Housing Market Note - Savillspdf.savills.com/documents/2015-06-04ValueofLand.pdf · Housing Market...

3
4 th June 2015 Housing Market Note Residential Research THE VALUE OF LAND A Leveraged Bet On House Prices? Land is the fundamental ingredient in the construction of new homes. Many of the issues limiting the rate of new home building can be traced back to the pricing and availability of land for residential development. The availability of development land is constrained by the planning system but also by other factors. Land is generally an appreciating asset and many landowners’ price expectations will be firmly set. Even if planning regulations were eased further, there are limited incentives for landowners to sell at a faster rate than they are currently as that might compromise the price they achieve. That is particularly the case where the land is already generating an income through other uses. Development land is typically valued using a residual approach with reference to comparable transactions. A developer assesses what new build house price is achievable in that location with reference to prices and sales rates in the second hand market and on nearby comparable new build sites. At a very basic level (assuming no affordable housing, S106 or CIL), multiply that new build house price by the number of homes to be built on the land and you arrive at the gross development value (GDV) of the site. The underlying value of the land is then the GDV less the cost of development and less an appropriate allowance for profit as the formula opposite shows. When in competition with other developers and assuming discipline on appropriate profit margins, the winning bidder will typically be the one that pushes for a combination of the highest new build price, the highest density (subject to planning) and the lowest build cost (unless one offsets the other). With land typically bought up front, this approach sets the target new build house price in stone. Developers will then only build and sell homes at the rate dictated by market demand for this target new build price. It is through this mechanism that the 10 to 1 ratio between overall housing market transactions and private housing starts is thought to arise. We can demonstrate the link between house prices and land values using a simple model. It uses Nationwide new build house prices as a proxy for GDV and the only input. It is based on an old land buyer’s rule of thumb: land is 1/3 rd of GDV. Therefore the modelled land value is 1/3 rd of the house price. The volatility in land prices is accounted for by assuming that the remaining 2/3 rds (effectively costs and profit) are sticky and do not fall. Therefore land values absorb the full impact of any falls in house price and the full benefit from any rises while house prices are below their previous peak. The model output (red line) does a reasonable job of tracing actual land values up until two years ago. Neal Hudson Associate Director 07590 531150 [email protected] @resi_analyst Residual Land Value = Gross Development Value - Development Costs - Profit Fig 1 Residential Development Land Values Source: Savills using VOA and Nationwide Savills Greenfield Land Index Valuation Office Agency (discontinued) Modelled Using New Build House Prices 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 Q1 1985 Q1 1986 Q1 1987 Q1 1988 Q1 1989 Q1 1990 Q1 1991 Q1 1992 Q1 1993 Q1 1994 Q1 1995 Q1 1996 Q1 1997 Q1 1998 Q1 1999 Q1 2000 Q1 2001 Q1 2002 Q1 2003 Q1 2004 Q1 2005 Q1 2006 Q1 2007 Q1 2008 Q1 2009 Q1 2010 Q1 2011 Q1 2012 Q1 2013 Q1 2014 Q1 2015 Index (2007 peak = 100) Start of Help-to- Buy Equity Loan

Transcript of Housing Market Note - Savillspdf.savills.com/documents/2015-06-04ValueofLand.pdf · Housing Market...

4th June 2015

Housing Market Note

Residential Research

THE VALUE OF LAND A Leveraged Bet On House Prices? Land is the fundamental ingredient in the construction of new homes. Many of the issues limiting the rate of new home building can be traced back to the pricing and availability of land for residential development.

The availability of development land is constrained by the planning system but also by other factors. Land is generally an appreciating asset and many landowners’ price expectations will be firmly set. Even if planning regulations were eased further, there are limited incentives for landowners to sell at a faster rate than they are currently as that might compromise the price they achieve. That is particularly the case where the land is already generating an income through other uses.

Development land is typically valued using a residual approach with reference to comparable transactions. A developer assesses what new build house price is achievable in that location with reference to prices and sales rates in the second hand market and on nearby comparable new build sites. At a very basic level (assuming no affordable housing, S106 or CIL), multiply that new build house price by the number of homes to be built on the land and you arrive at the gross development value (GDV) of the site. The underlying value of the land is then the GDV less the cost of development and less an appropriate allowance for profit as the formula opposite shows.

When in competition with other developers and assuming discipline on appropriate profit margins, the winning bidder will typically be the one that pushes for a combination of the highest new build price, the highest density (subject to planning) and the lowest build cost (unless one offsets the other). With land typically bought up front, this approach sets the target new build house price in stone. Developers will then only build and sell homes at the rate dictated by market demand for this target new build price. It is through this mechanism that the 10 to 1 ratio between overall housing market transactions and private housing starts is thought to arise.

We can demonstrate the link between house prices and land values using a simple model. It uses Nationwide new build house prices as a proxy for GDV and the only input. It is based on an old land buyer’s rule of thumb: land is 1/3rd of GDV. Therefore the modelled land value is 1/3rd of the house price. The volatility in land prices is accounted for by assuming that the remaining 2/3rds (effectively costs and profit) are sticky and do not fall. Therefore land values absorb the full impact of any falls in house price and the full benefit from any rises while house prices are below their previous peak. The model output (red line) does a reasonable job of tracing actual land values up until two years ago.

Neal Hudson Associate Director

07590 531150 [email protected]

@resi_analyst

Residual Land Value =

Gross Development Value -

Development Costs -

Profit

Fig 1 – Residential Development Land Values

Source: Savills using VOA and Nationwide

Savills Greenfield Land Index

Valuation Office Agency

(discontinued)

Modelled Using New Build House Prices

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

110

Q1

1985

Q1

1986

Q1

1987

Q1

1988

Q1

1989

Q1

1990

Q1

1991

Q1

1992

Q1

1993

Q1

1994

Q1

1995

Q1

1996

Q1

1997

Q1

1998

Q1

1999

Q1

2000

Q1

2001

Q1

2002

Q1

2003

Q1

2004

Q1

2005

Q1

2006

Q1

2007

Q1

2008

Q1

2009

Q1

2010

Q1

2011

Q1

2012

Q1

2013

Q1

2014

Q1

2015

Inde

x (2

007

peak

= 1

00)

Start of Help-to-Buy Equity Loan

2

4th June 2015

Housing Market Note

Other Factors At first sight, the model’s output suggests that there is substantial room for uplift in land values. However, the model is oversimplified by intention and the reality is more complex and varies by local market. Calculating actual land values has to account for a mix of property use classes; a mix of tenures; site remediation; infrastructure and CIL; affordable housing contributions; and other costs. It will also include forecasts for rates of sale, house prices and construction costs. These will then be balanced against the developer’s required rates of return. This all adds a degree of uncertainty to the calculation.

Many developers and housebuilders will remain cautious despite the current strength of the new build sales market. Housebuilders’ profit margins may be returning to pre-recession levels but there are other potential economic, political and market risks that warrant some caution. Build cost inflation and labour availability have been top of the constraints list recently and explain some of the underperformance. The need to absorb CIL and the lower value of affordable housing will continue to contribute to the gap between the model and actual land values in some markets. With large scale Government support of the housebuilding sector through the likes of Help-to-Buy, there will be political uncertainty created by the election cycle and a lack of long-term cross-party strategic planning for the provision of new homes.

Our house view is more balanced and suggests that the full uplift in land values will only be realised in markets with high housing demand and constrained land availability. There are currently a relatively high number of consents coming through the planning system compared to new housing starts although they are unevenly distributed across the country. Where starts exceed planning consents, this could lead to increased demand for land and an associated rise in land values. Thanks to the mechanisms detailed in this note, higher land values could then limit sales rates in markets unable to absorb higher new build prices. This approach means that developers and housebuilders will continue to build homes at a rate dictated by how fast they can sell them based on the price they had to pay for the land. The need for more land to be released is apparent.

Planning issues will always be a valid go-to complaint for developers but recent evidence suggests that the availability (and cost) of materials and labour has been a bigger constraint over the last couple of years. Survey responses from the HBF survey suggest these issues are declining in importance but remain high relative to recent years. The uncertainty around future build cost inflation will inevitably limit land prices to some degree.

Fig 2 – House Builder Production Constraints

Source: Home Builders Federation

Prior to 2001, indicators for build costs suggest that they generally matched the trend in house prices. That relationship broke down between 2001 and 2007 when house price inflation substantially outpaced build costs. The relationship has resumed post recession and the recent house price rises have been matched by increases in build costs.

Fig 3 –Build Costs Compared to Nationwide New Build House Price

Source: Nationwide, Holmans, BIS, ONS, BCIS

Labouravailability

Materials availabilityLand

availability/prices

Planning delays

Development finance

0102030405060708090

100

Q1

2000

Q1

2001

Q1

2002

Q1

2003

Q1

2004

Q1

2005

Q1

2006

Q1

2007

Q1

2008

Q1

2009

Q1

2010

Q1

2011

Q1

2012

Q1

2013

Q1

2014

Q1

2015

% c

onsi

derin

g fa

ctor

a 'm

ajor

co

nstra

int'

NationwideNew Build

House Price

Holmans

BIS

ONS

BCIS

5060708090

100110120130140150160

Q4

1973

Q4

1975

Q4

1977

Q4

1979

Q4

1981

Q4

1983

Q4

1985

Q4

1987

Q4

1989

Q4

1991

Q4

1993

Q4

1995

Q4

1997

Q4

1999

Q4

2001

Q4

2003

Q4

2005

Q4

2007

Q4

2009

Q4

2011

Q4

2013R

eal p

rice

indi

ces

(Q4

2001

=100

)

4th June 2015

Housing Market Note

The performance of local land values since the market peak in 2007 broadly reflects the underlying performance of the local housing market. There are exceptions that highlight local approaches to development and land release. Cambridge has seen similar or higher house price growth than other markets yet land values are lower relative to peak. This reflects the local approach where more land has been made available, including some from the Greenbelt, and there is clarity on the level of affordable housing required.

Fig 4 – Development Land Value & House Price Change From 2007 Peak

Source: HM Land Registry, Savills

Although not directly relevant to the above analysis, the chart opposite shows the trend in land values between 1892 and 1969. The substantial premium for commercial land across the period and the divergence in value between residential and agricultural land from the 1930s are both interesting features and reflect the importance of location in land values. Care should be taken in reading too much into any single year given the data collection periods.

Fig 5 – Land Values & Housebuilding

Source: Bank of England, EA Vallis, Estates Gazette

Previous Issues Peak Loneliness

http://sav.li/43c

Size Mattershttp://sav.li/3z8

This report is for general informative purposes only. It may not be published, reproduced or quoted in part or in whole, nor may it be used as aprospectus, agreement or other document without prior consent. Whilst every effort has been made to ensureany direct or consequential loss arising from its use. The content is strictly copyright and reproduction of the whole or parwritten permission from Savills Research.

-10%

-5%

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

-60%

Hou

se p

rice

chan

ge fr

om 2

007

peak

£100

£1,000

£10,000

£100,000

£1,000,000

Pric

e pe

r acr

e (lo

g)

Development Land Value & House Price Change From 2007 Peak

Source: HM Land Registry, Savills Land Values & Housebuilding – 1892 to 1969

Bank of England, EA Vallis, Estates Gazette (1973), DCLG

Size Matters http://sav.li/3z8

Housing Delivery http://sav.li/3wo

general informative purposes only. It may not be published, reproduced or quoted in part or in whole, nor may it be used as a

prospectus, agreement or other document without prior consent. Whilst every effort has been made to ensure its accuracy, Savills accepts no liability whatsoever for any direct or consequential loss arising from its use. The content is strictly copyright and reproduction of the whole or par

60% -40% -20% 0%Land value change from 2007 peak

Cambridge

Reading/Bracknell

UK

Milton Keynes

Norwich

Telford

Lincoln

Housebuilding (rhs)

Industrial

Commercial

Residential

Agricultural

£100

£1,000

£10,000

£100,000

£1,000,000

1890

1894

1898

1902

1906

1910

1914

1918

1922

1926

1930

1934

1938

1942

1946

1950

3

Development Land Value & House Price Change From 2007 Peak

Pension Reform http://sav.li/3ul

general informative purposes only. It may not be published, reproduced or quoted in part or in whole, nor may it be used as a basis for any contract,

its accuracy, Savills accepts no liability whatsoever for any direct or consequential loss arising from its use. The content is strictly copyright and reproduction of the whole or part of it in any form is prohibited without

20% 40%Land value change from 2007 peak

Oxford

Sevenoaks

London

Residential

Agricultural

0

50,000

100,000

150,000

200,000

250,000

300,000

350,000

400,000

450,000

1954

1958

1962

1966

1970

Ann

ual h

ouse

build

ing