Immigration and Economic Growth - Harvard University · 2019. 11. 12. · Immigration and Economic...

51
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMMIGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH George J. Borjas Working Paper 25836 http://www.nber.org/papers/w25836 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 May 2019 This paper was first presented at the “Prospects for Economic Growth Conference” held at Rice University’s Baker Institute in December 2018 and will be published in Prospects for Economic Growth in the United States, edited by John W. Diamond and George R. Zodrow (Oxford University Press). The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2019 by George J. Borjas. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

Transcript of Immigration and Economic Growth - Harvard University · 2019. 11. 12. · Immigration and Economic...

  • NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES

    IMMIGRATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH

    George J. Borjas

    Working Paper 25836http://www.nber.org/papers/w25836

    NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH1050 Massachusetts Avenue

    Cambridge, MA 02138May 2019

    This paper was first presented at the “Prospects for Economic Growth Conference” held at Rice University’s Baker Institute in December 2018 and will be published in Prospects for Economic Growth in the United States, edited by John W. Diamond and George R. Zodrow (Oxford University Press). The views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

    NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications.

    © 2019 by George J. Borjas. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

  • Immigration and Economic GrowthGeorge J. BorjasNBER Working Paper No. 25836May 2019JEL No. J6,O4

    ABSTRACT

    Immigration is sometimes claimed to be a key contributor to economic growth. Few academic studies, however, examine the direct link between immigration and growth. And the evidence on the outcomes that the literature does examine (such as the impact on wages or government receipts and expenditures) is far too mixed to allow unequivocal inferences. This paper surveys what we know about the relationship between immigration and growth. The canonical Solow model implies that a one-time supply shock will not have any impact on steady-state per-capita income, while a continuous supply shock will permanently reduce per-capita income. The observed relationship between immigration and growth obviously depends on many variables, including the skill composition of immigrants, the rate of assimilation, the distributional labor market consequences, the size of the immigration surplus, the potential human capital externalities, and the long-term fiscal impact. Despite the methodological disagreements about how to measure all of these effects, there is a consensus on one important point: Immigration has a more beneficial impact on growth when the immigrant flow is composed of high-skill workers.

    George J. BorjasHarvard Kennedy School79 JFK StreetCambridge, MA 02138and [email protected]

  • 3

    ImmigrationandEconomicGrowth

    GeorgeJ.Borjas*

    From1990to2014,U.S.economicgrowthwouldhavebeen15percentagepointslowerwithoutthebenefitofmigration.

    --CitiResearch(2018)

    There’sawayforPresidentTrumptoboosttheeconomybyfourpercent,butheprobablywon’tlikeit…Forevery1percentincreaseinU.S.populationmadeofimmigrants,GDPrises1.15percent.SoasimplewaytogettoTrump’s4percentGDPbump?Takeinabout8millionnetimmigrantsperyear.

    --ProPublica(2017)1.Introduction

    Therehasbeenaworldwidesurgeininternationalmigrationinrecentdecades.In

    theU.S.context,theimmigrantshareofthepopulationalmosttripledfromahistoriclowof

    4.7percentin1970to13.7percentby2017.

    Itissometimesclaimedthattheimmigrationsurgehasbeenakeycontributorto

    economicgrowth,andthatanevenlargernumberofimmigrantswouldincreaseour

    nationalwealthevenmore—althoughtheseclaimstendtoappearinreportsproducedby

    thinktanks,policyadvocates,andbusinessassociations.Infact,fewacademicstudies

    documentthedirectlinkbetweenimmigrationandgrowth.Andtheevidenceonthe

    outcomesthatthestudiesdoexamine(suchastheimpactonwages,employment,and

    governmentreceiptsandexpenditures)isfartoomixedandunsettledtojustifyblanket

    *RobertW.ScrivnerProfessorofEconomicsandSocialPolicy,HarvardKennedySchool;and

    ResearchAssociate,NationalBureauofEconomicResearch.Thispaperwasfirstpresentedatthe“ProspectsforEconomicGrowthConference”heldatRiceUniversity’sBakerInstituteinDecember2018andwillbepublishedinProspectsforEconomicGrowthintheUnitedStates,editedbyJohnW.DiamondandGeorgeR.Zodrow(OxfordUniversityPress).

  • 4

    statementsthatimmigrationaccountsforasubstantialpartofeconomicgrowth(or,

    conversely,thatitdoesnotcontributetoeconomicgrowthatall).

    Despitetherelativescarcityofcredibleresearchonthelinkbetweenimmigration

    andgrowth,thereisnodoubtthatimmigrantscontributesignificantlytoaggregateoutput.

    In2016,16.6percentofworkersintheU.S.labormarketwereforeign-born.Thelarge

    immigrantpresenceintheworkforceinevitablyimpliesthatforeign-bornlaborwas

    directlyresponsibleforasizablefractionofGDP.And,bydefinition,theimmigrationsurge

    musthaveledtoacorrespondinglylargeincreaseinGDP.Itisfarlessclear,however,that

    theimmigrantsupplyshocknecessarilyincreasedper-capitaincome.

    Thispaperpresentsatheoreticalandempiricalsurveyofwhatitisthatweknow

    aboutthelinkbetweenimmigrationandeconomicgrowth.ThecanonicalSolowgrowth

    modelhasstrikingimplicationsaboutwhathappensastheeconomyadjuststosupply

    shocks.Aone-timesupplyshockincreasesoutputanddecreasesper-capitaincomeinthe

    shortrun.Astheeconomyadjusts,therewillberelativelyrapid“catch-up”growth.Inthe

    end,however,per-capitaincomeendsupinexactlythesamesteadystatethatwouldhave

    beenobservedhadtherebeennoimmigration.Incontrast,apermanentincreaseinthe

    rateofgrowthoftheworkforceduetoapersistentimmigrantflowwillleadtoincreased

    outputbutatapermanentlylowerper-capitaincome.

    Iusetheseinsightstoframethediscussionofwhateconomicshastosayabout

    immigrationandgrowth.Thelinkobviouslydependsonmanyvariables,includingthe

    skillsthatimmigrantsbringtothecountry;therateatwhichimmigrantsbecomemore

    productive(whichistypicallythoughtofas“economicassimilation”);theimpactof

    immigrationontheemploymentopportunitiesofnativeworkers;theimpactimmigrants

  • 5

    haveonthetotalincomeaccruingtothepre-existingpopulation(i.e.,the“immigration

    surplus”);andthefiscalimpactofimmigration,asmeasuredbyacomparisonofthetaxes

    immigrantspaywiththecostoftheservicestheyreceive.Thenetimpactofimmigrationon

    economicgrowthwilldependonthedirectionandmagnitudeofalloftheseeffects.

    Despitetheuncertaintyaboutthemeasurementofeachoftheseeffects,thereisa

    consensusononeimportantpoint:Immigrationhasamorebeneficialimpactwhenthe

    immigrantinfluxiscomposedofhigh-skillworkers.Intheend,thereislittledoubtabout

    thetypeofimmigrationpolicyacountryshouldpursueifitwishedtouseimmigrationasa

    tooltospurgrowth:Admithigh-skillimmigrants.(Althoughtheliteratureistotallysilent

    onjusthowmanyhigh-skillimmigrantsshouldbeadmitted).Thereis,however,an

    importantnormativequestionthateconomics—andeconomists—cannotanswer:Should

    spurringeconomicgrowthbethesoleobjectiveofimmigrationpolicy?

    2.ImmigrationintheSolowModel

    Itisusefultofixideasbyillustratingthelinkbetweenimmigrationandgrowthin

    thecanonicalSolowmodel(BarroandSala-i-Martin,1999).Themodelissummarizedby:

    𝑌" = (𝐾")'(𝐴"𝐿")*+', (1)

    𝐾"̇ = 𝑠𝑌" − 𝛿𝐾", (2)

    𝐿" = 𝐿4𝑒6", (3)

    𝐴" = 𝐴4𝑒8". (4)

    Equation(1)givesthelinearhomogeneousCobb-Douglasproductionfunctionwhere

    Ytdenotesoutputattimet;Ktthecapitalstock;and(AtLt)thenumberofefficiencyunitsin

    thelabormarket,withAtbeingtheefficiencyparameterandLtthenumberofworkers.

    Equation(2)givestheequationofmotionforthecapitalstock,withconstantsavingsrates

  • 6

    anddepreciationrated.Finally,equations(3)and(4)specifythatthenumberofworkers

    growsatrategandtheefficiencyofaworkergrowsatrateh.

    Letktdenotethe“effective”capital-laborratio,Kt/AtLt.Incomeperefficiencyunit

    (whichisnotobserved)canbewrittenas:

    𝑦" =𝑌"𝐴"𝐿"

    = 𝑘"', (5)

    whiletheobservedper-capitaincome𝑦>"is:

    𝑦>" =𝑌"𝐿"= 𝐴"𝑘"' (6)

    Finally,thewage(w)andtherentalrateofcapital(r)attimetaregivenbythe

    marginalproductivityconditions:

    𝑤" = (1 − 𝛼)𝐴"𝑘"', (7)

    𝑟" = 𝛼𝑘"'+*. (8)

    Equation(2)canberewrittenintermsoftheeffectivecapital-laborratioas�̇� =

    𝑠𝑦" − (𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔)𝑘" .Thisimpliesthatthesteady-stateeffectivecapital-laborratiois:

    𝑘∗ = I𝑠

    𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔JK

    KLM. (9)

    Notethattherentalrateofcapitalisconstantinthesteadystate.Iflaborefficiencyis

    increasingatrateh>0,however,boththewageandper-capitaincomewillalsoincreaseat

    ratehinthesteadystate.

    Supposetheeconomyisinsteadystate,andimmigrationproducesaone-time

    increaseinthesizeoftheworkforce.Considerthespecialcasewherethesizeofthe

    workforcewasconstantpriortothesupplyshock(g=0).Aone-timeinfluxofimmigrants

    whoareperfectsubstituteswithpre-existingworkerscanthenbemodeledasasimple

  • 7

    shiftinL.Theone-timesupplyshockproducesanimmediatedropintheeffectivecapital-

    laborratio(whichinturn,increasestherentalrateofcapitalandreducesthewage).It

    followsthattheimmediateimpactonoutputandper-capitaincomearegivenby:

    𝜕𝑌"𝜕𝐿

    = (1 − 𝛼)𝑦>" > 0, (10)

    𝜕𝑦>"𝜕𝐿

    = 𝛼𝐴"𝑘"'+*𝜕𝑘"𝜕𝐿

    < 0, (11)

    Theone-timesupplyshocktriviallyincreasesGDP(moreworkersproducemoreoutput).

    Butthesupplyshockreducesper-capitaincomeintheshortrun.

    Thisshort-rundropisattenuatedastheeconomyadjuststothelargerworkforce.

    Thedeclineinthecapital-laborratioincreasestherateofreturntocapital,inducingan

    increaseinthecapitalstock.Asequation(9)shows,however,thesteadystateeffective

    capital-laborratiodoesnotdependonthesizeoftheworkforce.Asaresult,theone-time

    supplyshockdoesnotchangethesteadystatelevelofper-capitaincome:

    𝜕𝑦>∗

    𝜕𝐿= 0. (12)

    Oncethesteady-stateequilibriumisreestablished,theeconomyhasalargerGDP,andper-

    capitaincomecontinuestogrowatthesamerateh.1

    Themodelcanalsobeusedtoanalyzetheimpactofacontinuoussupplyshock,

    whichcanbemodeledasanincreaseing,therateofgrowthinthesizeoftheworkforce.

    Thispersistentshockhaslong-termconsequences.Equation(9)impliesthatitreducesthe

    steadystateleveloftheeffectivecapital-laborratio(¶k*/¶g<0).Itthenfollowsthat:

    1Thetransitionaldynamicsaftertheone-timeshockareinteresting.Per-capitaincomewasgrowing

    ataconstantrateofhpriortotheshock.Aftertheshock(andbeforetheeconomyisre-equilibrated),thegrowthrateincreasesto(η + 𝛼�̇�/𝑘),where�̇� > 0.Thegrowthspurtisshort-lived.Itonlyreflectsthattheshockimmediatelyreducedper-capitaincomeandtheeconomyisrevertingtotheoriginalsteadystate.

  • 8

    𝜕𝑦>∗

    𝜕𝑔 = 𝛼𝐴"𝑘"'+* 𝜕𝑘

    𝜕𝑔 < 0,(13)

    Inshort,apersistentimmigrantflowpermanentlyreducesper-capitaincome.

    AnaugmentedversionoftheSolowmodel(Mankiw,Romer,andWeil,1992;Dolado,

    Goria,andIchino,1994)canbeusedtoderivetheimplicationsifimmigrantsalsoincrease

    thecountry’shumancapitalstock(H).Thelinearhomogeneousproductionfunctioninthe

    augmentedmodelistypicallywrittenas:

    𝑌" = (𝐾")'(𝐻")V(𝐴"𝐿")*+'+V, (14)

    andtheequationsofmotionforthephysicalandhumancapitalstocksare:

    𝐾"̇ = 𝑠W𝑌" − 𝛿𝐾", (15)

    𝐻"̇ = 𝑠X𝑌" − 𝛿𝐻" + 𝑀"𝜋 I𝐻"𝐿"J , (16)

    wheresKandsHarethe(constant)investmentratesforphysicalandhumancapital,

    respectively;thedepreciationratedisassumedtobethesameforbothtypesofcapital;Mt

    isthenetnumberofimmigrants;andpmeasurestherelativecontributionofanimmigrant

    tothehumancapitalstock.Theimmigrantisasskilledasapre-existingworkerifp=1.

    Thechangeinthenumberofworkersis𝐿"̇ = 𝑔𝐿" + 𝑀" .Supposethatthenumberof

    immigrantsincreasesatthesamerateasthenativepopulation,sothatthenetmigration

    ratem=Mt/Ltisconstant.Theworkforcethengrowsatconstantrate(g+m),andthe

    equationsofmotionfortheeffectivecapital-laborratiosaregivenby:

    �̇� = 𝑠W𝑦" − [𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 +𝑚]𝑘", (17)

    ℎ̇ = 𝑠X𝑦" − [𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 + (1 − 𝜋)𝑚]ℎ". (18)

    Thesteadystateisdefinedby�̇� = 0andℎ̇ = 0.Theeffectivecapital/laborratiosin

    thesteadystateare:

  • 9

    𝑘∗ = I𝑠W

    𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 +𝑚JKL_

    KLML_I

    𝑠X𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 + (1 − 𝜋)𝑚J

    _KLML_

    , (19)

    ℎ∗ = I𝑠W

    𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 +𝑚J

    MKLML_

    I𝑠X

    𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 + (1 − 𝜋)𝑚J

    KLMKLML_

    . (20)

    Thesteadystatecapital-laborratiosinequations(19)and(20)areconstant.Asa

    result,effectiveper-capitaincome(givenby𝑦 = 𝑘'ℎV)willalsobeconstant.Incontrast,

    actualper-capitaincome(𝑦> = 𝐴𝑘'ℎV)willstillgrowatarateofh(aswasthecaseinthe

    simplerversionoftheSolowmodel).

    Equations(19)-(20)implythatimmigrationalterssteady-stateper-capitaincome:

    𝜕 log 𝑦>∗

    𝜕𝑚= −

    𝛼(1 − 𝛼 − 𝛽)𝐶

    −𝛽

    (1 − 𝛼 − 𝛽)𝐷[1 − 𝜋], (21)

    where𝐶 = [𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 +𝑚];and𝐷 = [𝛿 + 𝜂 + 𝑔 + (1 − 𝜋)𝑚] > 0.Per-capitaincomewill

    certainlydeclineifp£1(acaserelevantfortherecentU.S.contextwithhighnumbersof

    low-skillimmigrants).Infact,thediminishingmarginalproductivityoflaborimpliesthat

    per-capitaincomemightfallevenifimmigrantsarerelativelymoreskilled(withpbeing

    slightlyabove1).Equation(21)showsthatimmigrationcanspurlong-termgrowthonlyif

    theinfluxisveryskilled,withsufficientlyhighvaluesofp.

    AnimportantlessonfromthisbriefoverviewoftheSolowmodelisthatpersistent

    immigrationwilloftenreduceper-capitaincomeinthesteadystate,particularlywhenthe

    immigrantsareperfectsubstitutesorlessskilledthanthenatives.Immigrationmayspur

    long-termgrowthonlyifthesupplyshockiscomposedofveryhighlyskilledworkers.In

    fact,suchasupplyshockcouldincreaseper-capitaincomesbyfarmorethanthemodel

    suggestsiftheimmigrantsalsoproducehumancapitalexternalitiesthatpermanently

    increasetheproductivityofnativeworkers.

  • 10

    3.ImmigrationandGDP:Evidence

    Despitethecontentiouspolicydebateoverimmigration,onlyahandfulofstudies

    studytheempiricallinkbetweenimmigrationandlong-termgrowth.2Hence,itisusefulto

    beginbyillustratingtherelationshipbetweenGDPandimmigrationtrendsintheUnited

    States.

    Eachdecennialcensussince1850reportsthenumberofforeign-bornpersons,

    allowingthecalculationofnetimmigrationineachdecade.Definethenetmigrationratein

    thedecadebetweenyearstandt+10asthenetnumberofimmigrantsarrivinginthat

    decadedividedbythepopulationattimet.Forexpositionalconvenience,Imultiplythenet

    migrationrateby100sothatitgivesthenumberofnewimmigrantsper100persons.As

    Figure1shows,therehavebeenperiodsofveryhighandofverylowimmigration.Between

    1900and1910andbetween1990and2000,thenetmigrationratewasabout4persons

    perdecade.Incontrast,thenetmigrationratewasnegativebetween1930and1970.

    Thetwopanelsofthefigurealsoshowthedecadalrateofchangein(real)GDPand

    inper-capitaGDP.Itisvisuallyobviousthatthesimplecorrelationimpliedbythehistorical

    recorddoesnotsuggestthattherewasmorerapideconomicgrowthduringthoseperiods

    ofhighimmigration.Infact,theslopeofaregressionthatrelatestherateofchangeinGDP

    2SeeBoubtane,Dumont,andRault(2016),Dolado,Goria,andIchino(1994)andKaneandRutledge

    (2018).RelatedworkbyPeri(2012)correlatesimmigrationwithtotalfactorproductivity(TFP),whereTFPisaresidualfromaregressionthatlinksstate-levelGDPtothesizeoftheworkforceandmeasuresofthecapitalstock.ItisparticularlydifficulttointerpretthecorrelationbetweenTFPandimmigrationasmuchdependsontheregressionspecification,andonwhatexactlyisincludedandleftoutofthefirst-stageregression.

  • 11

    tothenetmigrationrateis0.008(withastandarderrorof0.014),whiletherespective

    coefficientintheper-capitagrowthregressionis-0.010(0.012).

    Obviously,theseweakcorrelationsdonotprovetheabsenceofacausallink

    betweenimmigrationandgrowth.Therearefartoomanyotherfactorsthatinfluencethe

    evolutionofeconomicoutputandFigure1doesnotcontrolforanyofthesefactors.Itis

    possible,however,toexaminethecausalrelationshipbylinkingtrendsinstate-level

    economicgrowthandimmigrationduringthe1960-2017period.

    Specifically,Iusethedecadalcensusdatatocalculatetheimmigrantshareinthe

    workforceofeachstaterattimetandestimatetheregressionmodel:3

    log 𝑦f" = 𝜃f + 𝜃" + 𝛽𝑝f" + 𝛾ℎf" + 𝜖, (22)

    whereyrtisameasureoftheGrossStateProduct(GSP)instaterattimet;qrandqt

    representvectorsofstateandyearfixedeffects,respectively;prtgivestheratioofthe

    numberofworkingimmigrantstothesizeoftheworkforceinthestate(´100);andhrt

    measuresthehumancapitalofthestate’sworkforce(whichIproxybythelogmeanyears

    ofeducationandbythefractionofworkersaged25and54).

    ThetoppanelofTable1reportsthecoefficientsestimatedbyordinaryleast

    squares.Thereisapositive(andsignificant)correlationbetweenimmigrationandGSP

    acrossstatesandovertime.Anincreaseintheimmigrantshareof1percentisassociated

    witha3.2percentincreaseinGSP.Note,however,thatthecoefficientbecomesinsignificant

    whentheregressionusesper-capitaGSPasthedependentvariable.

    3KaneandRutledge(2018)conductasimilaranalysisforthe1980-2015period.Thepanelusedin

    Table1consistsofsevencross-sections(1960,1970,1980,1990,2000,2010,and2017)and50states(theDistrictofColumbiaisexcludedfromtheregressions).Ialsoestimatedtheregressionsusingafirst-differencespecification.Theresultsarequalitativelysimilartothosereportedbelow.

  • 12

    Theregressionmodelinequation(22),whichisexactlyanalogoustothepanel

    regressiontypicallyestimatedtomeasurethewageimpactofimmigration(Borjas,2014),

    suffersfrompotentialendogeneitybias.Income-maximizingimmigrantswilllikelysettlein

    statesthatoffervibranteconomicconditions,buildinginapositivecorrelationbetweenyrt

    andprt.ThebottompanelofTable1reportsthecoefficientsestimatedfromIVregressions

    thatusethegeneric“shift-share”instrumenttocontrolfortheendogeneity(Card,2001).

    Inparticular,Iusedthe1960censustoobservethegeographicsettlementof

    immigrantswhooriginatedinaparticularcountry.Thekeyassumptionoftheshift-share

    instrumentisthatthisinitialgeographicdistributioninfluencesthesettlementoflater

    wavesofimmigrantsfromthatsamecountry.Futureimmigrantswillfinditcheaperto

    settleinthosepartsofthecountrywhereethnicnetworksfacilitatethemove.Theshift-

    shareinstrumentusesthe1960geographicdistributiontogeographicallyallocatethe

    immigrantsfromthatcountryobservedinasubsequentcross-sectiont.Thepredicted

    numberofimmigrantslivinginstaterattimetisthenobtainedbyaddingupacross

    countriesoforigin,andthispredictionisusedtocalculatethepredictedfractionof

    immigrantsintheworkforce.Note,however,thatiftheeconomicconditionsthatinduced

    the1960immigrantstosettleinparticularstatespersistovertime,theshift-share

    instrumentdoesnotsolvetheendogeneityproblem(Jaeger,Ruist,andStuhler,2018).

    TheIVestimatesofthe“causal”linkbetweenimmigrationandGDPreportedin

    Table1areagainpositiveforthelevelofGSPbutturnnegative(andinsignificant)when

    lookingatper-capitaGSP.Aone-pointincreaseintheimmigrantshareisassociatedwitha

    1.9percentincreaseinGSP,andwitha0.7percentdecreaseinper-capitaGDP.

  • 13

    Theprudentinferencefromtheexercisesreportedinthissectionseemstobethat

    thecorrelationbetweenimmigrationandper-capitaincomeis,atbest,zero.Thedatado

    notprovideanysupportforthehypothesisthatthetwovariablesarestronglyand

    positivelycorrelated,eitherhistoricallyoracrossregions.Itseemsthatafindingofstrong

    positiveeffectswillrequiremuchmoredatamanipulation(andmanymoreassumptions).

    4.TheImmigrationSurplus

    Thenegativeshort-runimpactofimmigrationonwagesandthepositiveimpacton

    thereturntocapitalimplythatimmigrationhasdistributionalconsequences.Theyalso

    raisethepossibilitythatthegainstofirmsexceedthelossestoworkers,andtheremightbe

    animmigrationsurplus,anetincreaseinthewealthofthe“native”population.

    Thesimplestmodeloftheimmigrationsurplusassumesthatimmigrantsand

    nativesareperfectsubstitutes(Borjas,1995).TheworkforcehasNnativeandMimmigrant

    workers,withL=N+M.TheaggregateproductionfunctionY=f(K,L)islinear

    homogeneous.Supposefurtherthatnativesownthecapitalstockandthatthesuppliesof

    bothnativesandimmigrantsareperfectlyinelastic.

    Eachfactorpriceequalstherespectivevalueofmarginalproductinacompetitive

    labormarket.Therentalrateofcapitalinthepre-immigrationequilibriumisr0=fK(K,N)

    andthepriceoflaborisw0=fL(K,N),whereoutputpriceisthenumeraire.Linear

    homogeneityimpliesthattheentireoutputisdistributedtotheownersofcapitalandto

    workers.Inthepre-immigrationregime,thenationalincomeaccruingtonatives,YN,is

    givenbyYN=r0K+w0N.

  • 14

    Figure2illustratesthisinitialequilibrium.ThevalueofYNisgivenbytheareaunder

    themarginalproductoflaborcurvefL,ortrapezoidABN0.Intheshortrun,thecapitalstock

    isfixed.TheentryofMimmigrantsshiftsthesupplycurveandlowersthewagetow1.The

    areainthetrapezoidACL0givesnationalincomeinthepost-immigrationeconomy.Partof

    theincreaseinnationalincomegoestoimmigrants(whoearnw1Mdollar).Theareainthe

    triangleBCDgivestheimmigrationsurplus,theincreaseinincomethataccruestonatives.

    Theimmigrationsurplus,asafractionofnationalincome,approximatelyequals:

    Δ𝑌l𝑌 = −

    12 𝑠m𝜀𝑝

    o, (23)

    wheresLislabor’sshareofincome(sL =wL/Y);eisthewageelasticity(e=dlogw/dlogL);

    andpistheimmigrantshareoftheworkforce(p=M/L).

    Equation(23)givesasimpleformulafordoinga“back-of-the-envelope”calculation

    (summarizedinTable2).Theshareoflaborincomehashoveredaround70percentfor

    sometime,andthefractionofimmigrantsintheworkforceis16.6percent.Supposefurther

    thatthelinearhomogeneousproductionfunctionisCobb-Douglas.Itistheneasytoshow

    thattheabsolutevalueofthewageelasticityeequalscapital’sshareofincome,orabout

    0.3.Theimmigrationsurplusisthen0.29percentofGDP.In2017,GDPwas$19.5trillion,

    sothattheshort-runimmigrationsurplusisabout$56billionayear,arelativelysmall

    numberinthecontextofaverylargeeconomy.

    Figure2showsthatimmigrationredistributesincomefromlabortocapital.Native

    workerslosetheareaintherectanglew0BDw1,andthisquantityplusthesurplusaccrues

    toemployers.Table2alsoreportstheimplieddollarvalueoftheselossesandgains(see

    Borjas,1995,foralgebraicdetails).Native-bornworkersloseabout2.9percentofGDP,

  • 15

    whilenative-ownedcapitalgainsabout3.2percentofGDP.The$19.5trillionGDPimplies

    thatworkerslose$567billionwhileemployersgain$623billion.Thesmallsurplusof$56

    billionmasksasizableredistributionfromworkerstotheusersofimmigrantlabor.

    Notethattheimmigrationsurplus,whichmeasuresthedollargainsaccruingto

    “natives,”isconceptuallydifferentfromthetotalincreaseinGDP.AsTable2alsoshows,a

    supplyshockthatincreasedtheworkforcebyalmost17percentgeneratedaverysizable

    increaseinGDP,ofover$2trillion.Almostallofthisincrease,however,goestothe

    immigrantsthemselvesaspaymentsfortheirservices.

    Finally,theshort-runsurplusderivedinFigure2assumedthatcapitalwasfixed.

    Theriseinthereturnstocapitalencouragescapitalinflowsuntiltherentalrateisagain

    equalizedacrossmarkets.Theassumptionofconstantreturnsimpliesthattheexpansionin

    thecapitalstockreestablishesthepre-immigrationcapital/laborratio.Intheend,

    immigrationdoesnotalterthepriceoflabororthereturnstocapital,andnativesneither

    gainnorlosefromimmigration.Inthelongrun,theimmigrationsurplusmustbezero.

    HeterogeneousLabor

    Figure2assumednativesandimmigrantsareperfectsubstitutes.Theremayexist

    productioncomplementaritiesbetweenthetwogroupsthatcanincreasethegains.

    Supposetherearetwotypesofworkers,low-skill(LU)andhigh-skill(LH).Thelinear

    homogeneousproductionfunctionisnowY=f(K,LU,LH).Supposefurtherthesupplyshock

    isnot“balanced”acrossskillgroups(i.e.,immigrantsarepredominantlylow-skillorhigh-

    skill).Thelong-termadjustmentinthecapitalstockwouldnotleadtoanewequilibrium

  • 16

    withtheeconomysimplyoperatingataproportionatelyhigherscaleforallinputs.4The

    potentialcomplementaritiesbetweenimmigrantsandnativeswouldhelpproducealarger

    immigrationsurplus.

    Notsurprisingly,capital-skillcomplementaritysuggeststhattheshort-runsurplus

    mightbelargeriftheimmigrantflowwascomposedofhigh-skillworkers.Byassumption,

    nativesownthecapitalstockandcapital-skillcomplementarityimpliesthatthereturnsto

    capitalincreasemorewhenimmigrantsarehigh-skill.Infact,simulationsofthemodel

    suggestthatestimatesoftheshort-runimmigrationsurplusmightdoubleiftheUnited

    Statesadmittedonlyhigh-skillimmigrants(Borjas,2014,p.158).However,thelong-run

    capitaladjustmentswouldattenuatetheimportanceofcapital-skillcomplementarityand

    greatlyreducethegainsfromhigh-skillsupplyshocks.

    HumanCapitalExternalities

    Thecalculationoftheimmigrationsurpluswithalinearhomogeneousproduction

    functionsuggeststhatevenalargesupplyshockofhigh-skillworkersmaynotgenerate

    relativelylargegainsforthenativepopulation.Nevertheless,thereisawidespread(and

    unshakeable)perceptionthatsometypesofimmigration,andparticularlytheimmigration

    ofhigh-skillworkers,canbehugelybeneficial.Thisperceptionreliesonacrucialdeparture

    fromthetextbookmodel,thebeliefthathigh-skillimmigrantsgeneratehumancapital

    4Inthehomogeneouslaborcase,anincreaseofxpercentinthenumberofworkersinducesanx

    percentincreaseinthecapitalstocksothatthelong-runequilibriumhastheeconomyoperatingatalargerscalewiththesameproportionateincreaseincapital,labor,andoutput.Intheheterogeneouslaborcasewithanunbalancedsupplyshock,theinputratioswouldbedifferentinthepre-andpost-shockequilibriums.

  • 17

    externalities.Thesuddenpresenceofhigh-skillimmigrantsexposesnativestonewforms

    ofknowledge,increasestheirhumancapital,andmakesthemmoreproductive.

    Itiseasytoillustratehowexternalitieschangetheimmigrationsurplus.Ifhigh-skill

    immigrantshadpositivespillovereffectsonnativeproductivity,aninfluxofimmigrants

    producesanoutwardshiftinthelabordemandcurvebecausethevalueofmarginal

    productforeverynativeworkerrises.Immigrationthenshiftsnotonlythesupplycurve,

    butalsoshiftsthedemandcurvetoFLinFigure3.Thechangeinincomeaccruingtonatives

    isthengivenbythesumofthetriangleB¢C¢D(orthetraditionalimmigrationsurplus)plus

    theshadedareaofthetrapezoidA¢B¢BA,whichmeasurestheimpactofimmigrationonthe

    totalproductofnativeworkers.Itisobviousthatiftheexternalitiesaresufficiently

    important,high-skillimmigrationcouldbeanimportantdriverofeconomicgrowth.

    Figure3suggestsatrivialback-of-the-envelopecalculationthatillustratejusthow

    importanttheexternalitiescanbe.Supposeahigh-skillsupplyshockraisesthemarginal

    productofeverynativeworkerbyjpercent,sothatthenewdemandcurveFL=(1+j)fL.

    Thisformulationimpliesthatthegainsproducedbytheexternalitiesequaljpercentofthe

    originalGDP.Table2suggeststhatthepre-immigrationGDP,measuredbytrapezoidABN0

    inFigure3,isabout$17trillion.Iftheexternalityincreasesmarginalproductby1percent,

    thegainsproducedbyhigh-skillimmigrationwouldbeabout$170billion.Inshort,the

    gainsfromhumancapitalexternalitiescaneasilydwarfthosemeasuredbythetraditional

    immigrationsurplus.Moreover,theselargegainsdonotdisappearinthelongrun,asthe

    increasedproductivityofthenativeworkforceisapermanentfixtureofthelabormarket.

    5.TheDistributionalImpactofImmigration

  • 18

    Intheabsenceofhumancapitalexternalities,thecanonicalmodelofthelabor

    marketsuggeststhataone-timesupplyshockwilldepressthewageofcompetingworkers

    intheshortrun,andthatthisnegativeeffectisattenuatedovertimeastheeconomy

    adjuststothelargerworkforce.Despitetheintuitiveappealoftheseinsights,theliterature

    thatestimatesthewageelasticity(thecrucialparameterforcalculatingboththegainsfrom

    immigrationandthedistributionalimpact)hasinsteadproducedaconfusinglabyrinth,

    withestimatesthatoftendependonthemethodologicalapproach,thesampleused,andthe

    periodexamined.

    Becauseimmigrantsclusterinarelativelysmallnumberofgeographicareas,many

    studiesexploitthegeographicdispersionofimmigrantstomeasurethewageeffect.These

    studiescomparenativeearningsincitieswheretheimmigrantshareoftheworkforceis

    large(forexample,LosAngeles)withearningsincitieswheretherearerelativelyfew

    immigrants.Anegativespatialcorrelationwouldthenbeinterpretedasshowingthatthe

    supplyshockreducedthewageofsubstitutablenatives.

    Theregressionmodelistypicallygivenby:

    logwrt=βprt+g Xrt+e (24)

    wherewrtisthemeanwageofnativeworkersincityrattimet,andprtistheimmigrant

    share.ThevectorXtypicallyincludesvariablesthatalsogeneratewagedispersionacross

    citiesandovertimeandareoftenproxiedbycityandyearfixedeffects.

    ItiswellknownthattheOLSestimateofbdoesnotmeasurethecausaleffectof

    immigration.Immigrantstendtosettleinhigh-wagecities.Theendogenousgeographic

    distributionthengeneratesapositivespuriouscorrelationbetweenimmigrationand

    nativewages.Asnotedearlier,moststudiesuseashift-shareinstrumenttoaddressthe

  • 19

    problem.Thisinstrumentgivesthepredictednumberofimmigrantsinacityattimet

    basedonthegeographicdistributionofearlierwaves.Theshift-shareinstrument,however,

    isvalidonlyiftheeconomicconditionsthatmotivatedearlierwavestosettleinparticular

    citiesareuncorrelatedwiththeconditionsinthosecitiestoday.

    Somestudiesavoidtheendogeneityproblembysearchingfornaturalexperiments

    wherelargenumbersofimmigrantsarerandomly“droppedoff”inaparticularlocationata

    particulartime,withtheMarielboatliftbeingtheclassiccontext.OnApril20,1980,Fidel

    CastrodeclaredthatCubanswishingtomovetotheUnitedStatescouldleavefreelyfrom

    theportofMariel.BySeptember1980,about125,000Cubanshadacceptedtheinvitation,

    andMiami’slaborforcehadunexpectedlygrownby8percent.

    Card(1990)concludedthattheaveragewageinMiamiwasbarelyaffectedbythe

    Marielsupplyshock(relativetowagetrendsincomparablecities).Borjas(2017),however,

    notedthattherefugeeswerepredominantlylow-skill.Nearlytwo-thirdsoftheMarielitos

    didnothaveahighschooldiploma,increasingthenumberofhighschooldropoutsin

    Miamibynearly20percent.ItwouldthenmakesensetolookfortheimpactofMarielin

    Miami’slow-skilllabormarket.Figure4ashowsthewagetrendsrevealedbytheMarch

    CurrentPopulationSurveys(CPS)inthesampleofnon-Hispanicmen,aged25-59,whodid

    nothaveahighschooldiploma.TherelativewageofthisgroupinMiamitookanosedive

    after1980,andittookadecadeforthewagetorecover.

    Severalsubsequentstudieshavearguedthatotherdefinitionsofthe“low-skill”

    workforceandthatadjustingforsamplingissuesintheCPSyielddifferentresults.Periand

    Yasenov(2015),forinstance,examinethewagetrendsinalow-skillsamplegivenbynon-

    Cubanworkers,aged16-61,whodidnothaveahighschooldiploma.AsFigure4bshows,

  • 20

    thewagetrendsinthissamplesuggestthatMarieldidnotaffectthelow-skillwage.5The

    questionthenbecomes:whichsamplebestcapturesconditionsinMiami’s“lowskill”labor

    market?Asanexampleofthenuancesinvolved,theadditionofworkersaged16-18tothe

    low-skillsampleimpliesthathighschoolstudentsareclassifiedas“highschooldropouts”

    becausetheydonotyethaveahighschooldiplomaandtheCPS(atthetime)didnot

    provideinformationonwhetherapersonwasenrolledinschool.Theverylargenumberof

    highschoolstudentsoverwhelmsthedataandpotentiallycontaminatesthewagetrend.6

    Spatialcorrelationsmightalsobeproblematicbecausenativesmayrespondto

    supplyshocksmigrationbymovingtootherlabormarkets.Iftheentryofimmigrantsintoa

    particularcitylowersthewage,nativesmightmovetoplacesunaffectedbyimmigration

    thatnowofferrelativelyhigherwages,diffusingtheimpactofimmigrationoverthe

    nationaleconomy.BeginningwithBorjas(2003),manystudieshavemovedawayfrom

    geographiccomparisonsandinsteadexaminedwagetrendsforspecificskillgroupsinthe

    nationallabormarket.The“skill-cellapproach”triestodetermineifthewageofspecific

    skillgroupsisrelatedtothenumberofimmigrantsthatenteredeachofthosegroups.

    Figure5illustratesakeyempiricalimplicationofthisapproach.Defineaskillgroup

    asthesetofworkerswithaparticularcombinationofeducationalattainmentandlabor

    marketexperience(forexample,highschooldropoutswith6-10yearsofexperience,or

    5ThisisthesampleusedintheoriginaldraftofPeriandYasenov(2015).RecentworkbyClemens

    andHunt(2019)notesanadditionalproblemwiththeMarchCPSsample:thefractionofthelow-skillworkforcethatisblackjumpeddramaticallyin1979,potentiallycontaminatingthewagetrend.Borjas(2019),however,documentsthatmuchofthewagedeclinedocumentedinFigure4aactuallyoccurredduringatimewhenthefractionofblackworkersintheCPSsamplewasrelativelyconstant.

    6ThereconciliationoftheMarielevidencewilllikelyrequiredatathatexaminesaspectsoftheMiamilabormarketnotmeasuredbytheCPS.Anastasopoulosetal(2018)examinetrendsinthenumberofjobvacancies(asmeasuredbytheConferenceBoardHelp-WantedIndex)anddocumentasizablepost-Marieldeclineintherelativenumberofhelp-wantedclassifiedsintheMiamiHerald.

  • 21

    collegegraduateswith20-24yearsofexperience).Eachpointinthescatterdiagramrelates

    thewagegrowthexperiencedbyaparticularskillgroupofnativesoveraparticulardecade

    tothechangeinthepercentofthegroupthatisforeignborn(usingdecadalCensusdata

    from1960through2010).Thereisanobviousnegativecorrelationbetweenthetwo

    variables,andtheregressionlinesuggeststhata10percentincreaseinthesizeoftheskill

    groupreducesthewageofthatgroupby3to4percent.

    Asthisbriefoverviewofahugeliteraturesuggests,therearemethodologicaland

    samplingchoicesthatoftenleadtoverydifferentconclusions.ArecentNationalAcademy

    ofSciences(NAS)reportontheeconomicimpactofimmigration(BlauandMackie,2016)

    summarizedthevalueofthewageelasticityestimatedinthemainstudies.Table3shows

    thatthepointestimatesarealloverthemap,andcanbepositive,zero,ornegative.

    Theskill-cellapproachcanbeexpandedtoaddressalimitationofthegeneric

    regressionmodelinequation(24).Asupplyshockinaparticularskillgroupaffectsthe

    wageofworkersinthatskillgroupandthewageofotherskillgroupsaswell.Giventhe

    vastnumberofpotentialskillgroupsintheworkforce,thecross-effectscanonlybe

    estimatedbyspecifyingastructuralmodeloftheproductiontechnologythatlimitsthe

    allowableinteractions.Borjas(2003)introducedthenestedCESframework:

    𝑄" = q𝜆W"𝐾"s + 𝜆𝐿"stKu (25)

    𝐿" = vw𝜃x"𝐿x"V

    x

    y

    K_

    , (26)

    𝐿x" = vw𝛼xz"𝐿xz"8

    z

    y

    K{

    , (27)

  • 22

    whereQtisoutput,Ktiscapital,Ltdenotesthenumberofefficiencyunitsintheaggregate

    labormarket;d=1–1/sKL,withsKLbeingtheelasticityofsubstitutionbetweencapital

    andlabor;Lstgivestheeffectivesupplyofworkerswitheducationsattimet;b=1–1/sS,

    withsSbeingtheelasticityofsubstitutionacrosstheseeducationaggregates;Lsxtgivesthe

    numberofworkersineducationgroupsandexperiencegroupxattimet;h=1–1/sX,with

    sXbeingtheelasticityofsubstitutionacrossexperienceclasses.

    Thestructuralapproachshowsthattheelasticitiesofsubstitutionamongdifferent

    typesofworkersarethe“fundamentals”thatdeterminethewageimpactofimmigration.

    The(log-linear)marginalproductivityconditionsimpliedbythenestedCESallowforeasy

    estimationoftheseelasticitiesusingdataonwagesandemploymentfortheskillcells.

    Table4,alsodrawnfromtheNASreport,usestheestimatedelasticitiestosimulatethe

    wageimpactoftheimmigrantswhoenteredbetween1990and2010(whoaretreatedasa

    one-timeshock).Evenafteraccountingforallpotentialcross-effects,thissupplyshock

    reducedthewageoftheleastskilledworkersby6.3percentintheshortrunandby3.1

    percentinthelongrun.

    Subsequentextensionsoftheframeworkinequations(25)-(27)emphasizethe

    importanceoftwoadditionalelasticitiesofsubstitutionthatmaychangetheimplicationsof

    thenumericalsimulation.OttavianoandPeri(2012)relaxedtheassumptioninequation

    (27)thatimmigrantsandnativeswhohavethesameeducationalattainmentandthesame

    labormarketexperienceareperfectsubstitutes.Thepotentialcomplementaritybetween

    observationallyequivalentimmigrantsandnativeswouldattenuateanynegativewage

  • 23

    effect.Card(2009)arguedthathighschooldropoutsandhighschoolgraduatesareperfect

    substitutes,changingthedefinitionofthelow-skillworkforce.

    ThevariouspanelsofTable4showhowthealternativeassumptionschangethe

    simulatedwageimpact.TheOttaviano-Peri(2012)estimateofanelasticityofsubstitution

    of20betweenobservationallyequivalentimmigrantsandnativesistoolargetomatter

    muchinthesimulation.Theshort-runimpactonthewageofhighschooldropoutsis-4.9

    percent,whilethelong-runimpactis-1.7percent.Buttheassumptionthathighschool

    dropoutsandhighschoolgraduatesareperfectsubstitutesmakesadifference.Byadding

    thetensofmillionsofnativeswhoarehighschoolgraduatesintothelow-skilllabor

    market,theimpactoftheentryofmillionsoflow-skillimmigrants(whooftendonothavea

    highschooldiploma)isdilutedbecausethebaselineworkforcegrowsevenmore.Itisthis

    “numericaltrick”thatproducesasimulationsuggestingthatimmigrationhasnoadverse

    impactonthewageoflow-skillworkers.

    HumanCapitalExternalities

    Humancapitalexternalitiescanattenuatetheadverseimpactofimmigrationon

    competingworkersandgenerateverylargeeconomicgainsatthesametime.Anumberof

    recentstudiesexaminespecifichistoricaleventsinvolvinghigh-skillsupplyshocksto

    determineiftherewereresultingexternalities.

    TheworkofWaldinger(2010,2012)exemplifiesthemethodologicalapproach.

    Immediatelyafterseizingpowerin1933,theNationalSocialistPartyenactedtheLawfor

    theRestorationoftheProfessionalCivilService,whichmandatedthedismissalofallJewish

    professorsfromGermanuniversities.Almost20percentofGermanmathematics

  • 24

    professorsweredismissed,includingsomeofthemostfamousmathematiciansoftheera

    (suchasJohnvonNeumann,RichardCourant,andRichardvonMises).

    TheJewishmathematicianshadnotbeenrandomlyemployedacrossGerman

    universities,sosomedepartmentsbarelynoticedthedismissalswhileotherdepartments

    lostoverhalftheirfaculty.Ifthoseexceptionalmathematiciansproducedbeneficial

    externalitiesfortheirstudentsorcolleagues,thedismissalswouldhavehadadetectable

    impactontheeventualproductivityofthepersons“leftbehind.”Waldinger(2010)shows

    thatthestudentsleftbehindinthedepartmentsthatsufferedtheheaviestlosses

    experiencedarelativedeclineintheirproductivity,suggestingthathumancapital

    externalitiesdomatter.Waldinger(2012),however,documentsthatthepublication rate of

    the colleagues left behind was not affected by the dismissals. The different results in the

    two Waldinger studies suggest that human capital externalities are not magically

    produced even when the supply shock involves exceptional workers. The outcome seems

    to depend on the nature of the relationship between the immigrants and the affected

    workers.

    BorjasandDoran(2012)conductasimilarexaminationofanotherhigh-skillsupply

    shock.Fordecadespriorto1992,therehadbeenlittleintellectualcontactbetweenSoviet

    andWesternmathematicians.Asaresult,thetwogroupsspecializedinverydifferent

    fields.ThetwomostpopularSovietfieldswerepartialdifferentialequationsandordinary

    differentialequations.ThetwomostpopularAmericanfieldswerestatisticsandoperations

    research.AfterthecollapseoftheSovietUnionin1992,severalhundredSoviet

    mathematiciansleftthecountryandsettledintheUnitedStates.

  • 25

    BorjasandDoran(2012)trackedthepublicationrecordofeveryAmerican

    mathematicianbeforeandafterthearrivaloftheSovietémigréstomeasuretheimpactof

    thesupplyshockonthemathematicianswhohadthemostSoviet-likeresearchagenda.

    Therearetwopossibleeffects.Thefirstisimpliedbythelawofdiminishingreturns.An

    increaseinthenumberofmathematiciansderivingtheoremsin,say,partialdifferential

    equationsmakesthecomparableAmericanmathematicianslessproductive.Thesecondis

    impliedbyhumancapitalexternalities.ExposingAmericanmathematicianstonew

    theoremsandtechniquescouldincreasetheproductivityofthemathematiciansworkingin

    thosefields.Itturnsoutthattherewasaprecipitousdeclineinthepublicationrateofthe

    groupwhoseresearchagendaoverlappedmostwiththeSoviets.

    Finally,severalstudiesexaminetheimpactofthehigh-techworkersadmittedinthe

    H-1Bvisaprogram.ThenumberofH-1Bvisasiscappedandthiscaphasfluctuatedover

    time.TheconclusionthattheH-1Bprogramproducesexternalitiesoftencomesfrom

    studiesthatestimatespatialcorrelations.BecauseH-1Bvisa-holdersclusterinasmall

    numberoflocations(suchasSanFrancisco),anexogenousincreaseinthecapwouldbe

    expectedtohavealargeimpactin“H-1Bdependent”cities.KerrandLincoln(2010)

    showedthatanincreaseinthecapledtomorepatentsoriginatinginthosecities.The

    increasedpatenting,however,camemainlyfrompersonswithIndianorChinesesurnames,

    suggestingthatthosenewpatentsoriginatedwiththeimmigrantsthemselves,ratherthan

    fromaspillovereffectonnativeworkers.

    Someofthesubsequentstudiesthatestimatespatialcorrelationsreportlarge

    beneficialeffects.Peri,Shih,andFarber(2015)relatetheH-1Binducedincreaseinthe

    numberofSTEMworkerstothewageofcollegegraduatesinthecityandfindaverystrong

  • 26

    positiveeffect.Themagnitude,however,seemsimplausible;a1percentincreaseinthesize

    oftheSTEMworkforceraisesthewageofcollegegraduatesby8percent(orawage

    elasticityof+8.0).Mostlikely,theendogeneityplaguingspatialcorrelationsandthe

    problemswiththeshift-shareinstrumentleadthedatatoregurgitatetheobviousfactthat

    high-skillimmigrantsendupinplaceswherethehigh-skilllabormarketisdoingquitewell.

    Doran,Gelber,andIsen(2016)avoidtheendogeneitybiasbyexamininganatural

    experimentcreatedbyapeculiarityoftheH-1Bprogram.Firmscanapplyforthevisasona

    first-come,first-servedbasisuntilthevisasrunout.Onsomerandomdayduringayear,the

    visasrunoutandonthatdaymorefirmstypicallyapplyforvisasthantherearevisas

    available.TheDepartmentofHomelandSecuritythenrunsalotterytodeterminewhich

    firmsgetthevisas.Itturnsoutthatthefirmsthatwonthelotterydidnotpatentmoreand

    thatnativeemploymentinthosefirmsfell.

    Inshort,theevidencesupportingtheconjecturethathigh-skillimmigration

    generatessizablehumancapitalexternalitiesismixed.Therearesomehistoricalevents

    thatproducedsuchexternalities,buttherearealsoothereventswheretheexternalitiesare

    absent.

    6.ImmigrantSkills

    AstheaugmentedSolowmodelsuggests,theimpactofimmigrantsoneconomic

    growthdependsonthehumancapitalstocktheybringintothecountry,andonhowthat

    stockchangesasassimilationtakesplace(Chiswick,1978;Borjas,1985).

    The2016NASreport(BlauandMackie,2016)usedthecensuscross-sections

    between1970and2010totracktheage-adjustedwageofspecificimmigrantwavesover

  • 27

    thepastfewdecades.Figure6aillustratesthetrendsintherelativewage.Thefigure

    revealstwointerestingandwell-knownfindings.Thefirstisthepresenceofsizablecohort

    differencesinentrywages,withthemorerecentcohortshavinglowerearningspotential

    thanearliercohortsthroughtheyear2000.In1970,themostrecentimmigrantwave

    earned23.5percentlessthancomparablenativesatthetimeofentry.By1990,theentry

    wagedisadvantagehadgrownto33.1percent,beforecontractingto27.3percentin2000.

    Figure6aalsohintsataslowdownintherateof“economicassimilation.”The

    immigrantcohortsthatarrivedpriortotheearly1980sexperiencedfasterrelativewage

    growththanthemorerecentarrivals.Consider,forexample,thecohortthatarrivedinthe

    late1960s.Therelativewageofthisgroupimprovedfromadisadvantageof23.5percent

    in1970to2.0percentby2000—agrowthofabout20percentagepointsovertwodecades.

    Incontrast,therelativewageofthecohortthatenteredthecountryinthelate1980sonly

    improvedfromanentrydisadvantageof33.1percentto25.2percentby2010.

    Theassimilationslowdownisalsoevidentindatathatisfarlesssensitivetothe

    impactoftransitoryeconomicconditionsontherelativewageofimmigrants.Figure6b

    showsthecomparabletrendsinthefractionofimmigrantswhospeakEnglishverywell(or

    onlyspeakEnglish).Notethat30.9percentoftheimmigrantswhoarrivedbetween1975

    and1980wereEnglishproficientatthetimeofarrival,andthisfractionincreasedto46.2

    percentby2000.Incontrast,theproficiencyrateofthecohortthatenteredthecountryin

    thelate1980sincreasedbyonly7percentagepointsduringthefirst20years.The

    evidencerevealedinFigure6,therefore,suggestthatthereisnoinevitableassimilation

    processthatwillmechanicallyincreaseper-capitaincomeastheimmigrantpopulation

    acquiresskillsthatattenuatetheinitialproductivitydisadvantage.

  • 28

    Itisinsightfultocomparethemodernevidencewiththehistoricalrecord.Although

    itiswidelybelievedthatthehumancapitalstockoftheimmigrantswhoarrivedatthe

    beginningofthe20thcenturyincreaseddramaticallyduringtheirlifetime,recentresearch

    suggeststhatthewidespreadconsensusmaybewrong.Thepublicreleaseofthecensus

    manuscriptscompiledatthetimeallowsmodernhistorianstotrackspecificpersonsfrom

    censustocensus.Thistrackingletsusinspectthecareerpathofspecificnativesand

    immigrants.Theexerciseturnsthewidespreadperceptionofrapidimprovementonits

    head.AsAbramitzky,Boustan,andEriksson(2014,pp.269-270)conclude:“Thenotion

    thatEuropeanimmigrantsconvergedwithnativesafterspending10to15yearsintheUS

    is…exaggerated,aswefindthatinitialimmigrant-nativeoccupationalgapspersistedover

    time.”Inshort,thehistoricalexperienceprovidessurprisinglylittleevidenceofanyrelative

    economicimprovementfortheEllisIslandimmigrantsduringtheirlifetime.

    Finally,theavailableevidencesuggestsapositivecorrelationbetweentheskillsthat

    immigrantsbringintotheUnitedStatesandtherateofsubsequentgrowthinearnings.

    Figure7illustratesthelinkthewageofgrowthexperiencedbyanationalorigingroupin

    thefirst10yearsintheUnitedStatesandtheaverageeducationofthegroupatthetimeof

    arrival.Itisevidentthatmoreskilledgroupsexperiencefasterassimilation.Theevidence,

    therefore,supportstheconjectureofcomplementarityintheproductionofhumancapital:

    thoseimmigrantswhoinvestedmoreinhumancapitalpriortomigrationarelikelyto

    investmoreinhumancapitalaftermigration.Putdifferently,therelativeeconomic

    contributionofhigh-skillimmigrantstoaggregateoutputincreasesovertime.

    7.TheFiscalImpact

  • 29

    Immigrationgeneratesashort-runeconomicgainthroughtheimmigrationsurplus

    andmaygeneratealong-runincreaseifimmigrantsaresufficientlyskilledorthereare

    humancapitalexternalities.Theeconomicgainsthataccruethroughthelabormarket,

    however,needtobecontrastedwiththefiscalimpactofimmigration.Thefiscalimpactcan

    eitherbepositiveornegative,dependingonhowmuchimmigrantscontributetothe

    fundingofgovernmentprogramsandhowmuchitcoststoprovideservicestothem.

    Thequestionofwhetherimmigrantsusegovernmentprogramsmoreorlessoften

    thannativesiscontroversialandtheanswerishighlydisputed.Infact,itisenlighteningto

    illustratehowthesamedatacanbemanipulatedindifferentwaystoreachverydifferent

    conclusionsabouttherelativeuseofwelfareprogramsbytheimmigrantpopulation.

    Since1994,theCurrentPopulationSurveys(CPS)provideinformationon

    participationinvariousassistanceprogramsforbothimmigrantsandnatives,makingit

    possibletodocumentthedifferenceinwelfareparticipationrates.Forexpositional

    convenience,supposethatbeing“onwelfare”meansreceivingbenefitsfromMedicaid,food

    stamps,orcashbenefits.WecanthenusetheCPStodetermineifthefractionofimmigrants

    onwelfareishigher,lower,orthesameasthefractionofnatives.

    ThetwopanelsofFigure8showthetrendsbetween1994and2018.Note,however,

    thatthetwopanelsyieldverydifferentresults.InFigure7a,thefractionofimmigrantson

    welfareisfarhigherthanthefractionofnatives,whileinFigure7b,theparticipationrateis

    essentiallythesameforthetwogroups.

    Bothpanelsofthefigureusethesamedatabutmanipulateitindifferentways.In

    particular,thetwopanelsuseadifferentunitofanalysisinthecalculations.Figure7auses

    thehouseholdastheunitofanalysis,whichisthewayinwhichwelfareuseismostoften

  • 30

    analyzed.Animmigranthouseholdisonewheretheheadofthehouseholdisforeign-born,

    andanativehouseholdisonewheretheheadisnative-born.Itisevidentthathouseholds

    headedbyanimmigranthavehighratesofwelfareuse(definedasanyoneinthehousehold

    receivingoneofthethreeprogramsunderanalysis),andthatthegapbetweenimmigrant

    andnativehouseholdsincreasedovertime.By2018,35.1percentofimmigranthouseholds

    wereonwelfareascomparedto22.6percentofnativehouseholds.Incontrast,Figure7b

    usesthepersonastheunitofanalysis.In2018,24.5percentofforeign-bornpersonsand

    23.1percentofthenative-bornreceivedassistancefromoneofthethreeprograms.

    Thereasonforthedifferencebetweenthetwopanelsiseasytograspbyconsidering

    atrivialexample.Ayoung,singleimmigrantwomanarrivesinthecountry.Afterafew

    years,shebecomesasinglemother,hasthreechildren,andqualifiesforMedicaid.InFigure

    8a,thefour-persongroupingwouldbeclassifiedasanimmigranthouseholdonwelfare.In

    Figure8b,thetallywouldrecordoneimmigrantpersononwelfareandthreenativepersons

    onwelfare.Andthereinliesthenumericaltrick:Becausethechildrenwereborninthe

    UnitedStates,theyenteronthenativesideoftheledger.

    The2016NASreportcontainsadetailedanalysisofthefiscalimpactthatgoesfar

    beyondthecalculationofwelfareparticipationrates(BlauandMackie,2016,Chapters8

    and9).TheNASreportaddsupboththetaxespaidandthecostoftheservicesreceivedfor

    immigrantsandtheirdescendants,soastocomeupwitha“bottom-line”numberthat

    summarizesthelong-runfiscalimpact.

    Thislong-runperspectiveaccountsforthefactthatmanycurrentexpenditures,

    suchasfundingschoolingforimmigrantchildrenorhealthcare,generatefuturereturns

    throughhigherearningswhenthechildrenenterthelabormarket.Theexercisealso

  • 31

    incorporatesthepossibilitythatimmigrantsmighthelpfiscallybecausethenative

    populationisaging,andfundswillbeneededtofundcurrentliabilitiesinSocialSecurity

    andMedicare.TheNASuseda75-yearperiodtocalculatethelong-runfiscalimpact.

    TheNASexerciseshowsthatthebottomlineofthelong-runcalculationforthe

    averageimmigrantdependsentirelyontheassumptionsmade.Itiseasytogenerateeither

    averypositivelong-runfiscalimpactoraverynegativeonebymakingdifferent

    assumptions.Twodistinctassumptionsdrivetheconclusion.First,thecalculationneedsto

    allocateexpendituresinpublicgoodsbetweenimmigrantsandnatives.Althoughitmakes

    sensetoassumethatthecostofpublicgoods,suchaspoliceprotectionornationaldefense,

    isunchangedifthecountryadmitsonemoreimmigrant(sothatthemarginalcostiszero),

    itmakeslesssensetoassumethatthecostofpublicgoodsisunchangedifthecountry

    admitsover40millionimmigrants.Similarly,anylong-runscenariomustmake

    assumptionsaboutthefuturepathoftaxesandgovernmentexpenditures,anddifferent

    assumptionsleadtodifferentconclusions.

    Table5summarizestheresultsfromfourscenariospresentedintheNASreport.

    Thelong-runfiscalimpactoftheaverageimmigrant(measuredasthepresentvalueofthe

    differencebetweentaxesandexpenditures)ispositiveonlyifimmigrantsdonotaffectthe

    costofpublicgoodsandwealsoassumethatfuturetaxratesandbenefitpaymentsfollow

    theprojectionsmadebytheCongressionalBudgetOffice(CBO).Thepositivelong-term

    impactofanimmigrant(anetpresentvalueof+$58,000)becomesaloss(potentiallyas

    largeas-$119,000)ifonegetsridofeitherofthoseassumptions.

    Note,however,thatthefiscalimpactofhigh-skillimmigrationisalwayspositive,

    whilethefiscalimpactoflow-skillimmigrationisalwaysnegative.Althoughitisimpossible

  • 32

    toknowwhichscenario(ifany)bestapproximatesthefuture,high-skillimmigrationis

    alwaysabetter“deal”fromafiscalperspective.Thelong-runfiscalbenefitfroman

    immigrantwithagraduatedegreeisbetween$236,000to$547,000,whilethelong-run

    fiscalburdenimposedbyahighschooldropoutisbetween-$196,000to-$301,000.

    Theseestimatesimplythatachangeinimmigrationpolicythatonlypermitsthe

    entryofhigh-skillworkerscanbeanimportantcontributortoeconomicgrowtheveninthe

    absenceofhumancapitalexternalities.Considerthescenariothatgeneratesthesmallest

    fiscalgainfortheaverageimmigrant(i.e.,thescenariothatassumesaveragecostpricing

    forpublicgoodsanddisregardstheCBOprojections).Theaverageimmigrantproducesa

    long-termlossof-$119,000.Suppose,however,thateveryimmigranthadbeenacollege

    graduate.Thenetpresentvalueinthisscenariojumpsfromaburdenof-$119,000toagain

    of+$39,000,oranetgainof+$158,000.Assuminga3percentrateofdiscount,the

    annualizedgainis$4,740.Therewere44.5millionimmigrantsin2017.Ifallthese

    immigrantshadbeencollegegraduates,thecountrywouldhavebeen$211billionricher.

    Theprojectedgainisevenlargerinthescenariothatassumesmarginalcostpricingand

    usestheCBOprojections.Theincreaseinthecountry’swealthifallimmigrantshadbeen

    collegegraduateswouldbe$311billion.Inshort,high-skillimmigrationcanbean

    importantdeterminantofeconomicgrowthsimplybecauseofitsfiscalconsequences.7

    8.Implications

    7Thisisapartialequilibriumexercisedesignedtogiveasenseofthemagnitudesinvolved.Thevery

    largeincreaseinthenumberofcollegegraduateswouldhavemajorlabormarketconsequences,includingasubstantialdropintherelativewageof(andtaxespaidby)high-skillworkers.

  • 33

    TheUnitedStatesoffersexceptionalopportunitiestoanyoneluckyenoughtolive

    withinitsborders.Asaresult,manymorepeoplewanttoimmigratethanthecountryis

    willingtoadmit.Consider,forexample,the“diversitylottery”heldannuallysince1995.

    Eachyear,somevisasaremadeavailabletopersonsoriginatingin“countrieswithlow

    ratesofimmigrationtotheUnitedStates.”Personslivingintheeligiblecountriescanapply

    forarandomchanceatwinningoneofthecovetedgreencards.The2018lotterydrew23.1

    millionqualifiedapplicationsforthe50,000availablevisas.

    Thehugeexcessdemandforentryvisasimpliesthatimmigrationpolicyoften

    specifiesasetofrationingrulestopickandchoosefromthemanyapplicants.Theserules

    maystressfamilyties(asiscurrentlydoneforthebulkoflegalimmigrants),ornational

    origin(asusedtobedone),orsocioeconomiccharacteristics(asisdoneinother

    countries).Whichtypesofimmigrantsshouldthecountryadmit?

    Thecasethatcanbemadeforpreferringonetypeofimmigrantoveranother

    ultimatelydependsonwhatoneassumesaboutthecountry’spolicyobjectives.Specifically,

    whatshouldtheUnitedStatesseektoaccomplishfromimmigration?Differentpolicygoals

    leadtodifferentchoicesaboutthecompositionoftheimmigrantflow.Ifimmigrationpolicy

    strivedtorelievethetaxburdenonnative-borntaxpayers,itwouldbefiscallyirresponsible

    toadmitmillionsoflow-skillimmigrantswhohaveahighpropensityforparticipatingin

    assistanceprograms.Butifthegoalweretohelpthemillionsofpersonsnowlivingin

    poverty-strickenregionsoftheworld,theincreasedcostoflow-skillimmigrationisthe

    pricethatAmericansarewillingtopayfortheirgenerosity.

    Assumethatthegoalofimmigrationpolicyistoachieveahighrateofeconomic

    growth.Averystrongcasecanbemadethattherewouldbefastereconomicgrowth,

  • 34

    particularlyasdefinedbythetrendinper-capitaincome,iftheUnitedStatesadoptedan

    immigrationpolicythatlimitedentrytohigh-skillworkers.

    Theargumentinfavorofthispolicycontainstwodistinctparts.Considerfirstthe

    roleofthefiscalimpactofimmigration.Thereisnodoubtthathigh-skillimmigrantsearn

    more,payhighertaxes,andrequirefewerservices.Putsimply,high-skillimmigration

    increasestheafter-taxincomeofnatives,whilethetaxburdenimposedbytheimmigration

    oflow-skillworkersreducesthenetwealthofnativetaxpayers.AndtheNationalAcademy

    estimatessuggestthatthefiscalbenefitsgeneratedbyhigh-skillimmigrationcanbequite

    large.

    Thesecondpartofthecaseforhigh-skillimmigrationreliesonhowimmigrants

    altertheproductivityofthenativeworkforceandofnative-ownedfirms.Intheshort-run,

    theeconomicpieexpandsthroughtheimmigrationsurplus.Manystudiessuggestthat

    thereismorecomplementaritybetweenhigh-skilllaborandcapitalthanbetweenunskilled

    laborandcapital.Capital-skillcomplementarity,therefore,suggeststhattheimmigration

    surpluswouldbelargeriftheimmigrantflowwerecomposedofskilledworkers.

    Theseshort-rungains,however,wouldbedissipatedastheeconomyadjuststothe

    largerworkforce.Inthelong-term,theimmigrantcontributiontoeconomicgrowthwould

    dependonthepossibilitythatimmigrantsintroducehumancapitalexternalities,which

    permanentlyincreasetheproductivityofnatives.High-skillimmigrantsarealsomore

    likelytobringinknowledge,skills,andabilitiesthatnativeslack,andnativesmaybeable

    tosomehowpickupthisknow-how.Althoughtheevidenceonthemagnitudeofthese

    externalitiesismixed,thepotentialfortheexternalitiestoevenexistislargerwhenthe

    immigrantinfluxiscomposedofexceptionalworkers.

  • 35

    Inshort,thereislittledoubtthattheimmigrantcontributiontoeconomicgrowth

    wouldbefarmoreimportantiftheimmigrantinflowwascomposedofhigh-skillworkers.

    Ifareceivingcountrywishedtopursueanimmigrationpolicythatmaximizedlong-term

    growth,therefore,thereislittleuncertaintyaboutthepaththatcountryshouldfollow.Itis

    farfromclear,however,thatimmigrationpolicyshouldbesetsolelyonthebasisof

    economicconsiderations.

  • 36

    References Abramitzky,Ran,LeahPlattBoustan,andKatherineEriksson.2014.”Anationofimmigrants:Assimilationandeconomicoutcomesintheageofmassmigration,”JournalofPoliticalEconomy122:467-506. Anastasapoulos,Jason,GeorgeJ.Borjas,GavinG.Cook,andMichaelLachanski.2018.“JobVacanciesandImmigration:EvidencefromPre-andPost-MarielData,”NBERWorkingPaperNo.24580. Barro,RobertJ.andXavierSala-i-Martin.1999.EconomicGrowth.Cambridge,MA:TheMITPress. Borjas,GeorgeJ.1985.“Assimilation,changesincohortquality,andtheearningsofimmigrants,”JournalofLaborEconomics3:463-489. Borjas,GeorgeJ.1995.“Theeconomicbenefitsfromimmigration,”JournalofEconomicPerspectives9:3-22. Borjas,GeorgeJ.2003.“Thelabordemandcurveisdownwardsloping:Reexaminingtheimpactofimmigrationonthelabormarket,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics118:1335-1374. Borjas,GeorgeJ.2014.ImmigrationEconomics.Cambridge,MA:HarvardUniversityPress. Borjas,GeorgeJ.2016.WeWantedWorkers:UnravelingtheImmigrationNarrative.NewYork,NY:Norton. Borjas,GeorgeJ.2017.“TheWageImpactoftheMarielitos:AReappraisal,”IndustrialandLaborRelationsReview70:1077-1110. Borjas,GeorgeJ.2019.“TheWageImpactoftheMarielitos:TheRoleofRace,”IndustrialandLaborRelationsReview,inpress. Borjas,GeorgeJ.,andKirkB.Doran.2012.“ThecollapseoftheSovietUnionandtheproductivityofAmericanmathematicians,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics127:1143-1203. Boubtane, Ekrame, Jean-Christophe Dumont, and Christophe Rault. 2016. “Immigration and Economic Growth in the OECD Countries 1986-2006,” Oxford Economic Papers: 340-360. Card,David.1990.“TheimpactoftheMarielboatliftontheMiamilabormarket,”IndustrialandLaborRelationsReview43:245-257. Card,David.2001.“Immigrantinflows,nativeoutflows,andthelocallabormarketimpactsofhigherimmigration,”JournalofLaborEconomics19:22-64.

  • 37

    Card,David.2009.Immigrationandinequality.AmericanEconomicReview99:1-21. Chiswick,BarryR.1978.“TheeffectofAmericanizationontheearningsofforeign-bornmen,”JournalofPoliticalEconomy86:897-921. Clemens,MichaelA.,andJenniferHunt.2019.“TheLaborMarketEffectsofRefugeeWaves:ReconcilingConflictingResults,”IndustrialandLaborRelationsReview,inpress. Dolado,Juan,AlessandraGoria,andAndreaIchino,1994.“Immigration,HumanCapitalandGrowthintheHostCountry:EvidencefromPooledCountryData,”JournalofPopulationEconomics7:193-215. Doran,Kirk,AlexanderGelber,andAdamIsen.2015.“TheEffectsofHigh-SkilledImmigrationPolicyonFirms:EvidencefromH-1BVisaLotteries,”NBERWorkingPaperNo.20668. Jaeger,DavidA.,JoakimRuist,andJanStuhler.2018.“Shift-ShareInstrumentsandtheImpactofImmigration,”NBERWorkingPaperNo.24285. Kane,TimandZachRutledge.2018.“ImmigrationandEconomicPerformanceAcrossFiftyU.S.Statesfrom1980-2015,”HooverInstitutionWorkingPaperNo.18112. Kerr,WilliamR.,andWilliamF.Lincoln.2010.“Thesupplysideofinnovation:H-1BvisareformsandU.S.ethnicinvention,”JournalofLaborEconomics28:473-508. Mankiw,N.Gregory,DavidRomer,andDavidN.Weil.1992.“AContributiontotheEmpiricsofEconomicGrowth,”QuarterlyJournalofEconomics107:407-437. Ottaviano,GianmarcoI.P.,andGiovanniPeri.2012.“Rethinkingtheeffectofimmigrationonwages,”JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation10:152-197.

    Peri,Giovanni.2012.“TheEffectofImmigrationonProductivity:EvidenceFromU.S.States.”ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics94:348–358. Peri,Giovanni,KevinShi,andChadSparber.2015.“STEMWorkers,H-1BVisas,andProductivityinUSCities,”JournalofLaborEconomics33:S225-S255. Peri,GiovanniandYasenov,Vasil.2015.“TheLaborMarketEffectsofaRefugeeWave:SyntheticControlMethodMeetstheMarielBoatlift,”NBERWorkingPaperNo.21801.

    Waldinger,Fabian.2010.“Qualitymatters:TheexpulsionofprofessorsandtheconsequencesforPh.D.studentoutcomesinNaziGermany,”JournalofPoliticalEconomy118:787-831.

  • 38

    Waldinger,Fabian.2012.“Peereffectsinscience:EvidencefromthedismissalofscientistsinNaziGermany,”ReviewofEconomicStudies79:838-861.

  • 39

    Figure1.Immigrationandeconomicgrowthindecadaldata,1850-2017

    A. GDP

    B. Per-capitaGDP

    Notes:ThehistoricalGDPserieswasobtainedfromMeasuringWorth.comandthenetmigrationdatawasdrawnfromthedecennialcensuses.Thedatafor2010-2020areextrapolationsfromthechangesobservedbetween2010and2017.ThereportedregressioncoefficientistheslopefromanOLSregressionofthedecadalGDPgrowthrateonthenetmigrationrate(withstandarderrorsinparentheses).

    -3

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    0.5

    0.6

    1850-60 1860-70 1870-80 1880-90 1890-00 1900-10 1910-20 1920-30 1930-40 1940-50 1950-60 1960-70 1970-80 1980-90 1990-00 2000-10 2010-20

    Net i

    mm

    igra

    tion

    rate

    (per

    100

    per

    sons

    )

    GDP

    grow

    th ra

    te

    Decade

    GDP growth rate

    Net migration rate

    Regression coefficient = 0.008(0.014)

    -3

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    0

    0.05

    0.1

    0.15

    0.2

    0.25

    0.3

    0.35

    0.4

    0.45

    1850-60 1860-70 1870-80 1880-90 1890-00 1900-10 1910-20 1920-30 1930-40 1940-50 1950-60 1960-70 1970-80 1980-90 1990-00 2000-10 2010-20

    Net i

    mm

    igra

    tion

    rate

    (per

    100

    per

    sons

    )

    Per-

    capi

    ta G

    DP g

    row

    th ra

    te

    Decade

    GDP growth rate

    Net migration rate

    Regression coefficient = -0.010(0.012)

  • 40

    FIGURE 2. The immigration surplus

    Wage

    EmploymentN L=N+M

    A

    B

    0

    w0

    w1 CD

    S¢S

    fL

  • 41

    Figure3.Theimmigrationsurplusandhumancapitalexternalities

    Wage

    EmploymentN L=N+M

    A

    B

    0

    w0

    w1 C¢D

    S¢S

    fL

    FL

  • 42

    Figure4.Marielandthewageofhighschooldropouts

    A.Non-Hispanicmenaged25-59 B.Non-Cubanworkersaged16-61

    Notes:AdaptedfromBorjas(2017).Thewagedatarepresenta3-yearmovingaverageandtheshadedareaisthe95percentconfidenceinterval.

    4.8

    5

    5.2

    5.4

    5.6

    5.8

    1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990

    Log

    wee

    kly

    wag

    e

    Year

    Outside Miami

    Miami

    4.7

    4.9

    5.1

    5.3

    5.5

    1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990

    Log

    wee

    kly

    wag

    e

    Year

    Outside Miami

    Miami

  • 43

    Figure5.Scatterrelatingwagesandimmigrantshare acrossskillgroupsandovertime,1960-2010

    Source:Borjas(2014),p.95.Eachpointinthescatterdiagramgivesthedecadalwagechangeandthedecadalchangeintheimmigrantsharefornativeworkingmenwithaparticularlevelofeducationandlabormarketexperience.

    -0.20

    -0.15

    -0.10

    -0.05

    0.00

    0.05

    0.10

    0.15

    0.20

    -0.2 -0.15 -0.1 -0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25

    Chan

    ge in

    log

    wee

    kly

    wag

    e

    Change in immigrant share

  • 44

    Figure6.Economicassimilationofimmigrants,1970-2010A.Relativewageprofiles

    B.Englishproficiencyprofiles

    Notes:BlauandMackie(2016),Table3-12,p.110,andFigure3-16,p.115.

    -0.35

    -0.3

    -0.25

    -0.2

    -0.15

    -0.1

    -0.05

    0

    0 5 10 15 20 25 30

    Log

    wag

    e re

    lativ

    e to

    nat

    ives

    Years since migration

    1975-79 cohort

    1985-89 cohort

    1995-99 cohort

    0.3

    0.32

    0.34

    0.36

    0.38

    0.4

    0.42

    0.44

    0.46

    0.48

    0.5

    0 5 10 15 20 25 30

    Frac

    tion

    spea

    king

    Eng

    lish

    very

    wel

    l

    Years since migration

    1975-79 cohort

    1985-89 cohort

    1995-99 cohort

  • 45

    Figure7.Economicassimilationandeducation

    Source:Borjas(2016),p.101.

    Canada

    Mexico

    Costa Rica

    El Salvador

    Guatemala

    Honduras

    Nicaragua

    Cuba

    Dominican Rep.Haiti

    Jamaica

    Argentina

    Brazil

    Chile

    Ecuador

    Guyana

    Peru

    Venezuela

    U.K.

    Ireland

    France

    Netherlands

    Albania

    Italy

    Bulgaria

    Czechoslovakia

    Germany

    Poland

    RomaniaYugoslavia

    RussiaChina

    Hong Kong

    Taiwan

    Japan

    Korea

    Indonesia

    ThailandVietnam

    India

    Bangladesh

    PakistanSri Lanka

    Iran

    Iraq

    Israel

    Syria

    Turkey

    Egypt

    Morocco

    GhanaEthiopia

    Kenya

    Somalia

    South Africa

    Australia

    -40

    -20

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    6 8 10 12 14 16 18

    Perc

    ent w

    age

    impr

    ovem

    ent i

    n fir

    st d

    ecad

    e

    Years of education at time of arrival

  • 46

    Figure8.Trendsinwelfareparticipationrates,1994-2018

    A. Households B. Persons

    Source:Author’scalculationsfromtheCurrentPopulationSurveys,AnnualSocialandEconomicSupplement.Welfareparticipationisdefinedintermsofuseofcashbenefits,foodstamps,orMedicaid..

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    40

    1990 2000 2010 2020

    Perc

    ent r

    ecei

    ving

    ass

    istan

    ce

    Year

    Natives

    Immigrants

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    1990 2000 2010 2020Pe

    rcen

    t rec

    eivi

    ng a

    ssist

    ance

    Year

    Natives

    Immigrants

  • 47

    Table1.ImmigrationandGSPacrossstates,1960-2017 LogGSP Logper-capitaGSPCharacteristicsofworkforce (1) (2) (1) (2)A. OLS Immigrantshare 0.032 0.031 -0.002 -0.000 (0.008) (0.008) (0.005) (0.003)Logyearsofschooling --- -0.702 --- 1.358 (0.745) (0.302)Percentprimeage --- -0.045 --- 1.113

    (1.317) (0.743) B. IV Immigrantshare 0.027 0.019 -0.012 -0.007 (0.011) (0.013) (0.005) (0.005)Logyearsofschooling --- -1.497 --- 0.920 (1.042) (0.526)Percentprimeage --- 0.299 --- 1.091

    (1.128) (0.715)Notes:Standarderrorsreportedinparenthesesandclusteredatthestatelevel.Allregressionsincludestateandyearfixedeffects.Thepre-2000GSPdatawasobtainedfromusgovernmentspending.com,andthepost-1997datafromtheBureauofEconomicAnalysis.Theimmigrantsharewascalculatedusingdatafromthe1960-2000decennialcensusesandthe2010and2017AmericanCommunitySurveys.Themeanschoolingandprime-agevariablesarecalculatedinthesampleofnativeworkers.TheIVregressionsusethe1960censustoconstructaninstrumentbasedonthegeographicsettlementofimmigrantsatthattime(withineachnationalorigingroup);seetextforadditionaldetails.TheOLSregressionshave350observations,andtheIVregressionshave300observations.

  • 48

    Table2.Theshort-runimmigrationsurplus,2017

    InbillionsofdollarsImmigrationsurplus 56.4 Losstonativeworkers 566.9 Gaintonativefirms 623.3

    TotalincreaseinGDP 2,322.3 Paymentstoimmigrants 2,265.9

    Source:UpdatedfromBorjas(1995).Thecalculationassumethatlabor’sshareofincomeis0.7andthattheimmigrantshareoftheworkforceis16.6percent.ThevalueofGDPin2017was$19.5trillion.

  • 49

    Table3.EstimatesofthewageelasticityStudy Elasticity NativesampleLlull(2015) -1.7 Men AltonjiandCard(1991) -1.7 Dropouts,blackmen -1.0 Dropouts Borjas(2016b) -1.4 Dropouts,non-Hispanicmen -0.5 Dropouts,non-Hispanicmen Monras(2015) -0.7 Highschoolgraduatesorless,non-Hispanic Borjas(2003) -0.6 Men Cortes(2008) -0.6 Dropouts,HispanicwithpoorEnglish -0.3 Dropouts,Hispanic -0.1 Dropouts CardandPeri(2016) -0.2 Men -0.1 Men Card(2001) -0.1 Men +0.1 Women PeriandYasenov(2015) +0.3 Dropouts,non-CubanSource:BlauandMackie(2016),Table5-2,p.242.SeetheNASreportfordetailedcitationstothestudiesincludedinthetable.

  • 50

    Table4.Simulatedpercentwageeffectsof1990-2010immigrantsupplyshockonnativeworkers

    HighSchoolDropouts

    HighSchoolGraduates

    SomeCollege

    CollegeGraduates

    Post-College

    AllNatives

    Percentsupplyshift 25.9 8.4 6.1 10.9 15.0 10.6 Basicsimulation: Shortrun -6.3 -2.8 -2.3 -3.3 -4.1 -3.2Longrun -3.1 0.4 0.9 -0.1 -0.9 0.0

    Similarimmigrantsandnativesarecomplements: Shortrun -4.9 -2.3 -2.0 -2.7 -3.3 -2.6Longrun -1.7 0.9 1.2 0.5 -0.1 0.6

    Andhighschooldropoutsandhighschoolgraduatesareperfectsubstitutes:

    Shortrun -2.1 -3.0 -2.0 -2.7 -3.3 -2.7Longrun 1.1 0.2 1.2 0.5 -0.1 0.5

    Source:BlauandMackie(2016),Table5-1,pp.236-237.Thesimulationresultsthatassumestatisticallysimilarimmigrantsandnativesarecomplementsassumeanelasticityofsubstitutionbetweenthetwogroupsequalto20.

  • 51

    Table5.Long-runfiscalimpactofimmigration

    Futurepathoftaxesandspendingprojectedby

    theCBO

    Currentpathoftaxesandspendingcontinues

    intofutureMarginalcostpricingforpublicgoods

    Allworkers +$58,000 -$36,000Highschooldropouts -196,000 -219,000Highschoolgraduates -47,000 -112,000Somecollege 99,000 -10,000Bachelor’sdegree 280,000 123,000Graduateeducation 547,000 318,000

    Averagecostpricingforpublicgoods

    Allworkers -$5,000 -$119,000Highschooldropouts -259,000 -301,000Highschoolgraduates -109,000 -193,000Somecollege 34,000 -96,000Bachelor’sdegree 216,000 39,000Graduateeducation 485,000 236,000

    Source:BlauandMackie(2016),Table8-12,pp.430-433.Allestimatesarein2013dollars.