Global Markets in Action

68
© 2015 Pearson

description

Global Markets in Action

Transcript of Global Markets in Action

Page 1: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

Page 2: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

Who wins and who loses

from globalization?

Page 3: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

1 Explain how markets work with international trade.

2 Identify the gains from international trade and its winners and losers.

3 Explain the effects of international trade barriers.

4 Explain and evaluate arguments used to justify restricting international trade.

CHAPTER CHECKLIST

Global Markets in Action

Page 4: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

Imports are the good and services that people and firms in one country buy from firms in other countries.

Exports are the goods and services firms in one country sell to people and firms in other countries.

Page 5: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

International Trade TodayThe United States is the world’s biggest international trader and accounts for 10 percent of world exports and 12 percent of world imports.

In 2012, total U.S. exports were $2.2 trillion, which is about 14 percent of the value of U.S. production.

In 2012, total U.S. imports were $2.8 trillion, which is about 17 percent of the value of total U.S. expenditure.

Page 6: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

The United States trades internationally in goods and services.

In 2012, U.S. exports of services were $0.6 trillion (30 percent of total exports) and U.S. imports of services were $0.4 trillion (16 percent of total imports).

The largest U.S. exports of goods are airplanes.

The largest U.S. imports of goods are crude oil and automobiles.

The largest U.S. exports of services are royalties, license fees, banking, business consulting, and other private services.

Page 7: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

What Drives International Trade?

The fundamental force that generates trade between nations is comparative advantage.

The basis for comparative trade is divergent opportunity costs between countries.

National comparative advantage is the ability of a nation to perform an activity or produce a good or service at a lower opportunity cost than any other nation.

Page 8: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

The opportunity cost of producing a T-shirt is lower in China than in the United States, so China has a comparative advantage in producing T-shirts.

The opportunity cost of producing an airplane is lower in the United States than in China, so the United States has a comparative advantage in producing airplanes.

Both countries can reap gains from trade by specializing in the production of the good at which they have a comparative advantage and then trading.

Both countries are better off.

Page 9: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

Figure 8.1(a) shows that with no international trade,

1. U.S. demand and U.S. supply determine

2. The U.S. price at $8 a T-shirt and

3. U.S. firms produce at 40 million T-shirts a year

and U.S. consumers buy 40 million T-shirts a year.

Why the United States Imports T-Shirts

Page 10: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

The demand for and supply of T-shirts in the world determine the world price at $5.

The world price is less than $8, so the rest of the world has a comparative advantage in producing T-shirts.

Figure 8.1(b) shows that with international trade,

4. The price in the United States falls to $5 a T-shirt.

Page 11: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

With international trade,

5. Americans increase the quantity they buy to 60 million T-shirts a year.

6. U.S. garment makers decrease the quantity they produce to 20 million T-shirts a year.

7. The United States imports 40 million T-shirts a year.

Page 12: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

Figure 8.2(a) shows that with no international trade,

1. Equilibrium in the U.S. airplane market.

2. The U.S. price is $100 million an airplane and

3. U.S. aircraft makers produce 400 airplanes a year and U.S. airlines buy 400 a year.

Why the United States Exports Airplanes

Page 13: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

The world market for airplanes determines the world price at $150 millionan airplane.

The world price is higher than $100 million, so the United States has a comparative advantage in producing airplanes.

Page 14: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

Figure 8.2(b) shows that with international trade,

4. The price of an airplane in the United States rises to $150 million.

Page 15: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.1 HOW GLOBAL MARKETS WORK

With international trade,

5. U.S. aircraft makers increase the quantity they produce to 700 airplanes a year.

6. U.S. airlines decrease the quantity they buy to 200 airplanes a year.

7. The United States exports 500 airplanes a year.

Page 16: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

International trade lowers the price of an imported good and raises the price of an exported good.

Buyers of imported goods benefit from lower prices and sellers of exported goods benefit from higher prices.

But some people complain about international competition: not everyone gains.

Who wins and who loses from free international trade?

We measure the gains and losses by examining the effects of international trade on consumer surplus, producer surplus, and total surplus.

Page 17: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

1. With no international trade, the price of a T-shirt in the United States is $8 and 40 million T-shirts a year are bought and sold.

2. Consumer surplus is the area of the green triangle.

3. Producer surplus is the area of the blue triangle.

Gains and Losses from Imports

Page 18: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

With international trade, the price of a T-shirt falls to the world price of $5.

4. Consumer surplus expands from area A to the area A + B + D.

5. Producer surplus shrinks to the area C.

Page 19: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

The area B is transferred from producers to consumers, but

6. Area D is an increase in total surplus.

Area D is the net U.S. gains from international trade.

Page 20: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

Consumers gain because they pay less, buy more T-shirts, and receive a larger consumer surplus.

Producers lose because they receive a lower price, produce fewer T-shirts, and receive a smaller producer surplus.

Consumers’ gain exceeds producers’ loss, so total surplus increases.

Page 21: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

1. With no international trade, the price of an airplane in the United States is $100 million and 400 a year are bought and sold.

2. Consumer surplus is the area of the green triangle.

3. Producer surplus is the area of the blue triangle.

Gains and Losses from Exports

Page 22: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

With international trade, the price of an airplane rises to the world price of $150 million.

4. Consumer surplus shrinks to the area A.

5. Producer surplus expands from area C to the area B + C + D.

Page 23: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

The area B is transferred from consumers to producers, but

6. Area D is an increase in total surplus.

Area D is the net U.S. gains from international trade.

Page 24: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.2 WINNERS, LOSERS, AND NET GAINS FROM TRADE

Consumers lose because they pay a higher price, buy fewer airplanes, and receive a smaller consumer surplus.

Producers gain because they receive a higher price, produce more airplanes, and receive a larger producer surplus.

Producers’ gain exceeds consumers’ loss, so total surplus increases.

Page 25: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Governments restrict international trade to protect domestic producers from competition.

The four sets of tools they use are• Tariffs• Import quotas• Other import restrictions• Export subsidies

Page 26: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Tariffs

A tariff is a tax on a good that is imposed by the importing country when an imported good crosses its international boundary.

For example, the government of India imposes a 100 percent tariff on wine imported from California.

So when an Indian wine merchant imports a $10 bottle of Californian wine, he pays the Indian government $10 import duty.

Page 27: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

The Effects of a Tariff

With free international trade, the world price of a T-shirt is $5 and the United States imports 40 million T-shirts a year.

Imagine that the United States imposes a tariff of $2 on each T-shirt imported.

The price of a T-shirt in the United States rises by $2.

Figure 8.5 shows the effect of the tariff on the market for T-shirts in the United States.

Page 28: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Figure 8.5(a) shows the market before the government imposes the tariff.

The price is the world price of $5 and

1. The United States imports 40 million T-shirts.

Page 29: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Figure 8.5(b) shows the market with the tariff.

2. The tariff of $2 raises the price in the U.S. market to $7.

3. U.S. imports decrease to 10 million a year.

4. U.S. government collects the tax revenue of $20 million a year.

Page 30: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Winners, Losers, and the Social Loss from a Tariff

When the U.S. government imposes a tariff on imported T-shirts:

• U.S. producers of T-shirts gain.

• U.S. consumers of T-shirts lose.

• U.S. consumers lose more than U.S. producers gain.

U.S. Producers of T-shirts Gain

U.S. producers receive a higher price (the world price plus the tariff), so they produce more T-shirts. Producer surplus increases.

Page 31: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

U.S. Producers of T-shirts Gain

U.S. garment makers can now sell T-shirts for a higher price (the world price plus the tariff), so they produce more T-shirts.

But the marginal cost of producing a T-shirt is less than the higher price, so the producer surplus increases.

The increased producer surplus is the gain to U.S. garment makers from the tariff.

Page 32: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

U.S. Consumers of T-shirts Lose

U.S. buyers of T-shirts now pay a higher price (the world price plus the tariff), so they buy fewer T-shirts.

The combination of a higher price and a smaller quantity bought decreases consumer surplus.

The loss of consumer surplus is the loss to U.S. consumers from the tariff.

Page 33: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

U.S. Consumers Lose More than U.S. Producers Gain

Consumer surplus decreases and producer surplus increases.

But which changes by more?

Figure 8.6 illustrates the change in total surplus.

Page 34: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Figure 8.6(a) shows the total surplus with free international trade.

The world price is $5 a T-shirt.

1. Imports

2. Consumer surplus

3. Producer surplus

4. The gains from free trade

Total surplus is maximized.

Page 35: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

5. The $2 tariff is added to the world price and increases the U.S. price of a T-shirt to $7.

The quantity of T-shirts produced in the United States increases and the quantity bought decreases.

6. Imports decrease.

Page 36: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

7. Consumer surplus shrinks to the green area.

8. Producer surplus expands to the blue area.

Area B is a transfer from consumer surplus to producer surplus.

Page 37: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Tariff revenue equals the imports of T-shirts multiplied by the tariff.

9. The tariff revenue is area C.

10.The sum of the two areas labeled D is the loss of total surplus—a deadweight loss.

Page 38: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Import Quotas

An import quota is a quantitative restriction on the import of a good that limits the maximum quantity of a good that may be imported in a given period.

Page 39: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

The Effects of an Import Quota

With free international trade, the world price of a T-shirt is $5 and the United States imports 40 million T-shirts a year.

Imagine that the United States imposes a quota of 10 million on imported T-shirts.

Figure 8.7 shows the effect of the quota on the market for T-shirts in the United States.

Page 40: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Figure 8.7(a) shows the market before the government imposes the quota.

The price is the world price of $5 and

1. The United States imports 40 million

T-shirts.

Page 41: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Figure 8.5(b) shows the market with the quota.

2. With an import quota of 10 million T-shirts, the supply of T-shirts in the United States becomes

S + quota.

3. The price rises to $7.

Page 42: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

With the higher price, Americans decrease the number of T-shirts they buy to 45 million a year.

U.S. garment makers increase production to 35 million T-shirts a year.

4. Imports of T-shirts decrease to the quota of 10 million.

Page 43: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Winners, Losers, and the Social Loss from an Import Quota

When the U.S. government imposes a quota on imported T-shirts:

• U.S. producers of T-shirts gain.• U.S. consumers of T-shirts lose.• Importers of T-shirts gain.• U.S. consumers lose more than U.S. producers gain

and importers gain.

Figure 8.8 illustrates the winners and losers with a quota.

Page 44: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Figure 8.8(a) shows the total surplus with free international trade.

The world price is $5 a T-shirt.

1. Imports

2. Consumer surplus

3. Producer surplus

4. The gains from free trade

Total surplus is maximized.

Page 45: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

The import quota raises the U.S. price of a T-shirt to $7.

The quantity of T-shirts produced in the United States increases and the quantity bought decreases.

5. Imports decrease.

Page 46: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

6. Consumer surplus shrinks to the green area.

7. Producer surplus expands to the bluearea.

Area B is a transfer from consumer surplus to producer surplus.

8. Importers’ profit is the sum of the two areas C.

Page 47: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

9. The sum of the two areas labeled D is the loss of total

surplus—a deadweight loss created by the import quota.

Page 48: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Other Import Barriers

Two sets of policies that influence imports are• Health, safety, and regulation barriers• Voluntary export restraints

Thousands of detailed health, safety, and other regulations restrict international trade.

For example, U.S. food imports are examined by the Food and Drug Administration to determine whether the food is “pure, wholesome, safe to eat, and produced under sanitary conditions.”

Page 49: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

A voluntary export restraint is like a quota allocated to a foreign exporter of the good.

A voluntary export restraint decreases imports just like a quota does but the foreign exporter gets the profit from the gap between the domestic price and the world price.

Page 50: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.3 INTERNATIONAL TRADE RESTRICTIONS

Export Subsidies

A subsidy is a payment made by the government to a producer.

An export subsidy is a payment made by the government to a domestic producer of an exported good.

Export subsidies bring gains to domestic producers, but they result in overproduction in the domestic economy and underproduction in the rest of the world and so create a deadweight loss.

Page 51: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Despite the fact that free trade promotes prosperity for all countries, trade is restricted.

Three Traditional Arguments for Protection

Three traditional arguments for restricting international trade are

• The national security argument • The infant industry argument• The dumping argument

Page 52: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

The National Security Argument

A country must protect industries that produce defense equipment and armaments and those on which the defense industries rely for their raw materials and other intermediate inputs.

This argument for protection can be taken too far.

Page 53: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

The Infant-Industry Argument

The infant-industry argument is that it is necessary to protect a new industry from import competition to enable it to grow into a mature industry that can compete in world markets.

This argument is based on the concept of dynamic competitive advantage, which can arise from learning-by-doing.

Learning-by-doing is a powerful engine of productivity growth, but this fact does not justify protection.

Page 54: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

The Dumping Argument

Dumping occurs when a foreign firm sells its exports at a lower price than its cost of production.

Two reasons why a firm might engage in dumping are• Predatory pricing—when a firm sells below cost in

the hope of driving out competitors• Subsidy—a firm receiving a subsidy can sell at

price below cost and make a profit.

Page 55: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

This argument does not justify protection because

1. It is virtually impossible to determine a firm’s costs.

2. If there was a natural global monopoly, it would be more efficient to regulate it than to impose a tariff against it.

3. If the market is truly a global monopoly, better to regulate it rather than restrict trade.

Page 56: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Four Newer Arguments for Protection

Other common arguments for protection are that it• Saves jobs• Allows us to compete with cheap foreign labor• Brings diversity and stability• Penalizes lax environmental standards

Page 57: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Saves Jobs

The idea that buying foreign goods costs domestic jobs is wrong.

Free trade destroys some jobs and creates other better jobs.

Free trade also increases foreign incomes and enables foreigners to buy more domestic production.

Protection to save particular jobs is very costly.

Page 58: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Allows Us to Compete with Cheap Foreign Labor

The idea that a high-wage country cannot compete with a low-wage country is wrong.

Low-wage labor is less productive than high-wage labor.

And wages and productivity tell us nothing about the source of gains from trade, which is comparative advantage.

Page 59: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Brings Diversity and Stability

A diversified investment portfolio is less risky than one that has all of its eggs in one basket. The same is true for an economy’s production.

A diversified economy fluctuates less than an economy that produces only one or two goods, …

but big, rich, diversified economies like those of the United States, Japan, and Europe do not have this type of stability problem.

Page 60: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Penalizes Lax Environmental Standards

The idea that protection is good for the environment is wrong.

Free trade increases incomes and poor countries have lower environmental standards than rich countries.

These countries cannot afford to spend as much on the environment as a rich country can and sometimes they have a comparative advantage at doing “dirty” work, which helps the global environment achieve higher environmental standards.

Page 61: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Why Is International Trade Restricted?The key reason why international trade restrictions are popular in the United States and most other developed countries is an activity called rent seeking.

Rent seeking is lobbying and other political activity that seeks to capture the gains from trade.

You’ve seen that free trade benefits consumers but shrinks the producer surplus of firms that compete in markets with imports.

Page 62: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Those who gain from free trade are the millions of consumers of low-cost imports. But the benefit per individual consumer is small.

Those who lose are the producers of import-competing items. Compared to the millions of consumers, there are only a few thousand producers.

Page 63: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Because the gain from a tariff is large, producers have a strong incentive to incur the expense of lobbying for a tariff and against free trade.

Because each consumer’s loss is small, consumers have little incentive to organize and incur the expense of lobbying for free trade.

The gain from free trade for any one person is too small for that person to spend much time or money on a political organization to lobby for free trade.

Page 64: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

8.4 THE CASE AGAINST PROTECTION

Each group weighs benefits against costs and chooses the best action for themselves.

But the group against free trade will undertake more political lobbying than will the group for free trade.

Page 65: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

Economists generally agree that the gains from globalization vastly outweigh the losses.

But there are both winners and losers.The U.S. consumer is a big winner.

Globalization has brought iPods, Wii games, Nike shoes, and a wide range of other products to our shops at ever lower prices.

© 2015 Pearson

Page 66: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

The Indian (and Chinese and other Asian) worker is another big winner.

Globalization has brought a wider range of more interesting jobs and higher wages.

© 2015 Pearson

Page 67: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

The U.S. (and European) textile workers and furniture makers are big losers.

Their jobs have disappeared and many of them have struggled to find new jobs even when they’ve been willing to take a pay cut.

© 2015 Pearson

Page 68: Global Markets in Action

© 2015 Pearson

But one of the biggest losers is the African farmer.

Blocked from global food markets by trade restrictions and subsidies in the United States and Europe, globalization is leaving much of Africa on the sidelines.

© 2015 Pearson