Industrial dynamics and innovation: progress and challenges · PDF fileIndustrial dynamics and...

download Industrial dynamics and innovation: progress and challenges · PDF fileIndustrial dynamics and innovation: progress and challenges Franco Malerba ... Bojan Jovanovic, ... Jovanovic,1982)

If you can't read please download the document

Transcript of Industrial dynamics and innovation: progress and challenges · PDF fileIndustrial dynamics and...

  • Industrial dynamics and innovation:

    progress and challenges

    Franco Malerba CESPRI - Bocconi University

    Via Sarfatti 25 - 20136 Milan Italy [email protected]

    Presidential Address delivered at the 32nd Conference of the European Association for Research

    in Industrial Economics (EARIE)

    Porto, 1-4 September 2005

    ABSTRACT

    Within the growing field of industrial dynamics, the analysis of innovation has witnessed major progress in several areas. Contributions at the empirical and modelling levels have greater advanced our understanding of innovation within industrial dynamics. The main point of the paper is that in order to have a deeper and clearer view of the relationship between industrial dynamics and innovation, research has to progress on three fronts: the analysis of demand, knowledge and networks.

    I wish to thank Stefano Breschi, Alfonso Gambardella, Francesco Lissoni and Lorenzo Zirulia for useful comments to an earlier draft.

  • 2

    1. Industrial dynamics as a growing research field

    Since the late 1970s industrial dynamics has emerged as a major area of inquiry in industrial

    economics. The analysis of birth, growth and decline of firms and industries and the factors

    affecting them has generated a very rich empirical and theoretical literature. And most of these

    contributions have recognised the central role of innovation for firms and industries.

    In this Address I will start by recognising the major recent growth of research in the area of

    industrial dynamics and then concentrate on the major progresses in the analysis of the relationship

    between industrial dynamics and innovation and on the challenges that lie ahead. In the first part of

    the paper I will discuss the progress, while in the second I will focus on three big research topics

    that I think require in-depth research scrutiny: demand, knowledge and networks.

    In the discussion I will not focus on the literature of transaction costs or on strategic interaction, but

    on the contributions regarding learning, the dynamics of technology and market structure and

    industry evolution. I will place a specific emphasis on a longitudinal perspective, in that it allows to

    focus on sequences of events, changes and feedbacks in industrial dynamics. This perspective is

    very important not only for understanding industrial dynamics, but also for the analysis of the

    broader evolution of markets, as clearly pointed out by the discussion and papers in Geroski-Mata

    (2001).

    2. Industrial dynamics and innovation

    Since the late 1970s, industrial dynamics has emerged as a major research area for industrial

    economists. Pioneering work by Paul Geroski and David Audretsch at the empirical level and by

    Bojan Jovanovic, Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter at the theoretical level have focussed the

    attention of researchers on the way industries change over time and on the dynamics processes of

    entry, selection and growth of firms within industries.

    Within the growing interest in industrial dynamics, innovation has been recognized as a key

    element affecting the dynamics of industries and the rate of entry, survival and growth of firms.

  • 3

    Looking back at the last 25 years, one has to recognise that on this front progress has been indeed

    impressive at both the empirical and the theoretical levels.

    2.1 The empirical contributions

    At the empirical level, since the late 1970s the so-called SPRU tradition has greatly contributed

    to our appreciative understanding of the role of innovation in the evolution of industries, and it has

    shown that the relationship between innovation and industrial change is multidimensional, involves

    several actors and differs greatly across industries (Pavitt,1984, Freeman-Soete,1997, Dosi,1988).

    Innovation in industries has been found to be the result of the interaction of different actors (firms,

    universities, public agencies, financial organizations) which are related both formally as well

    informally and have actions strongly influenced by their competences, learning processes, the

    knowledge base of sectors and institutions. In this frame, the notion of sectoral systems of

    innovation (Malerba,2004) has provided to be a useful tool for examining innovation in a sector.

    Industries have been shown to follow life cycles of innovation, firms entry and growth and changes

    in market structure (Abernathy-Utterback,1978; Utterback,1994). It has also been convincingly

    found that that these dynamic sequences are different from one industry to another (Klepper,1997,

    Geroski,2003).

    In addition, with the availability of advanced computer technology and new firm level data,

    econometric analyses have moved from cross sections work during the 1960s and 1970s to

    longitudinal analyses of industrial dynamics and innovation since the early 1990s. In general, great

    progress has been obtained in identifying, measuring and understanding stylized facts and statistical

    regularities and the factors explaining them: intersectoral diversity in firm size distribution; fat-

    tailedness of corporate growth rates across industries; heterogeneous firm-specific autocorrelation

    profiles with each industry; persistence of profitability, labor productivity and TFP differences

    across firms and across plants within industries at all level of disaggregation. It has been shown

    that market selection does not seem to work effectively particularly in the short and medium-run,

    the time span of the available statistics. Concerning then innovation more specifically, some other

    robust stylized facts and regularities have been identified:

  • 4

    -High within- industry heterogeneity in innovativeness

    Heterogeneity of firms innovativeness has been shown to be quite pervasive and persistent over

    time in spite of competition and selection processes. There is now a very broad set of contributions

    in the industrial dynamics literature that forcefully point to the role of heterogeneity. In most

    industries there are few firms which are responsible for a large number of innovation, and there is a

    core and a fringe of innovators. But there is more than that: heterogeneity concerns also the core

    and the fringe of innovators. This is not just a question of aggregation. As Griliches and Mairesse

    (1997) have clearly stated: The observed variability-heterogeneity does not really decline as we cut

    our data finer and finer. Heterogeneity across firms in innovation means the presence of

    idiosyncratic capabilities (absorptive, technological, etc.) and implies that firms not only do

    different things but, and most importantly, when they do the same thing, they know how to do it in

    different ways.

    This heterogeneity is closely associated to persistence in innovative activity, which is a key

    phenomenon that affect the patterns of innovative activities in a sector (Malerba-Orsenigo-

    Peretto,1997, Cefis,2003). Some of this heterogeneity is related to entry. It has been found that

    the entry process is driven by several factors (Geroski,1995, Bartelsman et al., 2005) and that there

    is a high rate of entry after a technological discontinuity. In particular, new entrants are the vehicles

    for the introduction of new technologies, as Geroski (1995), Audretsch (1995) and Baldwin (1995)

    among others have shown. In any case, entry differs very much also with respect to the type of

    innovation and speed of technological change.

    Heterogeneity in innovativeness is then translated into differential profitability, as documented by

    Geroski-Machin-Van Reenen (1993), while the impact of innovation on corporate growth is still a

    matter for deep empirical scrutiny, with a less straightforward relationship for firm level data than

    for plant level data (Baldwin,1995). Actually in some specific industries, such the international

    pharmaceutical industry, econometric evidence shows that dynamics is driven by the introduction

    of few major innovations, which create new markets, and by imitation. In this industry innovative

    firms do not grow more than the other firms. Rather there is a coexistence of quite heterogeneous

    innovators (Bottazzi et al.,2001)

    - Major inter-sectoral differences in the rate of technical change, market structure and organization

    of innovative activity

  • 5

    It has been shown that sectors differ greatly not only in terms of rate of innovation, but also of

    market structure and organization of innovative activities. Work at the patent level has found

    stylized and robust differences across sectors. In some in sectors innovative activities are

    concentrated in a few firms, stability of innovators is relevant and new innovators are rare. In other

    sectors patterns of innovation are distributed across a wide population of firms, with a high

    turbulence in innovative activity, and new innovators coming from every quarter. These two

    different models of organization of innovative activities, which could be labelled Schumpeter Mark

    II and Schumpeter Mark I, have been found in several industries and are quite robust for the same

    industry across countries (Malerba-Orsenigo,1995, 1997). These findings can be related to the old

    stylized fact concerning major inter-industry differences in concentration (see Schmalensee,1989)