Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" "...

28
1 Ceremonial Expenses as Relational Saving: The limitations of new financial technologies in mobilizing saving Final Report, September 2016 Isabelle Guérin, IRDCessma and French Institute of Pondicherry G. Venkatasubramanian, French Institute of Pondicherry Santosh Kumar, French Institute of Pondicherry Abstract Many initiatives aim to help the poor to save cash, in an echo of longstanding concerns. New technologies, harnessed to the lessons of behavioural economics, offer diverse unmediated tools for depositing savings. These socalled financial innovations have not always brought about the results expected, however. This paper draws on an ethnography from southern India to highlight the contradictions between unmediated saving and relational saving, defined as saving transactions that are both shaped by and constitutive of social relations. In the context studied here, ceremonial expenses are major forms of relational saving. Unlike unmediated saving, they operate over the long term, on various scales and serve multiple purposes. They allow for the accumulation of lump sums in order to organise large events. But they also ensure the reproduction of the social group (and set the definitions of its reproduction). And they not only express, but also transform, strengthen or bypass preexisting social and interdependency relations, or even create new ones. They are embedded within multiple, overlapping ties of hierarchy and obligation, but also within emotional,

Transcript of Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" "...

Page 1: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

1    

Ceremonial  Expenses  as  Relational  Saving:    

The   limitations   of   new   financial   technologies   in  mobilizing  

saving  

Final  Report,  September  2016  

Isabelle  Guérin,  IRD-­‐Cessma  and  French  Institute  of  Pondicherry  

G.  Venkatasubramanian,  French  Institute  of  Pondicherry  

Santosh  Kumar,  French  Institute  of  Pondicherry  

Abstract    

Many   initiatives   aim   to   help   the   poor   to   save   cash,   in   an   echo   of   long-­‐standing   concerns.   New  

technologies,  harnessed  to  the  lessons  of  behavioural  economics,  offer  diverse  unmediated  tools  for  

depositing  savings.  These  so-­‐called  financial   innovations  have  not  always  brought  about  the  results  

expected,   however.   This   paper   draws   on   an   ethnography   from   southern   India   to   highlight   the  

contradictions  between  unmediated  saving  and  relational  saving,  defined  as  saving  transactions  that  

are   both   shaped   by   and   constitutive   of   social   relations.   In   the   context   studied   here,   ceremonial  

expenses  are  major  forms  of  relational  saving.  Unlike  unmediated  saving,  they  operate  over  the  long  

term,  on  various  scales  and  serve  multiple  purposes.  They  allow  for  the  accumulation  of  lump  sums  

in  order  to  organise  large  events.  But  they  also  ensure  the  reproduction  of  the  social  group  (and  set  

the   definitions   of   its   reproduction).   And   they   not   only   express,   but   also   transform,   strengthen   or  

bypass   pre-­‐existing   social   and   interdependency   relations,   or   even   create   new   ones.   They   are  

embedded  within  multiple,  overlapping   ties  of  hierarchy  and  obligation,  but  also  within  emotional,  

Page 2: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

2    

unique  relationships.  The  design  of  innovative  financial  tools  should  take  inspiration  from  relational  

saving,  rather  than  ignoring  it.    

Helping  the  poor  to  save  has  been  for  long  a  concern  of  governments,  activists  and  philanthropists,  

and   sometimes   governments.   There   have   been   many   attempts   across   the   history   of   European  

industrialisation   and   colonisation   by   women's   health   auxiliaries,   social   workers,   Christian  

missionaries,   and   sometimes   unionists,   to   introduce   a   culture   of   saving   among   the   poor.   This   has  

included  home  economics  education  and  various  techniques  such  as  saving  groups  and  piggy  banks.    

This  concern  is  greater  than  ever,  especially  in  the  developing  world.  In  the  absence  of  a  public  health  

system  and  social  security,  as  is  the  case  in  many  developing  countries,  saving  can  help  the  poor  to  

cope  with  risk  and  emergencies  (Morduch  and  Sharma,  2002).  It  can  also  help  them  to  better  plan  for  

the   future,   whether   for   life   cycle   and   ritual   events,   education,   housing   or   economic   investments  

(Collins   et   al.,   2009).   Unlike   microcredit,   it   cannot   draw   people   into   vicious   cycles   of   over-­‐

indebtedness  (Guérin,  Morvant-­‐Roux  and  Villarreal,  2013:  301-­‐2).  Though  the  idea  is  not  new,  there  

has  been  renewed  interest  in  saving,  which  is  often  seen  as  microfinance's  'forgotten  other  half'  at  a  

time  when  hopes  for  microcredit  are  being  thwarted.    

At   the   same   time   practitioners   and   their   advisers   –   mostly   economists   -­‐   have   made   significant  

progress   in   the   attempt   to   understand   the   multiplicity   and   the   complexity   of   pre-­‐existing   saving  

practices.   It   is  now  widely  known  that  the  poor  save.  The  focus   is   less  to  encourage  saving  than  to  

improve   available   tools   and   better   support   people’s   existing   practices.   Echoing   longstanding  

anthropological  work,  the  book  Portfolio  of  the  Poor,  which  has  been  widely  disseminated  within  the  

microfinance  community,  sheds  light  on  the  diverse  existing  saving  strategies  and  points  out  several  

paths  to  improvement,  especially  the  need  for  reliable,  convenient,  and  flexible  products  (Collins  et  

al.  2009).  Over  the  last  decade,  new  technologies  and  the  explosion  of  mobile  phone  usage  has  made  

it  possible  to  design  unmediated  saving  tools  that,  it  seems,  meet  the  above  criteria.  Directly  paying  

social   transactions   into   bank   accounts   has   been   seen   as   another   potential   saving   incentive.  

Page 3: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

3    

Behavioural   economics,   which   is   very   much   in   fashion   in   the   development   world,   has   equally  

considered   the  cognitive  biases   that   can   limit   the  propensity   to   saving.  Various   ruses  and  prompts  

are   suggested   to   overcome   such   biases,   such   as   "commitment   accounts",  mobile   phone   reminder  

messages,  basic  financial  education  and  so  forth  (Karlan  et  al.  2014).    

We  call  however  for  making  further  efforts  to  really  grasp  the  meaning  and  scope  of  popular  saving  

practices.  This  requires  redefining  the  term  ‘saving’   in  the  light  of  economic  anthropology.    Storing,  

accumulating  and  circulating  value   largely  takes  place  through  what  we  define  as  relational  saving,  

namely  saving  transactions  that  are  both  shaped  by  and  constitutive  of  social  relations.  In  the  context  

of  this  study  (rural  Tamil  Nadu),  ceremonial  expenses  are  important  forms  of  relational  saving.  Unlike  

unmediated  saving,  they  operate  over  the  long  term,  on  various  scales  and  serve  multiple  purposes.  

They  allow  for  the  accumulation  of  lump  sums  in  order  to  organise  large  events.  But  they  also  ensure  

the   reproduction   of   the   social   group   (and   the   definitions   of   its   reproduction).   And   they   not   only  

express  but  also  transform,  strengthen  or  bypass  pre-­‐existing  social  and   interdependency  relations,  

or   even   create   new   ones.   They   are   embedded   within   multiple,   overlapping   ties   of   hierarchy   and  

obligation,  but  also  within  emotional,  unique  relationships.  Our  purpose  is  not  to  romanticize  these  

practices,   which   are   both   shaped   by   and   constitutive   of   various   forms   of   inequalities,   especially  

related   to   caste   and   gender,   but   to   highlight   the   set   of   norms   and   rules   that   have   an   impact   on  

behaviours,  ideas  and  aspirations.  

The  first  and  second  sections  present  the  concept  and  context  of  relational  saving.  The  later  sections  

focus   on   ceremonial   expenses   and   analyse   them   as   relational   (and   long-­‐term)   saving   in   which  

material,  social  and  emotional  aspects  are  interwoven.    

Relational  saving  

The  concept  of  relational  saving  is  closely  linked  to  that  of  “relational  economy”  or  “relational  work”  

(Zelizer  2012).  This  argues  that  economic  transactions  are  not  only  embedded  within  social  networks  

but   that   they  are   fundamentally  social   interactions.  As  Zelizer  argues,  “in  all  areas  of  economic   life  

Page 4: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

4    

people  are  creating,  maintaining,  symbolizing,  and  transforming  meaningful  social  relations”  (Zelizer  

2012:   149).   Zelizer   uses   the   concept   of   relational   work   to   explain   monetary   differentiation   and  

practices  of  money  earmarking.  People  consistently  differentiate  their  money   in  order  to  match  up  

monetary   transactions   to   their   social   relations.   In   deprived   contexts,   the   idea   of   the   relational  

economy   also   highlights   that   economic   activity   should   be   understood   not   only   as   productive   and  

income   generating,   but   as   a   reproductive   activity   to   sustain   household   survival,   dignity   and  

respectability  (Neves  and  du  Toit  2012).    

We  argue  that  relational  saving  as  an  idea  can  enrich  our  understanding  of  the  relational  economy.  

'Saving'   is   far   from   straightforward   as   a   term   because   in   many   cases,   the   distinction   between  

expenses,   investments,   consumption   and   saving   is   unclear   (Douglas   and   Isherwood   1980).   In  

anthropological   terminology,   it   would   make   more   sense   to   talk   about   practices   of   storing,  

accumulating  and  circulating  value.  We  keep  the  term  saving,  however,  in  order  to  contribute  to  the  

financial  inclusion  debate.  It  is  our  belief  that  anthropology  is  too  often  absent  from  these  debates  to  

which  it  has  a  lot  to  contribute.    

Economic  theory  often  distinguishes  between  precautionary  saving  (to  smooth  consumption  or  cope  

with   negative   income   shocks),   and   investment   saving   (to   maximize   expected   future   consumption  

through   the   gradual   accumulation   of   small   sums).   Following   Rosenzweig   (2001),   most   economic  

studies   have   considered   the   poor   to   be   in   essence   incapable   of  making   long-­‐term   considerations,  

since  short-­‐term  survival  is  their  primary  concern.  It  is  assumed  that  precautionary  saving  would  be  

the   most   common   form   of   saving,   with   investment   saving   inexistent.   Looking   at   the   relational  

dimension  of  saving  sheds   light  on  new  temporalities  and  unexpected  forms  of  saving.  We  use  the  

term  'saving'  because  these  transactions  allow  for  the  gradual  accumulation  of  lump  sums,  but  they  

are   first  and   foremost  social   transactions   insofar  as   their  primary   function   is   to  express,  symbolise,  

maintain,  transform  or  create  social  relations.      

This   paper's  main   argument   is   that   ceremonial   expenses   are  major   forms   of   relational   saving   that  

play  a  crucial  role  in  households’  reproduction,  both  economically  (helping  to  accumulate  lump  sums  

Page 5: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

5    

and  smooth  expenses  and  income  over  time)  and  socially  (helping  to  maintain  or  possibly  strengthen  

family’s   statuses   and   reputations).   All   the   people   in   our   study,   as   individuals   or   through   their  

household,   kinship   and   various   social   circles,   are   embedded   within   complex   webs   of   debts   and  

entitlements   related   to   ceremonial   transactions.   Following   the   classic   pattern   of   the   gift,   people  

regularly  contribute  to  ceremonies  in  their  circles,  which  are  subsequently  reciprocated  at  their  own  

ceremonies.  Return  gifts  do  not  strictly  follow  rules  of  equivalency,  but  rather  are  subtle  calculations  

based  on  issues  of  reciprocity,  obligation  and  status,  as  well  as  emotions  and  sentiments.  This  makes  

them  fundamentally  different  from  unmediated  saving  practices.    But  looking  at  ceremonial  expenses  

as  saving  demands  a  wider  vision  of  saving  than  in  usual  economic  analysis.    

As  we  shall  see  throughout  this  paper,  ceremonial  saving  does  not  take  place  on  the  individual  level  

but   through   larger,   variable   units   based   on   events   and   circumstances.   This   is   sometimes   the  

household,  sometimes  the  lineage  or  a  fraction  of  it  (given  that  definitions  of  household  and  lineage  

are  malleable  and  in  constant  reconfiguration).  Saving   is  not   limited  to  residual,  unspent   income:   it  

operates  over   the   long  term,  but  mostly  on  a  generational   level   (and  not  only   the   life  cycle  of  one  

particular   person).   It   primarily   works   towards   various   interwoven   objectives.   The   material   and  

immaterial   are   not   separate,   but   co-­‐constitutive.   It   is   thus   a   'multi-­‐purpose'   saving,   to   echo   the  

Polanyian  idea  of  'multiple-­‐purpose  money'.    

In   so   doing,   and   following   Guyer’s   suggestion   (Guyer   1997),   we   hope   to   contribute   to   two  

interrelated   but   unfortunately   disconnected   research   fields:   the   'anthropology   of   wealth'   and   the  

'economics  of  saving  and  insurance'.  The  dynamics  presented  here  illustrate  a  process  that  has  been  

widely  documented  since  the  pioneering  work  of  Mauss  and  Malinowski  on  the  role  of  gifts  in  social  

and   political   ties   and   further  work   on   "investment   in   people"   (Berry   1989).  While   anthropologists  

familiar  with   the  social,  cultural  and  symbolic  dimension  of  wealth  know  this  well,  we  believe  they  

can  still  learn  from  the  material  dimension  of  exchanges  that  anthropology  often  downplays.      

Page 6: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

6    

Context  

This   paper's   findings   are   part   of   a   of   long-­‐term   research   program   on   labour   and   finance   in   two  

districts   (Villipuram   and   Cuddalore)   of   north   and   coastal   rural   Tamil   Nadu,   southern   India.   This  

particular  research  project,  funded  by  IMTFI,  allowed  us  to  explore  in  more  detail  the  use  of  a  recent  

financial  inclusion  program  which  has  involved  channelling  social  payments  through  bank  accounts  in  

order  to  promote  saving  deposits.  Ethnography  was  combined  with  a  longitudinal  household  survey1.    

The   region   is   economically   dynamic.   It   features   a   large   proportion   of   irrigated   agriculture,   two  

industrial   towns   (Neyveli   and  Cuddalore)   and  a   regional  business   centre   (Panruti).   As  elsewhere   in  

Tamil  Nadu  and  India,  caste  remains  a  fundamental  factor  in  social,  economic,  ritualistic  and  political  

life.  Caste  here  is   inherited  through  one’s  birth  group.  It   is  characterized  by  endogamy,  the  rules  of  

commensality  and  hierarchy.  The  latter  is  still  associated  with  ritual  dirt  and  pollution.  Vanniyars  and  

Paraiyars  are  the  two  major  local  groups  across  the  region.  Vanniyars  are  a  farming  caste  with  a  low  

ritual   rank,  but   in   the  villages  we  studied,  as   in  many  places   in  northeast  Tamil  Nadu,   they  control  

much   of   the   land   and   are   politically   dominant.2   Paraiyars   are   one   of   the   three   major   Dalit   (ex-­‐

untouchable)  communities   in  Tamil  Nadu.  They  are  particularly  well-­‐established   in  the  north  of  the  

state.  There  are  also  a  few  Arunthathiyars  among  the  Dalits.  The  upper  castes  of  the  local  hierarchy  

are   the  Mudaliyars,  Naidus,   Reddiyars   and   Settus,  who   account   for   only   a   small   proportion   of   the  

village  population.  Christians  and  Muslims  are  a  minority  in  the  area.  

The   region  has   seen  many  changes  over   the  past   three  decades.  Upper   castes  have  mostly  moved  

away   from   the   villages   to   nearby   towns,   adopting   urban   jobs   and   lifestyles,   and   selling   a   large  

proportion  of  their  land  to  Vanniyars.  Overall,  upper  castes  still  have  a  hold  on  village  life  but  are  not  

                                                                                                                         1  405  households  surveyed   in  2010  and  again   in  2016.  Households  distributed  across   ten  villages   in  northern  coastal  rural  Tamil  Nadu  on  the  border  of  the  two  districts,  Villupuram  and  Cuddalore.  Households  and  villages  were  randomly  selected,  using  a  stratified  sample  based  on  caste  and  location  in  terms  of  water  availability  and  distance  to  town.  2  There  are  also  a  few  Gramanis,  Navithars,  Nattars,  Kulalars  and  Asarais,  who  have  a  similar  position  in  the  caste  hierarchy.  

Page 7: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

7    

as   powerful   as   they   used   to   be.   Land   transfers   to   Vanniyars   largely   explain   why   they   are   now  

dominant.  As  for  Dalits,  their  situation  has  been  improving,  albeit  to  varying  degrees  from  village  to  

village,   thanks   to   the  combination  of   short   term  migration   to  nearby   towns  and   industrial   centres,  

and  governmental  schemes  (reflected  by  subsidized  housing,  food,  education  and  so  fourth).    

As  in  many  other  contexts,  saving  among  the  poor  has  long  been  raising  public  interest.  Many  reports  

from   the   British   period   emphasized   the   inability   of   the   poor   to   plan   for   the   future,   their  

improvidence  and  extravagance.  Debt  was  seen  as  their  only  financial  strategy  (Pouchepadass  1980).  

In  the  region  we  studied,  there  were  reports  of  Christian  missionary  attempts  in  the  1930s  to  create  

saving   groups,   but   they   were   rapid   failures   (Cederlof   1997).   Since   independence   and   up   to   the  

contemporary  period,  there  has  been  a  succession  of  many  policies  and  programmes.  Saving  deposits  

were   often   a   secondary   objective   (the   priority   is   given   to  modernising   agriculture   and   diversifying  

rural   economies)   and   limited   to   well-­‐off   farmers   (through   rural   cooperatives).   As   the   poor   were  

thought   to   lack   any   potential   to   save,   the   focus   has   been   on   'productive'   credit,   with   the   idea   of  

helping  them  generate  income  and  acquire  assets.  In  the  1990s  the  Indian  model  of  Self-­‐Help-­‐Groups  

(SHG)  emerged  in  reaction  against  the  microcredit  wave.  It  was  based  on  the  'saving  first'  principle.  

Groups  are  made  eligible  for  microcredit  after  proving  their  ability  to  marshal  their  members  and  to  

circulate   savings   within   the   group.   Although   the   SHG   program   became   the   biggest   women's  

microcredit  program  worldwide  over  two  decades  (at  its  peak  in  2009,  1.6  million  groups  were  being  

financed,   mostly   consisting   of   women's   groups),   the   savings   element   has   been   much   less   of   a  

success.  Most  women  in  fact  only  save  the  minimum  necessary  to  be  eligible  for  credit.    

A  series  of  financial  inclusion  programs  has  strengthened  the  focus  on  saving  since  2005.  A  Reserve  

Bank  of   India  Report  concluded  that  “developing  a  culture  of  saving  among  large  segments  of  rural  

population  […]  is  a  pillar  of  the  financial   inclusion  agenda"  (RBI,  2013:  3).  Two  main  measures  were  

intended   to   incentivise   saving   through   bank   deposits.   The   first   was   to   bring   banking   services   to  

people’s  doorsteps   through   'business   correspondents'   (non-­‐bank  agents  who   travel   from  village   to  

Page 8: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

8    

village)3   and   new   technologies   for   digital   transactions   in   villages.   The   second  measure   was   direct  

payment  of  social  transfers  (which  can  be  a  high  share  of  poor  Indian  household  incomes)  into  bank  

accounts.   In  Tamil  Nadu,   the   region  we   studied,  households  no   longer  have  a   choice.  Eligibility   for  

welfare  schemes  requires  a  bank  account  into  which  social  transfers  are  transferred.    

In   2016,   twelve   years   after   the   launch   of   'Pradhan   Mantri   Jhan   Dhan   Yojana',   the   first   financial  

inclusion   public   program,   and   four   years   on   from   current   prime   minister   Narendra   Modi's  

announcement   of   the   plan   to   “eradicate   financial   untouchability”4,   the   'culture   of   saving'   Indian  

policy  makers  were   seeking   has   yet   to   emerge.   Bancarisation   has  made   enormous   progress.   As   of  

21.9.2016,  246  million  accounts  had  been  opened,  of  which  151  million  were  classified  as  rural5.   In  

our  field  area,  bank  account  take-­‐up  was  already  widespread  in  2010,  with  91.2%  households  having  

a  bank  account.  By  2016,  take-­‐up  had  risen  to  an  even  higher  97.5%.  Achievements  in  terms  of  saving  

deposits  however  are   less  convincing.  The  median  amount   is  unchanged   (around  600   INR)  and   the  

average  amount  had  even  decreased   (from  4470   INR  to  2043   INR).  Most  bank  accounts  are   in   fact  

‘dormant’  and  mostly  used  as  a  conduit  for  social  transfers.  

We  were  frequently  told  that  bank  deposits  were  “useless”.  People  were  clear  that   informal  saving  

made  more  sense,  both  socially  and  financially.  Gold,  in  particular,  meets  a  much  higher  demand  for  

storing  value  than  keeping  money  in  a  bank  account.  As  in  2010,  gold  is  still  the  most  important  form  

of   saving.  Most   households   own   gold   (95.7%)   at   an   average  weight   of   52.2   grams,   for   an   average  

value  of  155,653  INR  (76  times  more  than  the  average  value  of  bank  deposits).    

                                                                                                                         3  For  more  details  see  Nithyananda  and  Fouillet  2015  4  Quoted  in  Hindu  Business  Line,  2014.    5  Data  available  on  http://pmjdy.gov.in/account.    

Page 9: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

9    

Graph  1.  Saving  Value  (INR)  

 

Source:  Authors  (2016  household  survey)  

 

How  can  we  explain  this?  Our  data  offer  various  possible  explanations.    

Firstly,   our   study   reveals   a   serious   lack   of   trust   in   banks.   Saving   with   someone   demands   pre-­‐

established   trust,  which   remains   in   short   supply.   Technical   failures   are   a   first   explanation   for   this,  

including  poor   fingerprint  authentications,  bad   internet   connections,   low  battery   charges,  machine  

failures   and   poor  maintenance,   inadequate   information   transfers   between   administrative   services  

and   banks,   limited   amounts,   insufficient   cash   flows   or   even   absent   business   correspondents.   Such  

distrust   is   reinforced  by   the   real  or   imaginary  misuse  of  bank   information,   for   instance   to  pinpoint  

'below   poverty   line'   households   (people   fear   that   saving   deposits   may   make   them   lose   this  

administrative  status  and  their  eligibility  to  numerous  welfare  schemes),  or  sanctions  in  the  event  of  

a   loan   default.   The   evidence   shows   that   some   bankers   do   use   bank   payments   to   recover   SHG  

members'  past  dues.  

Gender   and   caste   barriers   are   another   obstacle,   both   in   terms   of   the   bank   and   correspondents.  

Bankers   are   by   and   large   neither   equipped   nor   willing   to   deal   with   poor   rural   women   and  many  

Page 10: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

10    

women   feel   denigrated,   especially   when   they   are   Dalits.   They   feel   they   are   treated   as   “goats”   or  

“dogs”,  as  we  heard  many  times.    As  far  as  caste  is  concerned,  business  correspondents  operating  on  

the  village  level  raises  numerous  conflicts,  since  there  is  still  considerable  spatial  segmentation  along  

caste   lines.   Non-­‐Dalit   business   correspondents   may   not   visit   Dalit   places   and   conversely,   Dalit  

business   correspondents   may   not   be   allowed   to   visit   non-­‐Dalit   places.   The   lack   of   anonymity   is  

another   constraint   as   transactions   are   most   often  made   in   public.   This   is   poorly   compatible   with  

current   saving   practices,   where   discretion   and   anonymity   are   the   prevailing   protection   against  

constant,  often  untimely  requests  from  close  circles.    

A  second,  closely  related  factor  is  the  'comparative  advantage'  of  prevailing  informal  saving  practices,  

to  quote   the  economists.  We  have  discussed  elsewhere   the  social,   cultural  and  political   factors   for  

the  persistence  of  informal  saving,  particularly  in  gold  (Villarreal  and  Guérin,  2013;  Goedecke,  Guérin,  

D’Espallier   and   Venkatasubramanian,   forthcoming;   see   also   Joseph,   2015).     It   is   less   common   to  

consider  ceremonies  as  saving,  as  we  propose  here.  

Ceremonies  as  Relational  and  Long-­‐term  Saving    

In  Tamil  Nadu  as  elsewhere  in  India,  social  and  religious  rituals  are  an  essential  part  of  social,  cultural  

and  political,  but  also  economic  life.  Rituals  are  from  a  residue  of  'tradition'  but  constantly  renewed  

and  reinvented,  with  strongly  contextual  specificities  and  homogenisation  processes.  It  is  an  ongoing  

question  as  to  whether  rituals  and  ceremonies  reproduce  inequalities  and  hierarchies,  or  conversely  

open  up   spaces  of   resistance  and  political   contestation.  Dominant   groups  have   long  used  debt   for  

rituals  as  a  strategy  for  domination  and  this  still  continues  today.  But  the  reality  is  now  more  complex  

with  the  (relative)  upward  mobility  of  some  low  groups  and  the  growing  influence  of  consumerism.  In  

rural   Tamil   Nadu,   the   reappropriation   of   rituals,   whether   in   terms   of   meaning   or   funding,   is   a  

powerful   tool   for   asserting   individual   and   collective   identities,   especially   among   Dalits   (Tarabout  

1993).   Notwithstanding   land   conflicts,   ceremonies   are   a   constant   opportunity   for   rivalry   and  

competition  between  Vanniyars  and  Dalits.  At  the  same  time,  some  dominant  group  rituals  continue  

Page 11: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

11    

to  spread.  This  is  the  case  of  the  dowry,  a  Brahmin  practice  which  many  social  groups  have  adopted  

in  recent  years,  and  around  the  1960s  in  Tamil  Nadu  (Kapadia  1996).  The  prevalence  of  the  dowry  is  

often  presented,  perceived  and  upheld,  as  pre-­‐mortem  compensation  for  non-­‐access  to  inheritance  

for  girls,   including  by  the  women  themselves.  Although  generous  dowries  certainly  boost  the  social  

standing   of   households,   clans   and   the   women   themselves   in   their   community   (much   less   than   it  

being  material  protection  for  the  women,  as  it  is  most  often  appropriated  by  in-­‐laws),  it  is  obviously  a  

symptom  of  –  and  a  powerful  tool  of  –  growing  patriarchy.    

In   the   context   of   our   study,   and   at   the   household   level6,   the   most   common   ceremonies   include  

children’s  weddings,  girls’  puberty,  funerals  and  more  recently,  first  birthdays  (mostly  for  boys)  and  

housewarmings.  Children’s  weddings  are  the  most  important  events  in  terms  of  amount,  which  vary  

according  to  social  group.  For  Dalits,  typical  amounts  in  the  region  now  range  from  three  to  six  lakhs  

(300,000   to   600,000   INR),  which  on   average   amounts   to   four   to   eight   years   of   household   income.  

These  amounts  have  risen  considerably  over  recent  decades  and  include  the  cost  of  the  cerebration,  

gifts  to  close  relatives  and  the  dowry.  

Families  usually  keep  one  notebook  per  event  (see  photograph  below  as  an  example),  with  a  list  of  

the  givers  specifying  their  names,   location  and  the  amount  of   their  gift,  which  can  be   in  cash  or   in  

kind,  mostly   gold,   clothes,   vessels   and   food7.  Gifts   in   kind   are   restricted   to   relatives   (exceptionally  

close  friends  may  give  gold).  When  given  in  gold,  the  unit  of  measure  is  the  weight  (see  photograph  

1).  When  given  in  cash  (the  most  common  form  of  gift),  amounts  are  usually  not  rounded  up  and  end  

in  one  (101  rupees,  501  rupees,  etc.,  see  photograph  2)  and  this  symbolises  continuity  in  the  relation.  

The  example  below  is  an  extract  from  a  notebook  for  a  housewarming.  The  book  lists  283  givers,  of  

which  25  are  given  below.      

                                                                                                                         6  Religious  festivals  related  to  temples  and  specific  divinities  are  another  crucial  component  of  rituals.  Their  funding  also  follows  complicated  rules  on  the  community  level,  which  we  will  not  cover  here.    7  We  refer  here  to  the  gifts  offered  by  the  guests,  and  not  the  dowry,  which  includes  a  specific  list  of  items.  

Page 12: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

12    

Photograph  1.  A  notebook  for  a  puberty  ceremony  

 

Source:  Venkatasubramanian,  2015  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Page 13: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

13    

Photograph  2.  A  notebook  for  a  housewarming  

 

Source:  Isabelle  Guérin,  2015  

Only  the  organisers  of  the  events  –  who  accept  the  gifts  on  the  day  of  the  ceremony  –  keep  detailed  

accounts.  Givers  usually  stick  to  mental  accounting.  Usually  a  member  of  each  family,  most  often  a  

woman,   is   in   charge   of   remembering   the   family   record,   which   can   be   traced   back   over   several  

generations.  In  this,  one  finds  here  a  number  of  techniques  close  to  those  Yates  identified  (1966)  for  

constructing  an  oral  memory.    The  women  told  us  that  they  keep  precise   images  of  people,  events  

and   locations.   Whenever   they   meet   someone   from   a   particular   family,   the   memory   of   the  

transaction  comes  up  in  their  mind.  Any  discussion  on  this  particular  family  is  also  an  opportunity  to  

remember.  When  transactions  cause  tension  or  conflict,  as   is  often  the  case  as  we  shall  see  below,  

recalling  them  repeatedly  also  helps  to  fix  the  memory.    It  may  happen  that  the  giver  keeps  a  written  

trace  of  his  or  her  own  gifts  (a  note  on  a  calendar,  a  chalk  mark  on  the  wall).  Organisers  also  often  

tick  off  lines  on  their  notebook  once  the  gift  has  been  given  back.    

Page 14: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

14    

As  Dowdy  (2014)  has  noted,  very  little  attention  has  unfortunately  been  paid  to  accounting  practices  

among  the  poor,  as  if  poverty,  by  essence,  were  incompatible  with  accounting.  And  yet  these  events,  

and  the  notebooks  that  go  with  them,  play  a  key  role  in  family  calculations,  long-­‐term  planning  and  

saving  strategies,  for  various  reasons.  First  of  all,  and  as  observed  in  other  contexts8,  these  events  are  

concrete  opportunities  to  display  and  make  visible  the  status  (mariyatai)  of  the  family.  Ceremonies,  

insofar  as  they  gather  the  whole  set  of  relations  of  individuals  and  their  families,  and  insofar  as  they  

are   in   great   part   funded   by   this   same   set   of   relations,   express   one’s  mariyatai   and   contribute   to  

building   it.   The   scale   of   the   ceremony   is   evaluated   in   terms   of   guest   numbers,   their   ‘quality’,   the  

quality  of   food  provided,  and  the  gifts  received:  all   this  aims  at  maintaining,  possibly  uplifting  or  at  

least  not  downgrading  the  organisers’  mariyatai  (and  that  of  their  respective  kin).    

The   scale   of   the   ceremony   mostly   depends   on   two   criteria9.   The   scale   of   ceremonies   recently  

organised   within   the   close   circle   (kinship   and   neighbourhood)   are   a   first   benchmark.   Doing   less  

amounts   to   a   downgrade   in   terms   of   honour.   Doing   better,   even   very   slightly,   is   usually   what   is  

expected.  At  the  same  time,  one  is  supposed  to  organise  an  event  within  one’s  financial  and  human  

resources.   Human   resources   are   needed   to   help   with   the   preparation   of   the   food,   service   and  

cleaning  –  the  events  usually  bring  together  several  hundred  guests  who  must  be  welcomed,  fed  and  

sometimes   accommodated.   Financial   resources   depend   on   available   savings   (has   the   family   been  

able  to  accumulate  gold,  possibly   land  that  can  be  offered,  sold  or  pledged?),  borrowing  capacities  

(how  much  can  the  family  borrow  and  what  is  its  creditworthiness  in  the  eyes  of  potential  creditors?)  

Last  but  not  least,  how  much  can  be  expected  from  the  guests  in  gifts  (moi)?  The  moi  pannam  (the  

sum  of  donations  offered  at  the  time  of  the  event)  most  often  represents  a  substantial  proportion  of  

ceremony  expenses,  or  even  more.   In   fact,  aside  from  daughters’  weddings  which  always   lead  to  a  

'loss'  due  to  the  dowry,  every  ceremony  is  expected  to  lead  to  a  surplus,  a  ‘profit’,  as  we  were  often  

told  (the  English  term  is  frequently  used).  In  fact,  the  moi  pannam  is  the  'knot'  of  the  event,  its  pillar.  

                                                                                                                         8  See  for  instance  Mesfin  (2012).    9  For  a  similar  analysis  in  Ethiopia,  see  Mesfin  (2012).    

Page 15: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

15    

In  other  words,  ceremonies  are  a  kind  of  bet  on  the  generosity  of  their  social  circle  (both  in  money  

and  in  time),  which   in  turn  depends  on  the  obligations  the  organisers  have  accrued  over  the  years.  

For  funerals,  guests  are  expected  to  provide  rice  and  cooking  items,  which  should  then  be  returned  in  

a  timely  fashion.  

Given   the  social   importance  of  ceremonies  and   the  amounts   they   involve,  but  also   their  place   in  a  

long   chain   of   rights   and   obligations   and   financial   transactions,   they   are   thus   at   the   core   of   family  

calculations.  As  we  were  told  once,  each  event  “is  a  link  to  the  past,  the  present  and  the  future”.  It  is  

an   opportunity   to   show   “the   strength   of   your   family   and   relatives”   as  we  were   also   told,   but   the  

strength   in   question   is   a   process:   each   event   updates   prior   relations   and   prefigures   upcoming  

relations.  Calculations  and  evaluations   take  place  before   the  event  and  help   the  organisers   to  plan  

ahead.   Calculations   and   evaluations   also   occur   after   the   event:   each   gift   (and   his/her   donator)   is  

evaluated,  valued,  and  judged  (in  short,  is  it  in  line  with  expectations?).    

To  return  to  saving,  the  wide  set  of  debts  and  entitlements  that  are  contracted  through  ceremonies  

is  thus  a  crucial  aspect  of  a  given  household's  financial  position.  As  in  many  other  contexts  (Peebles  

2010),  most  households  are  both  debtors  and  creditors,  not  only  for  small-­‐scale  daily  transactions10,  

but  on  a  long-­‐term  basis  and  for  high  scale  transactions.  Depending  upon  their  position  within  their  

life-­‐cycle,  but  also   the  nature  of   their   social  network  and  particular   circumstances,  households  are  

net  debtors  or  net  creditors.  Using  the  words  of  Rutherford  (2001),  some  households  “save  up”  (they  

slowly  accumulate  through  regular  donations  and  then  organise  their  own  event,  see  fig.  1  below),  

“save  down”  (they  organise  an  event  and  then  pay  back  slowly)  or  “save  through”  (a  mix  of  the  two).      

Fig.  1  below  shows  a  household  which  has  regularly  saved  since  marriage  in  2005  by  making  regular  

donations  to  its  social  circle,  and  getting  this  partly  back  for  the  daughter's  puberty  marriage.        

 

 

                                                                                                                         10  As  shown  by  Rutherford  (2001)  and  later  on  Collins  et  al.  (2009),  see  also  Morvant-­‐Roux  (2006).    

Page 16: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

16    

Fig.  1.  Ceremonies  as  'saving  up'  

 

Source:  Authors  

Parents  with  unmarried  daughters  most  often  "save  down".    Sivakumar  is  a  typical  example.  He  first  

organised  the  puberty  ceremony  of  his  daughter.  This  allowed  him  to  collect  13  sovereigns11  of  gold  

which  he  put  aside  for  her  future  marriage.  He  may  have  to  pledge  them  regularly  for  various  needs  

and  hope  he  won’t  lose  them.  He  will  “pay  back"  (this  is  the  term  used)  in  around  ten  years,  roughly  

at  the  time  of  his  daughter’s  marriage  for  which  he  will  go  back  into  debt  for  many  years.    

Calculations  and  equivalences    

There   is  no  strict  equivalency  between  savings  given  and   received,  and  gifts  and  counter-­‐gifts.  The  

amounts  result  from  subtle  calculations.  Here,  one  finds  the  various  modes  of  economic  exchange  –  

reciprocity,  redistribution,  sometimes  market  logic  –  but  these  hardly  operate  in  isolation  from  social  

relations,  both   for   the  group's   social   reproduction   (the   size  and  definition  of  which   is  permanently  

negotiated)  and  on  the  level  of  individual,  specific  relations.    

• Reciprocity  

For  friends,  colleagues  and  distant  relatives,  amounts  (in  cash)  or  weight  (in  gold)  are  systematically  

compared  with  how  much  has  previously  been  given  and  received:  in  brief,  how  much  do  I  owe  the  

                                                                                                                         11  One  sovereign  is  equal  to  around  8  grams  of  gold.  It  is  the  most  common  unit  of  measurement  of  gold  in  the  region.    

Page 17: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

17    

organiser  at  the  time  of  ceremony?  Reciprocity  is  both  specific  (calculated  for  one  particular  event)  

and   global   (on   the   scale   of   the   entire   chain   of   exchanges   between   families).   While   calculations  

distinguish   between   various   forms   of   ceremonies   –   one   may   not   give   the   same   amount   for   a  

housewarming   than  a  marriage  –   the   total   value  of   exchanges  between   two   families   can  be   taken  

into  account.  For   instance,  someone  who  has  had  several  children  get  married  may  give  more  to  a  

housewarming   ceremony   organised   by   someone   who   has   few   or   no   children.   In   the   same   vein,  

calculations  may   include  other   forms  of  exchanges  with   the  organiser   besides  ceremonies,   such  as  

loans  or  favours  received  or  offered.  Such  compensation  is  limited  however,  because  it  is  not  made  

public,  while  ceremonial  reciprocity  must  be  public.      

• Redistribution  

Transactions  with  close  relatives  relate  to  specific  obligations.  Within  the  kinship  for  instance,  elder  

brothers  and  maternal  uncles  are  expected  to  take  on  important  responsibilities  in  the  marriages  of  

their   younger   brothers   or   sisters   and   nieces.   Patrons   (big   landowners,   employers,   possibly   local  

politicians)   are   also   expected   to   help   significantly   (through   gifts   or   loans),   although   this   is   on   the  

decline.  In  return,  kinship  and  working  relations  are  not  something  people  have  but  something  they  

do,   and  ceremonies  are   instrumental   in   this  process.  Maternal  uncles  gain   their   status  of  maternal  

uncles  because  they  organise  their  nieces'  marriages.  Patrons  gain  their  status  of  patron  (or  used  to)  

partly  because  they  help  their  workers  or  voters  to  hold  their  ceremonies.    

• Social  reproduction    

As   mentioned   above,   the   status   of   the   family   is   the   defining   issue.   Reputations   are   formed   and  

reformed   at   the   time   of   ceremonies,   but   through   a   long-­‐term   process,   since   each   event   gets   a  

meaning  only  by   recalling  past  events  and  by  projecting   future  ones,  over   various   timeframes.   For  

instance,   a   puberty   ceremony   is   a   preview   of   a   marriage.   Comparing   marriages   of   daughters,  

mothers  and  grandmothers  is  used  to  assess  or  deny  the  upward  mobility  of  the  lineage.    

• Social  transactions    

Page 18: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

18    

Far   beyond   strict   and   fixed   rules   of   rights   and   obligations,   all   transactions   are   first   and   foremost  

social  relations,  whether  based  on  solidarity  or  hierarchy.  Closeness  is  hardly  a  given,  but  facilitated  

by  various  forms  of  social  ties  such  as  kinship,  neighbourhood,  work,  politics,  etc.  But  their  intensity  

is  based  on  emotional  ties  such  as  affection,  friendship  or  love.  Gifts  are  used  to  express  the  intensity  

of  the  bonds  and  the  willingness  to  continue  the  relationship.  Giving  much  more  (or  less)  than  what  

was  given  in  the  past  is  a  clear  signal  that  the  relation  should  continue  (or  stop).  One  person  may  give  

more  out  of  gratitude  or  pity;  another  may  give   less  out  of  vengeance  or  humiliation.   In   the   same  

vein,   obligations   are   not   dictated   by   tradition   but   constantly   negotiated.   Couples   who   leave   the  

extended   family   to   live   in   their  own  house  are  often  accused  of   selfishness  and  are  a   typical   case:  

they  must  show  solidarity  and  are  expected  to  give  much  more  than  if  they  had  remained  with  the  

group.  The  same  applies  for  hierarchical  relations.  The  social  positioning  between  giver  and  receiver  

certainly  depends  on  social  belonging  and  hierarchical  ties  based  on  class,  caste,  kinship  and  gender,  

but   also   on   specific   relations   and   aspirations.   Those   wanting   to   show   their   superiority   must   give  

more.   Comparison   is   crucial   here,   since   giving   less   than   people   from   the   same   rank   would   be  

degrading.  Comparisons  are  made  at  many  levels,  between  the  male  and  the  female  branch  of  one  

particular   family,   between   sisters-­‐in-­‐law   or   between   sisters,   neighbours   or   colleagues,   dominant  

families  within  a  neighbourhood,   close  neighbourhoods  or   castes.  Women’s   status  among   their   in-­‐

laws   is   in   greatly   shaped   by   how  much   was   given   for   their   marriage   (the   famous   dowry),   as   are  

rivalries  between  women,  although  this  doesn't  rule  out  solidarity.    

In  the  same  vein,  receivers  evaluate  gifts  according  to  diverse  criteria.  The  financial  value  of  the  gift  

matters,   but   so   to   does   the   human   and  moral   support   given   throughout   the   event,   from   the   first  

preparations  to  cleaning-­‐up.  As  we  were  often  told,  there  are  those  who  come,  eat,  and  leave,  and  

those   who   stay   from   morning   to   evening,   always   ready   to   help.   There   are   those   who   approve,  

encourage  and  congratulate,  and  those  who  disapprove,  complain  and  criticize.  The  meaning  of  each  

transaction   is   affected   by   pre-­‐existing   social   relations,   which   in   turn   may   be   strengthened   or  

modified.   In   other   words,   transactions  make   the   relations.   Relations   are   both   constitutive   of   and  

Page 19: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

19    

shaped   by   ceremonial   transactions.   As   Zelizer   (1994)   has   shown   at   length   elsewhere,   money   and  

social  ties  are  closely   interwoven.  Even  if  people  regularly  complain  about  the  fact  that  ceremonies  

are   now   a   “business”   –   and   indeed   the   sums   of  money   involved   are   astonishing,   the  way   people  

experience,   understand   and   comment   on   these   events   clearly   shows   the   pre-­‐eminence   of   social  

relations,  as  we  shall  see  in  the  next  section.  

Because   there   is   no   strict   equivalency,   amounts   received  may   differ  widely   from   expectations.   As  

mentioned  earlier,  people  largely  plan  the  scope  and  the  cost  of  a  ceremony  by  taking  into  account  

how  much  they  expect  as  gifts.  Calculations  always  have  an  element  of  uncertainty  (guests  may  give  

less  than  expected)  and  risk  (an  important  gift  may  never  be  reciprocated).    And  since  exchanges  take  

place  in  an  interrupted  chain  of  gifts  and  counter-­‐gifts,  disappointments  (guests  have  given  less  than  

expected)   may   be   counterbalanced   by   the   hope   of   future   reciprocity.   As   mentioned   above,  

transactions  are  shaped  by  but  also  constitutive  of  relations,  by  eliciting  recognition  and  gratitude,  or  

conversely  disappointment,  jealousy.  In  the  event  of  tensions  or  conflicts,  notebooks  can  be  used  as  

public  proof  for  the  local  authorities.  They  may  also  be  used  as  a  proof  for  in-­‐laws  (for  instance  in  the  

event  of  divorce  and  to  get  back  the  dowry)  or  even  for  children  in  case  they  complain  they  got  little  

support.          

Events  unrelated  to  the  life  cycle,  such  as  birthdays  or  housewarmings,  can  be  used  to  compensate  

for  'losses'  or  even  cash  flow  problems.  We  encountered  a  number  of  households  who  felt  they  had  

been  cheated  and  organised  a  birthday  or  a  housewarming  with  the  hope  of  getting  back  their  dues.  

In   theory,   transactions   take   place   in   distinct   exchange   spheres   –   a   gift   for   a   wedding   should   be  

reciprocated   for  another  wedding   -­‐  and  are   thus  non   fungible.   In  practice  however,  and  as  already  

mentioned   earlier,   getting   back   one’s   due   (or   not   plunging   in   over-­‐indebtedness)   is   a   constant  

concern  and  this   leads   to  a   relative   fungibility  of  exchanges  and  a  certain   form  of  market   logic   (on  

this  see  also  Cattelino  2009).  

Page 20: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

20    

In  the  same  vein,  organising  ceremonies  with  the  idea  of  paying  back  a  debt  is  rather  frequent.  Graph  

2  illustrates  such  a  calculation  with  a  woman  called  Parvathi,  and  her  husband,  heavily  indebted  for  

the  renovation  of  their  house.  They  organised  a  housewarming  to  pay  off  part  of  the  debt.  Gifts  to  

others  in  the  past  amounted  to  around  136000  INR,  while  they  received  69300.  This  made  them  “net  

creditors”  for  66550  INR,  distributed  among  various  circles  (distant  relatives,  close  relatives,  friends  

and  colleagues).  They  were  disappointed,  but  hope  to  get  more  for  the  marriage  of  their  son  in  the  

future.   Our   graph   gives   precise   figures  while   Parvathi’s   calculations   are   rough   estimates   based   on  

mental   arithmetic.   It   is   interesting   to   note   however   that   in   all   our   case   studies,   both   estimations  

were  very  similar.    

Graph  2.  Gifts  given  and  received  (housewarming  ceremony)  

 

Source:  Authors  

Emotional  calculations    

There  is  no  doubt  that  ceremonial  expenses  involve  subtle  financial  calculations,  which  are  often  very  

precise   and   on   various   scales,   whether   it   be   short   term   relations  with   colleagues   or   decisions   for  

children's  futures.  Future  plans  and  forthcoming  events  are  thus  crucial.  People  planning  to  organise  

an  event  may  be  more  generous  on  purpose   in  the  preceding  year.  Many  women  clearly  explained  

0  

20000  

40000  

60000  

80000  

100000  

120000  

140000  

160000  

close  relatves  

distant  relatves  

friends   neigbhours     workplace     TOTAL    

Given   Received     Expected  balance    

Page 21: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

21    

that  they  'save'  in  that  way  in  the  year  prior  to  their  own  event.  Guests  who  know  they  won’t  have  

further  opportunities  to  meet  the  organizer  may  give  such  that  accounts  are  cleared,  preventing  one  

party  from  being  a  net  debtor.  Although  financial  calculations  are  key,  it  would  be  misleading  to  stop  

here.  Emotional  aspects  are  also  crucial,  and  a  detailed  example  is  certainly  the  best  way  to  illustrate  

the  intermingling  of  financial  and  emotional  aspects.    

Sivaselvi  and  her  husband  Kumaresan  organised  a  housewarming  in  2014.  Around  750  people  came,  

most  in  families,  and  in  total,  the  organisers  received  283  gifts  (around  one  gift  per  family).  The  event  

cost   them   around   150  000   INR   (mostly   food   and   transport,   which   was   taken   care   of   for   distant  

guests).  They  received  192  365  INR  as  gift  (moi  panam),  which  means  a  “surplus”  of  around  40,000  

INR,  that  Sivaselvi  used  to  pay  off  past  debts.  Gifts  in  cash  ranged  from  50  to  3000  INR.  Gifts  in  gold  

ranged   from  a  quarter  of   sovereign   to  2.5   sovereigns   (from  around  5,500   to  55,000   INR).   Sivaselvi  

explained  bitterly  that  she  was  expecting  a  surplus  of  twice  more.    

Out   of   the   283   givers,   60   belong   to   the   circle   of   her   husband   (friends   and   colleagues).   She   is   not  

aware  of  the  prior  transactions  between  them  and  her  husband,  and  thus  she  is  not  able  to  evaluate  

their   contribution.   In   the   list,   141   givers   are   marked   with   a   cross:   she   considers   that   for   them,  

accounts  are  closed:  in  a  few  cases,  these  are  elderly  people  who  won’t  have  any  other  ceremonies  

in  the  future;  in  most  cases,  they  are  people  she  doesn't  want  to  deal  with  in  the  future  because  they  

gave  too  little.  For  the  remainder  (82),  accounts  are  still  open  and  in  most  cases  she  considers  that  

she  received  less  than  what  she  gave  in  the  past,  but  in  a  number  of  cases  for  good  reasons.  First,  this  

was  a  housewarming  ceremony:  this  is  not  a  systematic  practice,  many  don’t  do  it,  thus  there  are  no  

strict  rules  for  gifts  (as  observed  in  marriages  and  puberty  ceremonies  for   instance)  and  those  who  

don’t  organise  housewarmings  themselves  are  tempted  to  give  little.  People  give,  but  will  give  less  in  

the   future   for   more   “formal”   events   such   as   puberty   ceremonies   or   marriages.   In   the   case   of  

Sivaselvi,  she  has  two  children,  as  yet  unmarried.  Her  24-­‐year-­‐old  son  holds  a  master  degree.  He  will  

get  married  soon  and  people  know.  Her  daughter,  21  years  old,  is  also  of  marriageable  age  but  may  

not  do  so  since  she  is  physically  handicapped  (she  uses  a  wheelchair).  Amounts  given  at  the  time  of  

Page 22: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

22    

the   housewarming   take   into   account   these   two   (potential)   forthcoming   events.     For   instance,  

Rajendran  gave  500  INR,  while  Sivaselvi  gave  him  3000  INR  a  few  years  back  for  a  pilgrimage.  Pazhani  

gave  her  1001   INR,  while  Sivaselvi  gave  her  1000   INR  5  years  back  for  a  marriage  and  500   INR  two  

years  back   for  a  puberty  ceremony.   In  both  cases,  Sivaselvi   is  expecting   them  to  give  some  sort  of  

balance   at   the   time   of   the  marriage   of   her   children.   But   the   fact   that   her   daughter   may   not   get  

married   is  a  source  of  concern.  Notwithstanding  the  future  of  her  daughter,  which   is  of  course  the  

most  worrying  issue,  Sivaselvi  may  lose  money.  But  she  thinks  that  her  closest  relations  are  aware  of  

this  and  may  compensate  by  giving  her  more  for  her  son’s  marriage.    

Coming   back   to   the   housewarming,   the   greatest   disappointments  were   her   three   brothers-­‐in-­‐law.    

She  was  expecting  something  like  35,000/40,000  INR  (in  gold),  in  line  with  what  she  gave  them  in  the  

past  (the  three  brothers  live  together  in  the  same  house  and  had  a  housewarming  four  years  back).  

They  gave  only  one  sovereign  of  gold  (with  costs  around  22,000  at  the  time  of  the  ceremony)  and  she  

experienced  this  as  an  insult.    On  her  own  side  by  contrast,  her  brothers  have  been  rather  generous:  

her   elder   brother   gave   2.5   sovereign   and   the   younger   1   sovereign.   Her   older   brother   gave  much  

more   than   what   he   had   received   from   her   in   the   past.   Not   only   is   he   her   brother,   which   entails  

specific  obligations,  but  his  gesture  is  also  in  line  with  a  forthcoming  event:    their  respective  children  

(her   son   and   his   daughter)   will   get  married   together   (following   the   rule   of   cross-­‐cousin  marriage,  

widespread  in  Tamil  Nadu).  The  generosity  of  her  two  brothers  (although  one  of  them,  the  younger  

one,   is  “economically  down”  as  she  says)  also  results  from  a  deliberate  bid  to  do  “better”  than  her  

brothers-­‐in-­‐law.  As  often,  ceremonies  are  an  opportunity  for  comparison  and  competition  between  

lineages.  As  she  told  us,  “he  [one  of  her  brothers]  wants  to  show  the  strength  of  my  mothers’  side.  

The  idea  is  to  show  to  my  husband’s  family  that  they’re  doing  better.  The  status  of  my  husband  has  

fallen   with   this   event.   People   can   easily   laugh   at   my   husband’s   family”,   and   her   husband   is   also  

“down”  in  front  of  her.  He  “cannot  ask  for  anything”  she  says.    

She  interprets  her  brother-­‐in-­‐laws'  behaviour  as  a  continuity  of  their  previous  relations,  which  have  

been  conflictual   for  some  time.  Her  marriage  was  a  “love-­‐marriage”  and  she  has  always   felt   it  was  

Page 23: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

23    

never  accepted,  despite  many  efforts  to  help  and  support  them.    While  discussing  with  her  husband,  

whom  she  blames  for  the  greediness  of  his  brothers,  she  comes  to  find  out  that  he  hasn’t  been  very  

generous   with   them   on   various   occasions,   which   might   partly   explain   their   behaviour.   But   she  

remains  humiliated  and  her   reaction  was   immediate:  when  her   sister-­‐in-­‐law  was  hospitalized   soon  

after  the  housewarming,  she  did  not  even  care  to  visit  her.  Her  relationship  is  also  quite  tense  with  

her  own  husband.    

Another  disappointment  came  from  a  close  friend  (Punitha),  with  whom  relations  have  become  more  

distant   recently.   Punitha   criticizes   Sivaselvi   for  moving   around   too   freely,   in   circumstances   where  

women’s  mobility  remains  highly  restricted.  Sivaselvi  had  given  her  2000  INR  on  various  occasions  in  

the  past   and  Punitha   gave  her   exactly   the   same  amount.   She  does   not   have   any  upcoming   event,  

while   Sivaselvi   will   have   one   or   two   marriages   soon.   For   Sivaselvi   the   meaning   is   clear:   Punitha  

“repaid  the  entire  amount  at  once”  and  this  means  that  she  wants  to  stop  their  relationship.  Sivaselvi  

is  also  very  upset  with  Daniel  Babu:  he  gave  exactly  the  same  amount  she  had  given  four  years  back,  

while   his   position   has   greatly   improved   since   then:   she   thinks   he   should   have   done   more.   What  

comes   into   play   here   in   her   judgment   is   the   economic   position   of   the   giver:   he   gave   too   little  

compared  to  his  economic  status,  and  someone  who  is  experiencing  upward  mobility  is  expected  to  

be  more  generous  with  his  circle.    

Some  guests  have  given  very  little,  but  she  knows  their  difficulties  and  she  even  feels  “pity”  for  them.  

Hence  this   lady  -­‐  Parvathy  -­‐  who  gave  200  INR,  while  Sivaselvi  had  given  her  1000  INR  fifteen  years  

back   (daughter’s   marriage),   and   500   eight   years   back   (housewarming);     Sivaselvi   tells   us   that  

Parvathy  is  very  poor,  she  is  a  widow,  she  has  no  income  and  depends  on  her  son.  He  came  and  gave  

the  200  INR.    Sivaselvi  also  explains  that  Parvathy’s  son  does  not  necessarily  have  the  memory  of  past  

exchanges.  Another  good  friend,  Rose,  gave  101  INR,  while  Sivaselvi  had  given  her  500  INR  on  various  

occasions   over   the   last   twenty   years.   But   here,   too,   she   feels  more   compassion   than   resentment.  

Rose’s  husband  is  physically  challenged,  and  Rose  was  there  from  morning  to  evening  to  help  her  out  

on  the  day  of  the  housewarming.    

Page 24: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

24    

These  various  examples  show  that  moi  (gifts)  take  place  in  complicated  webs  of  debt  which  combine  

obligations   and   entitlements,   reciprocity,   feelings,   sentiments   and   emotions   such   as   humiliation,  

jealousy,  empathy,  compassion  and  solidarity.  Calculations  are  inseparable  from  affective  ties.  They  

not  only  reflect  but  make  and  remake  affective  ties.  

Conclusion  

The  main  purpose  of  this  paper  has  been  to  demonstrate  the  crucial  role  of  ceremonial  expenses  as  

relational   and   long-­‐term  saving.  We  have  been  using   the   term   'saving',   although   the  practices  and  

transactions  described  here  could  also  be  considered  as  expenses,   consumption,   investment,  debt,  

etc.  and   it   is  certainly  of  no  value  to  assign  a  precise  definition  to  each  category.  To  continue  with  

economic   terminology,   ceremonial   expenses   can  most  properly  be  ascribed  as   'investment-­‐saving',  

because  they  imply  long-­‐term  plans  and  some  sort  of  return.  But  this  does  not  exclude  precautionary  

concerns,  since  the  relations  underpinning  ceremonial  gifts  are  all  potential  safety  nets.    What  comes  

out   clearly   from   our   case   study   is   that   economic   transactions   are   social   transactions   and   it   is  

pointless  to  disentangle  them.  Clearly  too,  despite  widespread  biases  among  many  economists  and  

development  practitioners,  the  poor  have  long-­‐term  concerns,  but  these  are  focused  on  the  creation  

or  maintenance  of  wealth  understood  in  a  broad  sense.  It  includes  material  wealth  as  well  as  wealth  

"in  people"  (Guyer  1997)  and  "investment  in  others"  (Berry  1989).        

We   are   not   looking   to   idealise   these   practices,   which   both   reflect   and   strengthen   pre-­‐existing  

inequalities   along   various   lines,   especially   gender,   but   also   caste   and   class   lines.   Our   point   is   that  

those  dynamics  and   logics  cannot  be   ignored   if  we  truly  wish   to  design  adequate  and   fair   financial  

services.  For  the  moment,  in  the  context  of  our  study,  the  rural  poor  don’t  use  bank  saving  accounts  

as   it  goes  against  a  vision  of  wealth  that  constantly  circulates.  Our  research  highlights  an   immense  

pooling   of   wealth,   the   value   of   which   precisely   comes   from   the   fact   that   it   constantly   circulates.  

Given  the  importance  of  wealth  circulation,  one  may  imagine  that  in  the  near  future,  mobile  money  

Page 25: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

25    

transfers  will  be  successful  and  will  be  used  for  ceremonies,  as  has  already  been  observed  in  Kenya  

(Kusimba  et  al.  no  date).  

What   are   the  policy   implications  of   this   research?  The  answer   is   not   easy,   both  because  observed  

practices  draw  on  a  world  vision  which   is  quite   far   from  the  world  vision  banks  promote   (in   short,  

atomised   individuals   versus   interdependent   individuals;   stored   and   accumulated   wealth   versus  

circulating  wealth,  etc.),  while  being  based  on   relations   that   combine   solidarity  and  hierarchy.   The  

key  question,  and  one  which  would  deserve  further  research,  is  how  technology,  here  digital  finance,  

could  be  used  to  fight  specific  form  of  inequalities,  notably  gender  inequalities  in  this  case.  It  would  

of   course   be   naïve   to   imagine   that   technology   could   fight   the   dowry   system,   but   it   is   certainly  

possible  to  think  about  a  fair  and  democratic  use  of  digital  finance.  This  is  what  Mesfin  et  al  (2012)  

has   done   for   Ethiopia.   Drawing   on   a   fine-­‐grained   ethnography   of   local   rules   and   practices   of   gift-­‐

giving   these   suggest   various   tricks   that   could   allow   digital   finance   not   only   to   adapt   to   these  

complicated  and  multiple  rules,  but  also  to  fight  inequalities  in  access  such  as  illiteracy  (using  specific  

applications,  for  instance).    

Whether  we  like  it  or  not,  digital  finance  is  most  probably  going  to  invade  our  daily  lives,  including  in  

the  most  remote  areas.  Rather  than  being  overtaken,  it  is  urgent  to  think  about  the  multiple  ways  of  

using  it  for  democratic  and  equality  purposes,  especially  in  terms  of  gender.    

   

Page 26: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

26    

List  of  references  

Berry  S.  (1989)  Social  institutions  and  access  to  resources,  Africa,  LIX:  41-­‐55.  

Cattelino  J.  (2009)  Fungibility:  Florida  Seminole  Casino  Dividends  and  the  Fiscal  Politics  of  Indigeneity,  

American  Anthropologist,  111(2):  190–200.  

Cederlof  G.  (1997  Bonds  Lost;  Subordination,  Conflict  and  Mobilisation  in  Rural  South  India  c..  1900-­‐

1970,  New  Delhi:  Manohar.  

Collins  D,  Morduch  J,  Rutherford  S,  Ruthven  O.  (2009)  Portfolios  of  the  Poor:  How  the  World's  Poor  

Live  on  $2  a  Day.  Princeton  University  Press:  Princeton.    

Dowdy  S.  M.  (2014)  How  “The  Poor”  Account  Financial  Reckoning  and  its  Cosmoeconomics  in  Assam,  

India,   IMTFI   report.     http://www.imtfi.uci.edu/files/docs/2013/IMTFI_FInalReport_SeanDowdy.pdf  

(last  access  December  21,  2016)  

DOUGLAS  M.,  ISHERWOOD  B.  C.  (1980)  The  Worlds  of  Goods,  Harmondsworth:  Penguin  Books.  

Goedecke   J.   Guérin   I.,   D’Espallier   B.,Venkatasubramanian   G.   (2016)   Why   do   financial   inclusion  

polities  fail   in  mobilizing  savings  from  the  poor?  The  social  and  cultural  regulation  of  saving  in  rural  

India,  Development  Policy  Review,  forthcoming.  

Guérin   I.,   Morvant-­‐Roux   S.   and   Villarreal   M.   (2013)   Microfinance,   Debt   and   Over-­‐Indebtedness:  

Juggling  with  Money.  London  and  New  York.  Routledge.    

Ferguson   J.   (2015)  Give   a  man   a   fish.   Reflections   on   the   new   politics   of   distribution,   Durham   and  

Duke:  Duke  University  Press.  

Guyer,   J.   (1997)   ‘Endowments   and   assets:   the   anthropology   of   wealth   and   the   economics   of  

intrahousehold  allocation’,   in   L.  Haddad,   J.  Hoddinott,  and  H.  Alderman   (eds)   Intrahousehold  

Resource   Allocation   in   Developing   Countries:   Methods,   Models,   and   Policy.   Baltimore,   MD:  

Johns  Hopkins  University  Press.  

Page 27: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

27    

Hindu  Business  Line  (2014)  ‘End  financial  untouchability  for  freedom  from  poverty:  PM’,  Published  on  

28   August,   http://www.thehindubusinessline.com/banking/end-­‐financial-­‐untouchability-­‐for-­‐

freedom-­‐from-­‐poverty-­‐pm/article6360972.ece  (last  access  August  17th,  2015).  

Joseph,  N.  (2015)  “And  our  ears  have  been  empty  since  then”  –  Gold  Ownership  and  Changing  Work  

Vulnerability   in   the   Informal   Silk   Reeling   Economy   of   Post-­‐Liberalisation   South   India;   IMTFI   Blog,  

http://blog.imtfi.uci.edu/2015/08/and-­‐our-­‐ears-­‐have-­‐been-­‐empty-­‐since-­‐then.html  (last  access  March  

15th,  2016).    

Karlan,  D.,  Ratan,  A.   L.  and  Zinman,   J.   (2014),  Savings  by  and   for   the  Poor:  A  Research  Review  and  

Agenda.  Review  of  Income  and  Wealth,  60:  36–78.    

Kapadia,   K.,   1996,   Siva   and   her   Sisters.   Gender,   Caste   and   Class   in   Rural   South   India,   New  Delhi   :  

Oxford  University  Press.  

Kusimba   S.   Chaggar   H.,   Gross   E.   Kunyu   G.   (2013)   Social   Networks   of   Mobile   Money   in   Kenya,  

http://www.imtfi.uci.edu/files/kusimba_exec_summary_flyer_final_0.pdf.   Last   access   9th   November  

2016.    

Nithyananda,  K.   V.   and   Fouillet,   F.   (2015),   The   Socio-­‐economic   Lives   of   Banking   Correspondents   in  

India’s   Trichy   District,   http://blog.imtfi.uci.edu/2015/12/the-­‐socio-­‐economic-­‐lives-­‐of-­‐banking.html,  

(last  access  March,  15th  2016).  

Mesfin  F.  Woldmariam,  Gheorghita  Ghinea,  Solomon  Atnafu  &  Tor-­‐Morten  Groenli  (2016)  Monetary  

Practices   of   Traditional   Rural   Communities   in   Ethiopia:   Implications   for   New   Financial   Technology  

Design,  Human–Computer  Interaction,  31:6,  473-­‐517.  

Morduch,   J.,   and   Sharma,   M.   (2002)   Strengthening   public   safety   nets   from   the   bottom   up,  

Development  Policy  Review  20,  569–588.  

Morvant-­‐Roux   S.   (2006).  Processus   d’appropriation   des   dispositifs   de  microfinance  :   un   exemple   en  

milieu  rural  mexicain.  Thèse  de  doctorat  en  sciences  économiques.    Université  Lumière  Lyon  2.  

Page 28: Guérin et al Ceremonial expenses as long term saving final ... et... · 2" " unique"relationships."Thedesign"of"innovativefinancial"tools"should"takeinspiration"from"relational"

28    

Neves,   D.   and   du   Toit,   A.   (2012)   Money   and   sociality   in   south   Africa’s   informal   economy,  Africa,  

82(1):  131–149.  

Peebles  P.  (2010)  The  Anthropology  of  Credit  and  Debt,  Annual  Review  of  Anthropology,  39:  225-­‐240    

Pouchepadass  J.  (1980)  L’endettement  paysan  dans  le  Bihar  colonial,  Purusartha,  n°4,  pp.  165-­‐206.  

SHIPTON  P.  (1995)  How  Gambian  save  :  Culture  and  Economic  Strategy  at  an  Ethnic    Crossroad,  in  :  J.  

GUYER,   (éd.)  Money  Matters.   Instability,  Values  and  Social  Payments   in   the  Modern  History  of  West  

African  Communities,  Londres  :  Currey  et  Portsmouth  NH  :  Heinemann,  p.  245-­‐277.  

Reserve   Bank   of   India   (RBI)   (2013)   ‘Financial   Inclusion:   an   Assessment’.   New-­‐Delhi.   Available   at:  

http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Speeches/PDFs/MFI101213FS.pdf  (accessed  March  23,  2015).  

Rosenzweig,  M.  R.   (2001)   ‘Savings  behaviour   in   low-­‐income  countries’,  Oxford  Review  of   Economic  

Policy  17(1),  40–54.  

Rutherford,  S.  (2001)  The  Poor  and  Their  Money.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Tarabout  G.  (1993)  Ritual  rivalry  in  Kerala,  in  Brückner,  Lutze  and  Malik  (eds)  Flags  of  flame.  Studies  

in  south-­‐Asian  folk  culture,  New-­‐Delhi:  Manohar,  pp.  81-­‐108.    

Villarreal  M.,  Guérin   I.   (2013)  Generating,  storing  and  exchanging  value:  the  use  of  gold   in  Mexican  

and  Indian  rural  communities,  http://blog.imtfi.uci.edu/2013/10/generating-­‐storing-­‐and-­‐exchanging-­‐

value.html  

Zelizer  V.  (1994)  The  social  meaning  of  money,  New-­‐York:  Basic  Books.  

Zelizer  V.  (2012)  How  I  became  a  relational  economic  sociologist  and  what  does  that  mean?  Politics  &  

Society,  40(2):145-­‐174.