in the equity markets.

    The dynamics of the stochastic volatility can be derived without the need forany ad hoc assumptions.

    In fact, a very specific dynamical model for stochastic volatility is obtainedthusleading to a possible means by which the theory proposed here might be tested.

    We shall work out the volatility associated with the dynamics of the asset priceprocess

    {St}

    given by (87).

    First, as an example, we consider the dynamics of an asset that pays a singledividend DT at T.

    We assume that the dividend depends on the market factors

    {XT

    }=1,...,m.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 60 - 17 September 2007

    For t < T we then have:

    S P EQ X1 Xm 1 m

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    60/64

    St = PtTEQ T X1T, . . . , X mT 1tT, . . . , mtT

    = PtT

    T(x

    1, . . . , xm) 1tT(x1) mtT(xm) dx1 dxm. (91)Here the various conditional probability density functions tT(x) for = 1, . . . , m are

    tT(x) =p(x)exp

    T

    Tt

    x tT 12()2 x2t

    0 p(x)exp

    T

    Tt

    x tT 12()2 x2t

    dx, (92)

    where p(x) denotes the a priori probability density function for the factor XT.

    The drift of{St}0t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    61/64

    tT = T

    T tPtT Cov T X1T, . . . , X mT , XTFt , (94)

    and {Wt } denotes the Brownian motion associated with the informationprocess {t }, as defined in (86).The absolute volatility of

    {St}

    is of the form

    t =

    m

    =1(tT)

    2

    1/2. (95)

    For the dynamics of a multi-factor single-dividend paying asset we can thus write

    dSt = rtStdt + tdZt, (96)

    where the {Ft}-Brownian motion {Zt} that drives the asset-price process is

    Zt =t

    0

    1

    s

    m=1

    sT dW

    s . (97)

    The point to note here is that in the case of a multi-factor model we obtain anunhedgeable stochastic volatility.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 62 - 17 September 2007

    That is to say, although the asset price is in effect driven by a single Brownianmotion its volatility depends on a multiplicity of Brownian motions

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    62/64

    motion, its volatility depends on a multiplicity of Brownian motions.

    This means that in general an option position cannot be hedged with a positionin the underlying asset.

    The components of the volatility vector are given by the covariances of the cash

    flow and the independent market factors.Unhedgeable stochastic volatility thus emerges from the multiplicity of uncertainelements in the market that affect the value of the future cash flow.

    As a consequence we see that in this framework we obtain a natural explanationfor the origin of stochastic volatility.

    This result can be contrasted with, say, the Heston model, which despite itspopularity suffers from the fact that it is ad hoc in nature.

    Much the same can be said for the various generalisations of the Heston modelused in commercial applications.

    The approach to stochastic volatility proposed here is thus of a new character.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007

    Information-Based Asset Pricing - 63 - 17 September 2007

    Expression (93) generalises to the case for which the asset pays a set ofdividends DTk (k = 1, . . . , n) and for each k the dividend depends on the

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    63/64

    dividends DTk (k 1, . . . , n), and for each k the dividend depends on the

    X-factors {{XTj}

    =1,...,mjj=1,...,k }.

    The result can be summarised as follows:

    The price process of a multi-dividend asset has the following dynamics:

    dSt = rt St dt +n

    k=1

    mk=1

    1{t

  • 8/9/2019 Information-Based Asset Pricing

    64/64

    1. D. C. Brody, L. P. Hughston & A. Macrina (2007) Beyond hazard rates: a newframework for credit-risk modelling In Advances in Mathematical Finance,Festschrift volume in honour of Dilip Madan (Birkhauser, Basel).

    2. D. C. Brody, L. P. Hughston & A. Macrina (2007) Information-based approachto asset pricing (Submitted for publication).

    3. D. C. Brody, L. P. Hughston & A. Macrina (2007) Dam rain and cumulativegain (Submitted for publication).

    4. D. C. Brody, L. P. Hughston, A. Macrina & S. Zafeiropoulou (2007) Pricingbarrier options in an information-based framework (Working paper).

    5. M. Rutkowski and N. Yu (2007) An extension of the Brody-Hughston-Macrinaapproach to modelling of defaultable bonds Int. J. Theo. Appl. Fin. 10,

    557-589.

    Mathematical Methods for Finance: Educational Workshop c DC Brody 2007