Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

download Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

of 24

Transcript of Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    1/24

    Economic Growth and Income Inequality in India

    Keith Gehring,Graduate School of International Studies2201 S Gaylord Street, University of Denver,Denver, CO 80208.

    Kishore G. Kulkarni, Ph.D.,Professor of Economics, Campus Box 77,P. O. Box 173362, Metropolitan State College of Denver,Denver, CO 80217-3362.

    And Editor, Indian Journal of Economics and Business (visit: www.ijeb.com)

    First draft of this paper was completed in June 2006. Comments on this papershould be sent to the second author. Each author would like to blame the otherfor remaining errors.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    2/24

    2

    ECONOMIC GROWTH AND INCOME INEQUALITY

    IN INDIA

    Abstract:

    The Indian economy continues to grow as a global economic powerhouse. Indias

    development is particularly impressive given the considerable obstacles in fostering

    economic growth. These obstacles are truly epic with widespread poverty, limited natural

    resources, and one of the largest populations. While this growth is impressive, India

    continues to have hundreds of millions in abject poverty and much of the economic

    prosperity has been fairly localized to specific regions and sectors. The boomingsoftware and technology sector receives daily world attention, however those languishing

    in poverty remain largely ignored. Thus, it is important to understand whether the

    nascent economic prosperity has also caused an increase in income inequality. Economic

    theories vary on both the causes and implications of income equality, however empirical

    evidence indicates that India has been able to maintain low income inequality during

    periods of significant economic growth. It is important to not, that Indias economic

    miracle is a recent phenomenon and that future prospects are far from certain. How well

    the Indian people and government will be able to channel current growth into long-termprosperity remains to be seen.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    3/24

    3

    Economic Growth and Income Inequality in India

    Introduction:

    India has made significant economic progress over the last ten years and is rapidly

    emerging as a major economic force. Overall economic growth has continued at an

    impressive rate while specific sectors, most notably software and related services, are

    recording exponential rates of growth. This growth is all the more impressive, even if the

    significant obstacles inherent in the Indian economy remain to be overcome. These

    obstacles include: a high rate of poverty (primarily in absolute but also in relative terms);

    the lack of significant natural resources, administrative hassles, low rate of educational

    progress, income inequality and a very large population of 1.2 billion people, second only

    to China. However, it is suspected that because of the specific localization of the nascent

    economic growth, the benefits have been realized by a relative minority, while hundreds

    of millions continue to live in abject poverty. This could result in significant increases in

    income equality; a situation that may have significant repercussions.

    Economists and social scientists have dedicated significant effort to the study of

    income equality. The topic has waxed and waned in importance over the years, with

    many academics and policy experts choosing to focus more on absolute poverty than

    overall income distribution. However, income equality is important because of the

    implications for social and political development. It is widely understood that income

    equality can provide stability for a nation, which can only help in fostering long-term

    economic growth. More directly, income equality enables many more individuals to

    participate more fully in the economy. This is due to income equality providing

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    4/24

    4

    opportunities for employment, product consumption, access to borrowing, and the ability

    to invest and save.

    Therefore, it is necessary to understand the income distribution effects in India,

    with a primary emphasis on the last fifteen years when India began significant market

    reforms. India has had a relatively short history as an independent nation and during that

    time, has embarked on a variety of economic development strategies. Moreover, India is

    an incredibly diverse nation with widely varying cultural, economic, political, and

    religious norms. Thus, the implications for income equality are indeed significant in

    maintaining stability in such a large and diverse nation.

    By comparing Indias economic growth and income equality, one can determine

    whether the recent economic prosperity has been realized by many or relatively few

    individuals. This will aid in understanding the implications for other dimensions of

    development, including those pertaining to social and political aspects. The paper first

    documents the historical context of Indias development over the last several decades.

    Second, an examination of the existing theories concerning economic growth and income

    equality is provided. Third, the empirical evidence for India is provided and the existing

    theories tested. Finally, conclusions from the results of the empirical test, as well as

    future implications are discussed.

    It is important to note that Indias economic growth is a relatively recent

    phenomenon and the current global economic environment is increasingly more complex.

    The dynamic nature of global economic integration has rendered many traditional

    economic theories irrelevant in several situations. While the paper will attempt to

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    5/24

    5

    understand future implications for economic growth in India, it is primarily a historical

    review of standing information.

    The Road to Development

    India gained its independence from British colonial rule in 1947. The two years

    following independence witnessed significant bloodshed and the partitioning of the

    nation. Fortunately, partitioning was largely reconciled soon thereafter and India was able

    to return to the task of building a new state. Early in 1950, India successfully passed a

    constitution into law and became a secular democratic republic. Two years later, the new

    government began to implement significant reforms to improve the lives of its people and

    to foster development.

    Indias first Prime Minister, Jawaharlal Nehru, led many of the reforms in the

    republics early history. Nehru was a staunch socialist who distained capitalism and

    profit1. Nehru and his economic advisors sought to improve India through state-

    sponsored industrialization and by keeping the economy largely closed off from global

    trade. While the Nehru administration was responsible for implementing many pro-poor

    and pro-worker reforms including: the elimination of taxation for Indian farmers;

    minimum wage and benefits for blue-collar workers; and the nationalization of heavy

    industries, it was also committed to improving health and welfare by overseeing the

    construction of several hospitals, social service centers, atomic center, steel mills, and

    schools including the famous Indian Institutes of Technology (IITs). Nonetheless there

    was one apparent drawback in this overly nationalistic approach. When the rest of the

    world was seemed to be of little consequence to India planners, the role of international

    1 Greenspan, Anna, India and the IT Revolution, 2004, 22-3.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    6/24

    6

    trade was totally ignored in the progress of Indian economy. Swadeshi (self reliance)

    was overemphasized and the economy was allowed to be essentially one of autarky. The

    bureaucratic machinery increased, and with it, they were set into motion the

    administrative limitations that the world has rarely seen. While politicians saw

    economic rents in keeping up with the large public sector labor force, the academicians

    who proposed changes were completely ignored or maligned.

    These policies continued after Nehrus death in 1964 and saw periods of

    considerable fluctuation in economic growth. The state-run economic policies were

    successful in some ways, but ultimately produced an unsustainable situation. By the late

    1980s, stagnation had set in and India was in serious peril after depleting nearly all of its

    foreign exchange reserves. This was largely due to fiscal profligacy by the government,

    requiring substantial reductions in spending.2 The ensuing balance-of-payments crisis in

    1991 was the final catalyst pushing India to begin modest reforms in trade and finance.

    During the 1991, the then Finance Minister Manmohan Singh was able to usher in major

    reforms with the help of Prime Minister Narasimha Rao. The result was annual growth of

    between 4% and 8%, equating to an average growth rate around 6%. Moreover,

    expectations are that the current growth will continue through the end of the decade3.

    Because of the reforms of the 1990s, India now enjoys solid growth and a prominent

    position in the global economy.

    2 Ahluwalia, Montek S., Economic Reforms in India since 1991: Has Gradualism Worked?, The Journal

    of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 16, No.3, Summer, 2002.3 The Economist, Democracys Drawbacks, October 27, 2005.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    7/24

    7

    Economic Growth and Income Equality

    Economic growth is defined as the steady process by which the productive

    capacity of the economy is increased over time to bring about rising levels of national

    output and income.4 Economic growth is generally gauged by a variety of Gross

    Domestic Product (GDP) measures, where GDP represents the total output or production

    of an economy. GDP, while strictly a measure of output, is also understood to be total

    income as well. There are a variety of limitations to using GDP as a measure of output or

    income. Most notably, differences in inflation, population size, and purchasing power can

    cause significant variances when comparing GDP. However, overall GDP given in 2000

    US dollars (i.e. inflation adjusted) is a relatively robust figure for measuring growth,

    especially in relation to income equality.

    Income equality is the distribution of total income amongst the representative

    population. In a nation with perfect income equality, each and every individual has an

    equal share of the total income. This is contrasted with perfect income inequality, where

    one individual has all of the total income. Of course, neither of these extreme situations

    exists in any national economy. In practice, nations maintain income distributions

    somewhere between the two extremes. Income equality can be compared internally for a

    given nation, as well as externally between multiple nations.

    The variation in income distribution is represented diagrammatically by the

    Lorenz curve. The diagram charts the relationship between the percentage of individuals,

    or households, and the percentage of total income. In a nation with perfect income

    distribution, the relationship is perfectly linear with a slope equal to one. As noted in the

    4 Todaro, Michael P. & Smith, Stephen C., Economic Development, Eighth Edition, Pub. Addison Wesley

    2003.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    8/24

    8

    preceding, this condition does not exist in any national economy. Therefore, the

    relationship is normally bowed outward in a curvilinear form as depicted inFigure 1. The

    figure illustrates that a large number of individuals has a relatively small proportion of

    total income, while a small number of individuals has a relatively large proportion of

    total income. Thus, the more bowed away from the line of equality a nations Lorenz

    curve is, the more unequal the income is distributed.

    The Lorenz curve provides an easy way to represent income equality in terms of

    graphs, however, it does not work easily in comparative analysis. Comparative analyses,

    over time or between nations, require a discrete value for computation. The common

    value for representing income equality is the Gini coefficient. It is derived from the

    Lorenz curve and is represented as a ratio, where the region between the line of equality

    and the Lorenz Curve is the numerator and the total region below the line of equality is

    the denominator. Therefore, perfect income equality is equal to zero, perfect income

    inequality is equal to one, and all other values are somewhere between.

    The most immediate limitation of the Gini coefficient is that it does not

    sufficiently explain the overall variation in income distribution. It is possible that two

    nations could have equal Gini coefficients, but vary significantly in the allocation of

    income between specific groups. This usually occurs between nations where the income

    distribution varies between the poor and middle income groups, however other scenarios

    are also possible. For example, one nation may have fewer individuals in poverty, but

    have fewer middle income individuals; effectively squeezing the middle class.

    Conversely, a nation may have relatively more individuals in poverty, but have more

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    9/24

    9

    middle income individuals. In both cases the Gini Coefficient would be the same, but the

    two situations are quite distinct.

    In comparing economic growth with income equality, two aspects are considered.

    First, the effect of economic growth on income equality is a topic of considerable debate.

    Simon Kuznets hypothesized that as a nation increases per capita income (growth),

    income inequality will initially increase but in the long run return to original levels. This

    phenomenon was termed The Inverted-U Hypothesis, because of the shape of the

    relationship, as shown in Figure 2. Kuznets hypothesis is based on empirical research,

    predominantly in Latin America, and the observation that initial economic growth is

    localized to specific regions and economic sectors. Thus, while overall per capita GDP

    increases, the effects are often relegated to a relative minority. However, long term

    growth causes income inequality to decline, as spillover effects trickle down to more

    individuals.

    The second aspect focuses on the inverse relationship: impact of income equality

    on economic growth. While Kuznets hypothesis has received considerable attention, the

    effects of income equality on growth have not. One study by Persson and Tabillini

    concluded that income inequality is inversely correlated with economic growth, but that

    the relationship is only significant in democracies.5 The study utilized a diverse data set,

    representing multiple nations of varying economic development over several decades.

    The authors conclude that income inequality leads to policies that fail to protect property

    5 Persson, Torsten & Tabellini, Guido, Is Inequality Harmful for Growth, The American Economic

    Review, June 1994.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    10/24

    10

    rights and do not permit private appropriation of returns on investment.6 These findings

    support and extend the adverse impacts noted earlier in the introduction.

    Applying the Models to the Indian Economy

    The preceding models provide a sound basis for explaining the relationship

    between economic growth and income equality. However, all models have limitations so

    it is necessary to review the empirical data to determine if these models can be applied to

    the Indian economy. To test the models, historical data comprising: annual GDP growth;

    annual Gini coefficient; and annual trade as a percentage of GDP are required.

    Additionally, comparable data from other developing nations is required to contrast

    Indias performance against similar nations.

    With regards to Kuznets hypothesis, empirical evidence indicates India has not

    responded as predicted in the Inverted-U hypothesis. Figure 3 illustrates the relationship

    using data from the World Bank, World Development Indicators. Several years of data

    were missing for the Gini Coefficient, however through interpolation we can obtain a fair

    representation of the trend a 35 year timeframe, from 1966 through 2000. The data

    indicate Indias Gini coefficient has remained relatively the same during that time period,

    with an average coefficient of 31.3 and standard deviation of 1.0. Given that India had a

    coefficient of 31.1 in 1966 and 32.5 in 2000, the trend is effectively flat.

    However, Indias growth rate has increased on average during the same time

    period. During the pre-reform era of 1966-1991, the economy grew at an average rate of

    4.3%, with a standard deviation of 3.4. As noted previously, growth fluctuated

    dramatically during this time period, but was positive over the long run. From 1991-2000,

    6 Ibid.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    11/24

    11

    the economy grew at an average rate of 5.5%, with a standard deviation of 2.1. Thus,

    over the 35 year period, Indias economy has grown on average by 4.8% but kept income

    distribution relatively constant. Clearly the empirical evidence indicates Kuznets

    hypothesis fails to describe the past performance of the Indian economy.

    To further support the World Bank Data, an alternative model for determining

    income distribution is also provided. Gajwani, Kanbur, and Zhang use a disparate

    approach, whereby regional differences income equality is assessed.7 The authors utilize

    a sample set of 16 Indian states, and 32 observations from 1957 to 2003. This approach is

    contrasted with the World Bank Data, where income distribution does not consider

    regional differences. As shown in Figure 4, the authors results are mixed. In strict

    nominal terms, income inequality appears to be increasing from 12.1 in 1958 to 19 in

    2003. However, in viewed in terms, the average trend is effectively flat (11.7 in 1958 and

    11.4 in 2003). While the trend fluctuates significantly more than the trend from the World

    Bank dataset, it does not appear to be increasing in any way.

    Gajwani, Kanbur, and Zhang also utilize another technique to describe Indian

    income inequality: the measure of decomposable generalized entropy class (GE) of

    inequality measures.8 This technique provides an added benefit, in that it is additively

    decomposable, allowing inequality across groups to be broken down into within-group

    inequality and between-group inequality.9 The trend is represented in Figure 4 and once

    again supports the earlier conclusion that income distribution is effectively flat in India.

    7 Gajwani, Kiran, Kanbur, Ravi, & Zhang, Xiabo Patterns of Spatial Convergence and Divergence in India

    and China,Paper prepared for the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics (ABCDE),

    January 18-19 2006.8 Ibid.9 Ibid.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    12/24

    12

    Regarding the second model where income inequality is negatively correlated

    with economic growth, India appears to support this hypothesis. Indias current Gini

    coefficient of 33 is relatively low and usually ranks in the top 20% of all nations

    reporting. By contrast, other large developing nations all have higher coefficients:

    Indonesia 34.3; China 44.7; Nigeria 50.6; and Brazil 59.3. 10 India has also been a

    democracy for nearly fifty years, so the model from Persson and Tabillini would expect

    the Indian economy to grow at a relatively constant rate. As the data have shown, India

    has in fact grown steadily on average over the past 38 years. The few instances when

    India has observed negative growth were due to a variety of factors, none of which can be

    correlated with instances of rising income inequality.

    Thus, based on the observed data, Kuznets model (largely) fails to describe the

    impact of growth on income distribution, while the Persson and Tabillini model is

    supported. The fact that Kuznets model failed is surprising, given the role the software

    and related services sector has played in driving Indias recent growth. Because the

    growth of this sector has been localized to a relatively small proportion of the nation, in

    terms of geography and population, one would expect the Inverted-U hypothesis to be

    upheld. This scenario adheres perfectly to Kuznets thesis, where income inequality

    during periods of growth is a direct result of growth being localized to specific

    individuals and sectors. However, the data do not indicate this to be the case. In order to

    understand why this is, a more detailed review of the software and services sector is

    required.

    10 United Nations, 2005 Development Programme Report(page 270).

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    13/24

    13

    The Indian Economy and the Rise of the Software Sector

    In recent years, India has seen consistently strong overall economic growth, with

    exponential growth in the software and related services sector. However, the impact to

    the greater Indian economy and the population as a whole remains relatively modest.

    India has the second largest population with roughly 250 million citizens living below the

    poverty line11. India is still a large agrarian economy, constituting 21% of GDP12 and has

    yet to effectively exploit other potential industries like textiles and manufacturing. The

    software and related services sector, while impressive from an industry perspective, still

    comprises little more than 1 million or .01% of the total population13. This is however,

    predicted to double by 2008, but still insignificant when compared to Indias 470 million

    labor pool14.

    The growth in the software and services sector has enabled a burgeoning middle

    class, but also increasing disparity. This is due to the fact that most of the technology

    centers are clustered in just a few localized areas (e.g. Bangalore, Delhi, Hyderbad, Pune)

    and that the jobs available require English proficiency and technical aptitude. Most of

    Indias population lies outside of these regions and lacks the necessary skills to

    participate in the nascent economic prosperity. Also, limited spillover effects have been

    realized in other sectors, because of Indias undeveloped status. For the millions

    employed as welders, shop keepers, drivers, etc., the technology revolution has yet to

    impact them in any discernible way15

    . In contrast, Indias large neighbor China was able

    to mobilize (albeit forcibly) a labor force from the rural countryside into industry and lift

    11 Wikipedia contributors, India, Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia, March 13, 2006.12 Ibid.13 The Economist, Democracys Drawbacks, October 27, 2005.14 The Economist, The Remote Future, February 19, 2004.15 The Statesman (India), Winning Formula, January 21 2006.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    14/24

    14

    more than 200 million out of poverty. Unfortunately, it does not appear that the software

    and services sector by itself will have any chance at fostering the same scale of

    development in India as in China.

    Indian software and services firms are on target to increase annual revenues to

    $60 billion by 201016. Considering last years revenues totaled less than a third of that

    amount ($17.3 billion) the growth potential is impressive.17

    While future growth will

    continue to contribute an increasing proportion of overall GDP, the current contribution

    is relatively modest: roughly 3%. Thus, it is the rest of the Indian economy that is

    responsible for most of the economic growth and the relative constant income equality.

    While the Indian software and services sector has received significant press, it has yet to

    become a considerable force in the overall Indian economy.

    The Role of Government in Maintaining Income Equality

    While fairly modest at the present, the prospect of increasing disparity from the

    growth of the software and services sector has compelled many in Indias government to

    resist the movement towards complete economic liberation. Most notably, Indias Left

    Front has been particularly effective in resisting additional reforms18

    . The argument is

    based on differences of ideology and protectionist fears that continued openness will risk

    aspects of sovereignty, as international firms purchase increasing shares in formerly state-

    run enterprises and workers rights are reduced. The counterclaim, espoused by the current

    government under Prime Minister Manmohan Singh, is that India will never fully realize

    her potential without additional reforms and increasing involvement from private

    16 Business Week Online, India's Looming IT Labor Shortage, December 16, 2005.17 Ibid.18 The Economist, Democracys Drawbacks, October 27, 2005.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    15/24

    15

    enterprise. Given the historically poor performance of Indias state-run industries, he may

    be right.

    Regardless, it is in Indias best interest to reach a compromise. Such a

    compromise would have increasing openness but through controlled steps (e.g. by sector

    or industry). This presents the best opportunity to bring economic prosperity to more

    individuals, as it would spur development in other areas besides the software and services

    sector. India desperately needs to improve its infrastructure to support continued growth.

    Improvements in highways, airports, and utilities are all desperately needed; all of which

    could generate numerous jobs in other sectors. However, any compromise will require

    significant political will and effective leadership. In Indian terms, the current Prime

    Minister has moved mountains, however real reform remains elusive.

    While these efforts are quite laudable and represent a gradualist approach through

    compromise, they are however insufficient in the eyes of the International Monetary

    Fund (IMF). Last year, the IMF Managing Director, Rodrigo de Rato praised India for

    the reforms implemented thus far and has compared its success to the experience of other

    Asian nations.19

    However, the IMF also contends India needs to move forward with more

    reforms, specifically in the areas of opening private investment and in lowering trade

    tariffs.20

    India is continuing down the reform path and has made strides in opening up to

    increased private investment and trade. But India will probably continue to maintain a

    distinct development path, where economic reform is balanced with socialist pro-poor /

    pro-worker programs. This gradualist approach has been relatively successful in

    19 IMF Survey, De Rato applauds growth in China and India, Vol.34, No.5, March 21, 2005.20 Ibid.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    16/24

    16

    maintaining strong economic growth, while also ensuring economic equality. Critics

    contend this strategy has held India back, while others contend it is a pragmatic approach

    where the goals are indicated as a broad direction, precisely to control the pace of

    development.21 This has resulted in a more modest backlash from the opposition, and

    possibly an exit strategy should reforms prove detrimental. Thus, this gradualist process

    has been appropriately described as creating a strong consensus for weak reforms.22

    To

    attempt reforms at a faster pace would probably meet with significant resistance,

    jeopardizing the entire effort.

    Challenges and Opportunities

    The challenges to Indias sustained economic growth are considerable. Both

    internal and external factors will weigh heavily as India strives to maintain current

    growth trends. Poor infrastructure, stagnate reform, and underperforming industrial

    sectors will continue to cost India considerably. These challenges are well within Indias

    realm to resolve, however other challenges exist which are unfortunately, largely outside

    of Indias direct influence. First, direct competition in the global economy could make

    other entrants more attractive. China, for one, is closely studying the Indian model and

    hopes to overtake Indias current position in software development by the end of the

    decade23

    .

    Second, geopolitical instability could prove detrimental to Indian development.

    South Asia has seen a significant amount of tension in recent years, underscored by

    Indian and Pakistani nuclear weapons tests, US military operations in Afghanistan, and

    21 Ahluwalia, Montek S., Economic Reforms in India since 1991: Has Gradualism Worked?, The Journal

    of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 16, No.3, Summer, 2002.22 Ibid.23 Rai, Saritha, Chinese Race to Supplant India in Software, The New York Times, January 5, 2002.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    17/24

    17

    continuing hostilities in Kashmir. Thomas Friedman contends that while the region is

    relatively volatile, increasing trade and economic integration has helped and will continue

    to help stave of future conflicts24. This may be true up to a point, however should

    widespread conflict breakout in the region, most western firms will not be inclined to

    return.

    The challenges for India are significant, but the opportunities are promising. To

    sustain longer-term growth, Indian firms will need to move into currently untapped

    markets by leveraging more collaborative partnerships. Indian firms have a miniscule

    presence in markets outside of North America and Britain. To become truly global

    competitors, they will need to seriously target other markets, most notably in Continental

    Europe and Asia. However, these firms can not do it alone. They lack the relationships,

    language skills, and industry experience to be contenders, which is why collaborative

    partnering makes sense25. This approach is nothing new as it represents the global trend

    in managing supply chains and sourcing. By sourcing Indias talented and cost effective

    labor pool, with existing global business relationships, Indian firms will truly become

    industry giants.

    Undoubtedly though, unlimited potential lies in finding and exploiting new

    service offerings that are, as of yet, still waiting to be discovered. Technology has

    enabled unimaginable opportunities for sourcing work from anywhere in the world. The

    only limitation is that which cannot be digitized. Everything else, (e.g. radiology,

    derivatives analysis, legal services, etc.) is fair game. India, unlike China, fostered a

    strong sense of entrepreneurship which has arguably contributed heavily to the success of

    24 Friedman, Thomas, The World is Flat, 2005, 426.25 Kaka, Noshir and Sinha, Jayant, An Upgrade for the Indian IT Services Industry, McKinsey Quarterly.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    18/24

    18

    the revolution26. From pharmaceuticals to biotechnology, the technologies of the future

    will provide considerable opportunities to the astute entrepreneur.

    This entrepreneurship however, should not be limited to the areas dominated by

    technology alone. India still has untapped potential in the manufacturing and textiles

    sectors, both of which can contribute an increasing share of GDP growth. These sectors

    do have strong labor representation that is strongly supported by the left-leaning

    government parties, so reform will be difficult. However, this is not an impossible task.

    Even the Left Front has recognized the benefits produced by the reforms and its support

    of continued reforms. The Left Front will probably not allow extensive reforms in

    specific sectors (e.g. the so-called Indian crown jewels), but has yielded in other

    sectors. This could enable the manufacturing, textiles, and other production industries to

    compete on a global standard, thereby increasing overall growth while maintaining a

    strong and vibrant working class.

    The Indian government should continue to loosen the strong hold it has on both

    regulation and operation of business enterprises. The notorious License Raj has

    hindered normal business processes (e.g. incorporating a business, closing a business,

    litigation between parties, etc.), with overbearing and often corrupt regulations. The

    success of the software and services sector was in part due to the relative liberty the

    government permitted in the early stages of development. Second, the ineffective state-

    run enterprises should be diligently assessed and either reformed or closed. Again, this

    will be a very contentious activity with the strong support of the leftist parties, however it

    is possible.

    26 Khanna, Tarun China and India: The race to growth, McKinsey Quarterly.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    19/24

    19

    Finally, the Indian government can play a more effective role in ensuring the

    gains from economic growth are fairly redistributed to the greater Indian population.27

    Existing efforts have had mixed success, with such benefits as food subsidies largely

    benefiting large and wealthy producers, not the poor. However, continued investment in

    social services, specifically targeting health care, education, and job training, can provide

    considerable dividends. The success of the software and services sector clearly indicates

    that Indian knowledge workers are effective and in demand. By improving health

    services and education, more individuals will be able to participate in the growing

    economy.

    Conclusions

    The recent economic growth in India has been impressive. The fact that relative

    income equality has also remained largely stable makes this growth all the more

    remarkable. India has clearly shown that contrary to Kuznets Inverted-U Hypothesis, a

    nation can experience steady economic growth, while also maintaining stable income

    equality. This has been due to a variety of factors, although Indias strong commitment to

    democracy and pro-poor / pro-worker policies should be noted. The nascent software and

    related services sector has made a steadily increasing contribution to overall economic

    growth, however this contribution remains relatively small. Because India has reformed

    under a gradualist approach, a burgeoning technology sector has been able to emerge

    while the greater Indian population has not lost preexisting benefits.

    27 By Knowledge @ Wharton, India: Can Singh Spread the Shine?, Wharton School Publishing, June 2,

    2004.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    20/24

    20

    However, the more relevant results will be measured by how well India uses this

    growth in the years and decades to come. This paper details the multitude of challenges

    confronting India, both internal and external. These challenges will require India to

    address the growing potential for real disparity between those who have benefited and

    those who have been left behind. The software and services sector shows considerable

    economic potential, but also that the opportunities are available to a distinct minority.

    Moreover, the specific nature of the industry appears to offer few chances for spillover

    effects to benefit the larger population. Therefore, it will require bold and quite possibly

    painful decisions by the government to ensure income inequality does not become a

    issue.

    India should capitalize on the momentum from the current growth by expanding

    and developing other industries, most notably in manufacturing and textiles. The Indian

    government should also provide additional welfare benefits so that more Indians can

    participate in the growing and changing economy. Specifically, health and educational

    services can dramatically improve the nations human capital and ensure more Indians

    have the capabilities required to participate in the economy. This paper has noted several

    times that while income equality has remained relatively low, there is significant

    potential for that to change for the worse. By allowing income equality to worsen,

    stability could become an issue thereby jeopardizing all that has been gained. The Indian

    people have waited for a long time to take advantage of the benefits of globalization and

    a new market economy. It would indeed be a shame for them not to make the most of this

    unprecedented opportunity.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    21/24

    21

    Figures and Tables

    Figure 1 Figure 2

    Source: Institute for Social Research, Toronto Canada

    Figure 3

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    22/24

    22

    Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators

    Figure 4

    Source: Gajwani, Kanbur, Zhang, 2006

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    23/24

    23

    Bibliography

    Ahluwalia, Montek S., Economic Reforms in India since 1991: Has GradualismWorked?, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 16, No.3, Summer, 2002.

    Business Week Online, India's Looming IT Labor Shortage, December 16, 2005.

    By Knowledge @ Wharton, India: Can Singh Spread the Shine?, Wharton SchoolPublishing, June 2, 2004.

    Gajwani, Kiran, Kanbur, Ravi, & Zhang, Xiabo Patterns of Spatial Convergence andDivergence in India and China, Paper prepared for the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics (ABCDE), January 18-19 2006.The Economist, DemocracysDrawbacks, October 27, 2005.

    The Economist, The Remote Future, February 19, 2004.

    Friedman, Thomas, The World is Flat, 2005, 426.

    Greenspan, Anna, India and the IT Revolution, 2004, 22-3.

    IMF Survey, De Rato applauds growth in China and India, Vol.34, No.5, March 21,2005.

    Kaka, Noshir and Sinha, Jayant, An Upgrade for the Indian IT Services Industry,McKinsey Quarterly.

    Khanna, Tarun China and India: The race to growth, McKinsey Quarterly.

    Persson, Torsten & Tabellini, Guido, Is Inequality Harmful for Growth, The AmericanEconomic Review, June 1994.

    Rai, Saritha, Chinese Race to Supplant India in Software, The New York Times,January 5, 2002.

    The Statesman (India), Winning Formula, January 21 2006.

    Todaro, Michael P. & Smith, Stephen C., Economic Development, Eighth Edition, Pub.Addison Wesley 2003.

    United Nations, 2005 Development Programme Report(page 270).

    Wikipedia contributors, India, Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia, March 13, 2006.

  • 8/2/2019 Growth and Inequality in India With Keith

    24/24

    Wikipedia Contributors, Jawaharlal Nehru, Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia,December 21, 2004.