HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

download HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

of 28

Transcript of HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    1/28

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    2/28

    debates within the social fabric of each respective country. Through a

    comparative policy analysis, our paper does so by contextualizing higher-education policies within a welfare regime framework.

    The key for a meaningful comparative analysis is a comprehensive

    understanding of the trade-offs with which each country is faced when

    endeavouring to expand its higher-education system. It is simply not possible

    to achieve all of the following goals at the same time: low taxation, low or no

    tuition fees, high non-repayable student aid, and a high participation rate in

    adequately funded higher-education institutions. Policy decisions are necessary

    to prioritize these goals all of which are advocated by at least some interest

    groups. How countries deal with and respond to these trade-offs largely

    depend on their welfare regimes and the political traditions within which theyare embedded and upon which they rely. We propose that the concept of the

    welfare regime is a useful analytical tool to understand the different national

    approaches in higher education funding and development.

    Conceptual Perspectives

    Considerable variation can be observed in the social policies of advanced

    industrial nations. According to Hega and Hokenmaier (2002, 2), the specific

    nature of their provisions for healthcare, work injury, unemploymentcompensation, and old age pensions bear important consequences for the

    socioeconomic opportunities and outcomes of individuals and groups. A

    nations social programs reflect the socioeconomic and political institutions

    that shaped them. Categorization and classification of public social policies

    according to their content and extent of their provisions has resulted in the

    development of national profiles that have been further aggregated into

    typologies of welfare state regimes. The latter has been accomplished by

    generating categories according to the similarity of their social programs, by

    their tendency to produce similar and distinctive public policies (ibid.). In this

    paper, we employ the typology of welfare regimes advanced by Esping-

    Andersen (1990, 1999). Although other schemas exist, Esping-Andersens

    typology is described as a modern classic (Arts and Gelissen, 2002) that has

    dominated the field of research on welfare states (Hicks and Kenworthy, 2003).

    We prefer this framework as it incorporates a complex set of policy dynamics

    embedded within the state, market, and family. As Esping-Andersen (1999, 4)

    argues, such an approach allows for the interaction between the composite

    parts that, in unison, form contemporary welfare regimes. It is beyond the

    scope and page limitations of this paper to provide an extensive review of the

    literature. For such reviews, see for example, Arts and Gelissen (2002), Bradleyet al. (2003), Hicks and Kenworthy (2003), and Starke (2006).

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    26

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    3/28

    However, another related body of literature is worth mentioning. Iversen

    and Stephens (2008) have compared the welfare regime typology with theproduction regime approach of the varieties of capitalism theory (Hall and

    Soskice, 2001). The latter approach specifies differences in liberal market

    economies and coordinated market economies by contrasting the extent to

    which different regimes focus on general vs specific skill formation and the

    extent to which they provide vocational training. The interrelationships among

    social insurance, skill formation, and financing public education are central to

    the production regime typology. The extent to which each is embraced defines

    the location of a given country into one of the three worlds of human capital

    formation defined in this approach. Iversen and Stephens explicate how

    relationships among institutions, political parties, and electoral systemsinfluence and shape skill formation regimes. Elsewhere, we (Pechar and

    Andres, 2010) have employed such a comparative approach to examine

    educational and skill formation in secondary and tertiary education. In this

    paper, however, we focus on tertiary education and hence our conceptual lens

    is directed on general level skill formation.

    Welfare Regimes

    Esping-Andersen (1990) identified three types of welfare regimes that are shaped

    by political traditions and are characterized by coherent patterns of welfare policy.He describes different welfare regimes as qualitatively different arrangements

    between state, market, and the family (p. 26). A key concept of this typology is

    de-commodification, which refers to the degree to which individuals, or families,

    can uphold a socially acceptable standard of living independently of market

    participation (p. 37). The main criteria employed in Esping-Andersens typology

    is de-commodification of welfare provisions for old-age pensions, healthcare, and

    unemployment compensation (p. 50). The three types are as follows:

    Liberal welfare regimes(e.g., Canada, USA, Australia, New Zealand, and UK)

    are characterized by a low degree of de-commodification and a strong role for

    markets in the production of welfare. In liberal regimes, states provide a

    residual function; that is, the state assumes responsibility only when the family

    and market fails; it seeks to limit its commitments to marginal and deserving

    groups (Esping-Andersen, 1990, 20). Other characteristics include heavy

    reliance on minimal means tested benefits for clientele of low income (which

    often leads to stigmatization when receiving such benefits) and subsidies to

    private welfare schemes.

    Conservative welfare regimes (e.g., Austria, France, Germany, Netherlands,Italy, Switzerland, and Belgium) are characterized by a strong corporatist

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    27

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    4/28

    legacy and a commitment to preserve social structures and hierarchies, and in

    particular the traditional family. They are dominated by status-preservingsocial insurance schemes. Conservative welfare regimes support preservation of

    thestatus quoand its inequalities. Social rights are attached to class, status, and

    work effort. The primary provider of welfare insurance is the state, with the

    market and private insurance playing only marginal roles.

    Social-democratic (universal) welfare regimes (e.g., Denmark, Norway,

    Sweden, and Finland) are characterized by universal benefits based on

    citizenship, equal access to benefits and services of high standards, and a high

    degree of de-commodification. Welfare coverage is universal and the state

    attempts to treat all citizens equally and at a much higher standard thanminimal need. The goal is to guarantee the individual and families a socially

    acceptable standard of living independently of market participation (Esping-

    Andersen, 1990, 37) without discouraging individual aspirations or denying the

    opportunity for private socio-economic achievement.

    This typology has been criticized for not including education as part of the

    policy packages of welfare regimes. Although Esping-Andersen (1990) clearly

    delimited his attention and empirical investigation to income maintenance,

    pensions, and health services, he did acknowledge the importance of education

    as part of welfare policy:

    What, then, constitute salient dimensions of welfare-state stratification?

    Apart from its purely income-distributive role, the welfare state shapes

    class and status in a variety of ways. The educational system is an obvious

    and much studied instance, in which individuals mobility chances not only

    are affected, but from which entire class structures evolve.y[Moreover],

    the organization of social services, particularly for women, is decisive for a

    nations employment structure. (Esping-Andersen, 1990, 58)

    Moreover, he points out that except for the examination of the role of

    education in mobility studies, job attainment in relation to the welfare state has

    been largely unexamined (p. 146). In his more recent writing, he addresses the

    importance of education more directly (Esping-Andersen, 2009). Hokenmaier

    (1998) and Hega and Hokenmaier (2002) maintain that education policy

    should be included both conceptually and empirically in such analyses. After

    World War II, higher education was incorporated as an essential part of a

    coherent welfare-policy structure (along with healthcare, education, housing,

    and employment). However, from the 1950s to the 1970s, as welfare policies

    proliferated in most OECD countries, systematic differences prevailed.

    According to Hokenmaier (1998), education policy is clearly one component

    of a nations total public policy package; and it is not independent of othersocial policies (p. 710). Hega and Hokenmaier (2002) assert that education

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    28

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    5/28

    is no less than other public programs, recognized as a core entitlement in most

    Western countries (p. 2) in that it allows for upward social mobility, reducesthe extent to which individuals are dependent on wage labour and market

    forces, allows for the ability of individuals to improve their socio-economic

    status, and hence ameliorates individual overall life chances. As a result, more

    highly educated individuals are less likely to place demands on social safety

    nets; in turn, decreased demand will lessen the pressure on welfare states to

    provide income assistance and other social welfare programs. Castles (1989)

    points out that because of the possibility that education marches in step to a

    different drummer from other aspects of the peoples welfare (p. 432), it

    warrants particular attention as part of the welfare policy rubric. In Esping-

    Andersens (1999) later work, somewhat more of the discussion is devoted toeducation and skills in relation to equality. However, he invites educational

    experts to design a workable system of skilling entitlements, one that would

    befit an ideal postindustrial welfare regime (p. 184).

    Because the educational policy arena is vast, in this paper we focus primarily

    on higher education.1 Specifically, we seek to determine the nature and extent

    to which there is a consistent relationship between higher-education policy

    making and the different welfare regimes by examining whether systematic

    differences exist in (1) tertiary2 participation and graduation patterns; (2) pre-

    tertiary prerequisites for entry into tertiary education; (3) the role of

    government with respect to funding higher education; and (4) tuition feesand student financial aid policies and arrangements. However, in order to do

    so, we need to introduce the conceptual dimension of trade-off into the

    discussion.

    The Trade-Off Argument

    By adding education to the mix of social welfare policies to which countries

    must direct financial attention, we can consider whether and the extent to

    which educational policy competes with other welfare policies for public sector

    funding support. A small body of literature has demonstrated this relationship

    (Heidenheimer, 1981; Castles, 1989; Hokenmaier, 1998; Hega and Hokenmaier,

    2002). In an analysis of long term public policy trends in Europe and the USA,

    Heidenheimer (1981) concludes that a trade-off occurred in the extent to which

    countries have historically invested in either providing public post-primary

    educational opportunities or social insurance programs. Castles (1989) explains

    that the two sets of policy alternatives have different goals. Whereas social

    welfare policies such as unemployment insurance and old age pensions are

    intended to ensure equality of condition, the goal of educational policies is toenhance equality of opportunity. This trade-off thesis adds explanatory power

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    29

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    6/28

    to the paradox that although liberal regimes exhibit more inequality with

    respect to most indicators (e.g., income, Gini co-efficient, and housing patterns),they are socially more inclusive than conservative regimes in regard to

    educational participation and completion rates at all levels beyond post-primary.

    By directing resources toward education rather than toward policies that

    would buttress the development of other forms of social welfare, support for

    public education over social protection programs becomes an alternative

    welfare state policy strategy (Castles, 1989). The latter is future directed that

    is, oriented to improving the life chances of future generations, as opposed to

    supporting equality of condition of the current generation. However, historical

    funding preference for one set of social programs over the other may lead to

    difficulties in switching policy directions in the future (Hega and Hokenmaier,2002). Hega and Hokenmaier add that countries favouring post-primary

    educational opportunities are signalling that public safety nets exist only as

    temporary assistance and to buffer the effects of extreme socioeconomic change,

    not to insulate the individual from every risk of life, societal competition, and

    market forces (p. 4). In doing so, greater self-reliance on the part of the

    individual is encouraged and expected and education serves to provide the

    individual with the necessary human capital to succeed in the market.

    Some authors have attempted to link the trade-off thesis to Esping-

    Andersens theory of three distinctive welfare regimes by claiming that

    particular tendencies in educational policy correspond to Esping-Andersenswelfare regime types. We agree with Hega and Hokenmaier (2002) that it is a

    useful exercise to consider this typology in relation to the extent that there is a

    trade-off between public funding support for education and other social

    programs in welfare states. In this paper, informed by the findings and

    following along Hega and Hokenmaiers line of inquiry, we seek to further

    explore the relationships among welfare regimes, extent of expansion of higher

    education, and related trade-offs.

    One can question whether trade-offs that imply choosing between two

    alternatives are unavoidable. The welfare regime typology offers three

    perspectives, one of which appears to transcend such a binary trade-off. For

    that purpose, the concept of a trilemmaof subsidization, coverage, and public

    cost, as specified by Ansell (2008), may be more valid as it includes level of

    taxation as one of the dimensions of the public policy process. We revisit this in

    the conclusion and in light of our findings.

    Research Design

    To examine our analytical framework, we advance a few hypotheses. First, weexpect to find systematic differences in participation in tertiary education

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    30

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    7/28

    among the different welfare regimes. We expect that conservative regimes

    constrain the expansion of higher education. The main reason is the strongpreference embedded in the institutional arrangements of conservative

    regimes for preserving the established social order. Hence, educational

    opportunities are strongly linked to social estates.3 As a consequence, these

    regimes practise a strong kind of sponsored mobility (Turner, 1960). That is,

    the potential of the young generation is identified at a very early age and high

    potentials are encouraged to stay in the educational track that leads to the

    highest educational credentials; at the same time, the ambitions of the rest are

    discouraged and they are assigned to more modest opportunities (e.g., different

    tracks at lower secondary school and early vocational specialisation for the

    majority of the age group).We hypothesize that both liberal and social-democratic welfare regimes

    differ from the conservative approach in that they both welcome and

    encourage expansion at the tertiary level on the grounds of human capital

    enhancement and for equity considerations. Hence, we would expect a

    comparatively long period of comprehensive schooling, less (or even no)

    emphasis on vocational training at the secondary level, and, as a consequence,

    high entry and graduation rates at the tertiary level. However, we would also

    expect differences between the two regimes:

    Liberal regimes foster unrestricted human capital creation, they emphasizeindividual achievement and responsibility, and advancement to high levels of

    study based on meritocratic criteria (Turner, 1960). Education tends to be

    socially inclusive, through encouraging high aspirations and expectations

    (by, e.g., giving second and third chances) and by fostering social mobility.

    Encouragement of social mobility also serves to mitigate conflicts about

    social inequalities. There is very little (if any) social engineering and

    adjusting individual ambitions and societal needs. However, the strong

    emphasis on individual rights goes hand in hand with the requirement of

    large financial investments by individuals, unmatched by any other regime.

    Social-democratic regimes strive for a delicate balance between individualrights and the collective order. This collective order is not (as with the

    conservative regimes) the established hierarchy of social estates, but rather

    a notion of public welfare constructed by rational policy making. Hence,

    human capital formation is embedded within an overarching welfare

    structure and labour market policies (e.g., state economic and social

    planning, active labour-market policy, public responsibility for full employ-

    ment, and the provision of high-quality jobs in the public sector).

    Higher levels of tertiary participation require higher levels of funding.

    Hence, we look at different indicators for funding of tertiary education. First,we hypothesize that liberal regimes spend a high percentage of both total public

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    31

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    8/28

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    9/28

    adult population aged 2534 years who have attained tertiary level A and B

    credentials; adult population aged 2564 years who have attained tertiary level A and B

    credentials.4

    Second, we employ four pre-tertiary indicators as measures of prerequisites

    to tertiary education entry. These indicators are measures of the preconditions

    in place that determine the extent to which students can enter the next levels of

    education. For example, early tracking, as indicated by age of first selection

    into upper levels of education is a powerful instrument of social selection in

    that individuals are routed to institutions which, in turn, will largely determine

    their future life chances. The proportion of the age group engaged in general orvocational levels of education illustrates the proportion that will potentially

    enter university-level education, or conversely, an indicator of those destined

    for early vocational specialization. The likelihood of the students in vocational

    programs to enrol in tertiary education is smaller than those in general

    programs. The expectation to participate in International Standard Classifica-

    tion of Education (ISCED) level 5A or 6 is an indicator reflecting the

    ambitions of students shaped by the cultural climate and the expectations of

    society. The indicators we employ are as follows:

    first, age at which selection takes place; the proportion of age group in general programmes of upper secondary

    education5;

    the proportion of age group in vocational programmes of upper secondary

    education;

    the proportion of students expecting to complete ISCED level 5A or 6.

    Third, we examine the implications of these different welfare (and education)

    regimes on funding tertiary education, using the three indicators as specified

    separately below:

    public tertiary educational expenditures as a percentage of total publicexpenditures.

    This indicator signals the extent to which tertiary education policies have

    priority within the overall framework of government policies.

    public tertiary educational expenditures as a percentage of GDP.

    This indicator is a measure of the extent of public tertiary educational

    expenditures in relation to the wealth of a country.

    tertiary expenditures from public and private sources on educationalinstitutions as a percentage of GDP.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    33

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    10/28

    These are measures of (a) the extent of spending on tertiary education in

    relation to the wealth of a country, and (b) the proportion of public and privatesources of these expenditures.

    Finally, we look at the different patterns of tuition and student aid. We use

    the following indicators:

    estimated average annual tuition fees charged by tertiary-type A public

    educational institutions: actual amounts in USD;

    proportion of students with loans;

    annual gross amount of loan available to each student: actual amount in

    USD;

    proportion of graduates with debt;

    average amount of debt at graduation in USD.

    We employ these data to systematically relate the various dimensions of

    higher education within a framework of the welfare arrangements of each

    country. We have selected 16 of the 18 countries used by Esping-Andersen

    (1990)6 and organized our analyses around three different types of welfare

    states: conservative welfare states (Austria, France, Germany, the Netherlands.

    Italy, Switzerland, and Belgium), liberal welfare states (Canada, USA,

    Australia, New Zealand, and UK), and social-democratic (universal) welfarestates (Sweden, Denmark, Norway, and Finland). We use the data described

    above to demonstrate the logic of the relationships among participation in

    tertiary education, pre-tertiary prerequisites, educational funding, and levels of

    tuition and student financial aid.

    We recognize that extensions to Esping-Andersens original model have been

    proposed. For example, Mills and Blossfeld (2003) suggest a fivefold typology

    by adding two categories: the family-orientedregime of the Southern European

    countries (e.g., Italy and Spain) and the post-socialistic welfare regime to

    account for countries of the former socialist countries of Eastern Europe.

    Similarly, Castles (1993) has asserted that the liberal regime should be further

    divided to account for the role of labour movements in policy formation of

    some countries. However, Esping-Andersen (1999) has addressed these

    concerns and demonstrates that the explanatory benefits obtained by extending

    the number of categories is a matter of greater refinement, more nuance, and

    more precision (p. 92) but not of additional dimensionality. In this paper, we

    delimit our analysis to Esping-Andersens original three-regime framework.

    However, because we are focusing on tertiary education and as such are using a

    different set of indicators from those previously employed in other analyses,

    the results may suggest that an expansion of this framework is warranted. Wewill take up this issue in the discussion.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    34

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    11/28

    Results

    The most coherent and reliable database for international comparisons in

    education is that which contains the OECD indicators. However, this data set

    is far from perfect. Not all countries provided data for all indicators we wanted

    to include in this comparison. Also, some indicators are difficult to interpret.

    Despite its limitations, this database allows for an initial assessment of the

    soundness of our hypotheses. The data are summarized in Tables 1 to 4.

    Most of the data have been extracted from the 2008 OECD Education at a

    Glance (OECD, 2008a). Occasionally, we supplement missing data from this

    report with data available in the 2007 and 2006 reports (OECD, 2006a, 2007).

    In addition, when it is reasonable to do so, we supplement missing OECDindicators as specified above with indicators related to tuition and student

    financial assistance compiled by Usher (2005) and with data on tuition and

    student financial aid reported by Vossensteyn (2004). A more complete data

    profile permits a thorough examination of the types of student financial

    assistance provided by these countries. Data from sources other than the

    OECD 2008 report are identified in the tables.

    In Tables 1 to 4, we observe that there is wide variation within each of the

    three groups and a significant amount of overlap among the different regimes.

    Nonetheless, there is a correspondence between the indicators and welfare

    regimes.By examining enrolment and graduation patterns (Table 1), conservative

    regimes are clearly at the bottom with respect to expansion of tertiary

    education, with the Netherlands being a sort of outlier, whereas liberal regimes

    are at the top. Entry rates into tertiary-type A institutions vary between 35 and

    58% in conservative regimes, between 59 and 76% in social-democratic

    regimes, and between 57 and 84% in liberal regimes. This pattern remains

    evident in graduation rates (tertiary-type A), with conservative regimes varying

    between 21 and 43%, social-democratic regimes between 41 and 48%, and liberal

    regimes between 36 and 59%. Graduation rates from tertiary-type B institutions

    range from 7 to 19% in conservative regimes, 0 to 10% in social-democraticregimes, and 10 to 24% in liberal regimes. The range of the adult population aged

    2534 years of age holding tertiary-type A credentials extends from 1334%

    (conservative), 2940% (social-democratic), to 2935% (liberal). Comparable

    figures for tertiary-type B are 122%, 20%, and 526%, respectively.

    The long-term impact of educational expansion can be assessed by

    examining the proportion of the population aged 2564 years with tertiary-

    level credentials. Again, the proportion with tertiary-type A credentials within

    the conservative countries is low (1028%) when compared with social-

    democratic (1931%) and liberal regimes (2235%). Also, those aged 2564

    years holding tertiary-type B level credentials is low in both conservative and

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    35

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    12/28

    Table1

    IndicatorsofparticipationintertiaryeducationinselectOECDcountriesa

    Conservative

    Liberal

    Socialdemocratic

    AU

    FR

    DE

    NL

    IT

    CH

    BE

    CA

    US

    AUS

    NZ

    UK

    SE

    DK

    NO

    FI

    Entryratesintotertiaryeducation

    Tertiary-typeA

    40

    39**

    35

    58

    55

    38

    35

    m

    64

    84

    72

    57

    76

    59

    67

    76

    Tertiary-typeB

    7

    34**

    13

    n

    m

    15

    36

    m

    m

    m

    49

    29

    10

    22

    n

    a

    Grad

    uationratesfromtertiaryeducatio

    n

    Tertiary-typeA

    22

    27**

    21

    43

    39

    30

    m

    37

    36

    59

    52

    39

    41

    45

    43

    48

    Tertiary-typeB

    7

    19**

    11

    n

    n

    10

    m

    m

    10

    m

    24

    15

    5

    10

    1

    0

    Populationaged2534yearsthathasa

    ttainedtertiarylevelcredentials

    Tertiary-typeA

    13

    24

    15

    34

    17

    23

    19

    29

    35

    29

    30

    29

    31

    32

    40

    29

    Tertiary-typeB

    6

    18

    7

    2

    1

    9

    22

    26

    5

    10

    14

    8

    9

    9

    2

    9

    Populationaged2564yearswithtertiarylevelcredentials

    Tertiary-typeA

    10

    16

    15

    28

    12

    20

    14

    24

    35

    24

    23

    22

    22

    27

    31

    19

    Tertiary-typeB

    7

    11

    9

    2

    1

    10

    18

    23

    5

    9

    15

    9

    9

    8

    2

    16

    Changebetween2534and3564yearspopulationwithtertiarylevelcred

    entials

    Tertiary-typeA

    +3

    +8

    0

    +6

    +5

    +3

    +5

    +5

    0

    +5

    +7

    +7

    +9

    +5

    +9

    +10

    Tertiary-typeB

    1

    7

    2

    0

    0

    1

    +4

    +3

    0

    1

    1

    1

    0

    +1

    0

    7

    Total

    2

    15

    2

    +6

    +5

    +2

    +9

    +8

    0

    +4

    +6

    +6

    +9

    +6

    +9

    +3

    aDatasources:OECD,2008aandsupplementedwithOECD,2005,2006a,2007whennecessary.

    n

    Magnitudeiseithernegligibleor

    zero.

    a

    Dataarenotapplicablebecausethecategorydoesnotapply.

    m

    Dataarenotavailable.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    36

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    13/28

    Tab

    le3

    Educationalexpendituresin

    selectOECDcountries

    Conservative

    Libera

    l

    Socialdemocratic

    AU

    FR

    DE

    NL

    IT

    CH

    BE

    CA

    US

    AUS

    NZ

    UK

    SE

    DK

    NO

    FI

    Educationalexpenditures

    Publictertiaryeducationalexpendituresasa

    percentageoftotalpublicexpenditu

    res

    3.0

    2.2

    2.4

    3.0

    1.6

    3.3

    2.6

    4.2

    3.5

    3.5**

    4.8

    2.7

    3.5

    4.5

    5.3*

    4.0

    Publictertiaryeducationalexpendituresasa

    percentageofGDP

    1.5

    1.2

    1.1

    1.4

    0.8

    1.5

    1.3

    1.7

    1.3

    1.1

    1.5

    1.2

    1.9

    2.4

    2.3

    2.0

    Expenditureoneducationalinstitutions

    asa%

    ofGDP(publicandprivatesources)

    Total

    1.3

    1.3

    1.1

    1.3

    0.9

    1.4

    1.24

    2.6

    2.9

    1.6

    1.5

    1.3

    1.6

    1.7

    1.3

    1.7

    Public

    1.2

    1.1

    0.9

    1.0

    0.6

    1.4

    1.2

    1.4

    1.0

    0.8

    0.9

    0.9

    1.5

    1.6

    1.3

    1.7

    Private

    0.1

    0.2

    0.2

    0.3

    0.3

    0.0

    0.1

    1.1

    1.9

    0.8

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    Tab

    le2

    Pre-tertiaryindicatorsinselectOECDcountries

    Conservative

    Liberal

    Socialdemocratic

    AU

    FR

    DE

    NL

    IT

    CH

    BE

    CA

    US

    AUS

    NZ

    UK

    SE

    DK

    NO

    FI

    Pre-

    tertiaryindicators

    E

    arliestageofselection(years)

    10

    15

    10

    12

    14

    15

    12

    16

    16

    16

    16

    14a

    16

    16

    16

    16

    Proportioninuppersecondary

    generaleducation

    22

    57

    41

    33

    40

    36

    31

    95

    100.0

    38

    100**

    58

    45

    52

    40

    35

    Proportioninuppersecondary

    vocationaleducation

    72

    43

    59

    68

    25

    64

    69

    5

    0

    62

    0**

    42

    54

    48

    60

    65

    Proportionexpectedtocomplete

    IS

    CEDlevel5Aor6

    24

    35

    19

    41

    52

    18

    35

    63

    64

    63

    39

    32

    33

    26

    26

    52

    aWe

    useage14yearsfortheUKbasedoninformationprovidedinthesesites:inhttp://www.direct.gov.u

    k/en/EducationAndLearning/14To19/

    Yea

    rs10And11/DG_10013567;http://www.direct.gov.uk/en/EducationAndLearning/QualificationsExplained/DG_10039024;

    http

    ://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200708/cmselect/cmchilsch/169/16905.htm.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    37

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    14/28

    Tab

    le4

    Tuitionandstudentfinancia

    laidindicatorsintertiaryeducationinselectOECDcountries

    Conservative

    Liberal

    Socialdemocratic

    AU

    FR

    DE

    NL

    IT

    CH

    BE

    CA

    US

    AUS

    NZ

    UK

    SE

    DK

    NO

    FI

    Tuitionandstudentfinancialaid

    Estimatedaverageannualtuition

    fee

    schargedbytertiary-typeA

    pu

    bliceducationalinstitutionsor

    government-dependentprivate

    ins

    titutions(USD)

    837

    330a

    1,210b

    1,505b

    1,017

    1,873c

    574

    3,464

    5,027

    3,855

    2,6

    71

    1,859

    0

    0

    0

    0

    Finan

    cialaidtostudentsasa%

    oftotalpublicexpenditureontertiaryeducation

    Studentloans

    m

    a

    5.1

    15.5

    n

    0.2

    N

    2.8

    8.6

    17.7

    30

    .0

    19.1

    16.8

    5.0

    37.1

    n

    Scholarships/other

    grantstohouseholds

    16.8

    7.9

    14.1

    12.3

    16.8

    2.2

    15.2

    11.5

    14.9

    14.7

    11

    .6

    6.7

    10.3

    25.8

    10.9

    16.6

    To

    tal

    16.8

    7.9

    19.1

    27.7

    16.8

    2.4

    15.2

    14.4

    23.5

    32.3

    41

    .5

    25.8

    27.1

    30.8

    42.6

    16.6

    Proportionofstudentswithloans%

    0

    0

    0

    28

    0

    0

    1

    m

    38

    79

    m

    m

    80

    42

    100

    26

    Annualgrossamountofloan

    availabletoeachstudent(USD)

    0

    0

    0

    5,730

    0

    0

    m

    3,970

    6,430

    3,450

    4,3

    20

    5,480

    4,940

    2,500

    8,960

    2,710

    Proportionofgraduateswithdebt(%)

    0

    0

    15d

    15d

    0

    0

    0d

    50d

    65

    67

    57

    79

    83

    49

    78b

    39

    Averagedebtatgraduation(USD)

    0

    0

    6,973d

    12,270

    0

    0

    0c

    14,170d

    19,400

    10,838d

    15,320

    14,220

    20,590

    10,430

    20,290

    6,160

    aFranceaverageoftheOECDrange160490.

    bDa

    tafromVossensteyn,2004in2005USD.

    cSwitzerlanddiscrepanciesaredueto

    roundingerrors.

    dDa

    tafromUsherandCervenan,200

    5in2005USD.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    38

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    15/28

    social-democratic regimes. In contrast, there is wide variation in countries

    within the liberal regime rubric. When compared with the 2564-years agegroup, only two conservative countries (France and Belgium) have experienced

    large increases in the proportion of 2534 year olds participating in tertiary

    education. Yet, the proportion of the 2534-years age group with tertiary-type

    A credentials in these countries remains relatively low. The US has experienced

    zero growth. However, the 2564-years age group of this country is the most

    educated when compared with the same age group in all the countries we have

    included in the analysis. In other words, post-secondary expansion occurred

    much earlier in the US (see OECD, 2008a, Chart A1.3, 32). Goldin and Katz

    (2008) have demonstrated that the US was the pioneer of tertiary expansion,

    but since the 1980s has lost momentum.These systematic differences observed at the tertiary level could be

    anticipated and indeed are evident at earlier stages of educational careers.

    Table 2 demonstrates that selection into different school tracks commences

    much earlier in conservative regimes than in liberal and social-democratic

    regimes. Also, in conservative regimes, only 1841% of students at age 15 years

    expect to complete ISCED level 5A or 6, compared with 2652% in social-

    democratic regimes and 3264% in liberal regimes. However, the proportion of

    students attending upper secondary general studies varies considerably both

    within and among regimes at 2257% (conservative), 3552% (social-

    democratic), and 38100%7 (liberal regimes). Similarly, the proportion ofstudents enrolled in upper secondary vocational education varies across

    regimes, but is overall considerably lower in liberal regimes.

    These systematic differences in indicators that point to different levels of

    tertiary expansion and its preconditions are consistent with the differences at

    the level of funding. Consistent with enrolment and graduation rates, Table 3

    reveals the range of expenditures on tertiary education. The pattern is one of

    low contributions in conservative regimes and higher contributions in both

    liberal and social-democratic regimes. For example, public tertiary educational

    expenditure as a percentage of total public expenditure is low in conservative

    regimes (1.63.3%), moderate in liberal regimes (2.74.8%) and high in social-

    democratic welfare regimes (3.55.3%). Public tertiary educational expendi-

    tures as a percentage of GDP mirror these findings at 0.81.5% in conservative

    regimes, 1.11.7 in liberal regimes and 1.92.4% in social-democratic welfare

    regimes. In terms of total expenditure on educational institutions as a

    percentage of GDP at the tertiary level, liberal regimes are highest (1.32.9%),

    followed by social-democratic regimes (1.31.7), and conservative regimes

    (0.91.4%). If we differentiate between private and public expenditures, it

    becomes evident that the exceptionally high level of tertiary spending in some

    liberal countries (mainly North America) is possible only through very highprivate contributions. Private expenditures on tertiary education as a

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    39

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    16/28

    proportion of GDP are moderate in conservative regimes (0.10.3) and even

    lower in social-democratic regimes (0.10.2). In contrast, there is widevariation in liberal regime countries (0.41.9). However, it is noteworthy that

    UK with the lowest percentage exceeds event the highest percentage from any

    other regime. The US is exceptional in that private expenditures exceed public

    expenditures.

    The most important facet of private tertiary expenditures is tuition fees.

    Average annual tuition fees in the liberal regimes vary between 1,859 and 5,027

    USD. In conservative regimes they vary between 330 and 1,873 USD. Social-

    democratic regimes charge no fees at all (Table 4). Respectively, the relatively

    high level of spending in social-democratic regimes is reflected in high public

    expenditures on tertiary education as a percentage of GDP (see paragraphabove), whereas in conservative and liberal regimes the range is similar. These

    findings support our funding matrix hypothesis; that is, conservative regimes

    have low/medium public expenditures in combination with low/no tuition fees.

    Social-democratic regimes have high public expenditures and no tuition fees.

    Liberal regimes combine low/medium public expenditures with high tuition

    fees. Conservative and social-democratic regimes share a strong tendency to

    de-commodification, hence no/low tuition fees. Social-democratic and liberal

    regimes share a commitment to expansion of tertiary education; hence, they

    must raise not only sufficient resources but also the sources for funding tertiary

    education differ.The commitment to tertiary expansion requires sufficient means for student

    aid. According to the OECD (2008a),

    a key question in many OECD countries is whether financial subsidies for

    households should primarily be provided in the form of grants or loans.

    y Advocates of student loans argue that money spent on loans goes

    further: if the amount spent on grants were used to guarantee or subsidise

    loans instead, more aid would be available to students and overall access

    would increase. Loans also shift some of the cost of education to those

    who benefit most from educational investment. Opponents of loans arguethat student loans are less effective than grants in encouraging low-

    income students to pursue their education. (p. 275)

    OECD data reveal a clear relationship between the availability of student

    loans on the one hand and the amount of public financial aid to students on the

    other hand. Of all the countries covered in this paper, only those with loan

    schemes exceed the OECD average of public student aid as a percentage of total

    public expenditures on tertiary education (Table 4). Owing to a few outliers,

    variation does exist within all welfare regimes; however, a clear pattern can be

    identified. In the conservative regimes public student aid as a percentage of totalpublic expenditures on tertiary education ranges from 2.4 to 27.7%. Only the

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    40

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    17/28

    Netherlands (substantively) and Germany (marginally) exceed the OECD

    average of 17.6%. These are the only countries within the conservative familywith public loan schemes available. In the liberal countries, student aid ranges

    between 14.4 and 32.3% of total public expenditures. In all liberal countries

    public loan schemes are available; all but Canada spend more than the OECD

    average. The social-democratic regimes spend the highest percentage of their

    tertiary expenditures on student aid (16.642.6%). Finland, where loans only

    play a marginal role, is an outlier; hence, it is slightly below the OECD average.

    We can conclude that loans predominate in those countries, which are

    committed to tertiary expansion. As no country can afford to support a large

    number of students only by non-repayable stipends and scholarships (a pattern

    of support that was dominant in an era of elite higher education when thenumber of students who applied for support was small), social-democratic and

    liberal regimes have designed a wide range of student loan schemes.

    Conversely, in conservative regimes where expansion has remained low, loans

    play either a less important or no role at all. As expected, over 50% of students

    in liberal regimes graduate with student debt and the average amount of debt at

    graduation is high (i.e., greater than 14,000 USD). However, contrary to our

    hypotheses, a high proportion of students from social-democratic countries

    also have high debt loads and the average amount of student debt is high.

    Finland is the exception.

    By combining tuition fees and student aid data, the OECD has identifiedfour patterns that strongly align with the welfare regime typology. We can

    summarize the OECD findings as follows8: The first pattern defined by no or

    low tuition fees but quite generous student support systems (OECD, 2008a,

    272) includes the Nordic countries. The second pattern that is defined by high

    level of tuition fees and well developed student support systems (p. 273) and

    includes the liberal countries and as an outlier the Netherlands.

    Compared with the liberal countries, tuition fees in the Netherlands are

    moderate. Finally, the other conservative countries constitute a pattern that is

    defined as low level of tuition fees and less developed student support systems

    (p. 274).

    Correspondence Analysis

    Thus far, the analyses have demonstrated that there is reason to believe that the

    three welfare regimes differ in terms of participation in tertiary education, pre-

    tertiary prerequisites, educational funding, and levels of tuition and levels of

    borrowing. To further illuminate and confirm these relationships, we employ

    the analytic technique of correspondence analysis (CA). CA is a multivariatedescriptive data technique that summarizes information to provide a visual

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    41

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    18/28

    representation of data distribution in a two-dimensional map (Greenacre,

    2007). As Greenacre (1990) explains, CA is an exploratory statistical techniquewhich displays the rows and columns of a rectangular data matrix as points in

    a scatterplot (p. 1). It is similar to principal components analysis in that it is a

    method for decomposing the overallinertiaalong principal axes, but is applied

    to cross tabulations and hence allows for the analysis of categorical data. In

    CA, the patterns of association portrayed in larger data sets (and contained in

    the rectangular data matrix) are examined through a graphic description of

    tabular data, where each row and each column is depicted as a point. For an

    introduction to CA, see Greenacre (2007).

    Data are organized into columns and related rows. The columns in this

    analysis are the 16 countries. Rows are comprised of 17 indicators selected tobest represent the four categories identified in Tables 1 to 4. Our choice of

    indicators was also constrained by missing data for some countries. Only

    indicators with complete data for each country were employed in the

    correspondence analysis. We employ correspondence analysis to determine

    the combined role of four tertiary participation indicators, four pre-tertiary

    indicators, four funding indicators, and four tuition and student financial aid

    in relation to country. These indicators and their corresponding labels are

    listed in the legend. In other words, we are interested in measuring the

    correspondence between the columns (countries) and rows (educational

    indicators).CA is versatile in that through the transformation of continuous data into

    ranks,9 we are able to conduct this multivariate analysis using indicators

    contained in the OECD reports. Each indicator was recoded into a rank

    ranging from 0 (lowest) to 15 (highest) to create a positive pole; this figure is

    then subtracted from the maximum value of the positive pole (in all instances, 15)

    to create a negative pole. In doing so, we have created a set of complementary

    scales which represent the number of scaled points above and below the actual

    value (Greenacre, 2007). According to Greenacre, since the ranks are analysed

    and not the original values, the analysis [is] robust with respect to outliers

    and can be called a nonparametric CA of the data (p. 184). We used XLSTAT

    to compute the w2 coordinates of profile points and the statistical tests of

    the analysis.

    The data are displayed in a symmetric two-dimensional map, which reveal

    the relative positions of row and column profiles. The challenge in this analysis

    is to interpret the principal axes by identifying the latent (hidden) variables that

    explain the amount of the total inertia along each axis. w2 distances separate the

    row and column profiles and are used to compute inertia (or variance), which

    measures the dispersion of these profiles in a multidimensional space. The CA

    map corresponds to a lower-dimensional subspace defined by a pair of

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    42

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    19/28

    principal axes and displays the location of profile points as close as possible to

    the true set of profiles represented in the multi-dimensional space.The correspondence analysis map in Figure 1 positions the points

    corresponding to the 16 column profiles assigned to the country categories in

    relation to the 17 row profiles. This map displays the projection of points in the

    subspace defined by the first two principal axes that account for the largest

    amount of the overall inertia (37%).

    By examining the horizontal axis, with the exception of Finland, the groups

    of countries we have identified as belonging to the conservative regime, are

    AU

    FR

    DE

    NL

    IT

    CH

    BE

    CA

    US

    AUS

    NZ

    UK

    SE

    DK

    NO

    FI

    P_25_34trtcrdA+

    P_25_34trtcrdA-

    P_25_34_trtcrdB+

    P_25_34_trtcrdB-

    P_25_64_trtcrdA+

    P_25_64_trtcrdA-

    P_25_64_trtcrdB+

    P_25_64_trtcrdB-

    PT_agesel+

    PT_agesel- PT_upscgen+

    PT_upscgen-

    PT_upsecvoc+

    PT_upsecvoc-

    PT_ISCED5a6+

    PT_ISCED5a6-

    F_TPE_tert+

    F_TPEtert-

    F_EGDPtert+

    F_EGDPtert-

    F_EGDPtertpublic+

    F_EGDPtertpublic-

    F_EGDPtertpriv+

    F_EGDPtertpriv-

    FA_tuition+

    FA_tuition-

    FA_loans+

    FA_loans-

    FA_grants+ FA_grants-

    FA_propdebt+

    FA_propdebt-

    FA_averdebt+

    FA_averdebt-

    -0.6

    -0.2

    0.2

    0.6

    0.80.40-4.0-8.0

    F2(17.6

    3%)

    F1 (39.35 %)

    Figure 1. Correspondence analysis of countries and tertiary, pre-tertiary, educational expenditure,and tuition and student financial-aid indicators.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    43

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    20/28

    located to the left and are opposed to all other countries to the right side of the

    map. This axis accounts for 39% of the average total inertia. The columnprofiles that contribute the most to this axis correspond to Austria on the left

    and the USA on the right; these two extremes define the axis. Also, the profiles

    of Belgium and Italy are well aligned along the first axis toward Austria and

    New Zealand and Canada are well-aligned on the right with the USA. Sweden,

    Denmark, Norway, and Australia are aligned along the first axis, but less

    strongly so, toward the USA. Switzerland and France are similarly aligned

    toward Austria on the left. Finland, the Netherlands, and the UK contribute

    the least to the first axis and hence remain outliers of sorts. The placement of

    row profiles reveal that average amount of student debt at graduation, the

    proportion of the 2564-years age population with tertiary-type A credentials,the proportion of graduates with debt, and the proportion of the 2534-years

    age population with tertiary-type A credentials are well matched along the

    horizontal axis. The profile is also associated with the following variables: the

    proportion of students in upper secondary general education, age of selection,

    total loans to students as percentage of total public tertiary expenditure, and

    public educational expenditure on tertiary education as a percentage of (a)

    total public expenditures and (b) GDP. These variables also contribute most to

    the axis. We interpret this axis as an educational expansion dimension with the

    less expansion row profiles matching with the country column profiles to the

    left and more expansion row profiles matching well with the country columnprofiles to the right. Also included in this expansion dimension are pre-tertiary

    indicators, which determine whether young people have the prerequisites to

    engage in tertiary study. Finland is oriented closer to the left because of a

    relatively low proportion of the age 2534 and 2565 years population with

    tertiary-level credentials and low student debt. Conversely, this proportion is

    high in the Netherlands. Also, in the Netherlands financial aid to students as a

    percentage of total public expenditure on tertiary education does not fit the

    profile of a conservative regime country. As such, it is an outlier on this

    dimension.

    The vertical axis accounts for 18% of the total inertia, and mainly contrasts

    the column profile that corresponds to Finland (up) with the profile

    corresponding to Italy (down). Three row profiles associated with (a) public

    and (b) private expenditures on tertiary institutions as a percentage of GDP,

    and annual average tuition fees charged by tertiary-type A institutions

    contribute the most to this axis. Hence, the second dimension is a tertiary-

    funding dimension.

    Finland and Italy represent the two extremes of the vertical axis. In terms of

    public expenditures on tertiary institutions as a percentage of GDP, Italy ranks

    lowest of all countries (0.6%) and Finland highest (1.7%). Conversely, Italy(0.3%) (along with the Netherlands) ranks highest of all non-liberal countries

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    44

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    21/28

    in terms of private expenditures on tertiary institutions as a percentage of

    GDP, whereas Finland ranks among the lowest at 0.1%. Canada is drawncloser to the upper part of the map on the vertical dimension because of

    relatively high public expenditures on tertiary institutions as a percentage of

    GDP (at 1.4%), which aligns more closely with the Nordic countries. The

    Netherlands is an outlier because of relatively higher private expenditures on

    tertiary institutions as a percentage of GDP and higher tuition fees.

    In summary, this analysis demonstrates three clear clusters of countries that

    align with Esping-Andersens welfare typology. And they are indeed

    significantly associated with indicators of tertiary participation and gradua-

    tion, pre-tertiary indicators, and funding indicators (w2547.87, d.f.495, and

    po0.0001).

    Discussion

    Our analyses demonstrate a relationship between welfare regimes and patterns

    of education policy. In addition, our findings support the trade-off hypothesis

    that claims that there is a conflict of goals in either providing tertiary

    educational opportunities or investing in social insurance programs. The

    results reveal that countries that lean toward the goal of equality of condition

    invest less than those countries that strive for either enhancing equality ofopportunity or enhancing both equality of opportunity and condition. We

    continue by highlighting the advantages and disadvantages of each regime.

    Welfare regimes and higher education

    Countries that adhere to the liberal welfare approach minimize their efforts to

    establish equitable living conditions, but they apply a strong human-capital

    philosophy that involves the highest resources spent on higher education and

    the highest participation rates among the three welfare regimes. Clearly, this

    arrangement is in accordance with the basic requirements of knowledge-based

    economies to increase the stock of human capital. One problem of this pattern

    relates to those individuals who do not excel academically and, as a

    consequence, cannot benefit from the comparatively generous opportunities

    in postsecondary education. Individuals who drop out of high school or who

    do not continue their education at the tertiary level for other reasons seem to

    fall short of the minimal requirements expected for stable, well-paid jobs.

    Although the percentage of the age cohort with no tertiary education is smaller

    in liberal regimes than in any other regime, it still encompasses a significant

    proportion of the population. Because of the relative lack of vocational skillprovision and social safety net policies, the status and the labour market

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    45

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    22/28

    chances of this group is more precarious than those in comparable groups in

    the other welfare regimes. This is re-inforced by the general tendency of theliberal welfare regime to tolerate high levels of inequality of living conditions.

    Another issue of concern is the high amount of debt incurred by a large

    proportion of graduates. Under a liberal human capital approach with low

    levels of de-commodification, individuals are expected to contribute to the

    direct cost of their education. In most liberal countries, cost of higher

    education grew much faster than median family income during the last two

    decades. Hence, debt levels have escalated (The National Center for Public

    Policy and Higher Education, 2008).

    To summarize, liberal regimes provide tremendous opportunities for

    individuals who comply with the requirements of knowledge society (e.g.,minimally accepted level of academic ability, ambition to succeed, readiness to

    embrace lifelong learning). Those who fail to meet these requirements carry a

    heavy burden. The Economic Council of Canada has emphasized this weakness

    of a liberal market model:

    A drawback of this excessive emphasis on individualism is that certain

    people may lack the resources or influence to compete equally in the

    learning system and the labour market. This weakness can be tempered

    by the high level of accessibility of the system, which opens up a wide

    range of opportunities to everyone. However, individuals are largely leftalone to confront the world that surrounds them. (Economic Council of

    Canada, 1992, 46)

    Conservative welfare regimes, by contrast, provide better conditions for

    those who will never attain tertiary level credentials. The attitudes in these

    countries are shaped by remainders of an ideology that assigns individuals to

    their proper place in society. Educational streaming is a powerful mechanism

    of social reproduction. It is taken for granted that students from different

    social/educational backgrounds have different educational and career trajec-

    tories, but because of the de-commodified welfare provisions of these regimes

    the lower social estates still enjoy comparatively high standards of living.

    The extensive system of vocational training in most conservative countries

    plays an important role in providing an alternative training route for academic

    low achievers. Graduates of the apprenticeship system enjoy a higher social

    status and better labour market chances than do individuals in the liberal

    welfare regimes without tertiary education. This characteristic of conservative

    regimes contributes to the comparatively high level of equitable living

    conditions, but it comes at a high price. The other side of the coin is an

    education system that constrains expansion of learning at the tertiary level and

    discourages the ambitions of students who struggle to meet the requirements ofelite secondary schools with selection mechanisms that start as early as age 10

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    46

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    23/28

    years. As Lehmann (2005) points out, this system has been criticized as

    outdated and archaic [and] narrowly skills-based which has not yet addressedthe more broadly defined demands of new work places (p. 119). The

    consequence of maintaining patterns of sponsored mobility (Turner, 1960)

    even at the fringe of a knowledge based economy is that that conservative

    welfare regimes lag in expanding their systems of postsecondary education,

    whereas most other parts of the world move ahead. Advocates of extensive

    vocational training at the secondary level emphasize the danger of over-

    education and highlight the need for labour market planning. In the past, this

    strategy was relatively successful. The lack of tertiary graduates could easily be

    compensated by an ample supply of graduates of vocational training. Two

    recent trends could endanger this pattern. First, the expansion of a knowledge-based economy depends much more on a growing supply of tertiary graduates

    (Allmendinger and Leibfried, 2003) to assume jobs in a world increasingly

    defined as one of liquid modernity (Bauman, 2000). This is in contrast to solid

    modernity characterized by Fordist type regimes of past decades. Second,

    globalization of labour markets will advance the standardization of, and need

    for, education certificates. It is questionable if the conservative regimes will be

    successful in maintaining their niche.

    Trade-offs and higher education

    Our findings suggest that the trade-off hypothesis is confirmed through a

    comparison of liberal and conservative welfare regimes. However, it appears

    that social-democratic welfare regimes seem to avoid some of the trade-offs

    faced by liberal and conservative countries. The socially embedded human

    capital approach of these countries allows for expansion of higher education

    without neglecting those parts of the age cohort who are unable or unwilling to

    make use of that opportunity. Unlike the laissez-faire approach of liberal

    regimes, there is a certain degree of social engineering in balancing and

    adjusting supply and demand of higher learning opportunities by fostering the

    development of both general and specific skills. For example, all Nordic

    countries limit their seats for research universities through Numerus Clausus.10

    The commitment to de-commodification strategies results in resistance toward

    introducing tuition fees. Hence, those who are talented do not need to invest

    their own resources for the direct cost of their higher education. Only countries

    within social-democratic welfare regimes maintain a no fee philosophy that

    spread globally during the late 1960s but were subsequently reversed in most

    countries. Although there are no fees, the high level of public spending results

    in significantly higher total expenditures for tertiary education (as a percentageof GDP) than in all conservative regimes, where in most cases public

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    47

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    24/28

    expenditures are supplemented by admittedly low tuition fees. This

    pattern, however, depends on belief systems that have evolved over manydecades, encompassing not only egalitarian values but also a high trust in

    public administration (and hence an unparalleled readiness to pay high taxes).

    The question remains to what extent this Nordic exceptionalism can be

    maintained in an area of declining national sovereignty. The global trend in the

    last three decades has been to emphasize the benefits of markets and to reduce

    the tax base of governments. The Nordic countries have not been excluded

    from this trend. As in most countries, public expenditures as a proportion of

    GDP have also dropped in the social-democratic regimes (OECD, 2008b).

    Hence, the policy response to the subsidization, coverage, and public cost

    trilemma, as specified by Ansell (2008) may change.Another issue of concern is the amount of debt carried by graduates, which

    is similar to levels held by graduates in liberal regimes, hence not confirming

    our hypothesis in this regard. Such debt loads are somewhat surprising, given

    that university students in social-democratic regimes do not pay fees. However,

    the generous conditions for student loans allow students in these countries a

    high standard of living, for example living independently from their parents

    and not being obligated to work while completing their studies.

    The issue of loans11 reflects the different attitudes of the three welfare

    regimes in a nutshell. Conservative regimes have either no loan schemes for

    students or comparatively restrictive conditions. As a consequence, a highproportion of students work while studying to cover their costs of living. For

    example, Euro student data (Orr, 2008, 119) reveal that the employment rate

    of all students during the academic term is 4675%12 in conservative regimes

    compared to 4356% in social-democratic regimes (119). The need to self-

    finance results in less time available for students to devote to their studies

    (Orr, 2008, 121). Both liberal and social-democratic regimes foster their

    expansionist education strategies by providing loans to students. They differ,

    however, in the prerequisites for receiving loans and the restrictions for which

    students may make use of the money. In liberal regimes, students need loans to

    cover the fees for tuition and living expenses. In social-democratic regimes,

    students need loans only for the latter.

    Outliers

    Although we emphasize the relationship between educational policies and

    welfare regimes, we recognize that additional (independent) factors influence

    education policy, and result in identified outliers. For example, the welfare

    regime typology does not explain within regime differences such as, forexample, educational expansion between North America and the UK. North

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    48

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    25/28

    America, and in particular the US, has been a pioneer in expansion of upper

    secondary and tertiary education (Goldin and Katz, 2008). The UK was alaggard (not only compared with the US, but until the 1980s also with

    most European countries). The UK has a well-entrenched class system, and a

    historically stronger tradition of sorting students (e.g., into O and A levels).

    Also in the UK, a large proportion of the school population historically exited

    school at age 15 years or engaged in apprenticeships; as such, it was far slower

    to expand from an elite to mass higher-education system. Likewise, the

    Netherlands13 differs in many respects from the patterns observed in other

    conservative regimes. Nor does Finland fit neatly into the social-democratic

    framework. We believe that these outliers do not invalidate our thesis of a

    systematic relationship between welfare regimes and patterns of educationpolicy. Further investigation of these questions would not only contribute

    to a better understanding of this relationship, but of the welfare typology

    itself. The addition of countries from southern Europe and post-socialistic

    regimes in future analyses will further strengthen the analytical power of

    this theory.

    Conclusion

    The focus of this paper has been on the refinement of an analytical frameworkfor cross-national comparisons. We argue that combining the analysis of

    higher education and welfare policies furthers our understandings of national

    differences in both areas. Our focus is not on making normative judgements

    about the superiority or the deficiencies of the various national clusters.

    However, it is an intriguing question to ask whether some regimes are

    better equipped than others for the challenges of a knowledge-based

    economy.

    We conclude with a general observation about policy change. To a certain

    degree, each country is open to new dynamics; however, it is also bound by

    different historical forces and follows distinct trajectories from which it cannot

    easily or quickly diverge. Policy makers who intend to change this direction

    should be aware of this inertia. Adopting policy strategies from other contexts

    requires careful consideration of the underlying societal structures and

    traditions. The first step for governmental and educational policy makers is

    to recognize that their respective countries fit into a particular regime

    framework. Second, they need to assess the goals for higher education and

    the extent to which these goals are in line with current path dependencies.

    Third, they need to take the courageous step of aligning higher education

    policies with desired goals and outcomes which may require stepping beyondthe bounds of a given welfare regime framework.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    49

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    26/28

    Notes

    1 Other authors have demonstrated that systematic differences among welfare regimes exist at the

    secondary level. Allmendinger and Leibfried (2003) have identified four worlds of competence

    production on the basis of Programme for International Student Assessment data (PISA), three

    of which align with Esping-Andersens welfare typology. Social democratic regimes combine

    high levels with low variation of these competences. Liberal regimes have both high levels and

    high variation of competences. Conservative regimes combine low levels with high variation of

    competences. The three worlds of human capital production described by Iversen and Stephens

    (2008) match the three regimes that we employ in this article. However, Iversen and Stephens

    focus on skill formation primarily at the secondary level.

    2 We use the terms higher education and tertiary education interchangeably.

    3 The concept of social estates refers to the broad divisions of society throughout the history of

    Europe. Originally the concept distinguished nobility, clergy, and commons. In contemporarysociety it refers to the almost impermeable social divisions between upper, middle, and lower

    classes in some countries (Cox, 1945), which Allmendinger and Leibfried (2003) describe as

    adherence to a traditional feudal notion of class (p. 63).

    4 Tertiary-type A credentials are earned at institutions defined as largely theory-based and are

    designed to provide sufficient qualifications for entry into advanced research programmes and

    professions with high skill requirements (OECD, 2006b). Tertiary-type B credentials are earned

    at institutions that are typically shorter than those of tertiary-type A and focus on practical,

    technical or occupational skills for direct entry in the labour market (p. 15).

    5 The proportion of the age group enrolled in general or vocational education is a proportion of

    total enrolments in upper secondary education. These two figures do not necessarily add up to

    100% because in some countries students are enrolled in pre-vocational programs.

    6 Japan was excluded from the analysis because the traditions of Asian countries deserve an

    analysis in their own right. As rapid social and economic changes in Ireland may distort the

    analysis, we have not included it.

    7 See footnote 3.

    8 One pattern (Japan) is not relevant in our context.

    9 Owing to the nature of the data, it was necessary to use a ranking procedure. We follow the

    tenets of Greenacre (2007) to form the ranks. Because of the small sample size and the

    categorical nature of the variables, it is not possible to conduct either factor or cluster analyses.

    10 A Numerus Clausus approach specifies restrictions to admissions in those countries where

    certification earned at the secondary level entitle individuals to tertiary entry.

    11 We consider only state supported loans, not other types of loans such as private loans with

    banks.12 Italy, at 39%, is an outlier among the conservative countries.

    13 Goodin et al. (1999) locate the Netherlands in the social democratic regime category, which

    indicates that this country is not easy to label.

    References

    Allmendinger, J. and Leibfried, S. (2003) Education and the welfare sate: The four worlds of

    competence production, Journal of European Social Policy 13(1): 6381.

    Ansell, B.W. (2008) University challenges: Explaining institutional change in higher education,

    World Politics 60(2): 189230.

    Arts, W. and Gelissen, J. (2002) Three worlds of welfare capitalism or more? A state-of-the-artreport,Journal of European Social Policy 12(2): 137158.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    50

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    27/28

    Bauman, Z. (2000) Liquid Modernity, Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.

    Bradley, D., Huber, E., Moller, S., Nielsen, F. and Stephens, J.D. (2003) Distribution andredistribution in postindustrial economies, World Politics 55(2): 193228.

    Castles, F.G. (1989) Explaining public education expenditure in OECD countries, European

    Journal of Political Research 17(4): 431448.

    Castles, F.G. (1993) Families of Nations, Aldershot: Dartmouth.

    Cox, O.C. (1945) Estates, social classes, and political classes, American Sociological Review10(4):

    464469.

    Economic Council of Canada. (1992) A Lot to Learn: Education and Training in Canada, Ottawa,

    ON: Economic Council of Canada.

    Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Princeton, NJ: Princeton

    University Press.

    Esping-Andersen, G. (1999) Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies, Oxford: Oxford

    University Press.Esping-Andersen, G. (2009) The Incomplete Revolution. Adapting to Womens New Roles,

    Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.

    Goldin, C. and Katz, L. (2008)The Race between Education and Technology, Cambridge, MA: The

    Belnap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Goodin, R.E., Headey, B., Muffels, R. and Dirven, H.-J. (1999) The Real Worlds of Welfare

    Capitalism, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Greenacre, M. (1990) SimCA Users Manual, Pretoria: The Author.

    Greenacre, M. (2007) Correspondence Analysis in Practice, Boca Raton, FL: Chapman & Hall.

    Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001) Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of

    Comparative Advantage, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Hega, G.M. and Hokenmaier, K.G. (2002) The welfare state and education: A comparison of

    social and educational policy in advanced industrial countries, German Policy Studies 2(1):128.

    Heidenheimer, A.J. (1981) Education and Social Security Entitlements in Europe and America, in

    P. Flora and A.J. Heidenheimer (eds.) The Development of Welfare States in Europe and

    America, London: Transaction Books, Inc 265304.

    Hicks, A. and Kenworthy, L. (2003) Varieties of welfare capitalism, Socio-Economic Review

    1: 2761.

    Hokenmaier, K.G. (1998) Social security vs educational opportunity in advanced industrial

    societies: Is there a trade-off? American Journal of Political Science 42(2): 709711.

    Iversen, T. and Stephens, J.D. (2008) Partisan politics, the welfare state, and three worlds of

    human capital state formation, Comparative Political Studies 41(4/5): 600637.

    Johnstone, D.B. (2006) Financing Higher Education: Cost-Sharing in International Perspective,

    Boston, MA: Boston College Center for International Higher Education.

    Lehmann, W. (2005) Im still scrubbing the floors: Experiencing youth apprenticeships in Canada

    and Germany, Work, Employment, and Society 19(1): 107129.

    Martins, J., Boarini, R., Strauss, H, de la Maisoneuve, C. and Saadi, C. (2007) The Policy

    Determinants of Investment in Tertiary Education OECD Economics Department Working

    Papers, No. 576. Paris: OECD.

    Mills, M. and Blossfeld, H.-P. (2003) Globalization, uncertainty, and changes in early life courses,

    Zeitschrift fur Erziehungwissenschaft 6(2): 188218.

    OECD. (2005) Education at a Glance. OECD Indicators 2005, Paris: OECD.

    OECD. (2006a) Education at a Glance. OECD Indicators 2006, Paris: OECD.

    OECD. (2006b) Education Policy Analysis. Focus on Higher Education 20052006, Paris: OECD.

    OECD. (2007) Education at a Glance. OECD Indicators 2007, Paris: OECD.OECD. (2008a) Education at a Glance. OECD Indicators 2008, Paris: OECD.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    51

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24

  • 8/14/2019 HE Policy and Welfare Regimes

    28/28

    OECD. (2008b) Revenue Statistics 19652007, Paris: OECD.

    OECD. (2008c) Tertiary Education for the Knowledge Society, Paris: OECD.Orr, D. (2008) Social and Economic Conditions of Student Life in Europe, Bielefeld: Bertelsmann.

    Pechar, H. and Andres, L. (2010) Education and skill formation in secondary and tertiary

    education: A comparison of welfare and production regimes, Paper presented at the annual

    meeting of the Consortium of Higher Educational Research Conference, Oslo, Norway, June

    1012.

    Starke, P. (2006) The politics of welfare state retrenchment: A literature review, Social Policy and

    Administration40(1): 104120.

    The National Center for Public Policy and Higher Education. (2008) Measuring Up 2008. The

    National Report Card on Higher Education, San Jose, CA: The National Center for Public Policy

    and Higher Education.

    Turner, R. (1960) Sponsored and contest mobility and the school system, American Sociological

    Review25(6): 855867.Usher, A. (2005)Global Debt Patterns: An International Comparison of Student Loan Burdens and

    Repayment Conditions, Toronto, ON: Educational Policy Institute.

    Vossensteyn, H. (2004) Student Financial Support: An Inventory in 24 Countries, The Netherlands:

    CHEPS.

    Hans Pechar and Lesley AndresHigher-Education Policies and Welfare Regimes

    52

    Higher Education Policy 2011 24